28.12.2013 Views

értekezés - Budapesti Corvinus Egyetem

értekezés - Budapesti Corvinus Egyetem

értekezés - Budapesti Corvinus Egyetem

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

8. függelék - Az FSS [1993] modellt alátámasztó empirikus eredmények<br />

To empirically validate the impact of hedging on the coordination of investment and<br />

financing policies, the relationship between corporate risk management and liquidity can<br />

be analyzed. The results show that companies with low liquidity (small quick ratio or<br />

current ratio) are more likely to hedge than companies with high liquidity, which suggests<br />

that firms hold liquid assets as a substitute for hedging. 176 By the same token, Gay and<br />

Nam [1998] demonstrate that firms with a strong correlation between cash flow and<br />

investment expenses are naturally hedged and thus use fewer derivatives. Allayannis and<br />

Mozumdar [2000] show that investment cash flow sensitivity is lower for firms that hedge<br />

with foreign currency derivatives, consistent with Froot et al. [1993]. 177<br />

Deshmukh and Vogt [2000] test whether the difference in the sensitivity of investment<br />

spending to cash flow is significant across hedgers and non-hedgers, and find that, other<br />

things equal, the investment spending of hedgers is less sensitive to cash flow than for nonhedgers.<br />

Furthermore, their results suggest that the sensitivity of investment to cash flow is<br />

lower when the extent of hedging is higher, supporting the notion that firms appear to<br />

hedge to reduce their cash flow volatility and their reliance on external funds.<br />

Nance, Smith, and Smithson [1993] show that high R&D firms are more likely to hedge,<br />

which fits very well into the Froot et. al. [1993] model. First, it may be more difficult for<br />

R&D-intensive firms to raise external finance either because their principally intangible<br />

assets are not good collateral, or because there is likely to be more asymmetric information<br />

about the quality of their new projects. Second, R&D growth options are likely to represent<br />

valuable investments whose attractiveness is not correlated with easily hedgeable risks<br />

impacting internal cash flows, which would imply full hedging as per the model. 178<br />

176<br />

Graham/Rogers [1999], Geczy/Minton/Schrand [1997], Berkman/Bradbury [1999],<br />

Nance/Smith/Smithson [1993]<br />

177 Carter et al. [2003], however, criticizes the nature of Allayannis/Mozumdar’s [2000] test as it can not<br />

differentiate between whether the given results suggest that firms hedge to ensure sufficient amounts of cash<br />

to take advantage of valuable investment opportunities during unfavorable cash flow stock (as per Froot et<br />

al., 1993), or hedgers may be insulating investment from the scrutiny of outside investors (put forward by<br />

Tufano, 1998) so that managers can obtain private benefits from ‘pet projects’. See below for Tufano’s<br />

[1998] ‘pet project’ hypothesis.<br />

178 Allayannis and Ofek [2001], Dolde [1995], Gay and Nam [1998], Géczy et al. [1997] also find that<br />

hedging increases with the level of R&D expenditures.<br />

176

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!