04.09.2013 Views

Het schemergebied voor faillissement - Höcker Advocaten

Het schemergebied voor faillissement - Höcker Advocaten

Het schemergebied voor faillissement - Höcker Advocaten

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Summary<br />

– or as economists call it: the costs of financial distress – cause creditors not to<br />

obtain a market-efficient compensation for their risk as investor. Nevertheless,<br />

economists do recognise that sufficient equity is necessary for an optimal<br />

financing structure. This research has tried to come to a general but only<br />

conceptual explanation for the existence of trade credit, in light of the existing<br />

moral hazard for creditors. The reason that trade creditors give trade credit<br />

although not receiving a market-efficient compensation as investor, is explained<br />

by the fact that trade creditors are not investors but competitors trying to<br />

influence their results by obtaining and giving trade credit.<br />

Although the preferred position of financiers, through secured debt,<br />

exists in some form in all Western countries, as of yet the basis for its legitimacy<br />

lacked. This is to be found in the positive effect of financial leverage if and as<br />

long as a positive profitability of the company exists.<br />

XIV.5 The Pauliana-standard<br />

The Pauliana-standard applies to individual transactions with counter parties,<br />

which will cause other creditors do get less. The standard is based on the paritas<br />

creditorum. It is not a standard, making transactions illegal. It is a standard that<br />

imposes sharing if bankruptcy is to occur in the future in accordance with social<br />

intercourse. The Pauliana-standard requires in principle: (i) recourse insolvency:<br />

(ii) knowledge of threatening insolvency, which indeed follows later; (iii)<br />

anticipation of detriment to other creditors as a consequence of the transaction.<br />

The effect of the Pauliana-standard is relatively subdued compared to the<br />

(prolonged) Beklamel-standard, because: (a) the (prolonged) Beklamel-standard<br />

already ratifies harm to creditors in general; (b) the Pauliana-standard only<br />

considers individual transactions and (c) most parties not being insiders will not<br />

have knowledge of the imminent insolvency. If the Beklamel-standard is being<br />

violated, the Pauliana-standard is only relevant to transactions out of generosity.<br />

Because the Pauliana-standard is no more than a mechanism for distribution and<br />

sharing, the required knowledge of imputing any action is different than of the<br />

(prolonged) Beklamel-standard. This research shows that there is no good<br />

reason to differentiate in transactions whether or not an obligation to perform the<br />

transaction exists. The articles 47 and 53 of the Dutch Bankruptcy Code are<br />

unjustified.<br />

Because shareholders and financiers may have specific knowledge of a<br />

threatening bankruptcy, the Pauliana-standard has a specific application for the<br />

financing structure of the loss-making company. In case of dividend or financing<br />

against new collateral, a solvency test should be performed if the company is<br />

loss making, where after the solvability should at least be ‘sufficient’. 1316<br />

1316 ‘Sufficient’ solvability according to standards of Dutch banks vary between 15% and<br />

30%, depending on the nature of the business and valuation methods.<br />

529

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!