30.11.2012 Views

Sergio Amadeu da Silveira - Cidadania e Redes Digitais

Sergio Amadeu da Silveira - Cidadania e Redes Digitais

Sergio Amadeu da Silveira - Cidadania e Redes Digitais

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

eng<br />

c i t i z e n s h i p a n d d i g i t a l n e t w o r k s<br />

relationships of mutual reinforcement or mutual dependence. We can distinguish<br />

the relationships between positive forms — based on collaboration and oriented to<br />

mutual benefit — or negative ones — parasitism or depre<strong>da</strong>tion. These relationships<br />

have a fun<strong>da</strong>mental role in the creation of new digital species that are spreading the<br />

center of power, taking the system back to the citizen. In order for this positive dynamics<br />

to be passed on, a digital ecosystem must develop an infrastructure oriented<br />

to services that are public resources. In this sense, a digital ecosystem is defined as<br />

a digital self-organizing structure oriented to the creation of a digital environment<br />

distributed in a network. It is characterized by a series of elements: shared knowledge,<br />

open technologies, stan<strong>da</strong>rds and protocols, soli<strong>da</strong>rity cooperation and new<br />

business models.<br />

The implementation of such digital environment has the structure of procommons,<br />

which Benkler defines as institutional spaces in which one can exercise a certain<br />

degree of freedom regarding the restrictions imposed by the markets. These<br />

restrictions appear, frequently, as property relationships, which define who has control<br />

over which resources, and what the relationships between agents due to the<br />

possession or lack of a determined asset or resource are. This does not mean that the<br />

common assets are anarchic spaces, but that agents can perform thereon with a different<br />

logic than that of the market, avoiding the paradoxes produced in the Theory<br />

of Games when an agent seeks the maximization of the utility expected of their<br />

decisions. In other words, that is what happens when one performs in strategic environments,<br />

wherein various agents perform in a manner in which the decisions of one<br />

of them depend on the decisions of the others, following the rules of the parametric<br />

environments, those wherein the world and the set of possibilities already given are<br />

not modifiable by the decisions of other subjects 3 . The use of the common assets can<br />

3. An example based on the model of the Tragedy of the Commons (Hardin, 1968) can by enlightening.<br />

It is a cattle-raising community wherein the pastures and water are commons, in which each owner<br />

shall desire to increment their personal benefit by increasing their cattle, maximizing their gains, and<br />

therefore, their profit. But if all others do the same, the commons (pastures and water) will wear out,<br />

and all cattle raisers of the community will end in misery. Without agreeing with the conclusions<br />

extracted by Hardin from this mental experience, it is important to notice that the sum of individual<br />

benefits does not automatically lead to a collective benefit. In this case, the appearance of the rules for<br />

an individual (parametric) rationality converts this strategy into an absolutely illogical and counterproductive<br />

action from the collective (strategic) point of view. From this latter perspective, one gets<br />

a greater benefit when cooperating and when the personal benefit is restricted. This problem demonstrates<br />

the failure of the egoistical strategies in face of the cooperative strategies under certain circum-<br />

24

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!