15.02.2013 Views

Wirtschaftsgeographie - Institut für Wirtschafts- und ...

Wirtschaftsgeographie - Institut für Wirtschafts- und ...

Wirtschaftsgeographie - Institut für Wirtschafts- und ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong><br />

<strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

BUCHENVERLAG<br />

Informal Dynamics<br />

in Asian Megacities<br />

56. Jahrgang, 2012, Heft 1-2


Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

The German Journal of Economic Geography · 56. Jahrgang 2012 · Heft 1-2· Begründet von Dr. Irmfried Siedentop<br />

Die Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> wird in Social Sciences Citation Index (SSCI), Social Scisearch <strong>und</strong> Journal Citation<br />

Reports/Social Sciences Edition gelistet <strong>und</strong> ausgewertet. – The German Journal of Economic Geography is indexed and abstracted<br />

in Social Sciences Citation Index (SSCI), Social Scisearch and Journal Citation Reports/Social Sciences Edition.<br />

Herausgeber – Editors<br />

Prof. Dr. Walter Thomi Prof. i. R. Dr. Karl Vorlaufer<br />

<strong>Institut</strong> <strong>für</strong> Geowissenschaften Heidenfeldstr. 11<br />

Fachgruppe <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> 65812 Bad Soden am Taunus<br />

Martin-Luther-Universität Halle-Wittenberg<br />

Von-Seckendorff-Platz 4<br />

06099 Halle (Saale)<br />

Wissenschaftlicher Beirat – Advisory Board<br />

Prof. Dr. Christian Berndt, Zürich Prof. Dr. Jürgen Oßenbrügge, Hamburg<br />

Prof. i. R. Dr. Winfried Flüchter, Duisburg-Essen Prof. i. R. Dr. Eike W. Schamp, Frankfurt am Main<br />

Prof. Dr. Martina Fromhold-Eisebith, Aachen Prof. Dr. Rolf Sternberg, Hannover<br />

Prof. Dr. Johannes Glückler, Heidelberg Prof. Dr. Simone Strambach, Marburg<br />

Prof. Dr. Thomas Krings, Freiburg i. Br.<br />

Schriftleitung – Editorial Management<br />

Dr. Helmut Schneider<br />

Arbeitsgebiet Kulturgeographie (Fakultät <strong>für</strong> Gesellschaftswissenschaften) – Universität Duisburg-Essen<br />

Campus Duisburg, Lotharstr. 65, D-47048 Duisburg<br />

Tel.: 0203379 1365/1742, Fax: 02033793516, eMail: helmut.schneider@uni-due.de<br />

Internet: www.wirtschaftsgeographie.com<br />

Inhalt<br />

Editorial: Informal dynamics of economic processes – some remarks<br />

on the potential of the informality concept<br />

Susanne Meyer: The world’s factory and informal ties: Organisation of firm networks in the<br />

1 – 8<br />

electronics industry in the Greater Pearl River Delta, China<br />

Frank Bickenbach, Wan-Hsin Liu; Firm characteristics and informal governance of business<br />

9 – 24<br />

operations in the Pearl River Delta, China<br />

Markus Keck, Hans-Georg Bohle, Wolfgang-Peter Zingel: Dealing with insecurity. Informal relations<br />

25 – 42<br />

and risk adaptation among food wholesalers in Dhaka, Bangladesh<br />

Pamela Hartmann Kilian, Daniel Schiller, Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality and labour turnover in the<br />

43 – 57<br />

electronics industry of the Pearl River Delta, China: Contrasting employer and employee perspectives<br />

Wenying Fu, Daniel Schiller, Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity and organizational<br />

58 – 79<br />

proximity in product innovation: Empirical insight from the Pearl River Delta, China<br />

Friederike Schröder, Michael Waibel: Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta:<br />

80 – 96<br />

Investigating economic restructuring in Guangzhou 97 – 112<br />

Buchbesprechungen 113 – 120<br />

Moderation: Dr. Daniel Schiller, <strong>Institut</strong> <strong>für</strong> <strong>Wirtschafts</strong>- <strong>und</strong> Kulturgeographie, Leibniz Universität Hannover, Schneiderberg<br />

50 , 30167 Hannover , eMail: schiller@wigeo.uni-hannover.de<br />

Mitarbeiterinnen <strong>und</strong> Mitarbeiter des vorliegenden Heftes: Frank Bickenbach, <strong>Institut</strong>e <strong>für</strong> Weltwirtschaft Kiel, Hindenburgufer<br />

66, 24105 Kiel, eMail: frank.bickenbach@ifw-kiel.de; Prof. Dr. Hans-Georg Bohle, Geographisches <strong>Institut</strong>,<br />

Universität Bonn, Meckenheimer Allee 166, 53115 Bonn, eMail: bohle@geographie.uni-bonn.de; Prof. Dr. Revilla Diez,<br />

<strong>Institut</strong> <strong>für</strong> <strong>Wirtschafts</strong>- <strong>und</strong> Kulturgeographie, Leibniz Universität Hannover, Schneiderberg 50, 30167 Hannover, eMail:<br />

diez@wigeo.uni-hannover.de; Dr. Wenying Fu, School of Geography, South China Normal University, Zhongshan West<br />

Road No. 55, Tianhe District, Gungazhou, Peoples Republic of China, eMail: ferlicity31@163.com; Pamela Hartmann Kilian,<br />

Geographisches <strong>Institut</strong>, Universität Köln, Albertus-Magnus-Platz, 50923 Köln, eMail: pamela.hartmann@unikoeln.de;<br />

Markus Keck, Geographisches <strong>Institut</strong>, Universität Bonn, Meckenheimer Allee 166, 53115 Bonn, eMail:<br />

markus.keck@geographie.uni-bonn.de; Prof. Dr. Frauke Kraas, Geographisches <strong>Institut</strong>, Universität Köln, Albertus-Magnus-Platz,<br />

50923 Köln, eMail: f.kraas@uni-koeln.de; Wan-Hsin Liu, <strong>Institut</strong>e <strong>für</strong> Weltwirtschaft Kiel, Hindenburgufer 66,<br />

24105 Kiel, eMail: wan-hsin.liu@ifw-kiel.de; Dr. Susanne Meyer, Joanneum Research Forschungsgesellschaft mbH, Policies<br />

– Centre for Economic and Innovation Research, Sensengasse 1, 1090 Wien, Österreich, eMail: susanne. meyer@ joanneum.at;<br />

Friederike Schröder, HafenCity Universität Hamburg, Averhoffstr. 38, 22085 Hamburg, eMail: friederike.<br />

schroeder@hcu-hamburg.de; Dr. Michael Waibel, Geographisches <strong>Institut</strong>, Universität Hamburg, B<strong>und</strong>esstr. 55, 20146<br />

Hamburg, eMail:waibel@geowiss.uni-hamburg.de; Wolfgang-Peter Zingel, Südasien-<strong>Institut</strong>, Abt. Internationale Wirtschaft,<br />

Universität Heidelberg, Im Neuenheimer Feld 330, 69120 Heidelberg, eMail: h93@ix.urz.uni-heidelberg.de<br />

Titelfoto: Die Entstehung neuer Megastädte in China <strong>und</strong> die informelle Dynamik des Industrialisierungs- <strong>und</strong> Urbanisierungsprozesses<br />

wird in der an Hongkong grenzenden Metropole Shenzhen besonders augenfällig. Wo heute mehr als zehn<br />

Millionen Menschen leben, befanden sich vor 30 Jahren nur vereinzelte Fischerdörfer (Foto: Daniel Schiller, August 2009).


Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> Jg. 56 (2012) Heft 1-2, S.1-8<br />

Editorial<br />

Informal dynamics of economic processes<br />

Remarks on the potential of the informality concept<br />

The aim of this special issue is to expand the<br />

concept of informality by incorporating recent<br />

approaches from institutional economics and<br />

governance theory. The concept is applied empirically<br />

to analyse economic processes in the<br />

context of mega-urban regions and global<br />

change. This introduction outlines the conceptual<br />

approach by focusing on the advancements<br />

in comparison to earlier informality paradigms.<br />

It discusses the added value of a new informality<br />

perspective for economic geography and<br />

explains how the individual papers fit in. The<br />

contributions to this special issue are based on<br />

research projects that were carried out within<br />

the Priority Programme (SPP) 1233 “Megacities<br />

– Megachallenge: The Informal Dynamics<br />

of Global Change” f<strong>und</strong>ed by the German Research<br />

Fo<strong>und</strong>ation (Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft),<br />

whose support of the projects is<br />

thankfully acknowledged.<br />

The shifting conceptualisations<br />

of informality over time<br />

The terms ‘informal’ and ‘informality’ have a<br />

connotation of inferiority in the sense of ‘unofficial’<br />

or ‘without form’, but they can also be<br />

<strong>und</strong>erstood in a positive way as ‘casual’ with a<br />

focus on freedom of action. This simple illustration<br />

shows the ambivalent character of informality.<br />

The term informality was first used<br />

in the 1970s by the ILO (1972) and HART<br />

(1973) in several reports about the informal<br />

sector in developing countries. Their informal<br />

sector comprises all economic activities that<br />

are not organised in line with the legal, technological<br />

and managerial standards of modern<br />

sectors in developed countries. By drawing a<br />

clear line between the formal and the informal,<br />

these studies focused on those niches of the<br />

economy that (i) helped migrants in urban areas<br />

and slum dwellers to survive (survival<br />

economies), (ii) carried out illegal activities in<br />

the <strong>und</strong>ergro<strong>und</strong> scene without official regis-<br />

tration and unnoticed by the tax administration<br />

(shadow economies), or (iii) micro enterprises<br />

without any substantial capital stock that do<br />

not produce for the markets of the formal economy<br />

(subsistence economy) (PORTES et al.<br />

1989; CHEN/GEREFFI 1994). German-speaking<br />

human geographers used the concept of the informal<br />

sector intensively during the late 1980s<br />

and early 1990s (c.f. SCHAMP 1989, 1993; ES-<br />

CHER 1999a). A distinct structural debate<br />

emerged aro<strong>und</strong> the informalisation of labour<br />

during the post-Fordist transition. Formal wage<br />

labour became the leading form of labour organisation<br />

of Fordism and even spread to the<br />

economic periphery. From a Marxist point of<br />

view, this is not seen as a success of labour<br />

unions, but rather as being due to the benefits<br />

of formal labour for the capitalist system. At<br />

the same time, informal labour still persisted,<br />

for example in the form of domestic work, subsistence<br />

economy and production of petty<br />

goods. A renaissance of the informal economy<br />

was more recently caused by post-Fordism and<br />

also occurred in economic centres (KOMLOSY<br />

et al. 1997). While the Marxist tradition interpreted<br />

this shift as a coordinated attack on the<br />

organised labour class, other scholars of industrial<br />

organisation economics referred to the<br />

overall gains in efficiency and flexibility of a<br />

more informal organisation of economic systems<br />

and focused on the possibilities for prosperity<br />

that this new production paradigm implicated<br />

(PIORE/SABEL 1984).<br />

This earlier informality concept was problematic<br />

due to its dualistic nature that implied a<br />

clear distinction, and which turned out to be<br />

less useful in practical research. SCHAMP<br />

(1989,12) pointed out that the formal and the<br />

informal sectors were rather the extrema of a<br />

continuum. The heterogeneity of the informality<br />

definition made it virtually intangible in<br />

empirical studies, despite the fact that the<br />

coarse character (ESCHER 1999b) of the concept<br />

resulted in its ubiquitous application dur-


2 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

ing its time. Finally, the focus of research on<br />

informality and the informal sector was mainly<br />

limited to poor developing countries with an<br />

emphasis on urban areas. This hindered the integration<br />

of informality in modern growth and<br />

development theories in economic geography.<br />

The dualistic character of the criteria that defined<br />

the informal sector resulted in the lack of<br />

a so<strong>und</strong> theoretical fo<strong>und</strong>ation of informality,<br />

which became clearly apparent in comparative<br />

studies of different countries and regions. In<br />

this context, the quote ‘The informal sector is<br />

like an elephant: we may not be able to define<br />

it precisely, but we know it when we see it’ is<br />

attributed to Hernando de Soto (MEAD/MOR-<br />

RISSON 1996). Obviously, this fuzziness impedes<br />

the application of the concept for empirical<br />

research and policy recommendations and<br />

points out the necessity of a conceptual clarification.<br />

MEAD/MORRISSON (1996) declared that<br />

they would not use the term ‘informal sector’<br />

in future studies. FRIELING (1989, 74) stated<br />

that it was not possible to overcome the vague<br />

terminology of the research object ‘informal<br />

sector’, and that the term was merely <strong>und</strong>erstood<br />

as a residual that was inferior to the formal<br />

sector. The interpretation of informality as<br />

a residual category or something contrary to<br />

the rules is problematic in that it requires a definition<br />

of what is regular or normal. The formal-informal<br />

dichotomy of the informality literature<br />

in the 1980s and 1990s was based on<br />

formal laws defined by the dominant legal system<br />

in Europe and North America. Such an Eurocentric<br />

perspective overlooks the fact that<br />

the legal tradition of the Code Napoleon of<br />

1804 might be less meaningful in other parts of<br />

the world. Therefore, an informality definition<br />

that is applicable in other macro-institutional<br />

environments should be based on a generalisable<br />

concept.<br />

The recent debate surro<strong>und</strong>ing informality<br />

shifted the focus away from a dichotomous definition<br />

towards an integrative framework that<br />

is embedded within current conceptual developments<br />

in economics and social science.<br />

Based on a new <strong>und</strong>erstanding of the state and<br />

governance, the level of practice, regulatory<br />

systems and process-related elements is targeted<br />

instead of persisting with the investigation<br />

of structural elements. The concept of informality<br />

derived from this exercise avoids a<br />

strict distinction between formality and informality,<br />

and concerns itself with the interdependence<br />

of social process and structure. This al-<br />

lows an examination of informal dynamics<br />

both within a continuum (SINDZINGRE 2007)<br />

and from a multi-dimensional perspective that<br />

focuses on the informal dynamics of institutional<br />

arrangements rather than on a static informal<br />

sector. As a result, modern approaches<br />

to informality are neither predetermined as being<br />

an inferior residual category nor restricted<br />

to developing countries, but informal practices<br />

are <strong>und</strong>erstood as a governance mode in their<br />

own right that is intertwined with formal institutional<br />

arrangements. Indications of such an<br />

integrative perspective can already be fo<strong>und</strong> in<br />

critical reviews of the informal sector by<br />

CHENG/GEREFFI (1994) and FRIELING (1989).<br />

The advancement of the informality concept in<br />

economic geography is driven by the three<br />

strands of institutional approaches in economics<br />

and social science (MARTIN 2000). They<br />

have the potential to replace the older institutional<br />

tradition of the discipline that stressed<br />

the static-structural and historical-deterministic<br />

approach by Veblen (RAFIQUI 2009). <strong>Institut</strong>ional<br />

arrangements for the governance of organisations<br />

and collective goods, as introduced<br />

by COASE (1937), WILLIAMSON (1975), and OS-<br />

TROM (1990) form the starting point for a redefinition<br />

of informality and are central for the<br />

following explanations. New institutionalism<br />

with its central authors SCOTT (1987), DIMAG-<br />

GIO (2001) and Powell (POWELL/DIMAGGIO<br />

1991) provides additional elements from organisational<br />

studies. The historical <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />

of institutions by NORTH (1990) adds a<br />

dynamic-evolutionary perspective on institutional<br />

change. Furthermore, concepts of vulnerability<br />

and resilience as well as the sustainable<br />

livelihood approach that dominates geographical<br />

development studies allow for the integration<br />

of an institutional informality concept<br />

within the development debate.<br />

Informality in new institutional economics<br />

and organisation science<br />

<strong>Institut</strong>ions are defined in a broad sense as a<br />

system of rules (HODGSON 2006). These rules<br />

comprise consciously created and externally<br />

enforced formal rules, for example laws, and<br />

self-enforcing, informal ones, for example traditions,<br />

norms, conventions, or customs<br />

(NORTH 1990). Additionally, New <strong>Institut</strong>ional<br />

Economics (NIE) distinguishes between rules<br />

(= institutions) and actors (= organisations or


individuals) who are interdependent. The behaviour<br />

of actors is restricted and incentivised<br />

by institutions, but actors are also involved in<br />

the creation and transformation of institutions<br />

in a co-evolutionary way. Three levels for a<br />

conceptual redefinition of informality are derived:<br />

(i) informality of the institutional environment,<br />

(ii) informality of institutional<br />

arrangements, and (iii) informality of processes<br />

within organisations. An informality concept<br />

that is informed by institutional economics<br />

is not primarily focused on the structural<br />

elements (Which transactions are carried<br />

out?), but on the <strong>und</strong>erlying practices (How<br />

are transactions carried out?) and dynamic<br />

processes (What impact does co-evolution of<br />

institutional environment and arrangements<br />

have on institutional change?).<br />

<strong>Institut</strong>ional environment: The institutional environment<br />

has an informal and a formal component<br />

which are intentionally <strong>und</strong>erstood as<br />

interdependent in a co-evolutionary relationship<br />

by NORTH (1990), not in a dualistic, mutually<br />

exclusive way. Acceptance and enforceability<br />

of new formal institutions depends on<br />

the fit with existing informal institutions. The<br />

externally imposed adoption of rules and regulations<br />

during the transition of previously<br />

planned economies into market economies is a<br />

frequently cited example (STIGLITZ 1999;<br />

ROLAND 2000). It has been shown by DE SOTO<br />

(2000) that a lack of alignment of formal rules<br />

of capitalism with informal institutions resulted<br />

in dysfunctional institutional frameworks or<br />

institutional chaos. A central question of this<br />

strand of institutional informality at the process<br />

level is whether the institutional environment<br />

is better shaped by governments or related public<br />

actors in a top-down manner, or in a self-organised<br />

bottom-up manner through unintended<br />

effects of the aggregate behaviour of individuals.<br />

OSTROM (1990) explained why one should<br />

be sceptical about leaving formation and enforcement<br />

of institutions for collective action<br />

mainly to governmental bodies, and proved it<br />

by using the example of the commons. The<br />

Austrian school of economics (HAYEK 1973)<br />

has also indicated that the aggregate order of<br />

economy and space is brought about by complex<br />

interaction of its actors. Self-organisation<br />

and emergence of the institutional environment<br />

are <strong>und</strong>erstood as an expression of informality.<br />

<strong>Institut</strong>ional arrangements: <strong>Institut</strong>ional arrangements,<br />

i.e. contracts among economic ac-<br />

Editorial 3<br />

tors in a broad sense, are the central focus of<br />

the informality perspective in NIE. GUHA-<br />

KHASNOBIS et al. (2006) distinguish between<br />

two levels which can be applied for the analysis<br />

of informality of institutional arrangements.<br />

At the first level, the interdependence of an institutional<br />

arrangement with its formal and informal<br />

institutional environment is described<br />

and the explanatory power of the institutional<br />

environment for the arrangement is exposed.<br />

At the second level, the structuration of the institutional<br />

arrangement itself is depicted in several<br />

dimensions, the formal and informal aspects<br />

of which are not necessarily mutually exclusive,<br />

but mostly complementary. In a<br />

multi-dimensional approach, LI (2007) defined<br />

five dimensions to characterise the formal and<br />

informal contents of institutional arrangements:<br />

formation (exogenous vs. endogenous),<br />

codification (explicit vs. implicit), enforcement<br />

(tight and strict vs. loose and flexible), power<br />

(hierarchical vs. horizontal) and personalisation<br />

(depersonalised vs. personalised). Informality<br />

thus possesses a subjective, emotional<br />

and personal character, while formality is objectively<br />

based on facts and cognition. It is important<br />

to mention that this should not result in<br />

new dichotomies, but rather in multiple dimensions<br />

that allow for continuous specification of<br />

institutional arrangements within the formality-informality<br />

nexus.<br />

The multidimensional, non-dichotomous character<br />

of informality is illustrated by comparing<br />

the advantages of particular institutional<br />

arrangements. In most real world situations,<br />

economic activities are embedded flexibly in a<br />

dynamic and complex institutional environment.<br />

In such a situation, informality is a<br />

strategic opportunity to complement formal<br />

arrangements proactively. In close connection<br />

to NIE, contract theory (HART/MOORE 1999,<br />

2004) has shown that most contracts are unable<br />

to comprehend completely the object that is to<br />

be regulated in a formal way due to complexity<br />

and uncertainty. Therefore, contracts remain<br />

incomplete at the time they are concluded and<br />

are specified and modified in an informal<br />

process during the contract period. This<br />

process is often socially embedded. Nevertheless,<br />

if a high level of uncertainty is connected<br />

with the institutional environment at a particular<br />

location or in a market, it might be necessary<br />

to adapt informal arrangements as a passive<br />

reaction to non-enforceable formal<br />

arrangements.


4 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

<strong>Institut</strong>ions in organisation science: Sociological<br />

institutionalism, with SCOTT (1995),<br />

DIMAGGIO/POWELL (1991), and in Germany<br />

MAYNTZ/SCHARPF (1995) being its main authors,<br />

looks at economic activity as a process<br />

that is embedded in a socio-institutional system<br />

or culture-specific social network. Informality<br />

is defined in this approach as interaction between<br />

individuals or groups which could be described,<br />

for example, as casual, trust-based and<br />

reciprocal. This normative-collectivist perspective<br />

adds to the rational choice institutionalism<br />

of NIE by explaining why trust is of critical<br />

importance in economic and social life and<br />

why cooperative arrangements are formed<br />

even in addition to the transaction cost argument.<br />

The aim is not to deduce the most costefficient<br />

institutional arrangement in order to<br />

reach an economic goal. In fact, embedded institutional<br />

arrangements are not just strategic<br />

means in an economic sense, but they also<br />

shape the preferences and identities of a society.<br />

Their impact is not necessarily in the form<br />

of increasing efficiency, but also in the provision<br />

of societal legitimacy of individual actions.<br />

The embeddedness perspective on informality<br />

becomes important if culture-specific<br />

aspects are introduced to explain why personal<br />

trust-based networks are chosen for economic<br />

transactions in situations where alternative<br />

governance forms are available and useful.<br />

This approach is of importance to <strong>und</strong>erstand<br />

the relevance of informality for interactive<br />

learning and the related processes of transforming<br />

and exchanging knowledge. There is a<br />

close link with the concept of social capital.<br />

Research on social embeddedness of economic<br />

processes has also shown that informal networks<br />

may have a negative impact (GRA-<br />

NOVETTER 1973; GRABHER 1993). The starting<br />

point of this argument is the exclusiveness that<br />

is an almost necessary outcome of stable, trustbased<br />

networks and that is responsible for the<br />

desired effects of these networks. However,<br />

this feature often results in the judgement of alternative<br />

options based on the position of the<br />

actor in the network, and is no longer fair and<br />

unbiased. A lack of transparency as well as<br />

gatekeeper functions of central actors or<br />

groups in the network can be responsible for<br />

lock-ins or cronyism in the long run.<br />

The relevance of institutional approaches for<br />

economic geography has been shown prominently<br />

by MARTIN (2000), who explained why<br />

the spatial differences of institutional environments<br />

and arrangements and their effects on<br />

the space economy are important topics for the<br />

discipline. A major argument for the spatial dimension<br />

of NIE is the fact that institutions are<br />

not equal across space, but are localised at particular<br />

points in space and are territorially<br />

bo<strong>und</strong>ed in their effects. Formal institutions<br />

created by the state are particularly restricted<br />

by administrative borders. However, informal<br />

or self-organised institutions also contain a<br />

spatial dimension, since they came into being<br />

due to specific local actor constellations, for<br />

example in agglomerations or local networks,<br />

and they only guide action within these spaces.<br />

SCOTT/STORPER (2003) have shown that agglomerations<br />

are advantageous due to their<br />

ability to reduce transaction costs. Based on the<br />

discussion above, it is expected that spatial differences<br />

of institutional environments lead to<br />

specific institutional arrangements in each region.<br />

This is of particular relevance if transactions<br />

are analysed that span spaces with different<br />

institutional frameworks. Furthermore,<br />

conceptual considerations and empirical applications<br />

of NIE in growth theory (ACEMOGLU et<br />

al. 2005) have revealed a major impact of institutions<br />

on differences in growth rates across<br />

countries and regions. And finally, the institutionalism<br />

in sociology gains its spatial dimension<br />

from the fact that social action is embedded<br />

in local contexts and that informal institutions,<br />

and thus actions, depend on their spatial<br />

and cultural context.<br />

Informality in the mega-urban<br />

economy<br />

The definition of informality that has been discussed<br />

so far is not restricted to developing<br />

countries or urban regions, as is the case with<br />

the older concept of the informal sector. However,<br />

there are arguments in favour of the fact<br />

that mega-urban regions, such as the Pearl River<br />

Delta in China or Dhaka in Bangladesh, are<br />

characterised by high levels of informality in<br />

an institutional sense. Mega-urban regions are<br />

more complex and disparate in their economic<br />

and social structures. They are closely integrated<br />

into global processes due to their economic,<br />

political and societal importance. Furthermore,<br />

rapidly growing mega-urban regions are characterised<br />

by an increasing speed and degree of<br />

institutional change. They are also highly vulnerable<br />

to economic, social and ecological<br />

shocks. ALTVATER (2005) identified the time


and space compression <strong>und</strong>er conditions of<br />

globalization and the rapid growth of megacities<br />

as major drivers of an informalisation in<br />

mega-urban regions, which is also visible in<br />

advanced market economies (SASSEN 1997).<br />

While the negative impacts of informalisation,<br />

for example in terms of the exclusion of the urban<br />

poor, prevail in the literature, the potentials<br />

of informality for development and competitiveness<br />

at the individual, firm and regional<br />

level, which were already put forward by DE<br />

SOTO (1989), are at least equally important for<br />

the institutional approach used in this special<br />

issue. ALTVATER (2005) also concedes that informality<br />

enables the realisation of a b<strong>und</strong>le of<br />

political objectives such as formation of cooperatives<br />

and micro-credit organisations, support<br />

of local and regional networking, support<br />

of cooperation with universities and other public<br />

institutions, and creation of a legal framework<br />

which contains much more than the mere<br />

distribution of property rights. Thus, informality<br />

may provide the flexibility that is necessary<br />

to adapt to rapidly changing framework conditions.<br />

By focussing particularly on urban governance,<br />

ROY (2005) has shown that the ability of<br />

public actors is insufficient to plan mega-urban<br />

regions efficiently, but that informal self-organisation<br />

of institutions by non-public actors<br />

and related informal arrangements for risk<br />

management and increased resilience play a<br />

central role. This does not imply that largescale<br />

infrastructures are not provided by the<br />

formal government, but due to the complexity<br />

of mega-urban regions and the often limited<br />

governance capability of megacities in developing<br />

countries, a complementary use of informal<br />

arrangements is expected to increase the<br />

governance efficiency.<br />

The increasing global organisation and integration<br />

of economic activities as a central part of<br />

globalisation remains a megatrend that shapes<br />

the spatial economy (SCHÄTZL 2000). This<br />

process is characterised, among other things,<br />

by the spatial disintegration of value chains,<br />

the emergence of global production networks<br />

and an increasing division of labour based on<br />

the principle of flexible specialisation (PI-<br />

ORE/SABEL 1984). At the same time, shorter<br />

product life cycles require firms to remain flexible<br />

by adapting to volatile markets that are increasingly<br />

plagued by bubble-like expansions<br />

and crisis-like downturns. The <strong>und</strong>erlying<br />

Editorial 5<br />

changes of economic systems result in a higher<br />

number of interfaces among companies,<br />

sites within multinational corporations, business<br />

services, and knowledge providers along<br />

the global value chain. The increasing complexity<br />

of interactions and flows and the necessity<br />

to span spatial, institutional and organisational<br />

distances reduces the possibility to fall<br />

back to standardised, completely formalised<br />

institutional arrangements and increases transaction<br />

costs, with informal aspects such as incremental<br />

and continuous adaptation processes<br />

during the interaction becoming more important.<br />

It is expected that traditional formalised<br />

arrangements will remain important, but that<br />

they will be complemented by informal ones in<br />

the sense of incomplete contracts. In volatile<br />

competitive environments, informality of external<br />

relations at the micro level may provide<br />

organisations with the amount of flexibility<br />

that is necessary to gain stability and competitiveness<br />

at the macro level. The strategic use of<br />

opportunity informality is suggested to increase<br />

flexibility and competitiveness and is<br />

covered by using the terms agility or agile firm<br />

organisation.<br />

In recent years, the global economy has been<br />

characterised by far-reaching changes of formal<br />

institutional environments defined by the<br />

state at different levels which may be observed<br />

in countries and regions at different stages of<br />

development. The institutional fabric of developed<br />

countries in Western Europe and North<br />

America was adapted to the requirements of a<br />

globalised economy with further ro<strong>und</strong>s of<br />

deregulation and liberalisation. Previously centrally<br />

planned economies have been involved<br />

in a f<strong>und</strong>amental transition process since the<br />

1980s which is still going on in countries that<br />

have chosen a gradual strategy, such as China.<br />

The integration of developing countries into<br />

global value chains and the rapid industrialisation<br />

of regions in East and Southeast Asia are a<br />

related result of globalising forces in the first<br />

ro<strong>und</strong>, but have also been a driver of the most<br />

recent ro<strong>und</strong> of globalisation.<br />

Amidst these changes, it is particularly relevant<br />

to analyse the fit of new formal and existing informal<br />

institutions and to assess how economic<br />

actors cope with frictions of institutional<br />

systems. Since informal institutions are transformed<br />

slower than formal ones, it is very likely<br />

that self-organised institutions and institutional<br />

arrangements will be defined by the eco-


6 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

nomic actors themselves as a substitute for<br />

missing or dysfunctional formal institutions set<br />

by the state, at least for a certain period of time<br />

during accelerated institutional change. At the<br />

same time, the transition from plan to market<br />

redefines the relationship between the state and<br />

the market as well as that among individual<br />

economic actors. Uncertainties related to this<br />

process are expected to be bridged or reduced<br />

by the emergence of hybrid institutions and<br />

arrangements. However, necessity informality<br />

induced by rapid institutional change is rather<br />

expected to be a temporary phenomenon that<br />

arises from the necessity to substitute for missing<br />

or dysfunctional formal institutions.<br />

The six papers that were accepted for publication<br />

in this special issue specify different aspects<br />

of the institutional approach to informality<br />

and provide empirical tests and illustrations.<br />

Five papers deal with the mega-urban<br />

region of the Pearl River Delta, China, and one<br />

paper with the megacity of Dhaka, Bangladesh.<br />

Susanne Meyer deals with customer-supplier<br />

relationships and provides empirical facts that<br />

support the proposition, that an increasing<br />

amount of informality occurs due to the higher<br />

level of flexibility of production processes and<br />

the transcendence of different institutional environments<br />

by global production networks.<br />

Firms from Hong Kong use informal arrangements<br />

not only to govern transactions with local<br />

producers in the Pearl River Delta, but also<br />

with customers on the global scale. In these<br />

constellations, contractual relationships are becoming<br />

less specified and specifiable by complete<br />

contracts, and are governed by framework<br />

agreements that define the scope of the<br />

relationship and the terms of reference in general.<br />

Personal contacts are a method of identifying<br />

capable suppliers and reducing uncertainties<br />

about capabilities and conflicts of<br />

interest through personalised trust and reputation.<br />

In the low-tech sector, a competitive<br />

edge over a large number of technologically similar<br />

competitors is achieved through reliability<br />

and adaptability in terms of delivery times<br />

and product quantities with sufficient quality.<br />

In the high-tech sector, personal relations may<br />

be a method of ensuring the technological<br />

competence of the supplier. In addition, contracts<br />

are more often enforced informally using<br />

mediation or arbitration and through social<br />

power rather than using slower formal litigation,<br />

which is also more detrimental to reputations<br />

due to its publicity.<br />

Frank Bickenbach and Wan-Hsin Liu extend<br />

the discussion about the extent and determinants<br />

of informality to a larger set of business<br />

functions. Their argument is based on the hypothesis<br />

that the availability of formal rulebased<br />

procedures increases in the course of the<br />

Chinese transition process and that informal<br />

personal governance decreases. However, the<br />

expected effects are, in general, rather weak<br />

and only significant for very few business<br />

functions. Similar to the findings of Meyer,<br />

Bickenbach and Liu conclude that informality<br />

is not a transitory phenomenon that disappears<br />

in the process of institutional transition. There<br />

is evidence that positive effects of informality<br />

and path-dependent persistence prevail.<br />

Markus Keck, Hans-Georg Bohle and Wolfgang-Peter<br />

Zingel examine whether social<br />

processes and informal adaptation to risks result<br />

in an increasing level of resilience. Informality<br />

is defined as trust-based personal relations<br />

and a high degree of social capital. Effects<br />

are fo<strong>und</strong> for the micro level in the form<br />

of greater flexibility and adaptability of the actors,<br />

and at the macro level in terms of increased<br />

resilience of the urban food system as<br />

a whole.<br />

The effects of informality and flexibility are also<br />

empirically tested by Pamela Hartmann,<br />

Daniel Schiller and Frauke Kraas, who focus<br />

on the impact of workplace quality on labour<br />

turnover and its long-term effects for upgrading<br />

processes. Labour relations are significantly<br />

transformed by the flexibilisation of the production<br />

organisation. On the one hand, highly<br />

qualified employees with long-term contracts<br />

among the core staff are expected to fulfil a<br />

large and varying range of functions with highly<br />

flexibilised working hours. On the other<br />

hand, less qualified peripheral staff are strongly<br />

affected by numerical volatility. Flexible<br />

firms organise their labour force based on the<br />

concept of the ‘breathing factory’ and use informal<br />

channels of employment that differ<br />

from strict formal regulations. In developing<br />

countries, informal employment is related to<br />

missing or incomplete labour contracts, low<br />

qualifications and an absence of social security<br />

entitlements. Finally, the long-term effects of<br />

highly informal labour relations for training<br />

and upgrading of the labour force are discussed.<br />

It is concluded that informality and<br />

flexibility ensure the short-term success in<br />

highly competitive markets. However, there is


strong empirical evidence to suggest that it<br />

may not provide the preconditions in terms of<br />

absorptive capacity and skills to move beyond<br />

the low-tech, labour-intensive segments of the<br />

value chain in the long run.<br />

Wenying Fu, Daniel Schiller and Javier Revilla<br />

Diez are explicitly looking at these upgrading<br />

processes at the firm level and potentials<br />

for the emergence of innovative milieus in the<br />

Pearl River Delta. The importance of informality<br />

for upgrading is measured by social<br />

proximity in comparison to more formal organisational<br />

proximity. Positive effects of social<br />

proximity are revealed for the implementation<br />

of a wide range of innovation activities<br />

and for coping with volatile demand. However,<br />

social proximity is mainly applied by domestic<br />

firms to acquire access to the latest<br />

technology and market information from foreign<br />

firms. Therefore, the impact on product<br />

innovation performance is still fairly small and<br />

the level of trust-based interactive learning between<br />

firms in the region remains low. This is<br />

substantiated by the fact that firms that rely on<br />

formalised organisational proximity are at<br />

least as successful with respect to innovation<br />

outputs. This paper links the institutional perspective<br />

with an evolutionary approach, since<br />

it is shown that endogenous potentials of the<br />

currently externally governed production system<br />

of the Pearl River Delta are still too weak<br />

to provide the basis for the emergence of an innovative<br />

milieu.<br />

The global integration of economic activities<br />

and the related institutional change has resulted<br />

in a far-reaching transition of the role of the<br />

state and its relationship with economic actors.<br />

The catchwords ‘new public management’ and<br />

‘public-private partnership’ demonstrate the<br />

increasing overlap of public and private actions<br />

that has resulted in a total withdrawal of<br />

the state or outsourcing of its activities in some<br />

areas. Complex bargaining processes among<br />

the actors involved, new participative institutional<br />

arrangements and self-organisation have<br />

thereby come into being for the definition of<br />

institutional frameworks. The increasing level<br />

of differentiation of government actions seems<br />

to result in increasingly informal arrangements<br />

between the state and private actors.<br />

Friederike Schröder and Michael Waibel position<br />

their contribution at the interface of state<br />

and economy by focusing on informality in<br />

planning processes for the restructuring of ur-<br />

Editorial 7<br />

ban spaces. Their case study of a development<br />

project in Guangzhou, the capital of the<br />

Guangdong province, shows that the local government<br />

reacts to the dynamic complexities of<br />

the multi-faceted restructuring process by applying<br />

innovative and flexible governance<br />

modes. Experimental policies and informal<br />

governance allowing for a certain degree of<br />

self-organisation are exclusively applied in<br />

spatially-bo<strong>und</strong>ed development zones. Recently,<br />

the government has made particular use of<br />

this approach in projects that aim to attract<br />

knowledge-intensive business services and a<br />

highly qualified, creative workforce.<br />

References<br />

ACEMOGLU, D./JOHNSON, S./ROBINSON, J.A. (2005): <strong>Institut</strong>ions<br />

as a f<strong>und</strong>amental cause of long-run growth.<br />

In: Aghion, P./Durlauf, S.N. (Eds.): Handbook of economic<br />

growth, vol. 1A. Amsterdam, 385-472.<br />

ALTVATER, E. (2005): Globalization and the informalization<br />

of the urban space. Aalborg. (Aalborg University,<br />

Development Research Series: Working Paper No.<br />

131).<br />

COASE, R.H. (1937): The nature of the firm. In: Economica,<br />

4, 386-405.<br />

CHENG, L./GEREFFI, G. (1994): The informal economy<br />

in East Asian development. In: International Journal of<br />

Urban and Regional Research, (18)2, 194-219.<br />

DE SOTO, H. (1989): The other path. The invisible revolution<br />

in the Third World. New York.<br />

DE SOTO, H. (2000): The mystery of capital. Why capitalism<br />

triumphs in the West and fails everywhere else.<br />

New York.<br />

DIMAGGIO, P./POWELL, W.W. (1991): The new institutionalism<br />

in organizational analysis. Chicago.<br />

DIMAGGIO, P. (Ed.) (2001): The twenty-first-century<br />

firm. Changing economic organization in international<br />

perspective. Princeton.<br />

ESCHER, A. (Moderation)(1999a): Informeller Sektor in<br />

der Dritten Welt. In: Geographische R<strong>und</strong>schau, (51)12.<br />

(Themenheft).<br />

ESCHER, A. (1999b): Der Informelle Sektor in der Dritten<br />

Welt – Plädoyer <strong>für</strong> eine kritische Sicht. In: Geographische<br />

R<strong>und</strong>schau, (51)12, 658-661.<br />

FRIELING, H.-D. von (1989): Das Konzept des Informellen<br />

Sektors. Kritik eines Entwicklungsidealismus.<br />

in: Schamp, E.W. (Hrsg.): Der Informelle Sektor.<br />

Geographische Perspektiven eines umstrittenen<br />

Konzepts. Aachen, 169-199.<br />

GRABHER, G. (1993): The weakness of strong ties. The<br />

lock-in of regional development in the Ruhr Area. In:<br />

Grabher, G. (Ed.): The embedded firm. On the socioeconomics<br />

of industrial networks. London, 255-277.


8 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

GRANOVETTER, M.S. (1973): The strength of weak ties.<br />

In: The American Journal of Sociology, (78)6, 1360-<br />

1380.<br />

GUHA-KHASNOBIS, B./KANBUR, R./OSTROM, E. (Eds.)<br />

(2006): Linking the formal and informal economy. Concepts<br />

and Policies. Oxford. (WIDER Studies in Development<br />

Economics)<br />

HART, K. (1973): Informal income opportunities and urban<br />

employment in Ghana. In: Journal of Modern<br />

African Studies, 11, 61-89.<br />

HART, O./MOORE, J. (1999): Fo<strong>und</strong>ations of incomplete<br />

contracts. In: The Review of Economic Studies, 66,<br />

115-138.<br />

HART, O./MOORE, J. (2004): Agreeing now to agree later.<br />

Contracts that rule out but do not rule. Cambridge,<br />

MA. (NBER Working Paper No. 10397).<br />

HAYEK, F. v. (1973): Law, legislation and liberty. Vol. 1:<br />

Rules and orders. London.<br />

HODGSON, G.M. (2006): What are institutions? In: Journal<br />

of Economic Issues, 40, 1-25.<br />

ILO (International Labour Organization)(1972): Employment,<br />

incomes and equality. A strategy for increasing<br />

productive employment in Kenya. Geneva.<br />

KOMLOSY, A./PARNREITER, C./STACHER, I./ZIMMERMANN,<br />

S. (Eds.) (1997): Ungeregelt <strong>und</strong> unterbezahlt. Der informelle<br />

Sektor in der Weltwirtschaft. Frankfurt am<br />

Main.<br />

LI, P.P. (2007): Social tie, social capital, and social behaviour.<br />

Toward an integrative model of informal exchange.<br />

In: Asia-Pacific Journal of Management, 24,<br />

227-246.<br />

MARTIN, R. (2000): <strong>Institut</strong>ional approaches in economic<br />

geography. In: Sheppard, E./ Barnes, T. (Eds..): A<br />

companion to economic geography. Malden, 77-94.<br />

MAYNTZ, R./SCHARPF, F.W. (1995): Der Ansatz des akteurzentrierten<br />

<strong>Institut</strong>ionalismus. In: Mayntz, R./<br />

Scharpf, F.W. (Hrsg.): Steuerung <strong>und</strong> Selbstorganisation<br />

in staatsnahen Sektoren. Frankfurt am Main/New York,<br />

39-72.<br />

MEAD, D./MORRISSON, C. (1996): The informal sector<br />

elephant. In: World Development, (24)10, 1611-1619.<br />

NORTH, D.C. (1990): <strong>Institut</strong>ions, institutional change<br />

and economic performance. Cambridge.<br />

OSTROM, E. (1990): Governing the commons. The evolution<br />

of institutions for collective action. New York.<br />

PIORE, M.J./SABEL, C. (1984): The second industrial divide.<br />

Possibilities for prosperity. New York.<br />

PORTES, A./CASTELLS, M./BENTON, L. (1989): The informal<br />

economy. Studies in advanced and less developed<br />

countries. Maryland.<br />

RAFIQUI, P.S. (2009): Evolving economic landscapes.<br />

Why new institutional economics matters for economic<br />

geography. In: Journal of Economic Geography, 9, 329-<br />

353.<br />

ROLAND, G. (2000): Transition and economics. Politics,<br />

markets and firms. Cambridge, MA.<br />

ROY, A. (2005): Urban informality. Toward an epistemology<br />

of planning. In: Journal of the American Planning<br />

Association, (71)2, 147-158.<br />

SASSEN, S. (1997): Informalization in advanced market<br />

economies. Geneva. (ILO – Issues in Development Discussion<br />

Paper 20).<br />

SCHÄTZL, L. (2000): <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong>. Band 2:<br />

Empirie. Paderborn. (3. Aufl.)<br />

SCHAMP, E.W. (Hrsg.)(1989): Der Informelle Sektor.<br />

Geographische Perspektiven eines umstrittenen<br />

Konzepts. Aachen.<br />

SCHAMP, E.W. (Ed.)(1993): African small-scale industries<br />

in rural and urban environments. Challenges for<br />

development. Frankfurt am Main. (Frankfurter <strong>Wirtschafts</strong>-<br />

<strong>und</strong> Sozialgeographische Schriften 63).<br />

SCOTT, A.J./STORPER, M. (2003): Regions, globalization,<br />

and development. In: Regional Studies, (37) 6-7,<br />

579-593.<br />

SCOTT, W.R. (1995): <strong>Institut</strong>ions and organizations.<br />

Thousand Oaks.<br />

SINDZINGRE, A. (2007): The relevance of the concepts of<br />

formality and informality. A theoretical appraisal. In:<br />

Guha-Khasnobis, B./Kanbur, R./Ostrom, E. (Eds.):<br />

Linking the formal and informal economy. Concepts<br />

and policies. Oxford, 58-75.<br />

STIGLITZ, J. (1999): Whither reform. Ten years of the<br />

transition. Washington. (Paper prepared for the Annual<br />

World Bank Conference on Development Economics,<br />

Washington, D.C., April 28-30, 1999).<br />

WILLIAMSON, O.E. (1975): Markets and hierarchies –<br />

analysis and antitrust implications. A study in the economics<br />

of internal organization. New York.<br />

Daniel Schiller, Hannover


Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> Jg. 56 (2012) Heft 1-2, S. 9-24<br />

Susanne Meyer, Wien<br />

The world’s factory and informal ties – organisation of firm networks<br />

in the electronics industry in the Greater Pearl River Delta, China<br />

Abstract: <strong>Institut</strong>ional transition in countries such as China is expected to go hand in hand with the<br />

formalisation of interactional behaviour in firm networks. Recently, however, a different string of<br />

arguments has entered the academic discussion emphasising the limited extent of the formalisation<br />

of firms’ behaviour despite the institutional transition being complete. The aim of this paper is to<br />

show conceptually and empirically that a balance of formal and informal interactions is considered<br />

optimal for firms due to economic opportunities resulting from informality. The Greater Pearl River<br />

Delta (PRD), where Hong Kong (HK) firms act as cross-border intermediates between global<br />

customers and Chinese producers, serves as an example for studying the degree of informality applied<br />

when operating in two distinct institutional settings. A survey of electronics firms in HK investigates<br />

the way in which firms organise their contacting and selecting as well as their contracting<br />

processes when approaching global customers and Chinese producers. The findings show (1)<br />

that the degree of informality is greater when interacting with producers in the PRD due to the incompleteness<br />

of the institutional setting, but (2) that when acting with global customers, the behaviour<br />

of firms is only formalised to a certain extent. Informal interaction also serves as an opportunity<br />

for firms and is strategically used in an innovative organisational and management<br />

processes.<br />

Keywords: informality, institutions, business organisation, electronics industry, Hong Kong, China<br />

Introduction<br />

The Greater Pearl River Delta is responsible to<br />

a large extent for the economic growth and<br />

prosperity of China. It has made itself irreplaceable<br />

in the global value chain as a supplier<br />

for electronics products. The electronic<br />

firms in the region account for 38 % of Chinese<br />

exports and 32 % of the gross industrial output<br />

(Guangdong Provincial Bureau of Statistics<br />

2007). The region is unique in contrast to<br />

Shanghai or Bejing due to the intense firm networks<br />

between Hong Kong (HK), an established<br />

hub for trade with formal institutions<br />

meeting international standards, and the Pearl<br />

River Delta Economic Zone (PRD), part of the<br />

Chinese province of Guangdong and the<br />

‘world’s factory’ in the middle of a transitional<br />

process. HK firms act as intermediaries between<br />

producers of electronic products in the<br />

PRD and the global customer base located in<br />

industrialised economies. HK firms manage to<br />

interact well with partners in two distinct institutional<br />

settings.<br />

Following the general discussion, HK firms are<br />

expected to apply informal, more personal<br />

modes of interactions with PRD producers to<br />

overcome the institutional weaknesses in the<br />

PRD, for example missing laws or an inadequate<br />

enforcement of existing laws. Informality<br />

in interactions is considered to be a necessity.<br />

Global customers, in contrast, are expected<br />

to be served in a more formal way. However,<br />

there are theoretical considerations which emphasise<br />

the advantage of informal interactions<br />

even though a complete institutional setting is<br />

in place, for example social safeguards, trusted<br />

advice, room for flexible actions. Therefore,<br />

this paper addresses a slightly different line of<br />

thought which considers informality in interaction<br />

as an opportunity for HK firms as well,<br />

rather than merely as a necessity. This paper<br />

aims (1) to contribute to the academic discus-


10 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

sion on informal interactions in firm networks<br />

by adding a new strand of argumentation<br />

which turns away from informality as a necessity<br />

(survival strategy in transitional economies),<br />

towards informality as an opportunity to<br />

respond flexibly to the changing economic environment,<br />

(2) to open ways to operationalise<br />

and measure informal interactions and (3) to<br />

present initial empirical evidence to confirm<br />

that HK firms use informal interactions independently<br />

from the institutional setting.<br />

A firm survey conducted in HK revealed to<br />

what extent informal interactions are applied in<br />

the contacting and selection of new partners<br />

and the design of contracts. The answers of HK<br />

firms pertaining to PRD producers and global<br />

customers were compared. It could be fo<strong>und</strong><br />

that HK firms also apply informal modes of interaction<br />

with their global customer base despite<br />

the fact that formal institutions are perfectly<br />

developed. It seems to be a good alternative<br />

in combination with formal modes of<br />

interaction. It suits the need for speed in the negotiation<br />

processes resulting from volatile<br />

market conditions and provides the flexibility<br />

required to change agreements. Considering<br />

informal interactions as a conscious and strategic<br />

method in business organisation, it can be<br />

viewed as a managerial innovation. Understanding<br />

business concepts in Asia may produce<br />

learning effects.<br />

In the first section, this paper sheds light on the<br />

two lines of argument from a conceptual point<br />

of view: informality as a necessity versus informality<br />

as an opportunity. In the second part<br />

the focus is turned to the operationalisation of<br />

informal interactions and methods with which<br />

to measure it. The third section presents an empirical<br />

study of whether informal behaviour<br />

disappears with the development of comprehensive<br />

formal institutions on a regional level,<br />

or whether informal arrangements are considered<br />

as an opportunity for doing business<br />

independently of the institutional setting.<br />

Smoothing business relations:<br />

new perspectives on informality<br />

The recent academic discussion on informal<br />

interactions in business relations has moved<br />

away from non-legalisation and informal economies<br />

towards the importance of informal institutions<br />

and, beyond that, even towards infor-<br />

mal behaviour. In order to explain informal<br />

modes of interaction between economic<br />

agents, there are two arguments on which to<br />

focus. On the one hand, informal interactions<br />

may be a consequence of inefficient formal institutions.<br />

Informal interactions are considered<br />

to be a necessity (WILLIAMSON 2000). On the<br />

other hand, informal arrangements and behaviour<br />

may simply be perceived by firms as more<br />

efficient, although these firms may act within a<br />

complete institutional setting. Informal interaction<br />

is viewed as an opportunity (ETZOLD et<br />

al. 2009; LI 2007; SINDZINGRE 2006). The<br />

study of whether informality in business interactions<br />

is driven by necessity or opportunity<br />

requires a particular investigation of a region’s<br />

institutional environment and its evolution.<br />

These factors shape the framework conditions<br />

for firms’ interactional behaviour.<br />

Informal interactions as a necessity:<br />

inefficient formal institutions<br />

Formal and informal institutions influence the<br />

behaviour of firms. Informal constraints are<br />

characterised by the customs, norms, traditions,<br />

culture and religion of a region. They are<br />

based on implicit <strong>und</strong>erstanding and are socially<br />

derived, which makes them inaccessible<br />

through written documents. Informal institutions<br />

are path-dependent and have a long, pervasive<br />

influence on the character of economic<br />

development. They are also roots for the development<br />

of formal rules. The two are interwoven<br />

(WILLIAMSON 2000, 595 ff.). Formal<br />

rules involve laws and regulations (RICHTER/<br />

FURUBOTN 1996, 3 ff.). Although there is a<br />

clear distinction between formal and informal<br />

institutions (rules) and formal and informal behaviour<br />

of firms (actions), it can generally be<br />

agreed that formal institutions shape the path<br />

for formal behaviour (e.g. a comprehensive<br />

contract law encourages formal contracts) and<br />

informal institutions guide informal behaviour<br />

(e.g. a culture of harmony avoids formal disputes<br />

between partners), even though exceptions<br />

exist.<br />

This picture loses its simplicity when turning<br />

to economies <strong>und</strong>er institutional change, such<br />

as China. There are two arguments as to why<br />

firms perceive a deviation from formal interactions<br />

as necessary. Firstly, formal institutions<br />

are not completely in place following the arguments<br />

of the New <strong>Institut</strong>ional Economics. In<br />

their absence, firms are expected to rely on existing<br />

informal institutions. Secondly, prob-


Susanne Meyer: The world’s factory and informal ties<br />

lems occur because of a disharmony between<br />

formal and informal institutions. In transitional<br />

economies, formal institutions are mainly<br />

transferred from Western economies and are<br />

slightly adapted to local needs. This is, in general,<br />

more cost-efficient and time-saving than<br />

developing a new system. However, formal institutions<br />

are not rooted in regionally specific<br />

informal institutions (WILLIAMSON 2000). It is<br />

essential for successful reforms to change both<br />

the formal institutions and the belief systems<br />

(NORTH 1990). Otherwise, firms, led by individuals,<br />

will not support the new economic<br />

rules of the game, since their method of doing<br />

business is shaped by informal institutions and<br />

is not compatible with the new rules (GRA-<br />

NOVETTER 1973). It is not only the existence of<br />

formal institutions, but rather the costs, the efficiency<br />

and the willingness to use them which<br />

makes them attractive for firms. This explains<br />

why the economic system in some nations still<br />

does not work effectively, even though formal<br />

institutions are well developed.<br />

Although laws in China have been reformed,<br />

their functionality is still limited. At the same<br />

time, the Chinese are equipped with a set of<br />

strong informal institutions guiding social and<br />

economic interactions – guanxi. Basically,<br />

guanxi describes a personal connection between<br />

two people or a network of contacts, the<br />

idea of which is to draw on established connections<br />

in order to secure favours in personal<br />

interests (DUNNING/KIM 2007, LUO/CHEN<br />

1997, PARK/LUO 2001). These informal rules<br />

are already in place and may act perfectly as<br />

substitutes for dysfunctional and costly formal<br />

rules. The traits of guanxi are manifold (Tab.<br />

1). Firstly, guanxi operates on the level of individuals<br />

and corresponds to a highly personal<br />

relationship. Secondly, guanxi is reciprocal in<br />

the exchange of favours. Reciprocal processes<br />

are seen as a supplement to formal procedural<br />

rules. They involve mutual expectations on the<br />

part of the economic agents that a favour granted<br />

now will be repaid later. It is perpetual. Reciprocity<br />

can also result in mutual dependency.<br />

Thirdly, guanxi is an intangible asset. People in<br />

the network are committed to each other<br />

through an informal and unwritten code of<br />

trust. This guards against opportunistic behaviour,<br />

as the reputations of individuals are damaged<br />

when they disappoint their partners.<br />

Fourthly, guanxi is long-term oriented. Every<br />

guanxi relationship expands the stock of relational<br />

capital. It takes time to establish a functional<br />

guanxi network. Investments are initially<br />

high, but if a guanxi network is established,<br />

it enables firms to react quickly to changes and<br />

provides them with a certain degree of flexibility.<br />

Fifthly, guanxi is transferable. If A has<br />

guanxi with B, and B is a friend of C, then B<br />

can introduce and recommend A to C. Finally,<br />

guanxi is a utility concept. It is based on the exchange<br />

of favours, not on sentiments. If guanxi<br />

with other parties is no longer achieving objectives,<br />

it is easily broken (DUNNING/KIM 2007,<br />

330 f.; LUO/CHEN 1997; PARK/LUO 2001, 457).<br />

A manager's guanxi network is part of the Chinese<br />

way of doing business. Guanxi relations<br />

as fo<strong>und</strong> in Chinese society cannot easily be<br />

created – they are socially derived and are regionally<br />

embedded. Most of the contacts are<br />

built with people in spatial proximity, as trust<br />

and frequent interaction are the f<strong>und</strong>amental<br />

axes of guanxi. The network of guanxi is connected<br />

to a certain region, although guanxi also<br />

has the potential for long-distance relations,<br />

for example when family members or classmates<br />

move. The strong definition of informal<br />

rules supports entrepreneurs in adequately<br />

safeguarding their transactions in the absence<br />

of economic laws. For example, firms are hard-<br />

Tab. 1: The traits of guanxi<br />

Traits Description<br />

Personal Guanxi is established between individuals<br />

Reciprocal An individual’s reputation is tied up with reciprocal obligation<br />

Intangible Guanxi maintained by an unspoken commitment<br />

Long-term Guanxi is reinforced through long-term cultivation<br />

Transferable Guanxi is transferable through a third party as a referral<br />

Utilitarian Guanxi is purposefully driven by personal interests<br />

Source: according to DUNNING/KIM 2007, 331<br />

11


12 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

ly able to enforce contracts in the case of conflicts<br />

due to a lack of functionality of the Chinese<br />

court system.<br />

Despite all the positive effects of guanxi, it can<br />

also lead to lock-in effects, for example when<br />

firms are forced to select customers and producers<br />

via social ties (e.g. family members) instead<br />

of choosing the highest quality partner on<br />

a market basis. In other cases, firms cannot enforce<br />

contracts without considering the fact<br />

that this could burden the relationship. Therefore,<br />

it may be expected that against the backgro<strong>und</strong><br />

of profit maximisation, the guanxi network<br />

might become more functionally driven<br />

by personal connections and profit orientation.<br />

Business connections would then be associated<br />

with moderate informality, whereas private<br />

contacts are associated with a high degree of<br />

informality.<br />

According to the New <strong>Institut</strong>ional Economics,<br />

institutional change in transitional economies –<br />

setting up a complete set of formal institutions<br />

in harmony with existing informal rules – is<br />

expected to lead to a gradual formalisation of<br />

interactions. However, this paper goes beyond<br />

that and follows the idea that a sophisticated<br />

set of informal interactions could still work efficiently<br />

in business operations even though<br />

formal institutions are modernised. There<br />

might be a trade-off point where formal interactions<br />

substitute for informal behaviour of<br />

firms, indicating optimal behaviour. Following<br />

these lines of thought, this paper addresses<br />

YEUNG/LIN'S (2003) call for a context-specific<br />

theorising of the economic geographies of<br />

Asia.<br />

Informal interactions as opportunity –<br />

benefiting by smoothing business relations<br />

If interactions are formalised only to some extent<br />

in the course of institutional transition and<br />

keep a certain level of informality due to more<br />

efficient outcomes, informal interactions in<br />

business are no longer transitional, but become<br />

permanent. This line of argumentation states<br />

that there is not necessarily a complete formalisation<br />

of interaction, even if sufficient safeguards<br />

are provided by the current law system.<br />

Formal and informal interactions no longer<br />

serve as substitutes, but as complements. It is<br />

considered to be an opportunity rather than a<br />

necessity. Psychological research has shown<br />

that in personal contacts, face-to-face visual<br />

clues, such as facial expression, gesture and<br />

posture, play a significant role in <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />

and trusting the other party and can give all<br />

participants the impression that the others can<br />

be influenced more, thus making it appear<br />

more worthwhile to enter into cooperation<br />

(PUTNAM1993; MISZTAL 2000). MISZTAL (2000)<br />

proved that informal meetings still matter, as<br />

face-to-face contacts have the potential to draw<br />

individuals deeper into relationships with one<br />

another and to develop trust and intimacy.<br />

MACAULAY (1963) observed that business people<br />

trust in and rely on a person's word in a<br />

brief letter or a handshake, even if they take<br />

greater risks concerning the transaction. Moreover,<br />

experiments revealed that in face-to-face<br />

discussion, participants reach agreement sooner<br />

than in any other negotiation setting. This<br />

leads to greater confidence in the negotiation<br />

processes. Informal interaction contributes to<br />

greater flexibility. Firms have more freedom to<br />

adjust to specific circumstances. For example,<br />

firms can respond quickly without taking into<br />

account and discussing fixed contractual<br />

arrangements first. Additionally, studies discovered<br />

that personal contacts make negotiations<br />

more an issue between two people than<br />

one between two firms, and negotiations are<br />

less formalised.<br />

Researchers such as DUYSTERS et al. (1999),<br />

and recently PIDDUCK (2006, 265), argue that<br />

“a new perspective on partnership is needed to<br />

handle recent rapid economic and technological<br />

developments, and propose a more personal<br />

approach to partnership”. GRANOVETTER<br />

(1985) is thought to be the first to have intensively<br />

studied the effect of social networks on<br />

business success. Social networks transform<br />

into business networks and determine the<br />

choice of economic trading partners and how<br />

to interact with them. Empirical information on<br />

social networks proved the positive effects on<br />

economic development and democracy (PUT-<br />

NAM 1993; PUTNAM 2000), economic exchange<br />

(COLEMAN 1990; BURT 1992), education<br />

(COLEMAN 1988) and career success (BAKER<br />

2000). The advantages of informality have<br />

been recognised by firms. Therefore, some elements,<br />

for example face-to-face negotiation,<br />

are part of general business practices, rather<br />

than merely a specific phenomenon observed<br />

in China or HK, which may only occur there<br />

more frequently. Social networks are particularly<br />

beneficial when economic transactions<br />

take place in an environment of high risk and<br />

uncertainty. In the case of China, it must be in-


Susanne Meyer: The world’s factory and informal ties<br />

vestigated as to whether guanxi, originating as<br />

a social network, can transform into a comprehensive<br />

business network while preserving its<br />

efficient informal elements.<br />

Geography matters – regional institutions<br />

in the study region Greater Pearl River Delta<br />

Recently, the academic discussion in economic<br />

geography has stressed the spatial scale of institutions<br />

by applying concepts from the New<br />

<strong>Institut</strong>ional Economics to an institutional economic<br />

geography (GERTLER 2010; BOSCHMA/<br />

FRENKEN 2009; BOSCHMA/FRENKEN 2006).<br />

Economic interaction is shaped by a set of rules<br />

that are actively produced and reproduced over<br />

time and are typically bo<strong>und</strong> to a particular region<br />

(GERTLER 2010). Some regions provide<br />

comprehensive formal rules and laws to protect<br />

economic transactions, while others provide<br />

socially derived, well accepted informal rules<br />

of doing business. The dependency of firms’<br />

behaviour on the regionally specific institutional<br />

environment may be studied by examining<br />

cross border business operations between<br />

regions with two different institutional settings.<br />

The Greater Perl River Delta (GPRD) serves as<br />

a perfect study region for this phenomenon.<br />

The GPRD consists, on the one hand, of HK, a<br />

former British colony with a formal institutional<br />

environment corresponding to the international<br />

standard. On the other hand, there is the<br />

PRD, a transitional economy. Although firms<br />

in HK and the PRD act in distinct formal institutional<br />

settings, they have the same social<br />

roots resulting in similar informal institutions<br />

across the border. Production is usually organised<br />

in the PRD, whereas firms in HK serve as<br />

intermediaries for exporting and importing<br />

products to and from industrialised countries.<br />

HK firms are somewhat janus-faced (MEYER et<br />

al. 2009). One face is turned to the PRD producers,<br />

the other face is turned to the world’s<br />

leading firms as customers of products made in<br />

China.<br />

The unique institutional environment in the<br />

GPRD lends itself to the empirical testing of<br />

three hypotheses:<br />

(1) Firms in HK, working in two distinct institutional<br />

settings, organise business operations<br />

differently when dealing with PRD<br />

producers and global customers. According<br />

to this hypothesis, HK firms should work<br />

on a more informal basis with PRD producers<br />

due to the <strong>und</strong>erdevelopment of<br />

13<br />

comprehensive formal institutions in China,<br />

but on a more formal basis with global<br />

customers. The persistently unsatisfactory<br />

enforcement of formal laws combined with<br />

the lack of interwovenness of formal and<br />

informal institutions in the PRD lead to the<br />

expectation that Chinese firms do not yet<br />

rely on formal safeguards to ensure transactional<br />

success. FEARON/LAITIN (1996,<br />

730) fo<strong>und</strong> that social networks are better<br />

developed and interactions are more frequent<br />

within ethnic groups because they<br />

share certain similarities. Since entrepreneurs<br />

in HK and the PRD have the same<br />

ethnic and therefore social roots, their way<br />

of doing business on an informal basis is<br />

easier to realise, as it is driven by the concept<br />

of guanxi. The degree of informality in<br />

interactions is expected to be higher in HK<br />

firms’ relations to PRD firms than to global<br />

customers.<br />

(2) Since the rules of law in China have improved<br />

recently, the organisational behaviour<br />

has formalised to a certain extent, but<br />

informal organisation still prevails. According<br />

to the second hypothesis, interactions of<br />

HK firms with local producers are not completely<br />

informalised either. With the improvement<br />

of the institutional setting in<br />

China, HK entrepreneurs have formalised<br />

their relations with PRD producers to a certain<br />

extent. But since they know about the<br />

advantage of informal interactions (e.g.<br />

reciprocity, mutual <strong>und</strong>erstanding, flexibility),<br />

they may consider a combination of<br />

formal and informal interactions to be most<br />

beneficial for their relations with producers.<br />

This would provide evidence for the<br />

importance of personal interactions even<br />

going beyond the institutional setting. In<br />

the empirical section, the intensification of<br />

formal vs. informal interactions will be<br />

studied, comparing the behaviour of HK<br />

entrepreneurs when working with PRD<br />

producers and Western customers.<br />

(3) Informal methods enable HK firms to engage<br />

in more flexible behaviour and respond<br />

quickly to market and customer requirements.<br />

Informality as an opportunity<br />

implies that firms benefit from informal behaviour.<br />

One expected benefit is more flexible<br />

behaviour leading to quick reaction opportunities,<br />

for example. Trust-based relations<br />

could relax negotiation processes,


14 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

ease the changing of agreements or encourage<br />

the enforcement of agreements through<br />

social power.<br />

Operationalisation of informal<br />

interactions in business<br />

LI (2007) discussed the contrasting terms of<br />

formality and informality of firms' behaviour.<br />

He distinguished between formal and informal<br />

attributes of interaction, whereby these mark<br />

the extreme points of a continuum. According<br />

to LI (2007, 229), informality in interactions on<br />

the micro-level “refers to the nature of social<br />

ties and events as implicitly assumed, endogenously<br />

embraced and flexibly enforced by horizontal<br />

… pressures in a particularistic personalized<br />

process …, while formality as explicitly<br />

prescribed, exogenously imposed and rigidly<br />

enforced by vertical authority powers in a …<br />

depersonalized process.” To study formal and<br />

informal behaviour, he proposed dimensions of<br />

informality as a framework to study and measure<br />

empirically formal and informal practices<br />

in business interactions. He recommended taking<br />

into account the degree of personalisation<br />

in business interactions, the form of agreements<br />

concluded, the precision of arrangements,<br />

the enforcement mechanisms of contracts<br />

and the power of institutions used (Tab.<br />

2).<br />

LI (2007) divided each dimension into a variety<br />

of actions ranging from formal to informal.<br />

Taking the first dimension, personalisation, into<br />

account, he refers to business contacts that<br />

can be highly impersonal (formal) or very personal<br />

(informal). Personal processes are based<br />

on face-to-face contacts, trust between partners<br />

Tab. 2: Formal-informal dimensions in business interactions<br />

and private involvement. This may also determine<br />

the second dimension, the form of agreements.<br />

Contracts can be highly formalised in a<br />

written way or informally agreed on in a verbal<br />

way, when partners trust each other's word. Not<br />

only the form of agreements, but also the precision<br />

of agreements (third dimension) can<br />

range from very precise (formal) to openended<br />

(informal). Business culture can rely on<br />

open-ended agreements with permanent renegotiations<br />

rather than specifying details in advance.<br />

Formal and informal agreements rely on<br />

different enforcement mechanisms, which can<br />

either be very tight at the one extreme or very<br />

loose at the other. In the case of conflicts, the<br />

power used to enforce agreements can be legal<br />

via courts or social power relying on shared<br />

norms within a culture (LI 2007; SINDZINGRE<br />

2006). A firm may be characterised as acting<br />

on informal constraints in terms of customerproducer<br />

relations when dimensions tend to be<br />

specified by informal practices. In contrast, a<br />

firm is characterised as acting on formal constraints<br />

in terms of customer-producer relations<br />

when dimensions tend to have a formal shape.<br />

Here a special focus is placed on these three dimensions,<br />

namely personalisation in business<br />

interactions, the form of agreements concluded<br />

and the precision of arrangements. Along these<br />

dimensions, it will be tested empirically as to<br />

how high the degree of informality applied in<br />

business interactions is, comparing firms acting<br />

in two different institutional settings. To<br />

test the dimension of personalisation, the instruments<br />

of HK entrepreneurs for contacting<br />

and selecting customers and producers were<br />

studied. Contacting and selecting processes<br />

can be based on personal or impersonal ties,<br />

which refer to informal or formal modes re-<br />

Dimensions Formal Informal Operationlisation<br />

Personalisation impersonal personal Contacting and selecting of customers<br />

and producers<br />

Form of agreements written verbal Form of manufacturing agreements<br />

Preciseness of agreements precise open-ended Details fixed in manufacturing agree<br />

ments<br />

Enforcement of agreements tight loose<br />

Power legal (vertical) social (horizontal)<br />

Source: own composition according to LI 2007, 229ff.)


Susanne Meyer: The world’s factory and informal ties<br />

spectively. There are two arguments as to why<br />

informal means might be used in contacting<br />

and selecting processes:<br />

– In the neoclassical theory, firms are expected<br />

to contact and select their business partners<br />

by evaluating their rational factors of<br />

success (e.g. for example firm performance,<br />

product quality) (ANGELES/NATH 2000; HITT<br />

et al. 2000; SAFFU/MAMMAN 2000). This<br />

could be interpreted as an impersonal and<br />

therefore formal method of contacting customers<br />

and producers. But bo<strong>und</strong>ed rationality<br />

limits the scope of firms for assessing a<br />

potential partner's quality and reliability in<br />

advance. Even though firms can assess potential<br />

partners’ quality and reliability within<br />

a screening scheme of their own (formal),<br />

they can trust in a network of firms with<br />

pooled experiences (informal). Empirically,<br />

MENARD (2004, 361) could prove that the<br />

use of informal modes through networking<br />

to gain new customers and producers opens<br />

up additional opportunities for firms without<br />

weakening any formal modes.<br />

– Under volatile industry and market conditions<br />

with changing demand, time is essential<br />

for a firm's competitiveness. As a personal<br />

network is always ready to use, it<br />

seems to be a quicker way of activating new<br />

customers and producers at short notice<br />

(MILLINGTON et al. 2006).<br />

In order to study the dimensions of precision<br />

and form of contracts, HK firms' contracts<br />

with customers and producers pertaining to the<br />

manufacturing of electronics products were investigated.<br />

Emphasis was placed on the details<br />

fixed and the form of contracts. Again, there<br />

are three arguments as to why informal means<br />

might be used.<br />

– When the formal institutional environment<br />

does not provide safeguards for the enforcement<br />

of contracts, the incentive of firms to<br />

design precisely written contracts is low.<br />

Firms have to protect their transactional interests<br />

in other ways. A trust-based relationship,<br />

as which guanxi may be characterised,<br />

in which parties rely on reputation and reciprocity,<br />

provides informal safeguards which<br />

lead to self-enforcing contracts (POWELL<br />

1990; DIMAGGIO/LOUCH 1998; MENARD<br />

2004, 362). Despite improvements in the<br />

PRD, the institutional framework does not<br />

15<br />

provide firms with the appropriate safeguards<br />

for protecting their transactions efficiently.<br />

Even if contractual details are formally<br />

fixed and verifiable, it is still difficult<br />

to enforce them through courts (MENARD<br />

2004, 360).<br />

– Informal modes in contracting can also be<br />

expected due to the low impact of contracts<br />

in Chinese business culture. Contracts are not<br />

the results of intensive negotiations, but are<br />

seen rather as the beginning of a relationship<br />

over a much longer time period (see guanxi).<br />

Therefore, the permanent renegotiation of<br />

contracts is a process which accompanies the<br />

development of the relationship.<br />

– There is, however, another argument: Firms<br />

still weigh the costs of anticipating, devising<br />

optimal responses to and drafting provisions<br />

for future events against the value which<br />

would be lost in the case of conflicts. Only<br />

when transaction-specific investments are<br />

high is it worth incurring the considerable<br />

costs of administering complex and highly<br />

detailed contractual arrangements (model in<br />

HART/MOORE 2004, 5 ff.; MASTEN 2000). Under<br />

certain circumstances, firms are expected<br />

to attempt to agree only on the most necessary<br />

details (SEGAL 1999, 74). Besides cost<br />

motives, this is associated with greater flexibility.<br />

Firms can speed up the contractual<br />

process and revise and renegotiate on a<br />

steady platform in order to adapt to changing<br />

demand. In industries with rapidly shifting<br />

technologies and markets, firms need adjustable<br />

contracts embedded in networks to<br />

ensure the ability to react to the changing demand<br />

profiles of end customers (ERNST 2004,<br />

106).<br />

Despite the positive effects of informality on<br />

business interactions, one has to consider that it<br />

takes a lot of time and effort to build social ties.<br />

HUMPHREY/ASHFORTH (2000) showed that interpersonal<br />

relationships can also lead customers<br />

to award contracts to producers who<br />

have higher unit costs, lower quality and slower<br />

delivery times. Nevertheless, networks may<br />

also lead to a lock-in, if firms rely on them exclusively.<br />

Therefore, they need to be supported<br />

by formal structures to guard against the negative<br />

effects of informality, such as opportunistic<br />

behaviour and its intransparency (MISZTAL<br />

2000, 7).


16 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Data and methods<br />

Informality will be studied empirically, involving<br />

a comparison between the organisation of<br />

customer and producer relations of HK firms.<br />

Emphasis is placed on the contacting and selecting<br />

procedures and the contractual arrangements.<br />

To avoid sector-related skewness, the<br />

study was concentrated on one industry. The<br />

electronics industry in the GPRD was selected<br />

because of its large contribution to the economic<br />

growth in the GPRD and its dynamics<br />

(CANFEI et al. 2008). The electronics industry<br />

in the PRD is responsible for 38 % of all Chinese<br />

electronics exports and 32 % of the gross<br />

industrial output. 47 % of foreign direct investments<br />

come from HK (Guangdong Provincial<br />

Bureau of Statistics 2006).<br />

As there is a shortage of secondary data on<br />

this issue, a firm survey was conducted in HK<br />

focussing on the electronics industry. On a<br />

micro-level, a survey of small and mediumsized<br />

electronic firms was conducted in HK in<br />

2007 and 2008 to collect information on how<br />

HK firms organise relations to their PRD producers<br />

as well as to their global customer<br />

base. This was intended to show whether informal<br />

interactions are only applied in relations to<br />

PRD firms as a necessity for manoeuvring<br />

aro<strong>und</strong> institutional incompleteness, or whether<br />

HK firms also see advantages in organising<br />

business with customers in an informal way.<br />

The survey was based on the firm directory of<br />

the Hong Kong Trade Development Council.<br />

From 4,903 registered small and medium-sized<br />

HK electronic firms, a random sample of 2,000<br />

was selected. In a stepwise process, 1,000<br />

firms were chosen first, followed by another<br />

sample of 1,000 firms due to the low return rate<br />

from the first sample. The survey concentrated<br />

on firms with not more than 100 employees in<br />

HK according to HK statistical standards. Although<br />

a standardised survey was conducted,<br />

the information was collected personally in an<br />

hour-long interview to ensure high quality.<br />

CEOs or senior managers of 104 firms agreed<br />

to an interview (5 % return rate). Although the<br />

Social Science Research Center of the Hong<br />

Kong University (SSRC), who provided strong<br />

support in contacting and interviewing firms, is<br />

very professional and experienced, gaining HK<br />

CEOs for an interview proved to be very difficult.<br />

The low response rate may be explained<br />

by the fact that people in these positions were<br />

requested to participate due to the strategic ori-<br />

entation of the survey. Unfortunately, potential<br />

respondents often spend most of their time in<br />

their Chinese factory and were hardly available<br />

in HK. Moreover, we wanted CEOs to be<br />

interviewed personally in order to ensure the<br />

quality of the survey results, rather than using<br />

self-completed questionnaires, which also<br />

dropped the return rate. Additionally, HK firms<br />

are the target group of many surveys. As we<br />

cooperated with SSRC, we already had a<br />

strong academic partner for the interviews,<br />

which led to a reasonable response rate for HK<br />

circumstances, but in comparison to other surveys,<br />

the response rate is lower. However,<br />

since the collection of empirical data on informality<br />

in interactions is still at an explorative<br />

stage, no attempt was made to produce representative<br />

results. The accessibility of firms and<br />

reliability of data was of primary importance.<br />

Nevertheless, it could be proven that there is<br />

no significant difference between sample and<br />

population according to employment size.<br />

Applying informal interactions:<br />

contacting, selecting and contracting<br />

The previous sections raised the question of<br />

whether the institutional environment requires<br />

informal actions as a necessity or whether informal<br />

interactions could also be seen as an opportunity<br />

for firms. This section empirically<br />

studies the degree of informality applied in the<br />

customer-producer relations of HK firms in<br />

terms of contacting and selecting procedures<br />

and contractual arrangements, depending on<br />

the institutional environment.<br />

Contacting and selecting of customers<br />

and producers<br />

Contacting: When firms wish to contact new<br />

customers and producers, they may choose<br />

from a variety of methods ranging from very<br />

impersonal to very personal. The importance of<br />

seven different contact channels of HK firms<br />

for gaining new global customers (non-Chinese)<br />

is shown in Tab. 3. In the second part, the<br />

selecting processes of PRD producers will be<br />

studied as a comparison. Contact channels<br />

range from being very personal, and therefore<br />

informal (private contacts), to very impersonal,<br />

and therefore formal (bidding competition).<br />

HK firms were asked to assess their importance<br />

on a Likert scale (1 = very important to 5<br />

= not important). Recommendations by business<br />

partners are, as is shown in Tab. 3, the


Susanne Meyer: The world’s factory and informal ties<br />

most important (61 %). This requires a network<br />

of trustworthy business partners to receive recommendations.<br />

Whereas business contacts<br />

seem to be of importance, private networks are<br />

not (8 %). Sales agents are the second most important<br />

(54 %). Sales agents are responsible for<br />

contacting and keeping in touch with customers.<br />

The personal contact is important, as<br />

this creates an atmosphere of trust. However,<br />

sales agents account for moderate informality.<br />

In contrast, gaining customers at exhibitions is<br />

less personal, while gaining them on the internet<br />

or through bidding competitions is even<br />

more impersonal, and therefore very formal.<br />

Exhibitions and internet contact is third in<br />

terms of importance. Formal bidding processes,<br />

the contacting of former customers and private<br />

contacts are of minor importance. The<br />

Chi²-test shows that the indicated shares significantly<br />

differ from an equal distribution.<br />

Contacting channels with a medium degree of<br />

informality scored highest when HK firms contact<br />

global customers, although the institutional<br />

environment would allow them to rely on formal<br />

means only. Apparently, a certain degree of<br />

informality is conducive to business success.<br />

When firms can revert to networks, they enlarge<br />

their pool of choices for contacting and<br />

selecting partners. Very impersonal contact<br />

channels are at everybody's disposal, but personal<br />

channels are not available to all firms.<br />

Although formal safeguards can be ensured by<br />

a functional legal system in HK and transac-<br />

17<br />

tions with strangers can be ensured by contracts,<br />

recruitment within networks might still<br />

be appealing because of cost-reducing and<br />

time-saving aspects. Even if HK firms contact<br />

global customers, they prefer the use of networks<br />

and other moderately informal means.<br />

This raises the question of how guanxi networks<br />

are affected by institutional change.<br />

XIN/PEARCE (1996) and NEE (1992) see guanxi<br />

as a substitute for the deficiencies of formal institutional<br />

artifacts and failures in the legal system.<br />

Proponents of this thesis argue that guanxi<br />

will become less important in the future. On<br />

the other hand, other experts argue that guanxi<br />

is also transforming into a more functional<br />

business network. Whereas the traditional<br />

guanxi network consists of family (zijiaren)<br />

and fellows/helpers (shouren), it has now<br />

changed to strangers/business partners (shengren),<br />

which makes it more effective for business<br />

(MILLINGTON et al. 2006). Studies of business<br />

culture in HK or Taiwan are widely used<br />

to provide examples of the transition – but nevertheless<br />

survival – of guanxi in the modern<br />

market (FAN 2002; ZHANG/ZHANG 2006).<br />

The importance of business networks in comparison<br />

to private networks confirms the<br />

change of the nature of guanxi from a private<br />

to a functional network. This functional guanxi<br />

network is driven by personal connections.<br />

When firms in HK use their guanxi networks,<br />

they profit from the intangible, transferable and<br />

reciprocal character of the network. Other network<br />

members are committed either to provid-<br />

Tab. 3: Importance of formal and informal contacting channels of HK firms to global customers<br />

(in %)<br />

customers abroad (n=93)<br />

important moderate<br />

important<br />

not<br />

important<br />

Chi² significance<br />

(1) Bidding competition 19 9 72 64.323 .000<br />

(2) Internet 48 27 25 9.548 .008<br />

(3) Exhibitions and fairs 51 26 24 12.452 .002<br />

(4) Sales agents<br />

(5) Recommendation by<br />

54 22 25 17.613 .000<br />

business partners 61 26 13 35.032 .000<br />

(6) Former business<br />

relationship<br />

22 14 65 41.484 .000<br />

(7) Private contacts<br />

(e.g. family ties)<br />

8 12 81 93.935 .000<br />

Note: Importance is measured on a Likert scale with 1=very important to 5=not important, mean value indicated.<br />

Source: calculation based on own survey conducted in DFG SPP 1233 [2007]


18 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

ing their services to the firm (intangible), or<br />

they recommend a third party (transferable)<br />

(DIMAGGIO/LOUCH 1998). Firms save ex ante<br />

transaction costs for screening their environment<br />

for new customers and producers, collecting<br />

information and establishing the first<br />

contact, but they also hope to achieve better<br />

safeguards than in a formal process (POWELL<br />

1990; DIMAGGIO/LOUCH 1998; GRANOVETTER<br />

1985). Former experiences may be used as an<br />

indicator for future satisfaction (MACLEOD<br />

2006). If a producer has acquired a good reputation<br />

in a business network, it is treated as an<br />

asset which loses its value should the producer<br />

disappoint customers (MACLEOD 2006; ARAU-<br />

JO/ORNELAS 2007:3). As networks are reciprocal,<br />

firms are willing to repay favours. Preliminary<br />

empirical evidence was fo<strong>und</strong> in the<br />

study of GASTON/BELL (1988). They proved<br />

that two-thirds of investors in the informal capital<br />

market find investments through their networks.<br />

The most reliable sources are friends<br />

and business partners. SHILLER/POUND (1989)<br />

confirmed those findings. They fo<strong>und</strong> that the<br />

majority of purchasers of publicly traded common<br />

stocks buy based on information from<br />

friends and business associates. Networks are<br />

usually developed on an individual level, but<br />

are often transferred to a firm level. This does<br />

not skew empirical findings as long as firms<br />

are small and/or family-led. The owner and<br />

manager is the same person and the owner's<br />

network is identical to the firm's network. This<br />

mainly applies to small and medium enterprises<br />

(SME) in HK. In large firms with frequent<br />

changes in management positions, a distinction<br />

must be made between the networks of<br />

individuals and those of the firm.<br />

In conclusion, HK firms proved that contacting<br />

channels have not yet formalised completely,<br />

and that informal modes retain their importance.<br />

This is also in accordance with the theory<br />

outlined by ZENGER et al. (2002). Formal institutions<br />

do not necessarily go along with formal<br />

interactions, but provide room for the use<br />

of informal as well as formal actions.<br />

Selecting: It is expected that the contacting of<br />

customers and producers is carried out on a<br />

continual basis. A selection occurs if a new<br />

partner is needed. Selection processes are of<br />

Tab. 4: Importance of formal and informal selection criteria of HK firms for producers in<br />

equity cooperation and non-equity cooperation (in %)<br />

equity cooperation (n=17) non-equity cooperation (n=17) Chi² significance<br />

important moderate not important moderat not<br />

important important important important<br />

(1) Expertise<br />

(2) Good<br />

65 18 18 76 18 6 1.167 .558<br />

reputation<br />

(3) Good<br />

experiences<br />

in previous<br />

71 12 18 76 18 6 1.240 .538<br />

business<br />

(4) Get along<br />

with local<br />

workers/<br />

82 6 12 71 24 6 2.287 .319<br />

suppliers well<br />

(5) Get along<br />

with public<br />

29 35 35 24 41 35 .188 .910<br />

officials well<br />

(6) Existence<br />

of personal<br />

18 35 47 12 18 71 2.000 .368<br />

relationships 71 12 18 41 47 12 5.116 .077<br />

Note: Importance is measured on a Likert scale with 1=very important to 5=not important, mean value indicated.<br />

Source: calculation based on own survey conducted in DFG SPP 1233 [2007]


Susanne Meyer: The world’s factory and informal ties<br />

particular interest when firms look for new cooperation<br />

partners. MEYER et al. (2009) outlined<br />

that cooperation with PRD producers has<br />

become more important for HK firms in recent<br />

years. Therefore, the selection criteria for PRD<br />

producers in cooperation were analysed using<br />

the dimension ‘personalisation’ in the informality<br />

pattern. Selection criteria can range<br />

from very formal, without any involvement of<br />

personal assets, to very informal, which qualifies<br />

producers only because of personal relations.<br />

Expertise can be seen as an objective<br />

measurement of skills and is therefore very impersonal.<br />

A good reputation is based on a pool<br />

of subjective measurements and is therefore<br />

deemed to be impersonal, but not as impersonal<br />

as expertise. Positive experiences in previous<br />

business dealings are based on a firm's own<br />

subjective measurement of the producer's quality.<br />

It is linked to moderate personalisation. In<br />

contrast, selection criteria are more personal<br />

when they qualify producers to get along well<br />

with local workers, suppliers and public officials.<br />

When a producer is qualified because of<br />

a private connection, this counts as informal.<br />

For analysis, the focus is on cooperative relations,<br />

as they are concerned with the highest<br />

degree of mutual interaction and potentially informal<br />

traits. For simple reasons, there is a distinction<br />

between equity cooperation and nonequity<br />

cooperation of HK firms with PRD producers.<br />

Equity cooperation with Chinese firms<br />

was mandatory at the beginning of the transformation<br />

process and could be considered as<br />

the oldest mode of cooperation existing between<br />

HK firms and Chinese producers. Nonequity<br />

cooperation was a free-choice decision<br />

that appeared with the modernisation of Chinese<br />

laws. The differentiation between equity<br />

cooperation (e.g. joint ventures) and non-equity<br />

cooperation (e.g. loosely concluded cooperation<br />

agreements) provides interesting results<br />

about firms' preferences within those relationships<br />

and potential changes in cooperation. It<br />

can be seen, for example, whether personal relations<br />

still steer cooperation or whether they<br />

are equally important to other formal procedures.<br />

When looking at equity cooperation, Tab. 4<br />

shows that positive experience in previous<br />

business dealings is of the greatest importance<br />

(82 %), followed by a good reputation of producers<br />

and the existence of personal relationships<br />

(both 71 %). HK firms' selection criteria<br />

19<br />

for producers in equity cooperation are based<br />

on subjective quality measurements and personal<br />

relationships. Informal and moderately<br />

informal criteria are mainly applied. However,<br />

when turning to non-equity cooperation, expertise<br />

as an objective means of measuring the<br />

quality of producers is of the greatest importance,<br />

along with a good reputation (both<br />

76 %). The third most important factor is positive<br />

experience in previous business dealings<br />

(71 %). While some firms apparently need to<br />

smooth relationships to potential joint venture<br />

partners through informal modes, other firms<br />

working in non-equity cooperation set their<br />

priority on measurements of quality, for example<br />

personal relationships are much more important<br />

in equity than in non-equity relations.<br />

This also became significant in the Chi²-test.<br />

The findings showed that a successful partnership<br />

in non-equity cooperation is characterised<br />

by expertise and a good reputation of producers<br />

in combination with mutual <strong>und</strong>erstanding.<br />

In contrast, equity cooperation follows another<br />

strategy. It is mainly applied to running<br />

the business. This was the way in which HK<br />

firms were forced to work at the beginning of<br />

the Chinese opening policy. The way equity<br />

cooperation is seen by HK firms does not seem<br />

to have changed over recent years. There is an<br />

initial signal for a difference in importance of<br />

personal relations, and Guanxi might change<br />

from a purely personal to a business network.<br />

Moreover, it can be observed that in a modern<br />

non-equity relationship, HK firms balance formal<br />

and informal criteria instead of purely relying<br />

on informal ties. But to a certain extent,<br />

informality remains an opportunity. As these<br />

findings are only a preliminary sign, this issue<br />

definitely requires further research.<br />

In summary, the findings on contacting and selecting<br />

procedures of HK firms show, first, that<br />

personal relations are much more important<br />

when dealing with firms in China than with<br />

global customers, which is an expression of the<br />

influence of the institutional setting. But second,<br />

it could be shown that HK firms still use<br />

informal modes to contact and select global<br />

customers, even though the institutional environment<br />

would allow a reliance on formal<br />

modes only. This confirms again that a certain<br />

degree of informalisation smoothes business<br />

relations. HK firms tend to combine formal and<br />

informal modes in order to succeed. Formal<br />

and informal modes are not mutually exclu-


20 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

sive, but rather complement each other.<br />

MILLINGTON et al. (2006) also worked on the<br />

identification process of Chinese partners.<br />

Their findings also show that personal connections,<br />

and in particular guanxi, helped UK and<br />

US-invested manufacturers in China to select<br />

producers. They also observed, however, that<br />

guanxi nowadays consists of business rather<br />

than family and community connections.<br />

Contractual arrangements with customers<br />

and producers<br />

Precision and form of contracts: Once firms<br />

have contacted and selected their potential customers<br />

and producers, they have to settle transaction-specific<br />

details. This section provides<br />

evidence on how contractual arrangements are<br />

concluded. Two dimensions of informality are<br />

analysed: the form of agreements (written to<br />

verbal) and precision (precise to open-ended).<br />

Interviews with lawyers in the GPRD indicated<br />

that the following points require attention<br />

when contracts are concluded: product specification,<br />

quantity, price, delivery time, agreement<br />

on exclusivity, penalties for breach of<br />

contract.<br />

The proportions of HK firms which fix all<br />

points in contracts are shown in Tab. 5 (see<br />

columns ‘precision of contracts’). If points are<br />

fixed in contract, this could be in written form,<br />

verbal form or both (see columns ‘form of contracts’).<br />

The more open-ended an agreement is<br />

and the more details are agreed on verbally, the<br />

greater the informal character of a contractual<br />

Tab. 5: Preciseness and form of framework agreements of HK firms<br />

arrangement is. Again, a comparison is made<br />

between HK firms’ contractual organisation to<br />

global customers and to producers in the PRD.<br />

When looking at the precision as a dimension<br />

of informality, the findings show that more<br />

than three quarters of the necessary details are<br />

fixed before the actual production process<br />

starts. Only a small proportion of firms have<br />

imprecise and therefore informal contracts. A<br />

look at how points are fixed, the form of agreements,<br />

indicates that HK firms mainly keep to<br />

formal modes, although there is a slight trend<br />

towards more informal agreements with PRD<br />

producers. If points are agreed on in advance,<br />

the majority of HK firms fix important points<br />

in written form. In customer relations, an average<br />

of 51 % of HK firms reported fixing all<br />

points in writing, while in producer relations,<br />

the figure was 46 %. An exclusively verbal<br />

agreement is only concluded by a very small<br />

number of firms (customers: 7 %, producers:<br />

5 %). In producer relations, the combination of<br />

both written and verbal agreements is preferred<br />

by about one quarter of the firms, while in customer<br />

relations, the number drops to 20 %.<br />

Comparing customer and producer relations, it<br />

becomes clear that the number of written details<br />

in contracts is slightly higher with customers<br />

than with producers.<br />

HK firms apply informal modes when contacting<br />

and selecting customers and producers, but<br />

when it comes to contractual arrangements,<br />

they mostly do not rely on trust and a hand<br />

Customers (n=27) Producers (n=38)<br />

Precision of contracts Precision of contracts<br />

sum Form of contracts sum Form of contracts<br />

not fixed fixeda written/verbal/both not fixed fixeda written/verbal/both<br />

Product specification 100 7 93 → 63 7 22 100 16 84 → 50 3 32<br />

Quantity of products 100 22 78 → 48 7 22 100 13 87 → 55 0 32<br />

Price of products 100 15 85 → 63 4 19 100 16 84 → 53 3 29<br />

Delivery time<br />

Agreement on<br />

100 15 85 → 59 7 19 100 13 87 → 58 5 24<br />

exclusivity<br />

Penalties for<br />

100 37 63 → 33 7 22 100 47 53 → 32 5 16<br />

breach of contracts 100 33 67 → 41 7 19 100 42 58 → 26 16 16<br />

Mean 100 22 78 → 51 7 20 100 25 75 → 46 5 25<br />

a sum of shares written, verbal and both<br />

Source: calculation based on own survey conducted in DFG SPP 1233 [2007]


Susanne Meyer: The world’s factory and informal ties<br />

shake, but prefer written agreements. When<br />

disputes occur, a written document is of higher<br />

value than a person's word. What could not be<br />

proven in the quantitative data, but has been<br />

derived from the interviews, is that although<br />

points are fixed in a written form, those written<br />

contracts are not comparable to what Westerners<br />

intuitively associate with written contracts.<br />

Family ties and long-term business relationships<br />

are reasons for non-dedicated contracts.<br />

Lawyers have often experienced that Chinese<br />

firms have only rudimentary contracts, even<br />

for large projects. Often, a one-page contract is<br />

concluded covering the main points, but it is<br />

not proofed by lawyers. Those contracts are<br />

very difficult to enforce by law in the case of<br />

disputes. LEE (1997, 189) shows that one third<br />

of HK managers rely on verbal contracts.<br />

Informal contracts indicate greater flexibility:<br />

An important contribution of this work is to<br />

study the correlation of informality and flexibility.<br />

Although HK firms indeed indicated<br />

having formal contracts, there is some evidence<br />

for informal contracting as well. Initial<br />

proof of whether informal contracts lead to<br />

quicker response and greater flexibility can be<br />

considered as an answer to the question of<br />

whether informality serves as necessity or opportunity.<br />

It must be investigated as to whether<br />

informal contracts are perhaps of even greater<br />

advantage than formal contracts with respect to<br />

the time of negotiation. In order to prove the<br />

correlation of informality and flexibility, evidence<br />

must be fo<strong>und</strong> of informal contracts<br />

leaving more leeway for firms to arrange the<br />

actual order, saving them extra time and reducing<br />

transaction costs. Flexibility in contractual<br />

arrangements was measured according to the<br />

time in days required by firms to negotiate details<br />

before the production process could start.<br />

What effect informal contracts have on the<br />

time between the beginning of negotiations and<br />

the start of production in contrast to formal<br />

contracts is shown in Tab. 6, distinguishing between<br />

customers and producers. HK firms<br />

which have informal contracts with their pro-<br />

21<br />

ducers indicated a shorter negotiation time on<br />

average than firms with formal contracts (three<br />

days instead of five days). In this case, informal<br />

contracts seem to allow more leeway for<br />

final negotiation, which reduces negotiation<br />

time before production can start. In a rapidly<br />

changing business environment, the costs of<br />

drawing up a comprehensive contract are extremely<br />

high. PRD firms in particular, as component<br />

suppliers of HK firms, suffer from permanently<br />

changing market conditions and poor<br />

forecasting systems, which increases their need<br />

for flexibility. When producers are located<br />

within the PRD, informality in contractual<br />

arrangements works well in combination with<br />

spatial proximity and guanxi, as information<br />

may be verbally agreed on and revised. This<br />

finding cannot yet be generalised due to the<br />

low number of cases. Moreover, the difference<br />

between three and five days is not significant.<br />

This finding only serves as an initial signal for<br />

the advantages of informal behaviour, but definitely<br />

needs further investigation.<br />

Informal agreements with customers reduce<br />

the time required for negotiation when an actual<br />

order is placed from seven days to six days.<br />

It seems to be more difficult to agree upon<br />

actual orders when the contract is informally<br />

organised in long-distance customer relationships,<br />

because the absolute negotiation time is<br />

longer. Again, due to the low number of cases,<br />

the findings cannot be generalised. Potential<br />

explanations for this observation could be that<br />

forecasting systems of HK firms are better and<br />

the need for flexibility is lower, therefore informal<br />

agreements are of advantage, but formal<br />

agreements can hold their own in terms of<br />

speed. As HK firms and international customers<br />

work in a complete institutional environment,<br />

transaction costs for concluding written<br />

contracts are lower. Additionally, this<br />

seems to be of advantage for the enforcement<br />

of contracts, as the legal system provides firms<br />

with sufficient enforcement mechanisms.<br />

LYONS (1994) investigated firms in France and<br />

fo<strong>und</strong> that contracts between firms usually tend<br />

Tab. 6: Effects of formal and informal framework agreements on the negotiation time<br />

Customers Producers<br />

n Time of negotiation n Time of negotiation<br />

Formal Contract 18 7 days 23 5 days<br />

Informal Contract 9 6 days 15 3 days<br />

Source: calculation based on own survey conducted in DFG SPP 1233 [2007]


22 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

to be informalised when they work in rapidly<br />

changing business environments, because the<br />

costs of drawing up a comprehensive contract<br />

are too high.<br />

Conclusion<br />

The aim of this paper was to show the <strong>und</strong>erestimated<br />

importance of informal interactions<br />

for business operations in transitional economies,<br />

which serve more purposes than simply<br />

to replace dysfunctional formal rules. The<br />

GPRD, with its distinct institutional setting,<br />

served as an example to prove to what extent<br />

informality serves as an opportunity or as a necessity.<br />

Informal ties in firm networks are<br />

maintained to some extent due to their high efficiency,<br />

even if formal institutions are developed<br />

to international standards. Informal interactions<br />

turned out not only to be considered<br />

as a substitute for missing formal rules, but as<br />

a complement. A firm survey in HK in 2008<br />

delivered the empirical data to prove the hypotheses.<br />

104 small and medium-sized firms<br />

were interviewed. As the quality of the survey<br />

was of great importance, the return rate was<br />

only 5 %. This also resulted in a low number of<br />

cases for analysing specific questions. As this<br />

study is of an explorative nature, representative<br />

results were not aimed for. The findings cannot<br />

be generalised, but they deliver initial signals<br />

for a positive assessment of informality, which<br />

should be considered for further research.<br />

It could be proven that HK firms apply a lower<br />

degree of informalisation in relations with<br />

global customers than with local producers<br />

when contacting and selecting partners as well<br />

as designing contracts (hypothesis 1). However,<br />

when firms work with producers in the<br />

PRD, they do not rely purely on informal ties,<br />

but have a healthy balance of formal and informal<br />

behaviour (hypothesis 2). For contacting<br />

and selecting partners, firms use their networks<br />

instead of the formal procedure of quality<br />

assessment. Contracts are mainly fixed in<br />

writing, but they only cover the most important<br />

details, which are subject to negotiation afterwards.<br />

It turned out that HK firms use informal<br />

ties to organise business with global customers<br />

as well. They do not only use informality as a<br />

necessity in dealing with Chinese firms, but<br />

also see it as an opportunity to increase their<br />

variety of modes to do business. Therefore, it<br />

can be expected that the world’s factory for<br />

electronic products in the GPRD will continue<br />

to rely on informal ties between firms, even if<br />

China makes an effort to improve its formal institutional<br />

environment. In order to prove this,<br />

further research is needed to see whether informal<br />

ties in reality overcome the discussion<br />

about the influence of institutions on firms’ behaviour,<br />

and to what extent. There were also<br />

empirical signals confirming hypothesis 3. The<br />

data showed that informal contracting reduces<br />

the time of negotiating contracts and therefore<br />

increases flexibility. This is initial proof for informality<br />

providing an opportunity for firms.<br />

Informality is not limited to necessity. As the<br />

number of cases is low, further investigation is<br />

required here.<br />

Without being a newly introduced business<br />

concept to firms in the GPRD, the strategic application<br />

of informal interaction may be an innovative<br />

approach to Western firms. With this<br />

study having stepped forward in identifying the<br />

relevance of informal interactions, a so<strong>und</strong> empirical<br />

analysis is desirable in order to clarify<br />

the patterns and mechanisms in more detail.<br />

Acknowledgement<br />

I would like to thank my colleague Daniel Schiller for<br />

the fruitful discussions and joint development of the<br />

idea to study informality from the perspective of necessity<br />

and opportunity. This paper is the result of our idea.<br />

Moreover, I would like to thank the anonymous reviewer<br />

for her/his helpful comments on earlier versions of<br />

the paper. F<strong>und</strong>ing for this research was received from<br />

the German Research Fo<strong>und</strong>ation (DFG) within the<br />

Priority Programme (SPP 1233) “Megacities-Megachallenge<br />

– the informal dynamics of global change”<br />

<strong>und</strong>er grant RE 1720/8-1.<br />

References<br />

ANGELES, R./NATH, R. (2000): An empirical study of<br />

EDI trading partner selection criteria in customer-supplier<br />

relationships. In: Information & Management,<br />

(37)5, 241-255.<br />

ARAUJO, L./ORNELAS, E. (2007): Trust-based trade.<br />

London. (CEP Discussion Paper No 820, Centre for<br />

Economic Performance, London School of Economics<br />

and Political Science).<br />

BAKER, W. E. (2000): Achieving success through social<br />

capital. Tapping the hidden resources in your personal<br />

and business networks. San Francisco.<br />

BOSCHMA, R./FRENKEN K. (2009): Some notes on institutions<br />

in evolutionary economic geography. In: Economic<br />

Geography, (82)5, 151-158.


Susanne Meyer: The world’s factory and informal ties<br />

BOSCHMA, R./FRENKEN K. (2006): Why is economic geography<br />

not an evolutionary science? Towards an evolutionary<br />

economic geography. In: Journal of Economic<br />

Geography, 6, 273-302.<br />

BURT, R. S. (1992): Structural holes: the social structure<br />

of competition. Cambridge.<br />

CANFEI, H./WEI, Y.D./ XIUZHEN, X. (2008): Globalization,<br />

institutional change, and industrial location. Economic<br />

transition and industrial concentration in China.<br />

In: Regional Studies, (42)7, 923-945.<br />

COLEMAN, J.S. (1988): Social capital in the creation of<br />

human-capital. In: American Journal of Sociology, 94,<br />

95-120.<br />

COLEMAN, J.S. (1990): The fo<strong>und</strong>ations of social theory.<br />

Cambridge.<br />

DIMAGGIO, P./LOUCH, H. (1998): Socially embedded<br />

consumer transactions. For what kinds of purchases do<br />

people most often use networks? In: American Sociological<br />

Review, (63)5, 619-637.<br />

DUNNING, J. H./KIM, C. (2007): The cultural roots of<br />

Guanxi. An exploratory study. In: World Economy,<br />

(30)2, 329-341.<br />

DUYSTERS, G./KOK, G./VAANDRAGER, M. (1999): Crafting<br />

successful strategic technology partnerships. In:<br />

R&D Management, (29)4, 343-351.<br />

ERNST, D. (2004): Global production networks in East<br />

Asia's electronics industry and upgrading prospects in<br />

Malaysia. In: Yusuf, S./Altaf, M.A./Nabeshima, K.<br />

(Eds.): Global production networking and technological<br />

change in East Asia. Washington, 8-157.<br />

ETZOLD, B./KECK, M./BOHLE, H.-G./ZINGEL, W.-P.<br />

(2009): Informality as agency. Negotiating food security<br />

in Dhaka. In: Die Erde, (140)1, 1-22.<br />

FAN, Y. (2002): Questioning guanxi. Definition, classification<br />

and implications. In: International Business Review,<br />

11, 543-561.<br />

FEARON, J.D./LAITIN, D.D. (1996): Explaining interethnic<br />

cooperation. In: American Political Science Review,<br />

(90)4, 715-735.<br />

GASTON, R. J./BELL, S. (1988): The informal supply of<br />

capital. London. (Tech. report, Office of Economic Research,<br />

U.S. Small Business Administration).<br />

GERTLER, M. (2010): Rules of the game: The place of<br />

institutions in regional economic change. In: Regional<br />

Studies, (44)1, 1-15.<br />

GRANOVETTER, M. (1973): Strength of weak ties. In:<br />

American Journal of Sociology, (78)6, 1360-1380.<br />

GRANOVETTER,, M. (1985): Economic-action and socialstructure.<br />

The problem of embeddedness. In: American<br />

Journal of Sociology, (91)3, 481-510.<br />

Guangdong Provincial Bureau of Statistics (2006):<br />

Guangdong statistical yearbook 2006. (China Statistics<br />

Press).<br />

Guangdong Provincial Bureau of Statistics (2007):<br />

Guangdong statistical yearbook 2007. (China Statistics<br />

Press).<br />

HART, O./MOORE, J. (2004): Agreeing now to agree later.<br />

Contracts that rule out but do not rule. (China Statis-<br />

23<br />

tics Press) (Harvard Law and Economics Discussion Paper<br />

No. 465; Harvard <strong>Institut</strong>e of Econ. Research Disc.<br />

Paper 2032).<br />

HITT, M.A./DACIN, M.T./LEVITAS, E./ARREGLE,<br />

J.L./BORZA, A. (2000): Partner selection in emerging<br />

and developed market contexts. Resource-based and organizational<br />

learning perspectives. In: Academy of<br />

Management Journal, (43)3, 449-467.<br />

HUMPHREY, R. H./ASHFORTH, B.E. (2000): Buyer-supplier<br />

alliances in the automobile industry. How exitvoice<br />

strategies influence interpersonal relationships.<br />

In: Journal of Organizational Behavior, (21)6, 713-730.<br />

LEE, M.-K. (1997): The flexibility of the Hong Kong<br />

manufacturing sector. In: China Information, (12)1/2,<br />

189-214.<br />

LI, P.P. (2007): Social tie, social capital, and social behaviour.<br />

Toward an integrative model of informal exchange.<br />

In: Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 24,<br />

227-246.<br />

LUO, Y./CHEN, M. (1997): Does guanxi influence firm<br />

performance. In: Asia Pacific Journal of Management,<br />

14, 1-16.<br />

LYONS, B.R. (1994): Contracts and specific investment.<br />

An empirical test of transaction cost theory. In: Journal<br />

of Economics and Management Strategy, (3)2, 257-278.<br />

MACAULAY, S. (1963): Non-contractual relations in<br />

business. A preliminary-study. In: American Sociological<br />

Review, (28)1, 55-67.<br />

MACLEOD, W.B. (2006): Reputations, relationships and<br />

the enforcement of incomplete contracts. Ney York.<br />

(Center for Economic Studies & <strong>Institut</strong>e for Economic<br />

Research, Working Paper 1730).<br />

MASTEN, E.S. (2000): Contractual choice. In: Boukaert,<br />

B./De Geest, G. (Eds.): Encyclopedia of Law and Economics.<br />

Cheltenham, 25-45.<br />

MENARD, C. (2004): The economics of hybrid organizations.<br />

In: Journal of <strong>Institut</strong>ional and Theoretical Economics,<br />

(160)3, 345-376.<br />

MEYER, S./SCHILLER, D./REVILLA DIEZ, J. (2009): The<br />

Janus-faced economy: Hong Kong firms as intermediaries<br />

between global customers and local producers in<br />

the electronics industry. In: Tijdschrift voor economische<br />

en sociale geografie, (100)2, 224-235.<br />

Millington, A./Eberhardt, M./Wilkinson, B. (2006):<br />

Guanxi and supplier search mechanisms in China. In:<br />

Human Relations, (59)4, 505-531.<br />

MISZTAL, B. (2000): Informality. Social theory and contemporary<br />

practice. London.<br />

NEE, V. (1992): Organizational dynamics of market<br />

transition. Hybrid forms, property-rights, and mixed<br />

economy in China. In: Administrative Science Quarterly,<br />

(37)1, 1-27.<br />

NORTH, D. (1990): <strong>Institut</strong>ions, institutional change and<br />

economic performance. Cambridge.<br />

PARK, S.H./LUO, Y.D. (2001): Guanxi and organizational<br />

dynamics. Organizational networking in Chinese<br />

firms. In: Strategic Management Journal, (22)5, 455-<br />

477.


24 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

PIDDUCK, A.B. (2006): Issues in supplier partner selection.<br />

In: Journal of Enterprise Information Management,<br />

(19)3, 262-276.<br />

POWELL, W.W. (1990): Neither market nor hierarchy.<br />

Network forms of organization. In: Research in Organizational<br />

Behavior, 12, 295-336.<br />

PUTNAM, R.D. (1993): Making democracy work. Civic<br />

traditions in modern Italy. Princeton.<br />

PUTNAM, R.D. (2000): Bowling alone. The collapse and<br />

revival of American community. New York.<br />

RICHTER, R./FURUBOTN, E. (1996): Neue <strong>Institut</strong>ionenökonomik.<br />

Eine Einführung <strong>und</strong> kritische Würdigung.<br />

Tübingen.<br />

SAFFU, K./MAMMAN, A. (2000): Mechanics, problems<br />

and contributions of tertiary strategic alliances. The case<br />

of 22 Australian universities. In: Library Consortium<br />

Management: An International Journal, (2)2, 44-53.<br />

SEGAL, I. (1999): Complexity and renegotiation. A fo<strong>und</strong>ation<br />

for incomplete contracts. In: Review of Economic<br />

Studies, (66)1, 57-82.<br />

SHILLER, R.J./POUND, J. (1989): Survey evidence on diffusion<br />

of interest and information among investors. In: Journal<br />

of Economic Behavior & Organization, (1)1, 47-66.<br />

SINDZINGRE, A. (2006): The relevance of the concepts of<br />

formality and informality. A theoretical appraisal. In:<br />

Guha-Khasnobis, B./Kanbur, R./Ostrom, E. (Eds.):<br />

Linking the formal and informal economy. Concepts<br />

and policies. Oxford, 58-74.<br />

WILLIAMSON, O. (2000): The new institutional economics.<br />

Taking stock, looking ahead. In: Journal of Economic<br />

Literature, (38)3, 595-613.<br />

XIN, K.R./PEARCE, J.L. (1996): Guanxi: Connections as<br />

substitutes for formal institutional support. In: Academy<br />

of Management Journal, (39)6, 1641-1658.<br />

YEUNG, H.W. C., LIN, G.C.S. (2003) Theorizing economic<br />

geographies of Asia. In: Economic Geography,<br />

(79)2, 107-128.<br />

ZENGER, T.R./LAZZARINI, S.G./POPPO, L. (2002): Informal<br />

and formal organization in new institutional economics.<br />

In: New <strong>Institut</strong>ionalism in Strategic Management,<br />

19, 277-305.<br />

ZHANG, Y./ZHANG, Z.G. (2006): Guanxi and organizational<br />

dynamics in China. A link between individual and<br />

organizational levels. In: Journal of Business Ethics,<br />

(67)4, 375-392.


Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> Jg. 56 (2012) Heft 1-2, S. 25-42<br />

Frank Bickenbach/ Wan-Hsin Liu, Kiel<br />

Firm characteristics and informal governance of business operations<br />

in the Pearl River Delta, China<br />

Abstract: This paper describes the Chinese economic and institutional reform process as a gradual<br />

transition of an informal, relation-based governance system into a more formal and rule-based<br />

governance system. The consequences of macro-level institutional reforms on the importance of<br />

personal relationships for the firm-level governance of business operations are discussed. Theoretical<br />

considerations suggest that in a transition economy such as China companies’ incentives to<br />

reduce the reliance on personal relationships should depend on firm characteristics such as the age,<br />

size and the internationalization of the firm. We confront these suppositions with empirical data<br />

obtained from a company survey performed among 222 companies in the electronics industry operating<br />

in the Pearl River Delta, China. From this we obtain some, though often weak, evidence<br />

in favor of the suppositions.<br />

Keywords: formal and informal institutions, relation-based governance, firm characteristics,<br />

China, company survey<br />

JEL classification: L20, L63, P0<br />

Introduction<br />

Over the last three decades, China has recorded<br />

very high economic growth rates and developed<br />

into the second largest economy in the<br />

world. This remarkable growth was accompanied<br />

and fueled by continuing reforms of formal<br />

legal and market institutions which together<br />

led to substantial changes in the institutional<br />

environment in which business firms operate in<br />

China. This reform process may be viewed as a<br />

gradual transformation of the Chinese economy<br />

from an informal, relation-based governance<br />

system to a more formal and rule-based<br />

governance system (LI 2004; LI/PARK/LI<br />

2004).<br />

The importance and pervasive use of personal<br />

relationships in daily social and business life in<br />

China has attracted considerable attention<br />

among researchers from various disciplines.<br />

There has in particular been a growing economics<br />

and management literature on the role<br />

of personal relationships for doing business in<br />

China. Most of the empirical studies of that literature<br />

are based on surveys among Chinese<br />

managers or foreign managers with some experience<br />

in Chinese business (e.g. XIN/PEARCE<br />

1996; DAVIES/LEUNG/LUK/WONG 1995; LUO<br />

1997; PARK/LUO 2001). Generally, the survey<br />

results confirm the importance of personal relationships<br />

with other managers and/or with<br />

government officials (for a summary see LAN-<br />

GENBERG 2007, LUO 2007). In a study related to<br />

the present one, BICKENBACH/LIU (2010) confirm<br />

this general observation for Hong Kong<br />

based companies with operations in the Pearl<br />

River Delta (PRD) 1 , China. They also find evidence<br />

showing that personal relationships are<br />

less important than other more objective criteria<br />

for these companies’ decisions on business<br />

partners (and business locations). This result<br />

may be interpreted as an indication that the improvements<br />

in the formal institutional environment<br />

induce companies operating in current<br />

China to gradually reduce their predominant<br />

reliance on informal relation-based governance<br />

instruments and turn to make increased use of<br />

rule-based governance instruments such as formal<br />

contracting and public information institutions.<br />

Theoretical considerations suggest that, in a<br />

transition economy such as China, not all companies<br />

will have equally strong incentives to


26 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

move from informal relation-based to more<br />

formal, rule-based forms of governance. The<br />

incentives to reduce the reliance on personal<br />

relations will be stronger, in particular, for older,<br />

larger and faster growing firms. The same<br />

may be expected to be true for companies with<br />

more international business contacts (international<br />

suppliers or customers) or larger foreign<br />

ownership interests. This paper outlines the<br />

theoretical considerations <strong>und</strong>erlying these<br />

suppositions and confronts them with data obtained<br />

from a company survey that was done<br />

among 222 companies in the electronics industry<br />

operating in the PRD, China.<br />

In the following we briefly present the institutional<br />

economics perspective on the nature of<br />

informal, relation-based and formal, rule-based<br />

modes of governance and their comparative<br />

(dis)advantages, both at the aggregate and at<br />

the firm level and derive our core suppositions<br />

regarding the relation between firm characteristics<br />

and firms’ incentives to use of personal<br />

relationships for doing business in a “transition”<br />

economy. Then we outline the changing<br />

institutional environment in China in general<br />

and in the PRD in particular and we discuss the<br />

empirical results regarding the relation between<br />

firm characteristics and the role of personal<br />

relationships for doing business in the<br />

PRD.<br />

Theoretical considerations<br />

<strong>Institut</strong>ions, i.e. rules and instruments to enforce<br />

these rules, matter for the efficiency of<br />

human exchange (NORTH 1990). By defining<br />

and protecting property rights, enforcing contracts,<br />

and providing reliable information, well<br />

functioning (economic) institutions can reduce<br />

the risks and transaction costs of investment<br />

and exchange. These institutions can be formal<br />

or informal. Formal institutions include political,<br />

judicial and economic rules, ranging from<br />

written constitutions and statutory laws to specific<br />

regulations and to individual contracts.<br />

Informal institutions include the social and religious<br />

norms, traditions and codes of conduct<br />

and the social networks that exist in a society<br />

(NORTH 1990, 36, 47). Two levels of institutions<br />

are to be distinguished: the institutional<br />

environment and institutional arrangements.<br />

The institutional environment is the overarching<br />

framework of political, social and legal<br />

rules and constraints that define the context in<br />

which economic and social interaction takes<br />

place. Within this framework, parties to a specific<br />

exchange set up institutional arrangements,<br />

i.e., formal and informal (micro-level)<br />

rules and forms of contracts that govern the<br />

way in which they cooperate and/or compete<br />

(WILLIAMSON 1996, 378).<br />

Three elements of the institutional environment,<br />

in particular, are of great importance for<br />

the level and the organization of economic exchange<br />

of an economy: contracting institutions,<br />

property rights institutions and information<br />

institutions. Contracting institutions are<br />

the rules that support the conclusion and the<br />

enforcement of contracts between (private)<br />

economic agents (ACEMOGLU/JOHNSON 2005,<br />

955). They affect the costs of drafting and enforcing<br />

contracts and consequently the type of<br />

contracts and transactions realized. Property<br />

rights institutions are the rules that protect (the<br />

returns to) the assets held by economic agents<br />

against expropriation by others, in particular,<br />

by the government and politically powerful<br />

elites (ACEMOGLU/JOHNSON 2005, 955; GREIF<br />

2005, 728). They affect the risk of direct government<br />

expropriation as well as the level to<br />

which regulations and public decisions determine<br />

a level playing field for all economic actors<br />

or favor and protect a small elite with close<br />

relationships with the government. Information<br />

institutions are public or private institutions<br />

for gathering and distributing information.<br />

They affect the amount and the quality of<br />

information available to economic actors (and<br />

public agents) and impact, in particular, the<br />

cost of screening (potential) business partners<br />

and of monitoring their performance. 2<br />

There are substantial differences between societies<br />

in the nature and sophistication of their<br />

basic institutions and in the degree to which<br />

they are able to reduce the transaction costs<br />

and the risks associated with economic exchange<br />

and investments in private assets. In<br />

Western societies, over time, a complex system<br />

of formal institutions for public information<br />

provision, contract enforcement and property<br />

rights protection has been devised, on which<br />

people can build for governing economic exchanges.<br />

Many of these formal institutions are<br />

non-existent, weak or poorly devised in less<br />

developed countries (BARDHAN 2005, 512). To<br />

govern economic exchanges people in these<br />

countries tend to rely more on informal institu-


Frank Bickenbach / Wan-Hsin Liu: Firm characteristics and informal governance 27<br />

tions and personal relations, e.g., guanxi in<br />

China (LI/PARK/LI 2004, 63).<br />

Based on this general observation, we may<br />

distinguish for analytical purposes between<br />

two modes of governance systems: relationbased<br />

and rule-based governance systems (LI<br />

2003; LI/PARK/LI 2004; DIXIT 2004). The two<br />

systems differ both at the macro-level of the<br />

institutional environment and at the micro-level<br />

of the institutional arrangements chosen to<br />

govern individual transactions between economic<br />

agents. These differences have profo<strong>und</strong><br />

implications for the nature and size of<br />

transaction costs <strong>und</strong>er the two governance<br />

systems.<br />

In a rule-based governance system public rules<br />

(laws and regulations) and state policies are<br />

transparent, fair, and universally applied and<br />

economic transactions are largely based on impersonal<br />

and explicit formal contracts. Both,<br />

public rules and private contracts can be impartially<br />

enforced by the executive and the<br />

court system (LI 2003, 655; LI/PARK/LI 2004,<br />

64). Economic agents have access to highquality<br />

and verifiable business information<br />

provided through a broad range of well established<br />

public information institutions (e.g. accounting<br />

and auditing rules, credit information<br />

institutions). This reduces the costs of screening<br />

and monitoring (potential) business partners<br />

and of enforcing business contracts (LI<br />

2003, 657).<br />

In a relation-based governance system, by contrast,<br />

public rules tend to be unfair and opaque,<br />

and the state is unable to enforce these rules<br />

impartially (LI /PARK /LI 2004, 64). Courts,<br />

due to the lack of independence and/or competence,<br />

are generally not able to enforce public<br />

rules or private contracts effectively. Most<br />

transactions between business partners are<br />

governed by personal and implicit agreements<br />

that are enforced outside the courtrooms (LI<br />

2003, 652). Publicly available information<br />

about (potential) business partners is rare and<br />

generally of low-quality. Key information<br />

about business partners has to be derived from<br />

personal relations. Information about business<br />

partners and business relationships tends to remain<br />

personal, and relational, i.e., mutually<br />

observable to the two transaction partners but<br />

unverifiable by people outside the relationship<br />

(LI/PARK/LI 2004, 64, 69; LI 2004, 108). 3<br />

It is widely recognized that the importance and<br />

the relative efficiency of formal institutions<br />

and rule-based governance increases relative to<br />

that of informal institution and relation-based<br />

governance as the scope of market exchange<br />

broadens and deepens (see NORTH 1990; LII<br />

2003; DIXIT 2004; LI/PARK/LI 2004). Relationbased<br />

governance systems work well in small<br />

or/and well-knit groups, whereas efficient exchange<br />

relations in large groups require more<br />

formal institutions for information dissemination<br />

and enforcement. At the aggregate level<br />

relation-based governance is associated with<br />

comparatively low fixed costs as it avoids the<br />

high fixed costs of developing elaborate formal<br />

public information and contracting institutions.<br />

At the level of individual exchanges, parties<br />

with existing personal relationships will find<br />

relation-based governance to be less costly as it<br />

saves the costs of legal enforcement and information<br />

verification. However, relation-based<br />

governance exhibits comparatively high and<br />

increasing costs of extending business to new<br />

business partners. Extending business will increasingly<br />

require establishing relations with<br />

persons, to which agents have a priori only<br />

weak or no private relations which raises the<br />

costs of searching for competent and reliable<br />

partners and of establishing personal relations<br />

with them.<br />

A rule-based governance system, in contrast,<br />

involves large fixed costs for establishing the<br />

necessary legal and informational infrastructure.<br />

However, once the necessary information<br />

and contracting institutions have been established<br />

the marginal costs of screening potential<br />

business partners and of negotiating and enforcing<br />

an (additional) contract between an<br />

(additional) pair of transaction parties, including<br />

strangers, are comparatively low due to the<br />

quality of publicly available information and<br />

the fact that the contracts are explicit, impersonal,<br />

and standardized (LI 2003, 657;<br />

LI/PARK/LI 2004, 65). As the scale and scope<br />

of the economy increases, the fixed costs of establishing<br />

a rule-based governance system can<br />

be spread over a larger number of transactions,<br />

thus lowering the average costs. Eventually an<br />

expanding economy will reach a point where<br />

the average transaction costs are smaller <strong>und</strong>er<br />

rule-based governance than <strong>und</strong>er relationbased<br />

governance and it would be advantageous<br />

for society to develop an institutional environment<br />

that supports rule-based governance.


28 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

The transition of an economy from a (more) relation-based<br />

to a (more) rule-based governance<br />

system will generally be a gradual and slow<br />

process. The basic informal institutions that exist<br />

in a society are often embedded in cultural<br />

traditions and moral value systems. They therefore<br />

possess inertia that slows the pace of institutional<br />

change (ZENGER/LAZZARINI/POPPO<br />

2002, 283 f.). 4 Even the effects of occasional<br />

broad and fast changes of formal institutions<br />

may be limited by tensions between the new<br />

formal rules and existing informal rules that respond<br />

only gradually to changes in the formal<br />

institutions. These tensions may <strong>und</strong>ermine<br />

compliance with formal rules and may create a<br />

lag between the implementation of a new formal<br />

institutional structure and its overall functionality<br />

(ZENGER/LAZZARINI/POPPO 2002, 283<br />

f.; NORTH 1990, 91). Simply issuing new, Western-type,<br />

business laws and formal institutions<br />

may thus not be sufficient to substantially improve<br />

the quality of public information, of legal<br />

contract enforcement and of the effective<br />

protection of property rights. And even if the<br />

new formal institutions work reasonably well,<br />

persistent cultural norms may still induce<br />

(some) economic agents at the micro-level to<br />

stick to the use of relation-based forms of governance.<br />

This is true, in particular, where the<br />

cost advantage of rule-based governance is still<br />

relatively small (and competitive pressures are<br />

not too strong).<br />

The theoretical considerations about the working<br />

and the (relative) costs and benefits of the<br />

two modes of governance suggest, that firms’<br />

incentives to move from relation-based to rulebased<br />

governance should depend on a number<br />

of firm characteristics, such as the size and the<br />

growth performance of the firm, its age, its<br />

ownership and the degree of its integration into<br />

national and international markets. The marginal<br />

cost of relation-based governance will<br />

generally be higher for large firms than for<br />

small firms. At the same time it will be easier<br />

for them to bear the firm-level fixed costs of<br />

rule-based governance – such as the costs of<br />

introducing new accounting and auditing systems<br />

or of acquiring the skills necessary to formulate<br />

and manage externally enforceable contracts.<br />

We should therefore expect that large<br />

firms have a greater propensity to engage in<br />

rule-based governance than small firms. Similarly,<br />

as the development of personal relations<br />

to new business partners is costly and timeconsuming,<br />

firms that are growing quickly in<br />

size and in the number of business partners will<br />

have greater incentives to reduce their reliance<br />

on personal relationships. Firms that are able<br />

and willing to make use of formal, rule-based<br />

mechanisms for searching and screening new<br />

business partners and managing and enforcing<br />

contractual agreements will find it easier to<br />

quickly expand the number of their business<br />

partners and will thus be able to grow faster.<br />

The age of a firm is certainly correlated with its<br />

size and possibly with its growth rate. The age<br />

of a firm will therefore have an indirect effect<br />

on its incentives to use rule-based governance<br />

mechanisms. The age of a firm can be expected<br />

to also have a direct influence on these incentives,<br />

however. Old-established firms will<br />

have accumulated substantial experience with<br />

relation-based governance and will already<br />

have established long-term personal relationships<br />

with a number of business partners and<br />

possibly public officials as well. Even as institutions<br />

of rule-based governance get gradually<br />

established at the level of the institutional environment,<br />

these firms will have an interest to<br />

continue to make use of their existing relationships,<br />

though it may become increasingly difficult<br />

to sustain these relationships as switching<br />

business partners becomes easier during the<br />

transition. At the same time established firms<br />

may have built up a public reputation as reliable<br />

business partners which allows them to<br />

get into business with new partners more easily.<br />

By contrast, even with improving information<br />

institutions new firms will generally have<br />

great difficulties signalling reliability and competence.<br />

At least with respect to getting into<br />

contact with new business partners existing<br />

personal relations with family members or<br />

friends (or early business partners) can thus be<br />

expected to be more important for young firms<br />

than for old-established ones. As to the importance<br />

of personal relations for doing business<br />

in general there is no clear conjecture about the<br />

role of firm age, however. On the one hand it<br />

will be very difficult for young firms to establish<br />

themselves in the market without personal<br />

relations, on the other hand older firms will<br />

simply have more well-established personal relations<br />

to business partners or public officials<br />

on that they can continue to build.<br />

For heads of firms from a relation-based economy<br />

it is generally much more difficult to establish<br />

and cultivate personal relations with<br />

foreign business partners that are not acquaint-


Frank Bickenbach / Wan-Hsin Liu: Firm characteristics and informal governance 29<br />

ed with the specifics of relation-based governance<br />

than with business partners from their<br />

own region or country. Domestic firms will<br />

therefore be less likely to use relation-based<br />

governance mechanisms for business transactions<br />

with foreigners than for transactions with<br />

domestic business partners. As firms with<br />

many foreign business partners will get acquainted<br />

with using formal information and<br />

contracting institutions and will have to invest<br />

in their ability to use these institutions, they<br />

will also be more likely to reduce their reliance<br />

on relation-based governance even for transactions<br />

with domestic business partners. In a<br />

transition economy, relation-based governance<br />

will therefore be comparatively less important<br />

for firms that have more business relations<br />

with customers or suppliers from Western<br />

economies. Similar arguments apply to the<br />

comparison of domestically-owned and foreign-owned<br />

firms. Foreign owners and managers<br />

will generally not be familiar with the<br />

specifics of relation-based governance and it<br />

will be much harder for them to establish personal<br />

relationships with executives of local<br />

firms. At the same time, they are familiar with<br />

rule-based governance instruments. They will<br />

therefore have an incentive to extend formal<br />

governance mechanisms to their local subsidiaries<br />

and their transactions with local partners<br />

as well. In transition economies, foreignowned<br />

(in particular Western-owned) firms can<br />

thus be expected to make less use of personal<br />

relationships than domestically owned firms.<br />

Changing institutional environment for<br />

doing business<br />

China today may be viewed as a society that is<br />

in a gradual process of transition from a relation-based<br />

to a more rule-based governance<br />

system (LI 2004; LI/PARK/LI 2004).<br />

The (traditional) role of personal<br />

relationships in China<br />

The importance and pervasive use of personal<br />

relationships in daily social and business life in<br />

China has been stressed by numerous observers<br />

and has attracted considerable attention<br />

among researchers from various disciplines<br />

(for a partial overview with a focus on business<br />

economics and sociological economics see<br />

LANGENBERG 2007). While the cultivation of<br />

personal relationships, in some form and to<br />

some extent, exists in every society, its specif-<br />

ic form, guanxi, and its pervasiveness and importance<br />

in daily social and business life are<br />

often considered distinctively Chinese (STAN-<br />

DIFIRD/MARSHALL 2000, 22). Guanxi is cultivated<br />

through the repeated exchange of gifts<br />

and favors, which creates a sense of reciprocal<br />

obligation and indebtedness of the partners<br />

(STANDIFIRD/MARSHALL 2000, 22 f.). Developing<br />

bilateral guanxi to several other persons<br />

that may also develop personal relationships<br />

among each other leads to a guanxi network.<br />

As information about a partner’s opportunistic<br />

behavior with one of his exchange partners<br />

spreads through the whole network, such behavior<br />

can easily result in the offending party<br />

being banished from the network altogether.<br />

Within guanxi networks, the threat of network<br />

expulsion increases the cost of opportunistic<br />

behavior, thus providing an increased assurance<br />

that one’s exchange partner will not act<br />

opportunistically. The flow of information<br />

within guanxi networks is not restricted to information<br />

on members’ conduct for the purpose<br />

of sanctioning opportunistic behavior,<br />

however. There is also a vivid exchange of information<br />

about business opportunities and<br />

about the competence and reliability of potential<br />

business partners. “The exchange of information<br />

favors in guanxi networks is so common<br />

that guanxi is said to act as an ‘information<br />

bridge’” (LANGENBERG 2007, 46). These<br />

benefits do not come for free, however. Establishing<br />

and cultivating guanxi networks takes<br />

time and other resources. Moreover, having to<br />

choose, due to reciprocal obligations, transaction<br />

partners from within one’s personal network<br />

may inhibit potentially profitable transactions<br />

with people outside the network (LAN-<br />

GENBERG 2007).<br />

The importance of guanxi in China is not restricted<br />

to relations between private persons.<br />

Given the paramount role that the state (government<br />

and bureaucracy) continues to play in<br />

the Chinese society and economy, personal relationships<br />

with government and party officials<br />

(political relations) are considered to be of<br />

great significance for citizens’ quality of life<br />

and businesses’ success (see, e.g., LANGENBERG<br />

2007). 5<br />

Reform of the formal institutional<br />

environment in China<br />

Since the beginning of economic reforms in<br />

1978 there have been dramatic changes in the<br />

institutional environment for doing business in


30 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

China. By 2007, the year of the company survey<br />

<strong>und</strong>erlying our empirical analysis, formal<br />

contracting, information, and with some reservations<br />

also, property rights institutions have<br />

been improved considerably. The first Economic<br />

Contract Law passed in 1981 was still<br />

intended largely to regularize relations between<br />

state-owned enterprises. As economic<br />

reforms gradually led to a great expansion in<br />

the number and importance of non-state enterprises<br />

the role of contract law shifted towards<br />

governing the interactions between independent<br />

economic agents. The overall scope of<br />

contract laws was gradually broadened by<br />

passing specific contract laws and amending<br />

the Economic Contract Law. In 1999, the different<br />

contract laws were replaced by a new<br />

unified contract law that gave broad range to<br />

freedom of contract and provided a uniform legal<br />

framework for economic contracts by individuals<br />

and enterprises alike, regardless of<br />

ownership and nationality (for details see<br />

CLARKE/MURRELL/WHITING 2008). During the<br />

reform, the importance of courts for the resolution<br />

of disputes over contracts increased substantially.<br />

Despite their many remaining deficiencies<br />

courts are now playing a significant<br />

role in dispute resolution (CLARKE/ MUR-<br />

RELL/WHITING 2008), and in comparison with<br />

other developing and developed countries, the<br />

ability of Chinese courts to solve disputes over<br />

simple and clearly written contracts has been<br />

rated quite favorably (in 2007). 6<br />

Like contract law, many of the public information<br />

institutions that are of great importance in<br />

modern market economies were virtually nonexistent<br />

when the reform process began. By<br />

2007, China has made substantial progress in<br />

reforming or introducing some of these information<br />

institutions – though much remains to<br />

be done. An important example are accounting<br />

standards. In the early stages of the reform<br />

process, several different sets of accounting<br />

rules applying to firms with different ownership<br />

structures and from different industries<br />

were introduced. Generally, these rules deviated<br />

substantially from international accounting<br />

standards. The new Accounting Standards for<br />

Business Enterprises that came into force in<br />

2007 are, by contrast, broadly in line with international<br />

accounting standards but they are<br />

mandatory, for now, only for listed companies.<br />

Despite some convergence with international<br />

standards, the practical application of China’s<br />

accounting principles is still a complex and<br />

opaque process (for additional information see<br />

World Bank 2009). A second example relates to<br />

credit information. In the early 2000s the People’s<br />

Bank of China established a rapidly expanding<br />

Corporate Credit Information Database<br />

that contains information on companies’<br />

bank and non-bank credit relationships (see<br />

JENTZSCH 2008). In 2006, it contained information<br />

on about eleven million enterprises of<br />

which about five million had a credit relationship.<br />

Later the system was extended to include<br />

credit information on individuals. 7 As these examples<br />

illustrate, access to business information<br />

has expanded substantially during the reform<br />

period. Several important reform steps<br />

have been taken only rather recently, however,<br />

and there is still a long way to go before public<br />

information institutions in China reach Western<br />

standards.<br />

Compared to the progress made in improving<br />

formal contracting and information institutions,<br />

reform progress in formal property rights<br />

institutions has been (even) more limited. Only<br />

in 2007, after several years of considerable<br />

controversy and delay, a unified Property Law<br />

was passed. This law introduces and defines<br />

the concept of property rights in a unified way<br />

covering state property, collective property as<br />

well as private property. It defines the rights<br />

owners have over their property and the obligations<br />

assumed by others in respect of this<br />

property. However, to ensure that the law was<br />

passed, a number of areas, including modalities<br />

of legal redress, have been left vague, limiting<br />

the effectiveness of the protection of private<br />

property rights in practice (OECD 2008, 23 ff.;<br />

MARECHAL/TEKIN/GULIYEVA 2009).<br />

More generally, due to broad decision making<br />

powers of numerous (local and central) government<br />

bodies and courts’ inability to effectively<br />

constrain (arbitrary) government action<br />

China’s current legal system is largely unable<br />

to provide secure property rights. A main reason<br />

for courts’ inability to effectively enforce<br />

laws and constrain governments is their political<br />

and financial dependence on local governments.<br />

8 This makes it difficult for courts to decide<br />

against the wishes of local governments,<br />

and allows local governments to influence<br />

courts, or to ignore their decisions, in order to<br />

accommodate the interests of companies with<br />

strong political relationships (CLARKE/MUR-<br />

RELL/WHITING 2008; for examples see LI<br />

2004).


Frank Bickenbach / Wan-Hsin Liu: Firm characteristics and informal governance 31<br />

In current China, local and central government<br />

officials still hold numerous instruments and<br />

wide discretionary powers to interfere with<br />

business operations and affect business success.<br />

Business operations require licenses, permits<br />

and approvals from various governmental<br />

authorities and are subject to numerous business<br />

laws and regulations. The requirements<br />

for obtaining licenses and permits as well as<br />

the terms and interpretations of business regulations<br />

often lack transparency. They can differ<br />

substantially across provinces, districts and<br />

even towns and are subject to frequent<br />

changes. Business success is also affected by<br />

officials’ decisions on the allocation of landuse<br />

rights and of other scarce resources, or by<br />

their decisions on subsidies, favorable tax<br />

treatments and government procurement contracts.<br />

Against this backgro<strong>und</strong> personal relations<br />

with public officials can help smooth<br />

business operations and reduce the risk of expropriation<br />

by the politically powerful.<br />

Changing institutional business<br />

environment in the PRD<br />

As a consequence of the substantial influence<br />

that local and regional politicians have on<br />

business relevant policies and on the enforcement<br />

of laws and contracts, the quality of the<br />

legal system and of formal market institutions<br />

can differ considerably across Chinese provinces.<br />

Our empirical analysis is restricted to<br />

firms located in the Pearl River Delta in the<br />

province of Guangdong. Therefore, the quality<br />

of the institutional environment of Guangdong<br />

is of particular interest to our analysis. Guangdong<br />

has been a pioneer region of the Chinese<br />

economic reforms over the last three decades.<br />

Since the beginning of reforms the business<br />

and investment environment in Guangdong<br />

has been more developed and more business<br />

friendly than in many other Chinese provinces.<br />

This has recently been confirmed by a World<br />

Bank report (World Bank 2008) that compared<br />

the business and investment environments of<br />

30 major cities in China (from all Chinese<br />

provinces, with the exception of Tibet). Four<br />

indicators of a business-friendly environment<br />

were compared: the ease of starting a business,<br />

of registering property, of getting credit, and of<br />

enforcing contracts. Guangzhou, the capital of<br />

Guangdong, ranked among the top three cities<br />

for all four indicators and it even ranked first<br />

for contract enforcement. Legal and formal<br />

market institutions are thus generally more developed<br />

in Guangdong (and in the PRD in par-<br />

ticular), than in most other Chinese provinces.<br />

Still, as compared to advanced Western countries<br />

(or to neighboring Hong Kong) formal legal<br />

and market institutions in Guangdong are<br />

still clearly deficient and certainly much less<br />

favorable to a rule-based governance of individual<br />

business operations.<br />

It is worth mentioning that the comparatively<br />

advanced institutional reform process in<br />

Guangdong has gone hand in hand with an<br />

expansion and internationalization of (private)<br />

economic activity that is outstanding even for<br />

Chinese standards. Guangdong had the highest<br />

GDP (2,621 bio. RMB) of all Chinese provinces<br />

and the growth rate (15 %) was also among<br />

the highest in China in 2006 (NBSC 2007). In<br />

the same year, the number of state-owned and<br />

non-state-owned industrial enterprises with annual<br />

revenues of over 5 mio. RMB was about<br />

37,500, the second largest number of all Chinese<br />

provinces, and these companies’ gross industrial<br />

output and industrial value added were<br />

higher than the corresponding figures in all<br />

other provinces. Having the second highest<br />

openness index 9 , Guangdong’s economy was<br />

also more strongly integrated into the international<br />

markets than all other Chinese provinces,<br />

with the exception of Shanghai.<br />

For an institutional and economic environment<br />

such as that of Guangdong, or the PRD, the institutional<br />

approach suggests that personal relations<br />

with business partners and with public<br />

officials are still playing an important role for<br />

many firms’ business operations. However,<br />

with continuously improved formal institutions<br />

and with increasing scale and complexity in<br />

business operations on site, certain firms may<br />

already begin to reduce their dependence on<br />

personal relations and to increasingly rely on<br />

formal institutions for governing their business<br />

operations.<br />

Empirical analysis<br />

The PRD Company Survey 2007 on which our<br />

empirical analysis is based was addressed to<br />

executives of electronics companies in the<br />

PRD. 10 As the economically dominant region<br />

within Guangdong province with its comparatively<br />

advanced institutional reform process<br />

and its vivid private enterprise sector, the PRD<br />

constitutes a suitable research region for our<br />

research purpose. The focus on a single indus-


32 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

try helps to reduce industry-level firm heterogeneity<br />

and allows our analysis to focus on<br />

those firm characteristics that are, according to<br />

the theoretical considerations, likely to affect<br />

firms’ decisions on the use of relation-based or<br />

rule-based governance instruments. The electronics<br />

industry was selected due to its substantial<br />

importance for the regional economy in<br />

the PRD. The gross output of the electronics<br />

industry’s enterprises (state-owned enterprises<br />

and non-state-owned enterprises with annual<br />

business revenues of at least 5 mio. RMB)<br />

amounted to 41 % of all industries in 2006<br />

(GPBS 2007). Moreover, the electronics industry<br />

is a very dynamic industry characterized by<br />

short product life-cycles, quick product-related<br />

process modifications, and large research and<br />

development expenditures (TUAN/NG, 1995).<br />

In combination with the high intensity of global<br />

competition within the industry, these features<br />

force companies to continuously optimize<br />

the governance of their business operations.<br />

For our survey a total of 400 electronics companies<br />

were randomly selected from the comprehensive<br />

company catalogue Guangdong<br />

Electronics 2007. Overall 222 of these companies<br />

completed and returned the questionnaire.<br />

Our empirical analysis is based on the responses<br />

to a subset of the questions of these questionnaires.<br />

In the following we first present our<br />

results on the general role of personal relationships<br />

for doing business in the PRD. We then<br />

turn to the results on the importance of personal<br />

relationships (relative to other more formal<br />

and impersonal alternatives) for three critical<br />

business functions, namely for getting into<br />

contact with customers and with suppliers and<br />

for obtaining short-term finance. Finally, we<br />

present evidence on how the importance of<br />

personal relationships for individual firms<br />

varies with firm characteristics such as age,<br />

ownership structure, size and growth performance.<br />

Role of personal relationships<br />

for doing business in general<br />

Within the questionnaire two questions relate<br />

to the general importance of personal relationships<br />

for companies’ business operations in the<br />

PRD, with the first one considering personal<br />

relationships in general and the second one focusing<br />

on political relations. As to the importance<br />

of personal relationships in general, executives<br />

were asked to use a five-level Likert<br />

scale to assess the importance of six specified<br />

reasons for their firms’ decisions to fulfill some<br />

business tasks in the PRD via personal networks:<br />

to “substitute for missing laws and regulations”<br />

(SubMLaw), to “respond quickly to<br />

customer demands” (ResCus), to “increase<br />

company’s operational flexibility” (IncFlex),<br />

to “reduce risks and uncertainties” (RedRisk),<br />

to get “access to business-related information”<br />

(AccInfo), and to “solve business disputes”<br />

(SolDis). In total, about two thirds of respondents<br />

consider responding quickly to customer<br />

demands as a very important or important reason<br />

for their company to fulfill some tasks via<br />

personal relationships, whereas only about a<br />

quarter of them do so for substituting missing<br />

laws/regulations, or for solving business disputes<br />

(Tab.1). The shares of respondents considering<br />

the other three reasons as very important<br />

or important are at intermediate levels. 11<br />

Of the 212 executives who answered this question,<br />

170 executives (about 80 %) considered at<br />

least one reason as very important or important<br />

for their company to fulfill some tasks in PRD<br />

Tab. 1: Importance of reasons for using personal relationships – company distribution<br />

SubMLaw ResCus IncFlex RedRisk AccInfo SolDis<br />

1 very important 24 (13.3) 76 (37.4) 56 (29.3) 40 (21.1) 49 (25.5) 19 (10.4)<br />

2 important 24 (13.3) 60 (29.6) 42 (22.0) 39 (20.5) 28 (14.6) 26 (14.2)<br />

3 of normal<br />

importance 41 (22.8) 38 (18.7) 54 (28.3) 62 (32.6) 62 (32.3) 53 (29.0)<br />

4 of little<br />

importance 26 (14.4) 9 (4.4) 14 (7.3) 17 (9.0) 14 (7.3) 35 (19.1)<br />

5 not important 65 (36.1) 20 (9.9) 25 (13.1) 32 (16.8) 39 (20.3) 50 (27.3)<br />

Total 180 (100) 203 (100) 191 (100) 190 (100) 192 (100) 183 (100)<br />

Note: Numbers in parentheses refer to the corresponding company shares (%).<br />

Source: own survey


Frank Bickenbach / Wan-Hsin Liu: Firm characteristics and informal governance 33<br />

via personal relations (not documented in Tab.<br />

1). This suggests that personal relations are, for<br />

one reason or another, playing an important<br />

role for most companies in the PRD. It is less<br />

clear, however, how this relates to the weakness<br />

of formal legal and market institutions in<br />

current China. The two most important reasons<br />

for using personal relations, improving the<br />

ability to quickly respond to customer needs<br />

and increasing companies’ operational flexibility<br />

– the executives’ assessments of the importance<br />

of these two reasons are highly correlated<br />

across firms (Spearman correlation coefficient<br />

of almost 0.6) –, are essentially performance<br />

objectives and relation-based<br />

governance instruments may be advantageous<br />

for achieving these objectives even if formal<br />

institutions were well developed. And the one<br />

reason that explicitly refers to weak formal institutions,<br />

namely using personal relations as a<br />

“substitute for missing laws and regulations”<br />

has been considered important or very important<br />

by a minority (25 %) of respondents only.<br />

This seems to suggest that most companies in<br />

PRD do not see the deficiencies in the institutional<br />

environment but general transactions<br />

costs advantages of relation-based governance<br />

as the main reason for their use of personal relations.<br />

12<br />

Given the fact that public officials in China still<br />

have ample opportunities to directly or indirectly<br />

interfere with business operations and<br />

affect business success, companies may not only<br />

consider personal relationships with private<br />

economic agents important for doing business<br />

in the PRD but also personal relationships with<br />

public officials (political relations). Executives<br />

were therefore asked to assess the importance<br />

of political relations for carrying out five business<br />

“activities” 13 : “getting permissions for<br />

production/investment” (GetPermProd), “get-<br />

ting export/import concessions or licenses”<br />

(GetExImCon), getting “access to buildings<br />

and/or land” (AccBuild), getting “access to<br />

materials and resources” (AccRes), getting<br />

“access to financial support from government”<br />

(AccGovSup). Of the 212 companies that have<br />

answered the question, 144 companies (about<br />

68 %) considered political relations very important<br />

or important for at least one of the “activities”<br />

considered (Tab. 2). While more than<br />

half (54 %) of all respondents considered personal<br />

relationships with public officials very<br />

important or important for companies in PRD<br />

to get permissions for production and investment,<br />

only about 27 % and 31 % of them considered<br />

political relations important or very important<br />

for getting access to materials and resources<br />

and to financial support from<br />

government, respectively. The shares for the<br />

other two alternatives take intermediate values.<br />

These results suggest that political relationships<br />

are still important for companies to get<br />

access to ‘production factors’ that are crucial<br />

for companies’ operations and are still <strong>und</strong>er<br />

the control of government.<br />

An analysis of the pair-wise correlations between<br />

the assessments of the alternatives from<br />

the preceding two questions reveals that those<br />

executives that considered political relations<br />

more important (than other executives) also<br />

tended to consider “missing laws and regulations”<br />

as a more important reason for using<br />

personal relations in general. This may be taken<br />

as an indication that firms tend to consider<br />

the importance of political relations a consequence<br />

of weak formal institutions.<br />

The role of personal relationships for critical<br />

business functions<br />

Getting into contact with customers: It has<br />

been argued that in relation-based economies<br />

Tab. 2: Importance of political relations – company distribution<br />

GetPermProd GetExImCon AccBuild AccRes AccGovSup<br />

1 very important 82 (40.0) 51 (26.3) 44 (22.5) 35 (18.0) 36 (18.7)<br />

2 important 30 (14.6) 28 (14.4) 33 (16.8) 18 (9.3) 24 (12.4)<br />

3 of normal importance 36 (17.6) 47 (24.2) 39 (19.9) 48 (24.7) 39 (20.2)<br />

4 of little importance 16 (7.8) 20 (10.3) 25 (12.8) 27 (13.9) 27 (14.0)<br />

5 not important 41 (20.0) 48 (24.7) 55 (28.1) 66 (34.0) 67 (34.7)<br />

Total 205 (100) 194 (100) 196 (100) 194 (100) 193 (100)<br />

Note: Numbers in parentheses refer to the corresponding company shares (%).<br />

Source: own survey


34 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

personal relations are playing an important role<br />

in selecting business partners, while other impersonal<br />

alternatives of searching for and<br />

screening (potential) business partners are becoming<br />

more important as formal information<br />

and contracting institutions are getting more<br />

effective. In order to investigate the relative<br />

importance of relation-based governance<br />

mechanisms for companies to find new customers,<br />

we asked the executives to assess the<br />

importance of four different channels for getting<br />

into contact with their customers. (We also<br />

asked them to indicate if their companies<br />

did no use the respective channel at all.) Two of<br />

the four channels are non-relation-based,<br />

namely “bidding competitions”, and “active<br />

searching (e.g., exhibitions, internet, sales<br />

agents)”, while the other two are relationbased,<br />

using “business contacts (e.g., recommendation<br />

from business partners)” or “private<br />

contacts (e.g., recommendation from family<br />

members and friends)”.<br />

The results (Tab. 3) paint a mixed picture of the<br />

(relative) importance of personal relations for<br />

getting into contact with customers. While one<br />

formal channel “bidding competition” was the<br />

least frequently used channel among the companies<br />

in the PRD, the other formal channel “active<br />

searching” was the most frequently used<br />

one with only 10 % of companies not using this<br />

channel at all. The share of executives assessing<br />

“active searching” as very important or important<br />

(65 %) is also the highest one among the<br />

four channels considered. Interestingly, an almost<br />

equal share of executives (61 %) considered<br />

“business contacts”, very important or important.<br />

In contrast, only about a third of respondents<br />

assigned the same importance levels<br />

to the other two channels, private contacts and<br />

bidding competition, respectively. 14<br />

Overall, these results suggest that for a majority<br />

of firms in the PRD personal relations, in<br />

particular existing business contacts, still play<br />

an important role for searching for and screening<br />

new customers. However, despite remaining<br />

deficiencies in the formal institutional environment,<br />

most firms do not exclusively rely<br />

on relation-based channels to get into contact<br />

with customers but make important use of<br />

more formal, impersonal instruments for<br />

searching new customers as well.<br />

Part of an explanation for the substantial importance<br />

of impersonal (formal) instruments<br />

for getting into contact with new customers<br />

may be the importance of foreign customers<br />

(exports) for many electronics companies in<br />

the PRD. Personal relations may be expected to<br />

be of much less importance for these customers.<br />

On average, firms in our sample sold<br />

roughly half of their products (in value terms)<br />

to customers in mainland China and slightly<br />

less than a quarter of products to “advanced<br />

countries” (North America, Western Europe,<br />

Australasia and Japan). We expect that the two<br />

relation-based contacting channels tend to be<br />

more important for companies with higher<br />

shares of product sales in the mainland China.<br />

To test this supposition, we calculated the pairwise<br />

Spearman correlations between the executives’<br />

assessment of the importance of the two<br />

relation-based channels of contacting customers<br />

on the one hand and their firms’ shares<br />

of sales in mainland China on the other hand.<br />

The results confirm our supposition. With respect<br />

to the share of sales in mainland China,<br />

Tab. 3: Importance of channels used to get into contact with customers – company distribution<br />

Bidding Active Business Private<br />

competition searching contacts contacts<br />

1 very important 38 (17.4) 96 (43.6) 67 (30.5) 38 (17.3)<br />

2 important 26 (11.9) 48 (21.8) 67 (30.5) 36 (16.4)<br />

3 of normal importance 27 (12.4) 38 (17.3) 41 (18.6) 49 (22.3)<br />

4 of little importance 13 (6.0) 11 (5.0) 10 (4.6) 25 (11.4)<br />

5 not important 29 (13.3) 5 (2.3) 9 (4.1) 21 (9.6)<br />

Not used 85 (39.0) 22 (10.0) 26 (11.8) 51 (23.2)<br />

Total 218 (100) 220 (100) 220 (100) 220 (100)<br />

Note: Numbers in parentheses refer to the corresponding company shares (%).<br />

Source: own survey


Frank Bickenbach / Wan-Hsin Liu: Firm characteristics and informal governance 35<br />

both correlation coefficients are negative –<br />

though only the one for private contacts is statistically<br />

significant – suggesting that the higher<br />

the share of sales realized in mainland China,<br />

the more important the two relation-based<br />

channels for contacting customers.<br />

Getting into contact with suppliers: Similar arguments<br />

also apply to companies’ search for<br />

potent and reliable suppliers. Therefore the<br />

questionnaire also contained a question on the<br />

importance of different channels for getting into<br />

contact with suppliers. The same four channels<br />

as in the case of customers were considered<br />

and the same five-level Likert scale was<br />

applied. The responses are generally quite similar<br />

to those obtained for the case of customers<br />

(Tab. 4). 15 “Bidding competition” turns out to<br />

be the least frequently used channel, while “active<br />

searching” is the most frequently used one.<br />

As to the importance of the four channels considered,<br />

the responses suggest that “active<br />

searching” is the most important channel for<br />

getting into contact with suppliers (with about<br />

70 % of respondents considering this channel<br />

as very important or important), followed by<br />

“business contacts” (about 56 %). “Private<br />

contacts” and “bidding competition” are considered<br />

the least important channels.<br />

As for the case of customers, we expect the two<br />

relation-based channels of getting into contact<br />

with suppliers to be more important for companies<br />

sourcing a greater share of inputs from<br />

Chinese suppliers. On average, companies<br />

source about 73 % of their inputs from mainland<br />

Chinese but only 8 % from the “advanced<br />

countries”. To test this supposition, we calculated<br />

the pair-wise Spearman correlations.<br />

Contrary to our supposition, none of the correlation<br />

was fo<strong>und</strong> to be statistically significant.<br />

One possible explanation for this is that there is<br />

too little variation between firms with respect<br />

to the locations of their suppliers (73 % from<br />

mainland China). Differences between firms in<br />

the importance of the two relation-based channels<br />

for getting into contact with suppliers thus<br />

have to be attributed to differences in other<br />

firm characteristics.<br />

Financing: For relation-based economies in<br />

transition such as current China (or PRD) we<br />

expect personal relations to also play an important<br />

role for companies’ efforts to secure adequate<br />

finance and, in particular, for their ability<br />

to obtain short-term finance. In order to investigate<br />

this issue, executives were asked to<br />

assess the accessibility of six different sources<br />

for meeting their firms’ short-term financial<br />

needs: “Chinese banks”, “HK banks”, “foreign<br />

banks”, “affiliated companies/business partners”,<br />

“customers”, and “family members and<br />

friends”. The last three sourcing alternatives<br />

may be considered relation-based. A five-level<br />

Likert scale was applied, with “1” indicating<br />

“very easily accessible” and “5” “not accessible”.<br />

According to the executives’ responses<br />

(Tab. 5), only about 26 % of companies never<br />

obtained short-term finance from a Chinese<br />

bank, while 44.8 % and 45 % never obtained<br />

short-term finance from “family members and<br />

friends” and from “affiliated companies”, respectively.<br />

About 37 % never did so from “customers”.<br />

Generally, to obtain short-term finance<br />

is not an easy task for most companies.<br />

After all, only about 29% considered it easy or<br />

very easy to obtain short-term finance from a<br />

Chinese bank. For the other (potential) sources<br />

Tab. 4: Importance of channels used to get into contact with suppliers – company distribution<br />

Bidding Active Business Private<br />

competition searching contacts contacts<br />

1 very important 34 (15.7) 93 (42.7) 57 (26.2) 24 (11.1)<br />

2 important 21 (9.7) 58 (26.6) 64 (29.4) 34 (15.7)<br />

3 of normal importance 27 (12.4) 35 (16.1) 52 (23.9) 52 (24.0)<br />

4 of little importance 15 (6.9) 8 (3.7) 7 (3.2) 30 (13.8)<br />

5 not important 37 (17.1) 7 (3.2) 6 (2.8) 23 (10.6)<br />

Not used 83 (38.3) 17 (7.8) 32 (14.7) 54 (24.9)<br />

Total 217 (100) 218 (100) 218 (100) 217 (100)<br />

Note: Numbers in parentheses refer to the corresponding company shares (%).<br />

Source: own survey


36 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Tab. 5: Short-time accessibility of finance by source – company distribution<br />

CNBank HKBank ForBank AffComPart Customer FamFrd<br />

1 very easily<br />

accessible 36 (17.1) 16 (7.6) 5 (2.4) 10 (4.7) 17 (8.1) 15 (7.1)<br />

2 easily accessible 25 (11.9) 22 (10.4) 13 (6.2) 15 (7.1) 29 (13.7) 20 (9.5)<br />

3 normal accessible 36 (17.1) 12 (5.7) 11 (5.2) 38 (18.0) 40 (19.0) 33 (15.7)<br />

4 little accessible 28 (13.3) 8 (3.8) 10 (4.7) 21 (10.0) 25 (11.9) 22 (10.5)<br />

5 not accessible 31 (14.7) 48 (22.8) 54 (25.6) 32 (15.2) 21 (10.0) 26 (12.4)<br />

Not used 55 (26.1) 105 (49.8) 118 (55.9) 95 (45.0) 79 (37.4) 94 (44.8)<br />

Total 211 (100) 211 (100) 211 (100) 211 (100) 211 (100) 210 (100)<br />

Note: Numbers in parentheses refer to the corresponding company shares (%).<br />

Source: own survey<br />

this number is even lower. To obtain short-term<br />

finance from family and friends was easy or<br />

very easy for only about 17 % of the companies.<br />

The corresponding numbers for customers<br />

and affiliated companies are 22 % and<br />

12 % respectively. 16<br />

The result that many PRD companies face substantial<br />

difficulties when trying to obtain shortterm<br />

finance from Chinese or even foreign<br />

banks should not be surprising, given the deficiencies<br />

in, e.g., accounting and credit information<br />

institutions. It is not generally true,<br />

however that it is easier for firms in the PRD,<br />

and therefore more widespread, to obtain shortterm<br />

finance by using personal relationships<br />

(either with family members, affiliated companies<br />

or customers) to. In particular, only slightly<br />

more than half of all firms ever obtained<br />

short-term finance from family members or<br />

friends and only about one out of six of these<br />

firms considered it (very) easy to obtain finance<br />

from this source. In the following section<br />

we will see, however, that there are significant<br />

differences between different “types” of<br />

firms with respect to their assessment of relation-based<br />

finance.<br />

Firm characteristics and personal<br />

relationships for doing business<br />

We expect that different “types” of firms may<br />

differ systematically in their use of relationbased<br />

versus rule-based instruments for governing<br />

their business operations. More specifically,<br />

larger firms or faster growing firms and<br />

foreign-owned firms in China should tend to<br />

make less use of relation-based governance<br />

than smaller, stagnant and Chinese-owned<br />

firms. We also expect younger, less estab-<br />

lished, firms to rely more on personal relations<br />

than older firms for getting into contact with<br />

new customers or suppliers or obtaining shortterm<br />

finance. This should be true in particular<br />

for private relationships with family members<br />

and friends. We therefore look into the empirical<br />

relation between the executives’ assessment<br />

of the importance of personal relationships (as<br />

reflected by their answers to the questions discussed<br />

above) on the one hand and their firms’<br />

age, ownership structure, size, and growth performance<br />

on the other hand.<br />

Firm characteristics and personal relationships<br />

for doing business in general: In order to<br />

investigate the role of firm characteristics for<br />

the importance of personal relations, we first<br />

analyze the pair-wise correlations between<br />

firm characteristics and executives’ responses<br />

to the questions on the general role of personal<br />

relationships for doing business in the PRD<br />

and on the importance of political relations, respectively<br />

(cf. Tab. 1, 2). The firm characteristics<br />

considered are defined as follows: (1) company<br />

age (Age) is equal to the difference between<br />

the survey year (2007) and the fo<strong>und</strong>ing<br />

year of a company (plus 1); (2) ownership<br />

(ForeignOwn) is an ordinal variable ranging<br />

from 0 to 3 and referring to Chinese-owned enterprise,<br />

Chinese-foreign cooperative joint<br />

venture, Chinese-foreign equity joint venture<br />

and wholly foreign-owned enterprise, respectively;<br />

(3) a first size variable (Employ) is<br />

equal to the average number of total employees<br />

during the year before the survey; (4) a second<br />

size variable (Sales) is an ordinal variable<br />

ranging from 0 to 5, with values corresponding<br />

to different levels of sales in 2006, defined by<br />

the following intervals in million RMB (0, 1),


Frank Bickenbach / Wan-Hsin Liu: Firm characteristics and informal governance 37<br />

Tab. 6: Relation between firm characteristics and the importance of reasons for relation-based<br />

governance – Spearman correlations<br />

Age ForeignOwn Employ Sales GrowSales<br />

SubMLaw -0.024 (179) -0.065 (177) 0.078 (177) 0.020 (175) -0.186 (172)<br />

ResCus 0.117* (202) 0.123** (198) 0.142** (197) 0.057 (197) -0.023 (192)<br />

IncFlex 0.048 (189) 0.080 (187) 0.094* (187) 0.041 (185) -0.050 (184)<br />

RedRisk 0.129*(188) 0.108* (187) 0.074 (186) 0.072 (184) -0.058 (182)<br />

AccInfo 0.062 (191) 0.176*** (189) 0.123** (186) 0.098* (187) -0.061 (183)<br />

SolDis 0.022 (181) 0.156** (180) 0.109* (180) 0.085 (177) 0.008 (176)<br />

Notes: Numbers in parentheses refer to numbers of corresponding observations.<br />

***/**/* refer to the 1%/5%/10% significance level in two-tailed (Age) or one-tailed significance tests.<br />

Source: own survey<br />

[1, 5), [5, 10), [10, 50), [50, 100), and [100, ∞);<br />

(5) growth performance is measured by an ordinal<br />

variable (GrowSales) with four classes (0<br />

to 3) for the average annual growth rates since<br />

2002, where classes are defined as (-∞, 0%),<br />

[0%, 2%), [2%, 10%), [10%, ∞) (see also the<br />

appendix).<br />

The Spearman correlations between firm characteristics<br />

and the importance of the six reasons<br />

for using personal relations are reported in<br />

Tab. 6. For the age variable five of the six correlations<br />

are positive, though only two of them<br />

(“responding quickly to customer demands”<br />

and “reducing risks and uncertainties”) are statistically<br />

significant. 17 Still, the predominantly<br />

positive correlations could be considered as<br />

(weak) support for the view that personal relations<br />

are generally more important for younger<br />

firms, e.g. because it is relatively more difficult<br />

and costly for them to use formal institutions<br />

and public reputation mechanisms to govern<br />

their business relations.<br />

As to the ownership structure, correlation results<br />

give strong support for our hypothesis<br />

that greater foreign participation in company<br />

ownership is associated with a lower general<br />

importance of personal relationships for that<br />

company. This effect may (partially) be attributed<br />

to the fact that foreign owners will generally<br />

be more (less) acquainted with rule-based<br />

governance (relation-based governance). Legal<br />

and cultural norms of the foreign owners’ home<br />

country may aggravate reservations against the<br />

use of informal, relational institutions.<br />

Correlation results for the size variables, particularly<br />

those for the employment variable,<br />

give support to our supposition that personal<br />

relations tend to be less important for larger<br />

firms. All correlations with respect to “Employ”<br />

are positive and four out of six are statistically<br />

significantly so. Correlations with respect<br />

to the other variable used to proxy firm<br />

size, “Sales”, are also uniformly positive,<br />

though only one of them is significant. As to<br />

firm growth there is no supportive evidence for<br />

our supposition of a positive relation between a<br />

company’s growth performance and the general<br />

relevance of personal relationships, however.<br />

Almost all relevant correlations are negative<br />

(though generally quite small), suggesting that<br />

a better growth performance of firms is, if anything,<br />

associated with a greater importance of<br />

(the various reasons for using) personal relationships.<br />

A possible explanation is that fast<br />

growing firms may have to mobilize all their<br />

resources, including their personal networks,<br />

and use all available formal and informal governance<br />

instruments to support their expansion.<br />

Turning next to the importance of political relations<br />

for doing business in the PRD, there<br />

seem to be (almost) no associations of this with<br />

the different firm characteristics (see Tab. 7).<br />

Given the severe deficiencies of the institutional<br />

environment in China with respect to the<br />

protection of private property rights against expropriation<br />

by government and the ample opportunities<br />

that public officials have to interfere<br />

with firms’ business operations and success,<br />

political relations seem to be of similar<br />

importance for all types of companies. 18<br />

Firm characteristics and the role of personal<br />

relationships for critical business functions:<br />

We, finally, investigate the association between<br />

firm characteristics and the importance of personal<br />

relations for contacting new customers


38 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Tab. 7: Relation between firm characteristics and the importance of political relations – Spearman<br />

correlations<br />

Age ForeignOwn Employ Sales GrowSales<br />

GetPermProd -0.053 (203) 0.003 (200) 0.100* (199) 0.061 (198) 0.064 (193)<br />

GetExImCon -0.115 (192) -0.144 (191) -0.101 (190) -0.071 (188) -0.029 (184)<br />

AccBuild -0.165 (194)* -0.046 (192) -0.085 (192) -0.119 (190) -0.028 (186)<br />

AccRes -0.094 (192) -0.039 (190) -0.001 (191) 0.147** (189) 0.066 (185)<br />

AccGovSup -0.036 (191) 0.029 (190) 0.082 (191) 0.099* (188) 0.054 (185)<br />

Notes: Numbers in parentheses refer to the numbers of corresponding observations.<br />

***/**/* refer to the 1%/5%/10% significance level in two-tailed (Age) or one-tailed significance tests.<br />

Source: own survey<br />

and new suppliers as well as for obtaining<br />

short-term finance. We expect each of the firm<br />

characteristics – firm age, firm size, growth<br />

performance and foreign ownership – to be<br />

negatively related to the importance of relation-based<br />

governance instruments. (Note that<br />

contrary to the case of the general role of personal<br />

relationships for doing business we do<br />

expect a negative effect of age on the importance<br />

of personal relations here. Due to our importance<br />

scale, “1” being very important, this<br />

implies that we are expecting positive correlation<br />

coefficients). In order to test these suppositions,<br />

we calculated pair-wise Spearman correlations<br />

between the different firm characteristics<br />

and the importance of relation-based<br />

governance for getting into contact with customers<br />

and with suppliers and for obtaining<br />

short-term finance.<br />

The results (Tab. 8) suggest that firm age, in<br />

particular, is playing an important role for<br />

firms’ decisions to use relation-based governance<br />

in the business context considered here.<br />

Most age-related correlations are significantly<br />

positive, suggesting that younger firms tend to<br />

consider relation-based channels more important<br />

(more easily accessible) than older firms<br />

for getting into contact with their customers<br />

and suppliers (for obtaining short-term finance).<br />

Moreover, the correlations between<br />

firm age and the importance of private contacts<br />

to get into contact with customers and suppliers<br />

are (slightly) larger than the correlations<br />

with respect to business contacts. This suggests<br />

that as firms get older the importance of private<br />

(e.g., family) relations tends to decline faster<br />

than that of relations to business partners in<br />

general. This may reflect the simple fact that<br />

younger firms, can build on a limited network<br />

of business contacts but a relatively larger pool<br />

of private contacts, whereas the business network<br />

tends to increase as firms get older. This<br />

effect seems to be even substantially stronger<br />

for firm size.<br />

For both measures of firm size the correlations<br />

with the importance of private relations for<br />

making contacts with both customers and suppliers<br />

are positive and statistically highly significant,<br />

while correlations with the importance<br />

of business contacts are insignificant.<br />

This suggests that larger firms tend to rely<br />

more on personal contacts but no less on business<br />

contacts for screening new customers and<br />

suppliers than smaller firms. When firms are<br />

small, existing private contacts may be sufficient<br />

for supporting their business operations.<br />

However, as firms grow and their operations<br />

become more numerous and manifold, existing<br />

private contacts may become an insufficient<br />

basis for expanding the business. Contrary to<br />

our expectations, there seems to be no systematic<br />

effect of firm size on the importance or accessibility<br />

of relation-based sources of shortterm<br />

finance. In addition, as above (and possibly<br />

also for the same reasons) we do not find<br />

any support of our supposition of a negative association<br />

between firms’ growth performance<br />

and the importance of personal relations.<br />

As to foreign ownership, there is, again contrary<br />

to our expectations, no statistically significant<br />

effect of the ownership structure on the<br />

importance of private or business relations for<br />

contacting new customers and suppliers. At<br />

least the sign of the correlations suggests, however,<br />

that private contacts but not business contacts<br />

might be slightly less important for firms<br />

with foreign ownership participation. This may<br />

be interpreted as an indication of a substitutive<br />

relation between private and business contacts.


Frank Bickenbach / Wan-Hsin Liu: Firm characteristics and informal governance 39<br />

Tab. 8: Relation between firm characteristics and the importance of relation-based instruments<br />

for critical business functions – Spearman correlations<br />

Age ForeignOwn Employ Sales GrowSales<br />

Contacting customers<br />

Business contacts 0.104* (217) -0.072 (216) 0.001 (211) 0.063 (211) -0.117 (205)<br />

Private contacts 0.203*** (217) 0.084 (216) 0.223***(211) 0.188*** (211) -0.012 (205)<br />

Contacting suppliers<br />

Business contacts 0.161*** (216) -0.049 (214) 0.032 (209) -0.041 (210) -0.020 (202)<br />

Private contacts 0.185*** (215) 0.037 (213) 0.158** (209) 0.158** (210) 0.024 (204)<br />

Short-term financing<br />

AffComPart -0.043 (209) 0.040 (207) -0.085 (203) 0.060 (203) 0.054 (197)<br />

Customer 0.020 (209) 0.113* (207) -0.023 (203) 0.032 (203) -0.009 (197)<br />

FamFrd 0.124** (208) 0.234*** (206) 0.090 (202) 0.087 (202) 0.051 (196)<br />

Note: Numbers in parentheses refer to the numbers of corresponding observations. Coding as in Table 3, Table 4,<br />

and Table 5, respectively; with “not used = 6”. For further explanations see appendix.<br />

***/**/* refer to the 1%/5%/10% significance level in one-tailed significance tests.<br />

Source: own survey<br />

The limited number of private contacts on site<br />

may induce foreign-owned firms to more<br />

strongly rely on existing business contacts for<br />

extending their business to new customers and<br />

suppliers. With respect to financing, the effect<br />

of the ownership pattern is more clear-cut and<br />

consistent with our supposition. All three relation-based<br />

sources are less important for shortterm<br />

financing for firms with stronger foreign<br />

ownership interests and the coefficients regarding<br />

“customers” and “family and friends” are<br />

statistically significant or even highly significant.<br />

In summary, for most firms personal relationships<br />

with business partners and with political<br />

officials seem to be of substantial importance<br />

for doing business in the PRD in general. For<br />

several critical business activities – getting into<br />

contact with new customers and suppliers<br />

and accessing short-term finance – relationbased<br />

mechanisms and sources are not generally<br />

more important than more formal or impersonal<br />

ones, however. Finally, there is some,<br />

though generally rather weak, evidence that<br />

firm characteristics, such as company age, size<br />

and foreign ownership are, as expected, negatively<br />

associated with firms’ reliance on personal<br />

relationships for at least some of the<br />

business functions considered. In contrast, no<br />

systematic (negative) relation was fo<strong>und</strong> in<br />

general between firms’ growth performance<br />

and the importance of personal relationships.<br />

Conclusions<br />

China today may be viewed as a society that is<br />

in a gradual process of transition from an informal<br />

and relation-based to a more formal<br />

and rule-based governance system. At the<br />

macro-level of the institutional environment<br />

there have been, over the last decades, remarkable<br />

improvements of the formal contracting,<br />

information and (with some reservations)<br />

property rights institutions. This is true, in particular,<br />

for the province of Guangdong, which<br />

has been a pioneer region of economic and institutional<br />

reform in China, and for the PRD,<br />

Guangdong’s core economic region. Even<br />

there, however, the quality of many formal legal<br />

and market institutions is still far from<br />

what it is in most advanced economies.<br />

In light of the gradual character of the reform<br />

process and the remaining deficiencies in the<br />

institutional environment, theoretical considerations<br />

suggest that informal institutions and<br />

personal relations with private business partners<br />

and with political officials can be expected<br />

to be still of considerable importance for<br />

the firm-level governance of business operations<br />

in the PRD, in general. Given the continuing<br />

improvements of formal institutions at<br />

the macro-level and an increasing scale and<br />

scope of firms’ business operations, firms’<br />

marginal costs of developing personal relations<br />

will increase and their benefits will decrease.<br />

As a consequence, firms operating in<br />

China will tend to gradually reduce their re-


40 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

liance on informal relation-based governance<br />

and make increased use of rule-based governance<br />

instruments, such as formal contracting<br />

and public information institutions, instead.<br />

Not all firms will have equally strong incentives<br />

to move from relation-based to more formal<br />

governance mechanism, however. Rather,<br />

we expect the incentives to reduce the reliance<br />

on personal relations to be stronger, in particular,<br />

for older, larger and faster growing firms as<br />

well as for firms with more international business<br />

contacts (international suppliers or customers)<br />

or with larger foreign ownership interests.<br />

These suppositions were confronted with firmlevel<br />

data obtained from a survey of 222 companies<br />

of the electronics industry operating in<br />

the PRD. Though most of the empirical results<br />

seem to be broadly in line with the theoretically<br />

fo<strong>und</strong>ed suppositions, the empirical evidence<br />

is generally rather weak. This weakness<br />

may be partially attributed to a small sample<br />

size and the limited number of relevant variables<br />

we could construct from the available<br />

database. The paper should thus be taken only<br />

as a first, exploratory attempt to obtain (empirical)<br />

evidence on the relation between firm<br />

characteristics and the firm-level importance of<br />

relation-based governance during China’s institutional<br />

reform process. Future research may<br />

build and improve upon the current study by<br />

employing a larger and richer database on an<br />

issue that is of considerable importance to the<br />

future economic development of China and<br />

other transition economies.<br />

Acknowlegement<br />

Liu would like to thank the German Research Fo<strong>und</strong>ation<br />

(DFG) for its financial support of the cooperative<br />

projects “Informal Dynamics of Agile Firm Organization<br />

in the Greater Pearl River Delta” and “Regional<br />

Agility and Upgrading in Hong Kong and the PRD”<br />

(Priority Program 1233: Megacities - Megachallenge:<br />

Informal Dynamics of Global Change).<br />

Notes<br />

1 The Pearl River Delta (PRD) comprises nine municipalities<br />

of the Chinese Province of Guangdong:<br />

Dongguan, Foshan, Guangzhou, Huizhou, Jiangmen,<br />

Shenzhen, Zhaoqing, Zhongshan, and Zhuhai.<br />

2 <strong>Institut</strong>ions that improve the availability and quality<br />

of information on economic agents’ past conduct<br />

and their ability to perform include accounting and<br />

auditing rules, credit rating and credit reporting institutions<br />

and land and liens registries. As these institutions<br />

also impact the cost of designing, managing<br />

and enforcing contractual agreements there are<br />

important interdependencies between information<br />

institutions and contracting institutions.<br />

3 In relation-based governance systems agreements<br />

are, therefore, mostly enforced by second-party enforcement<br />

mechanisms: each party to an ongoing relationship<br />

is deterred from behaving opportunistically<br />

and from breaching the (implicit) agreement<br />

by the other parties’ threat to retaliate and/or to terminate<br />

the relationship. Sometimes agreements and<br />

information about business partners’ performance<br />

will be made partially explicit and verifiable to<br />

third-parties to allow for third-party enforcement,<br />

which may take one of two forms. In relation-based<br />

third party enforcement, the deterrent to breach an<br />

agreement is strengthened by the threat that the miscreant<br />

will be barred from future business not only<br />

with the particular partner on which he acted opportunistically<br />

but with a whole group of (potential)<br />

business partners. This threat may be further buttressed<br />

by social ostracism if the group fosters social<br />

ties among its business members (DIXIT 2004, 27 f.).<br />

The second form is third party enforcement by the<br />

state, which will not generally be impartial in relation-based<br />

systems, however. Frequently, in case of<br />

conflict, the contracting parties’ personal relations<br />

with politicians or state officials will determine the<br />

enforcement outcome or the ex-post bargaining<br />

power of the parties (LI 2003, 657).<br />

4 The basic formal institutions of a society generally<br />

also tend to be quite persistent and their change<br />

mostly incremental. Occasionally, however, windows<br />

of opportunity arise, in which formal institutions<br />

can change very fast and in large discrete steps<br />

(NORTH 1990, 89 ff.).<br />

5 Political relations can be a ‘lubricant’ for a wide variety<br />

of private or business-related activities: e.g.,<br />

obtaining driver’s licenses, getting access to medical<br />

treatment or to universities, gaining favorable<br />

verdicts in lawsuits, obtaining the permits required<br />

for all kind of business operations, getting access to<br />

scarce resources.<br />

6 In terms of the ease or difficulty of enforcing a simple<br />

commercial contract, China ranked 20th of 178<br />

economies in the World Bank’s report “Doing Business<br />

2008” (World Bank 2007). Criteria used to determine<br />

the ranking are the time, the cost and the<br />

number of procedures involved from the moment a<br />

plaintiff files the lawsuit until actual payment in a<br />

specific, well defined commercial dispute.<br />

7 The scope, accessibility and quality of credit information<br />

available through either public or private<br />

credit registries and their coverage are central criteria<br />

in the World Bank’s ease of ‘getting credit’-index.<br />

For this index, China ranked 84th of 178<br />

economies in 2007 (World Bank 2007).<br />

8 The power to appoint and to dismiss courts’ leadership<br />

rests with government or party organizations at


Frank Bickenbach / Wan-Hsin Liu: Firm characteristics and informal governance 41<br />

the same administrative level. Local governments<br />

also control court finances, material supplies, and<br />

welfare benefits for court officials (CLARKE/MUR-<br />

RELL/WHITING 2008, 395). Other reasons for the<br />

lack of efficient law enforcement are the widespread<br />

corruption and the generally low level of legal training<br />

and competence of judges (TREBIL-COCK/LENG<br />

2006, 1554).<br />

9 The openness index is defined as the value of external<br />

trade (exports plus imports) over GDP. Its value<br />

for Guangdong was 1.604 in 2006 (second only to<br />

that of Shanghai with a value of 1.750).<br />

10 The survey was carried out <strong>und</strong>er the cooperative<br />

project “Informal Dynamics of Agile Firm Organization<br />

in the GPRD” financially supported by the<br />

Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft (DFG). The survey<br />

was conducted by our local partner, Prof. Li and<br />

his team from the Geography and Planning School<br />

at the Sun Yat-Sen University in Guangdong.<br />

11 This ranking of the importance of the different reasons<br />

is confirmed by two-tailed pair-wise Wilcoxon<br />

Signed-Rank Tests (WSRTs). According to these<br />

tests ResCus (IncFlex) is the most (second most) important<br />

reason for companies in the PRD to use personal<br />

relationships for business, while SolDis and<br />

SubMLaw are the two least important ones.<br />

12 In a related study among executives of Hong Kong<br />

based companies operating in the PRD (BICKEN-<br />

BACH/LIU 2010) institutional deficiencies were considered<br />

important or very important by a substantially<br />

larger share of executives (55 %). A possible<br />

explanation is that executives from Hong Kong are<br />

more familiar with the working of well developed<br />

formal rules and are therefore also more aware of<br />

the substitutive role of formal and informal governance<br />

instruments.<br />

13 In this question executives were asked to evaluate<br />

the importance of political relations in PRD in general,<br />

not just for their company. We chose to formulate<br />

this question in a less personal way as it may be<br />

considered highly sensitive by executives (due to a<br />

possible association of political relations with<br />

bribery and corruption). We still think that executives’<br />

responses are largely determined by their own<br />

experience, however.<br />

14 Two-tailed WSRTs, considering only firms that<br />

make use of the respective channels, support this<br />

ranking: “active searching” and “business contacts”<br />

are the 1st and 2nd most important channels, respectively.<br />

The other two channels are significantly<br />

less important (with no statistically significant difference<br />

between the two).<br />

15 Correlation analyses between the responses to the<br />

questions on customer contacts and on supplier contacts<br />

show that executives that emphasize the importance<br />

of private contacts (business contacts) for<br />

contacting suppliers also tend to do so for contacting<br />

customers.<br />

16 Pair-wise WSRTs (considering only firms that make<br />

use of the respective sources) indicate that the differences<br />

between Chinese banks, family and friends<br />

and customers are not statistically significant. However,<br />

these three sources are statistically significantly<br />

easier to access than either HK banks, affiliated<br />

companies, or foreign banks.<br />

17 With respect to firm age, two-tailed significance<br />

tests were used, as it is unclear a priori whether we<br />

should expect a positive or a negative relation between<br />

firm age and the general importance of personal<br />

relationships for doing business. With respect<br />

to the other firm characteristics one-tailed significance<br />

tests were used as we have formulated unambiguous<br />

hypotheses about the expected sign of the<br />

relations.<br />

18 It may be worth noting, however, that all correlations<br />

with the age variable are negative though not<br />

significant (with one exception). This may be considered<br />

weak evidence for older firms tending to rely<br />

more on political relations than younger firms.<br />

This is different from the case of personal relations<br />

in general (Tab. 6), where age tends to have the opposite<br />

effect.<br />

Appendix<br />

Basic information on firm characteristics<br />

Age (Age): The youngest companies in the sample were<br />

fo<strong>und</strong>ed in the year of survey (2007), the oldest one in<br />

1952. Half of the companies were fo<strong>und</strong>ed after 2000,<br />

thus having less than 8 years of experience in doing<br />

business in the PRD. On average, companies interviewed<br />

have about 10 years of business experience in<br />

the PRD.<br />

Ownership Structure (ForeignOwn): About 57 % of<br />

companies are Chinese-owned companies, of which<br />

about 94 % are private companies (the rest being stateowned<br />

or collectively-owned). Among the companies<br />

with foreign ownership participation (about 43 % of all<br />

companies), 80 % were wholly foreign owned, 17 %<br />

were Chinese-foreign equity joint ventures, and 3 %<br />

Chinese-foreign cooperative joint ventures.<br />

Employment (Employ): The mean value is 742 employees.<br />

The variation of the variable is substantial ranging<br />

from 2 employees in the smallest firm to 30,000 employees<br />

in the largest (standard deviation 2,867). In<br />

about 85 % of companies the number of employees is<br />

below the average. The first, second and third quantile<br />

of the number of total employees of companies interviewed<br />

is 51, 150, and 500 persons, respectively.<br />

Sales (Sales): The greatest share of firms (30 %) falls in<br />

the category with sales between 10 million and 50 million<br />

RMB. The shares of companies realizing sales in<br />

the categories (-∞, 1), [1, 5), [5, 10), [50, 100), and<br />

[100, ∞) are about 9 %, 23 %, 16 %, 9 %, and 13 %, respectively.<br />

Growth Performance (GrowSales): The shares of firms<br />

in categories 0 to 3 are 3.4 %, 17.9 %, 48.3 % and 30.4<br />

%, respectively. This implies that for almost 80% of<br />

firms sales increase by an average rate of more than 2 %<br />

per year.


42 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

References<br />

ACEMOGLU, D./JOHNSON. S. (2005): Unb<strong>und</strong>ling institutions.<br />

In: Journal of Political Economy, (113)5, 949-<br />

995.<br />

BARDHAN, P. (2005): <strong>Institut</strong>ions matter, but which<br />

ones? In: Economics of Transition, (13)3, 499-532.<br />

BICKENBACH, F./LIU, W.-H. (2010): On the role of personal<br />

relationships for doing business in the Greater<br />

Pearl River Delta, China. In: China Economic Journal,<br />

(3)3, 281-306.<br />

CLARKE, D./MURRELL, P./WHITING, S. (2008): The role<br />

of law in China’s economic development. In: Brandt,<br />

L./Rawski, T.G. (Eds.): China’s Great Economic Transformation.<br />

Cambridge/UK, New York, 375-428.<br />

DAVIES, H./LEUNG, T.K.P./LUK, S.T.K./WONG, Y. (1995):<br />

The benefits of ‘guanxi’: The value of relationships in<br />

developing the Chinese market. In: Industrial Management<br />

Marketing, (24), 207-214.<br />

DIXIT, A.K. (2004): Lawlessness and economics. Alternative<br />

modes of governance. Princeton/ New Jersey.<br />

GPBS (Guangdong Provincial Bureau of Statistics)(2007):<br />

Guangdong statistical yearbook 2007. Beijing.<br />

GREIF, A. (2005): Commitment, coercion, and markets.<br />

The nature and dynamics of institutions supporting exchange.<br />

In: Ménard, C./Shirley, M.M. (Eds.): Handbook<br />

of New <strong>Institut</strong>ional Economics. Dordrecht, 727-786.<br />

JENTZSCH, N. (2008): An economic analysis of China’s<br />

credit information system. In: China Economic Review,<br />

(19), 537-550.<br />

LANGENBERG, E.A. (2007): Guanxi and business strategy.<br />

Theory and implications for multinational companies.<br />

Heidelberg.<br />

LI, S. (2004). Why is property rights protection lacking<br />

in China? An institutional explanation. In: California<br />

Management Review, (46)3, 100-115.<br />

LI, S./PARK, S.H./LI, S. (2004): The Great Leap Forward.<br />

The transition from relation-based governance to<br />

rule-based governance. In: Organizational Dynamics,<br />

(33)1, 63-78.<br />

LI, J.S. (2003): Relation-based versus rule-based governance.<br />

An explanation of the East Asian miracle and<br />

Asian crisis. In: Review of International Economics,<br />

(11) 4, 651-673.<br />

LUO, Y. (1997): Guanxi and performance of foreign-invested<br />

enterprises in China. An empirical inquiry. In:<br />

Management International Review, (37), 51-71.<br />

LUO, Y. (2007): Guanxi and business. Singapore. (2nd<br />

ed.)<br />

MARECHAL, V./TEKIN, P./GULIYEVA, H. (2009): China’s<br />

new property rights law - an important step towards improving<br />

access to credit for small and medium enterprises.<br />

Internet: http://www.doingbusiness.org/documents/casestudies/2009/DB09_Reforms_China.pdf,<br />

20.9. 2010.<br />

NBSC (National Bureau of Statistics of China)(2007):<br />

China statistical yearbook 2007. Beijing.<br />

NORTH, D. (1990): <strong>Institut</strong>ions, institutional change and<br />

economic performance. Cambridge.<br />

OECD (2008): OECD investment policy reviews - China<br />

2008. Encouraging responsible business conduct.<br />

Paris.<br />

PARK, S.H./LUO, Y. (2001): Guanxi and organizational<br />

dynamics. Organizational networking in Chinese firms.<br />

In: Strategic Management Journal, (22)5, 455-477.<br />

STANDIFIRT, S.S./MARSHALL, R.S. (2000): The transaction<br />

cost advantage of Guanxi-based business practices.<br />

In: Journal of World Economics, (35)1, 21-42.<br />

TREBILCOCK, M./LENG, J. (2006): The role of formal<br />

contract law and enforcement in economic development.<br />

In: Virginia Law Review, (92), 1517-1580.<br />

TUAN, C./Ng, L.N.Y. (1995): Evolution of Hong Kong’s<br />

electronics industry <strong>und</strong>er a passive industrial policy.<br />

In: Managerial and Decision Economics, (16)5, 509-<br />

523.<br />

WILLIAMSON, O.E. (1996): The mechanisms of governance.<br />

New York.<br />

World Bank (2007): Doing business 2008. Washington<br />

DC. Internet: http://www.doingbusiness.org/documents/<br />

FullReport/2008/DB08_Full_Report.pdf , 20.9. 2010.<br />

World Bank (2008): Doing Business in China 2008.<br />

Washington DC. Internet: http://www.doingbusiness.<br />

org/subnational/exploreeconomies/China.aspx.<br />

World Bank (2009): Report on the observance of standards<br />

and codes (ROSC). Accounting and auditing. People’s<br />

Republic of China. Internet: http://www.worldbank.org/ifa/rosc_aa_chn.pdf,<br />

20.9. 2010. (The World<br />

Bank. Financial Management – Central Operational<br />

Services Unit, East Asia and Pacific Region)<br />

XIN, K.R./PEARCE, J.L. (1996): Guanxi. Connections as<br />

substitutes for formal institutional support. In: Academy<br />

of Management Journal, (39)6, 1641-1658.<br />

ZENGER, T./LAZZARINI, S./POPPO, L. (2002): Informal<br />

and formal organization in New <strong>Institut</strong>ional Economics.<br />

In: Ingram, P./Silverman, B. (Eds.): Advances in<br />

strategic management. The new institutionalism in<br />

strategic management. Oxford, 275-303.


Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> Jg. 56 (2012) Heft 1-2, S.43-57<br />

Markus Keck/Hans-Georg Bohle, Bonn/Wolfgang-Peter Zingel, Heidelberg<br />

Dealing with insecurity<br />

Informal business relations and risk governance among food wholesalers in Dhaka,<br />

Bangladesh<br />

Abstract: The article investigates <strong>und</strong>erlying social mechanisms that contribute to the remarkable<br />

resilience of Dhaka’s food system with a special focus on wholesalers and their informal business<br />

networks. A relational approach to the subject matter is elaborated that <strong>und</strong>erstands informality as<br />

a specific governance mode of business relations that is coined by horizontal power relations, and<br />

by the implicit codification, endogenous imposition, and personalized implementation of procedural<br />

rules. Empirical evidence is presented from recent fieldwork with rice and fish wholesalers<br />

that suggests that informality, in the form of trustworthy relations and social capital, has the potential<br />

to foster the traders’ adaptive capacities and thus not only their individual business performance,<br />

but also the overall robustness of the urban food system.<br />

Keywords: informality, embeddedness, wholesaling, food system, Bangladesh<br />

Introduction<br />

Since the 1970s, Dhaka exhibits unprecedented<br />

rates of population growth and spatial expansion<br />

that have let it become one of the largest<br />

cities worldwide (UN 2008). At a current<br />

growth rate of 3.5 % (World Bank 2007), its<br />

population increases by an estimated number<br />

of 450.000 people every year. Such a rapid urbanization<br />

process not only challenges governmental<br />

authorities –SIDDIQUI et al. (2000) attested<br />

the capital of Bangladesh already at the<br />

end of the last century a severe and extensive<br />

‘governance crisis’ (cf. also ISLAM 2005). It also<br />

brings up the question of how urban supply<br />

and distribution systems currently work <strong>und</strong>er<br />

such conditions. In the following this question<br />

is examined by taking the food system of Dhaka<br />

as a case. Food systems are conceived as a<br />

set of activities ranging from production, processing<br />

and packaging, over distribution and<br />

retailing, to final consumption (ERICKSON<br />

2008, 236). Despite their overwhelming importance,<br />

distribution systems, particularly in the<br />

urban context, are least <strong>und</strong>erstood (BOHLE et<br />

al. 2009, 9). As GUYER (1987) has rightly noted,<br />

urban food supply and distribution is usually<br />

seen as a routine function in all kinds of so-<br />

cieties and taken for granted most of the time<br />

by those not directly involved. More often than<br />

not, it is <strong>und</strong>er conditions of food crises that urban<br />

food supply suddenly becomes “a public<br />

issue which can blaze on the political agenda<br />

with suddenness, urgency, and often ferocity”<br />

(loc.cit. 1). While the persistence of famines in<br />

the era of global change has been discussed<br />

from manifold and diverse vantage points (DE-<br />

VEREUX 2007), the question of what social<br />

mechanisms exactly shape the resilience of urban<br />

food systems during non-famine times<br />

widely lacks empirical evidence in the literature.<br />

Our study concentrates on the entry points of<br />

food into the city, i.e. on the wholesale markets<br />

as the major distributional nodes from which<br />

food flows into various channels of the urban<br />

food system. Empirical data are presented on<br />

rice and fish wholesalers’ risk adaptation activities,<br />

with a special focus on informality. It is assumed<br />

that it is the continuous effort of food<br />

traders in general and their constant investment<br />

in informal business relations in particular that<br />

determines the food system’s overall resilience<br />

to a large extent.


44 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

The food system of Dhaka and its<br />

robustness<br />

In 1951, Dhaka had a population of 336,000<br />

(BBS 1951 after ISLAM 2005, 13); today there<br />

are roughly 14.2 million (ISLAM 2010, 6): 42<br />

times more inhabitants than before! While the<br />

first figure refers to the area of the Dhaka City<br />

Corporation (DCC) with an extension of 145<br />

km 2 , the latter number refers to Dhaka Metropolitan<br />

Development Planning Area (DMDP)<br />

with a size of 1,528 km 2 . For all those people<br />

who are involved in the megacity’s food system,<br />

the rapid urbanization means a challenge<br />

in economic, financial and logistical ways.<br />

Surprisingly, however, Dhaka’s food supply<br />

system has been remarkably resilient over the<br />

past 40 years.<br />

In most of South Asia, rice is the major staple<br />

of the people, regardless of their economic,<br />

social, or ethnic backgro<strong>und</strong>. On average, the<br />

citizens of Dhaka meet their caloric demand to<br />

65 % by cereals. With an average intake of 378<br />

g per head and day, cereals (almost exclusively<br />

rice) are the most important basic food items<br />

for Dhaka’s and Bangladesh’s population (cf.<br />

BBS 2007). Bangladesh’s rice granaries are located<br />

in north-western and northern regions of<br />

the country (KECK et al. 2008, 29). Rice is<br />

grown mostly on small farms of less than 2.5<br />

acres (1 ha). Up to three harvests are possible<br />

per year, i.e. aman, boro and aus (AHMED<br />

2001, 2; DOROSH et al. 2004, 14). In the fiscal<br />

year 2006/07 55 % of the total rice production<br />

stemmed from the boro season, whereas aus<br />

lost its importance and plays only a marginal<br />

role now with hardly 6 % (FPMU 2009, 1).<br />

Bangladesh has been able to more than triple<br />

rice (paddy) production since independence in<br />

1971. Domestic production rose from 14.9 million<br />

tons in 1971 to 43.1 million tons in 2007<br />

and to a record harvest of 46.9 million tons in<br />

2008 (here and in the following “tons” refer to<br />

metric tons). This success was possible only<br />

because yields increased from 1,602 kg/ha in<br />

1971 to 3,995 kg/ha in 2008. Today, Bangladesh<br />

holds the fourth position among the<br />

world’s rice producing countries. But despite<br />

all impressive production increases, Bangladesh<br />

is still not in a position to feed its population.<br />

More than 3 million tons foodgrains had<br />

to be imported in 2007: 2.4 million tons wheat,<br />

0.6 million tons (milled) rice and 0.2 million<br />

tons maize (FAOSTAT 2010). In 2008 rice imports<br />

counted for well over 1 million tons<br />

(FAO 2009b, 25).<br />

Bangladesh’s market liberalization of the<br />

1990s coincided with India’s removal of export<br />

restrictions. India’s rice exports increased dramatically<br />

from 0.9 million tons in 1994 to 4.9<br />

million tons in 1995. India started dominating<br />

the rice imports of her neighbour, thus replacing<br />

Thailand as the major source of rice imports<br />

to Bangladesh (DOROSH/MURSHID 2004,<br />

109). One has to bear in mind, however, that<br />

India had been exporting rice to Bangladesh also<br />

before, although illegally and unrecorded.<br />

The long and winding border was never effectively<br />

controlled and whenever prices differed<br />

in the two neighbouring countries, large quantities<br />

would be smuggled across. But also after<br />

India started to liberalise its foreign trade, she<br />

continued to look at her consumers first. In<br />

times of high world market prices, India restricts<br />

her exports rather than allow her domestic<br />

prices to rise. As a consequence, India’s rice<br />

exports were reduced from 5 million tons in<br />

2007 (FAO 2008, 32) to 3.57 million tons in<br />

2008 (FAO 2009a, 29) at a time when<br />

Bangladesh needed to import. In 2007, floods<br />

and the cyclone Sidr brought devastation and<br />

much of the paddy crop was destroyed. Consequently,<br />

the country had to import large quantities<br />

of grain just when world market prices<br />

started to rise to unprecedented heights. In late<br />

2007, the price of the major rice exporters<br />

showed a pronounced increase with a peak in<br />

mid-2008. The price of high quality Thai rice<br />

almost quadrupled (!) within a period of one<br />

year. From August 2004 until November 2006<br />

it had risen from 250 US$/t to 300 US$/t, while<br />

afterwards it jumped up to more than 1,000<br />

US$/t in mid-2008. From the end of 2008 onwards<br />

prices fell and remained at a high level<br />

of aro<strong>und</strong> 600 US$/t (www.indexm<strong>und</strong>i.com,<br />

20.8.2009). The situation in Dhaka followed<br />

this general trend. Here, prices of low quality<br />

(coarse) rice, that is mainly consumed by low<br />

income groups, more than doubled in the mentioned<br />

period, i.e. from 16.50 Bangladesh Taka<br />

(BDT) in January 2006 to 35.00 BDT in December<br />

2008. Since the beginning of the year<br />

2009 prices have come down again to a rate of<br />

20.00 BDT to 25.00 BDT (ZINGEL et al. 2011,<br />

305; according to data provided by the Ministry<br />

of Agriculture, Department of Agricultural<br />

Marketing, Government of the People’s Republic<br />

of Bangladesh).<br />

Although this hike of world rice prices caused<br />

severe distortions of Bangladesh’s food security<br />

situation (for a discussion of its impact on


Markus Keck / Hans-Georg Bohle / Wolfgang-Peter Zingel: Dealing with insecurity 45<br />

Dhaka’s urban poor see ZINGEL et al. 2011),<br />

there has always been enough food in the city<br />

to secure at least a minimum supply for the urban<br />

population. Without wanting to downplay<br />

the “silent violence” (cf. WATTS 1983) that was<br />

caused by the food price hike, it must be mentioned<br />

that dispite Dhaka’s rapid growth,<br />

countrywide floods, the devastating cyclone<br />

Sidr, the global food price hikes, and political<br />

upheaval, the food supply and distribution system<br />

as a whole remained remarkably stable.<br />

What are the social mechanisms that made this<br />

system so resilient? To answer the question,<br />

our analysis will focus on food wholesalers<br />

and their informal business networks. Before<br />

moving to the empirical part of this paper, the<br />

term of informality has to be clarifyed.<br />

Informality – a relational approach<br />

Although HART (1973) and his colleagues of<br />

the International Labour Organization’s employment<br />

missions (ILO 1972) were quite<br />

positive about the informal sector – noting its<br />

efficiency, creativity, and resilience – in subsequent<br />

years, the concept was widely interpreted<br />

in negative terms. Scholars from many<br />

disciplinary backgro<strong>und</strong>s referred to informality<br />

in such a way and assessed it predominantly<br />

in terms of demanding, dirty, and dangerous<br />

labour conditions, unregistered and partly illegal<br />

small-scale ‘survival economies’, or marginal<br />

residential areas (for the informal sector<br />

debate see CHEN 2006). From this vantage<br />

point, megacities are often described as global<br />

risk areas (KRAAS 2008), that are menaced by<br />

environmental degradation, capacity overload<br />

of public distribution systems, marginalization,<br />

social exclusion, and prevailing poverty<br />

that all together add to the vulnerability of<br />

large segments of cities worldwide (KRAAS/<br />

MERTINS 2008). But, despite these sad truths,<br />

informality in today’s megacities also bears<br />

the inherent potential for adaptive and efficient<br />

governance modes and, thus, opportunities for<br />

future development that should not be overseen<br />

(KRAAS/NITSCHKE 2006). In this article, it<br />

is the positive aspects of informality that are<br />

aimed to be put back on the agenda of the current<br />

debate.<br />

In order to elaborate a relational approach to<br />

informality, we draw back on the work of<br />

NORTH (1990) on formal and informal institutions.<br />

According to NORTH (loc.cit. 3), institu-<br />

tions are <strong>und</strong>erstood as all kinds of “humanly<br />

devised constraints that shape human interaction”,<br />

whereas constraints encompass obligations<br />

and restrictions, but also rights and privileges<br />

(SCOTT 2008, 50). Since human beings<br />

live in an uncertain world, they device institutions<br />

to bring about some security and to minimize<br />

related transaction costs (DE SOYSA/ JÜT-<br />

TING 2007, 31). While formal institutions are<br />

codified political, juridical, and economic rules<br />

that are outlined in constitutions, laws, ordinances,<br />

and all kinds of legal contracts, that are<br />

usually enforced by official entities such as<br />

parlaments, courts, bureaucrats, and other legal<br />

persons (NORTH 1990, 55 ff.), informal institutions<br />

are basically <strong>und</strong>erstood as uncodified social<br />

norms that are reproduced largely through<br />

self-enforcing mechanisms of mutual agreement.<br />

As such they comprise customs and<br />

habits, obligations and social entitlements, and<br />

all kinds of other deontic rules (loc.cit. 43 ff.).<br />

According to NORTH (loc.cit. 55), the difference<br />

between formal and informal institutions<br />

is a matter of degree; both kinds of rules together<br />

span a continuum. Consequently, social<br />

realities seldomly fit into either the one or the<br />

other category. Instead, organizations as the<br />

players of the game are rather embedded in an<br />

“institutional matrix” that comprise both formal<br />

and informal institutions at the same time<br />

(loc.cit.1990; 2005). Despite these regulative<br />

and normative aspects of formal and informal<br />

institutions (cf. SCOTT 2008), SEARLE (1995)<br />

convincingly addressed the <strong>und</strong>erlying constitutive<br />

element of institutions. Based on collective<br />

intentionality, that is the cognitive property<br />

of human beings to direct their minds in<br />

agreement with each other at specific states of<br />

affairs in the world, people turn brute facts into<br />

institutional facts and thus produce social reality<br />

in accordance to the logical form of “X<br />

counts as Y in C”. For instance, the brute fact<br />

of a handshake (X) in the context of a market<br />

place (C) counts as the closing of a contract<br />

(Y), if both partners of this interaction agree<br />

upon it. As such, all institutional facts, e.g.<br />

money, marriage, business organizations or<br />

governments, do indeed exist only because we<br />

believe them to exist.<br />

This constitutive feature of institutions is most<br />

tricky (ADELSTEIN 2010, 344), especially when<br />

considering informal institutions. Since it is a<br />

matter of social consensus, first of all, different<br />

scales of institutions are to be distinguished,<br />

from mutual agreements between two partners


46 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Tab. 1: Continuum of formal and informal relations<br />

Formal-informal<br />

continuum<br />

<strong>Institut</strong>ions reproduced<br />

in social relations<br />

Strong- formal Statutory law and<br />

authority<br />

Weak-formal Market and<br />

delegation<br />

Governance and social interaction<br />

Explicit codification, exogenous imposition, as<br />

well as rigid and depersonalized implementation<br />

of processual rules in hierachical power relations<br />

Rigid and depersonalized implementation<br />

Weak-informal Culture and ethics Implicit codification, endogenous imposition, as<br />

Strong-informal Personal trust and<br />

friendship<br />

Source: LI 2007, 230; ETZOLD et al. 2009, 8<br />

in dyadic relationships over widely accepted<br />

norms of a society to nearly universalistic values<br />

of global humanity. Secondly, institutions<br />

must be perceived as being in permanent flux<br />

and motion, they constantly arise and vanish as<br />

they are the subject of permanent negotiation<br />

in contested political arenas (ETZOLD et al.<br />

2009). Taking into account GIDDENS’ (1984)<br />

theory of structuration and his elaboration on<br />

people’s agency, we can speak of a duality of<br />

institutions that constitutes them as both medium<br />

and outcome of social practices. With these<br />

considerations in mind, we may distinguish<br />

with LI (2007) between formality and informality<br />

as a specific governance mode of social<br />

interaction. Formality refers to procedural<br />

rules that are “explicitly prescribed, exogenously<br />

imposed, and rigidly enforced by vertical<br />

authority powers in a (sic!) universalistic<br />

depersonalized process”, while informality refers<br />

to institutions that are “implicitly assumed,<br />

endogenously embraced, and flexibly enforced<br />

by horizontal peer pressures in a particularistic<br />

personalized process” (loc.cit. 229). By these<br />

criteria, personalized trust, strong social ties,<br />

and affective commitment are strong-informal<br />

elements, while clan control, religion, culture<br />

and ethics are weak-informal. Similarly, law,<br />

state policies, legal ownership, and organizational<br />

hierarchies are strong-formal, while<br />

more or less regularized markets and delegation<br />

are weak-formal (see Tab.1). Such a conceptualization,<br />

thus, allows to apply informality<br />

to both the political and the economic sphere<br />

of society.<br />

With this differentiation, LI (2007) builds a<br />

bridge to the debates on embeddedness (cf.<br />

GRANOVETTER 1973, 1985; UZZI 1996, 1997)<br />

well as flexible and personalized implementation<br />

of processual rules in horizontal power relations<br />

Flexible and personalized implementation<br />

and social capital (cf. COLEMAN 1990; PUTNAM<br />

1993; PORTES 1998; BURT 2001; BOHLE 2005).<br />

With the term of embeddedness, GRANOVETTER<br />

(1990, 98; cited after GLÜCKLER 2001, 214) insists<br />

on the fact that economic action and outcomes<br />

“are affected by actors’ personal<br />

[dyadic] relations, and by the structure of the<br />

overall network of relations”. In this regard he<br />

speaks of relational and structural aspects of<br />

embeddedness. LI (2007, 231 ff.) also follows<br />

this differentiation and distinguishes between<br />

the structure of social relations, expressed as<br />

measures of network diversity and density, as<br />

well as positions of centrality and rank, and the<br />

content of social relations, expressed as measures<br />

of dyadic tie strength and access benefits.<br />

The focus of this article is on the content<br />

of social relations at the scale of dyadic relations<br />

and – more precisely – on personalized<br />

trust as a “mode of commitment [that] results<br />

from strong ties, and also results in relationship<br />

commitment behavior” (loc.cit. 236). By following<br />

GRANOVETTER (1985, 487), informality<br />

is thus approached empirically from the perspective<br />

of “concrete, ongoing systems of social<br />

relations”. In this regard, social capital is<br />

addressed as “an informal access to others’ resources<br />

due to social ties” (LI 2007, 231).<br />

To sum up, informality is a specific governance<br />

mode of social relations in horizontal networks,<br />

most prominently expressed in trustworthy<br />

ties, that comprise institutional<br />

arrangements that are implicitly codified, endogenously<br />

imposed, and dealt with in a flexible,<br />

personalized and thus particularistic manner.<br />

While social ties are the antecedents or<br />

prerequisites of relations, social practices are<br />

the outcome or consequence of institutions. As


Markus Keck / Hans-Georg Bohle / Wolfgang-Peter Zingel: Dealing with insecurity 47<br />

such, social relations, institutions, and social<br />

practice together appear as an interdependent<br />

trialectic which is the fo<strong>und</strong>ing pillar of the<br />

constant reproduction of social reality.<br />

Informal relations and risk adaptation<br />

of food wholesalers in Dhaka<br />

Food wholesalers in Dhaka<br />

As prerequisite for empirical work, the food<br />

system of Dhaka was analytically subdivided<br />

into three different layers, i.e. (i) the wholesaling<br />

of raw food (wholesale markets; single<br />

wholesale stores), (ii) the retailing of raw food<br />

(kitchen markets; permanent retail shops; supermarkets;<br />

semi-permanent and mobile hawkers),<br />

and (iii) the sale of cooked food (restaurants;<br />

canteens; street food stalls). For the<br />

study of the first layer, in total, 42 rice and fish<br />

wholesalers were consulted by means of qualitative<br />

interviews. In addition, certain questions<br />

were deepened with the help of the participatory<br />

tool of Venn diagrams (KUMAR 2000), that<br />

were <strong>und</strong>ertaken with support of local market<br />

associations. Quantitative measures such as<br />

mappings and a panel survey were used to<br />

broaden the perspective of the study. A standardized<br />

random sample survey was conducted<br />

with 448 wholesalers (206 rice and 242 fish<br />

wholesalers) at 21 wholesale markets (twelve<br />

rice and nine fish markets) to test certain hypotheses.<br />

1<br />

Food wholesalers play a pivotal role within the<br />

megaurban food system of Dhaka. They are<br />

crucial intermediaries between providers and<br />

suppliers on the one hand, and retailers and<br />

consumers on the other. The panel survey<br />

(2009 and 2010) revealed that, at present, raw<br />

food is sold at 87 wholesale markets within the<br />

area of Dhaka City Corporation (DCC) (see<br />

Fig. 1). 2 Out of them, there are 24 rice and 13<br />

fish markets with an estimated total number of<br />

1.700 wholesalers (roughly 900 fish and 800<br />

rice wholesalers) who work in 90 % of the<br />

cases as commission agents by order of rice<br />

millers, pond owners or intermediary suppliers<br />

in rural areas (own survey 2009). Sales<br />

amounts of 3,800 kg rice and 800 kg fish on<br />

average per day, and monthly expenses of<br />

32.000 Bangladesh Taka (BDT) in the case of<br />

rice traders and 63.000 BDT in the case of fish<br />

traders on average are substantial compared to<br />

those of retailers or street food vendors. These<br />

sheer numbers show the traders’ significance<br />

within the urban food system. Nevertheless,<br />

there are great socioeconomic disparities amid<br />

the wholesalers. In terms of business volume,<br />

the top 10 % of Dhaka’s fish merchants sell<br />

39 % of the total turnover, while the bottom<br />

10 % sell only 2 %; respective numbers for rice<br />

traders are 35 % and 2 % (own survey 2010).<br />

Besides few ‘big fishes’ among the wholesalers,<br />

large millers and pond owners in rural<br />

areas and the emerging supermarkets with their<br />

much higher profit margins dominate the food<br />

system.<br />

Urban stress and business risks<br />

Qualitative interviews revealed a variety of insecurities<br />

that the merchants face in Dhaka.<br />

From the traders’ perspective, we can distinguish<br />

between the general stress that is related<br />

to social life in the megacity, and particular<br />

risks that are related to the business of wholesaling<br />

as such. Stress refers to negatively perceived<br />

long-term trends such as the accelerated<br />

population growth and spatial expansion of<br />

Dhaka especially since independence that bestows<br />

on customers and merchants ever increasing<br />

distances and travel times. In order to<br />

keep in step with these developments, wholesalers<br />

establish more and more markets at the<br />

urban fringe. For the merchants, this is a viable<br />

strategy to secure their livelihoods. For the<br />

city, these markets are of vital importance. Despite<br />

Dhaka’s rapid urbanization and a number<br />

of inhabitants that easily exceeds that of most<br />

European states, a sufficient number of markets<br />

guarantees enough food to be brought to<br />

the consumer in an efficient way.<br />

Other types of stress are related to the goverance<br />

of the megacity. The most prominent example<br />

is the bribing of numerous power brokers,<br />

such as patrolling policemen in order to<br />

get access to otherwise restricted roads, bureaucrats<br />

in order to reduce the time waiting in<br />

queues, or criminals that would guarantee market<br />

place security in return. Other examples are<br />

the governmental markets of the city. Wholesalers<br />

need to pay high advance payments in<br />

order to be allowed to appropriate and use<br />

these public places. Actually, these markets<br />

have been established by the municipality for<br />

being leased out to the merchants. However,<br />

more often than not, there are lessees who lease<br />

particular market plots in order to rent them out<br />

to the merchants. As such, the public markets<br />

of Dhaka are severely subject to rent-seeking


48 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Fig. 1: Food wholesale markets in Dhaka City<br />

53 8<br />

56<br />

12<br />

50 8<br />

Shah Ali<br />

51<br />

35<br />

54<br />

>250<br />

55<br />

4<br />

57<br />

10<br />

Adabar<br />

52 9<br />

7<br />

15<br />

58 7<br />

6<br />

153<br />

45<br />

10<br />

46 7<br />

Mirpur<br />

Foodtype<br />

Rice<br />

Fish<br />

Pulses / Edible Oil<br />

Fruits / Vegetables / Wheat<br />

Animals / Meat / Eggs<br />

Daily Turnover in Metric Tons<br />

>250 Tons<br />

>50 - 250 Tons<br />

>1 - 50 Tons<br />

12 Name of Market<br />

45 Number of<br />

Wholesale Stores<br />

Settlements in Dhaka<br />

Metropolitan Area (2003)<br />

0<br />

Water Bodies<br />

Major Roads<br />

Railway<br />

1<br />

2 km<br />

Pallabi<br />

48<br />

14<br />

49<br />

12<br />

44<br />

14<br />

80<br />

23<br />

9<br />

40<br />

47<br />

7<br />

Karful<br />

Mohammadpur<br />

77<br />

8<br />

12<br />

15<br />

84<br />

45<br />

Dhanmondi<br />

15<br />

30<br />

42<br />

20<br />

83<br />

70<br />

16<br />

60<br />

40<br />

65<br />

79<br />

>250<br />

41<br />

5<br />

85<br />

35<br />

81<br />

15<br />

18<br />

11<br />

43<br />

5<br />

60<br />

7<br />

76<br />

20<br />

82<br />

48<br />

78<br />

>250<br />

Hazaribag<br />

Shahbag<br />

8<br />

30<br />

10<br />

14<br />

New Market<br />

100<br />

21 40<br />

11 20<br />

12<br />

8<br />

150<br />

Kamrangir<br />

Char<br />

Buriganga River<br />

Military<br />

Airport<br />

Lalbag<br />

Tejgaon<br />

Draft: M. Keck and S. Raupp<br />

Source: Author's own survey 2008-2010<br />

Cartography: G. Storbeck,<br />

Department of Geography,<br />

University of Bonn<br />

International<br />

Airport<br />

13<br />

63<br />

23<br />

17 100<br />

30<br />

Cantonment<br />

86 5<br />

24<br />

3<br />

61<br />

3<br />

31<br />

17<br />

25<br />

100<br />

19<br />

30<br />

87<br />

30<br />

28<br />

100<br />

33<br />

65<br />

Uttara<br />

Gulshan<br />

Tejgaon I/A<br />

Paltan<br />

32<br />

35<br />

63<br />

4<br />

70<br />

30<br />

66<br />

18<br />

67<br />

4<br />

62<br />

4<br />

69<br />

3<br />

29<br />

30<br />

22<br />

12<br />

5<br />

201<br />

Old Dhaka<br />

Kot- 26<br />

wali >250<br />

5<br />

2<br />

Khilgaon<br />

Kamalapur<br />

Train Station<br />

Motijheel<br />

27<br />

30<br />

Sutrapur<br />

3<br />

20<br />

4<br />

60<br />

59<br />

60<br />

65<br />

5<br />

64<br />

7<br />

68<br />

79<br />

71<br />

8<br />

75<br />

11<br />

Sabujbag<br />

74<br />

34<br />

73<br />

12<br />

34<br />

258<br />

38<br />

100<br />

36<br />

22<br />

2<br />

77<br />

Uttara<br />

Badda<br />

37<br />

>250<br />

35 Jatra-<br />

250 bari<br />

39<br />

35<br />

1<br />

16<br />

72<br />

8


Markus Keck / Hans-Georg Bohle / Wolfgang-Peter Zingel: Dealing with insecurity 49<br />

1 Azampur Rail Gate Fish Market<br />

2 Sultan Shah Fish Market<br />

3 Tarun Mahmud Shah Fish Market<br />

4 BDR Wholesale Markt<br />

5 Narda Bazar Rice Market<br />

6, 7 Krishi Market<br />

8 New Market<br />

9 Hazi Sayed Hossain Fruits Market<br />

10 Khalil Sarder Krishi Market<br />

11 Nawabganj Rice Market<br />

12 Lalbag Fort Mor Bazar<br />

13 Swarighat Fish Market<br />

14 - 19 Moulavi Bazar<br />

20 Chowk Bazar<br />

21 Begum Bazar<br />

22, 23 Badamtuli / Babubazar<br />

24 Nazira Bazar<br />

25 Sadar Ghat<br />

26 - 28 Shyam Bazar<br />

29 - 33 Kaptan Bazar<br />

34 - 39 Jatrabari<br />

40 - 43 Kochukhet Market<br />

44 Fakirbari Bazar<br />

45 Mirpur 10 Rice Market<br />

46 - 49 Mirpur 11 Kacha Bazar<br />

50 - 52 Mirpur 1 Kacha Bazar<br />

53 Boro Bazar<br />

54 Gabtoli Cattle Market<br />

55 - 57 Dipjol Bazar<br />

58 Mirpur 2 Bazar<br />

59 Notun Bazar<br />

60, 61 Mohakhali Puran Bazar<br />

62 Modda Badda Bazar<br />

63 - 65 Uttor Badda Bazar<br />

66 Uttor Badda Rice Market<br />

67 Merul Badda Fruits Market<br />

68 Merul Badda Fish Market<br />

69 Rampura Bazar<br />

70 Chowdhuripara Rice Market<br />

71 Sipahibag Hotel Bazar<br />

72 Madertek Bazar<br />

73 Mugdapara Boro Bazar<br />

74 Mugdapara Fish Market<br />

75 Khilgaon Railgate Bazar<br />

76 Govt. Hawkers Market Tejgaon<br />

77 West Nakhal Para Bazar<br />

78 - 86 Kawran Bazar<br />

87 Malibag<br />

activities of widely unknown actors who use<br />

their social relations to political elites to capitalise<br />

on the contested public space in Dhaka.<br />

In terms of business risks, the wholesalers<br />

mentioned a range of adverse incidents that can<br />

be further differentiated in risks that (i) are related<br />

to internal affairs of a wholesaling enterprise,<br />

(ii) those that are related to the wholesalers’<br />

suppliers and customers, and (iii) those<br />

that are related to the wider context of the<br />

megacity. Examples of the first case are the replacement<br />

of staff or employees’ accidents. Examples<br />

of the last category comprise the theft<br />

of goods by outsiders, the robbery on the way<br />

to the bank, or the eviction by state authorities.<br />

Inthe following the focus is on the second category<br />

of risks that are related to the merchants’<br />

business relations to their suppliers and customers.<br />

Based on results of qualitative interviews,<br />

in the standardized survey, the traders<br />

were asked to appraise a selected number of<br />

such risks in regard to the frequency of their<br />

occurance, the perceived severity of their impact,<br />

and the time and effort that is necessary to<br />

cope with them. In the survey it was asked for<br />

six particular types of risks, i.e. the default of<br />

credit paybacks by customers, late delivery of<br />

goods, the delivery of already deteriorated<br />

goods, the default of an entire truck load, the<br />

default of the delivery of goods by a supplier<br />

after the wholesaler paid him in advance, and<br />

the closure of the shop for one day due to supply<br />

cuts. In relation to each of these risks, four<br />

related questions were asked. The first question<br />

was: How often did this incident happen in the<br />

course of the last three years?. Answers were<br />

predefined and ranged from never (that equals<br />

a value of 1), over once (2), 2-3 times (3), and<br />

4-5 times (4), to more than 5 times (5). In a second<br />

question, it was asked for the perceived<br />

severity of the risk impact. It was asked: How<br />

do you assess the severity of the impact of<br />

this/these event/s on your business performance?.<br />

Answers ranged from not severe (1) to<br />

extremely severe (4). The third question addressed<br />

the recovery time after the specific<br />

event occured. It was asked: After this/these<br />

event/s, how long did you need to recover from<br />

its negative impact? Similar to the questions<br />

before, answers were pregiven; at most a week<br />

was weighted with 1, a month with 2, several<br />

months with 3, a year with 4, and more than a<br />

year with 5 points. Eventually, it was asked:<br />

After this/these events, how much extra management<br />

effort did you need to overcome the


50 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Fig. 2: Rice and fish wholesalers’ susceptibility to business risks<br />

Severity<br />

3.30<br />

2.80<br />

2.30<br />

B<br />

E<br />

F<br />

F<br />

problem? Answers ranged from no extra effort<br />

(1) to extreme extra effort (4).<br />

The results in Fig. 2 are the mean numbers, for<br />

rice and fish wholesalers individually. While<br />

the severity and frequency of the mentioned<br />

risks are plotted on the x- and y-axis, the recovery<br />

time and managerial effort are expressed<br />

in a combined way as cost of coping,<br />

that is indicated in the diagramme as symbol<br />

sizes. This cost of coping is calculated by summing<br />

the scores of recovery time (1 to 5) by the<br />

scores of managerial effort (1 to 4), thus resulting<br />

in an index with a range from 1 to 9. The<br />

risk appraisal from the perspective of the food<br />

wholesalers generally follows the logic that<br />

more frequent shocks are evaluated as much<br />

less severe (see Fig. 2). Contrary, less frequent<br />

shocks are assessed as being not only much<br />

more severe in their impact, they also involve<br />

much higher costs of coping for the traders. As<br />

such, late delivery of goods is more frequent in<br />

its occurance but perceived as less severe in its<br />

impact than the supply of already deteriorated<br />

goods. As the approximation curves show, fish<br />

business in general involves more frequent and<br />

D<br />

E<br />

1.80<br />

0.70 1.70 2.70<br />

Frequency<br />

3.70 4.70<br />

Source: own survey 2010, own draft<br />

D<br />

B<br />

C<br />

A<br />

C<br />

A<br />

Fish Wholesalers (n=242)<br />

Rice Wholesalers (n=206)<br />

A: Default of credit payback<br />

by customer<br />

B: Default of delivery by<br />

supplier despite advance<br />

payment<br />

C: Late delivery of goods<br />

D: Default of truckload<br />

E: Shop closure for a day<br />

due to supply cuts<br />

F: Delivery of deteriorated<br />

goods<br />

Costs of Coping:<br />

7.05<br />

2.82<br />

more severe risks in comparison to rice business,<br />

a matter that is explained by the different<br />

perishability of both goods.<br />

Nevertheless, four business related risks do not<br />

fit into this general trend. First of all, the risk of<br />

shop closure due to supply cuts equals a frequency<br />

of nearly zero in the case of rice traders.<br />

The reason behind is, that rice traders usually<br />

command godowns that allow rice to be stored<br />

at least for some days. Beside that, the risk of<br />

customers who do not pay back their credits is<br />

evaluated to be not only highly frequent, but also<br />

highly severe in its consequence. In case of<br />

fish wholesalers, the risk that suppliers do not<br />

deliver goods despite the fact that money was<br />

already paid in advance, is also assessed in this<br />

way. The extraordinary positions of these last<br />

three risks in the appraisal are seen as an indication<br />

for the general importance they have for<br />

the everyday business of the merchants. It is argued<br />

that it is especially these financial risks<br />

that make informal trustworthy relationsships<br />

between the traders and their suppliers and customers<br />

so important.


Markus Keck / Hans-Georg Bohle / Wolfgang-Peter Zingel: Dealing with insecurity 51<br />

Case study: A fish wholesaler<br />

and his business relations<br />

Md. Gilgad Gazi is one of more than 270<br />

wholesalers of Five-Star Fish Market at<br />

Kawran Bazar in the heart of Dhaka City<br />

(market no. 78, Fig. 1). He is in his late 30s<br />

and comes from a small village (gram) not far<br />

from the city of Narail (in Narail district). Mr.<br />

Gazi moved to Dhaka in 1993. He lives together<br />

with his wife and children in a small<br />

appartment in Mohammadpur, some three<br />

kilometers away from his place of work. His<br />

father was a salesman for clothing and taught<br />

him everything he needed to know about how<br />

to manage a store.<br />

Mr. Gazi started his business in 1993 with a<br />

vending stall at Sonali Market (one of the five<br />

compo<strong>und</strong>s of Five-Star Fish Market). He<br />

rented a second stall in 1997, and a third one<br />

in 2001. In 2007, he had the financial resources<br />

to rent three further stalls. Today, he<br />

runs six fish vending sites with a total number<br />

of 20 employees. Each one is run by a manager,<br />

an auctioneer and a weigher. Two helpers<br />

rotate between the single stalls to make shure<br />

that there is always enough fish to be sold<br />

(Venn-diagram of Mr. Gazi in Fig. 3).<br />

From all his employees, Mr. Gazi places one<br />

of his managers (1) first, giving him the highest<br />

score of importance. During the market<br />

hours, this manager is responsible for the<br />

same tasks as the other managers. But afterwards,<br />

he collects the records and earnings of<br />

all other managers for the central book-keeping.<br />

As such, he has decisive control over the<br />

total income of Mr. Gazi’s six vending sites.<br />

The six auctioneers (2) are placed second.<br />

From all other workers, they are most important<br />

due to their responsibility to realize good<br />

sales prices. As he explains, the auctioneers<br />

must be very experienced. They need to know<br />

the customers and their bargaining behavior,<br />

and they need to strategically manage the auctioning<br />

by forcing or reducing the pace. In<br />

third position are the managers of his remaining<br />

five vending sites and his six weighers (3).<br />

He <strong>und</strong>erlines that all of them fulfill important<br />

tasks. Nonetheless, he evaluates them to be of<br />

lower importance compared to the hitherto<br />

mentioned employees. Interestingly, the night<br />

labourers (4), who are not directly employed<br />

by himself but by the market association, are<br />

assessed to be more important and socially<br />

closer to him than his own labourers (5). He<br />

explains this by the fact that the night labourers<br />

bear the responsibility for the unloading of<br />

the trucks and for the correct allocation of his<br />

supplies, a task that they perform independently<br />

at night when his workers are not yet at<br />

the market. The responsibilities of his own<br />

labourers are much less.<br />

After the explanation of the role of his employees,<br />

Mr. Gazi turns to his suppliers. He divides<br />

his 16 suppliers into three groups. Each<br />

group is regarded with different degrees of importance<br />

and placed in different distances to<br />

himself: “There are times, when I deal only<br />

with ten suppliers. But there are also times<br />

when I deal with up to 16 suppliers at the same<br />

time. Ten of my suppliers are very important<br />

for my business. They all deliver fish aro<strong>und</strong><br />

the whole year. The others are far less important.<br />

I know them, but we do business only<br />

from time to time”. In fact, the first (6) and the<br />

second (7) group of suppliers are those whom<br />

Mr. Gazi provides with advance payments<br />

(dadon) that range from 50,000 to 150,000<br />

BDT per year. As return service, they are<br />

bo<strong>und</strong> to deliver a certain amount of fish of a<br />

specific type in regular intervals. Every New<br />

Year, at hal katta, the contracts are anewed.<br />

With four of them (6), very close bonds exisit,<br />

as they stem from Mr. Gazi’s home district<br />

Narail. These four suppliers are those partners<br />

with whom he started his business. To share<br />

the same home district is seen as the f<strong>und</strong>amental<br />

pillar of these relationships. The relations<br />

to the six following suppliers (7) rest on<br />

a long joint business history. In fact, Mr. Gazi<br />

deals with all of them for ten years and more.<br />

These long-lasting business relations and the<br />

shared experience are enough proof for the<br />

good will of each of them. The remaining six<br />

suppliers (8) can be harked back to in times of<br />

need or can be dealt with in case of good offers.<br />

As Mr. Gazi <strong>und</strong>erlines, these suppliers<br />

must be trustworthy as well for fullfilling mutual<br />

agreements. Nonetheless, these six latter<br />

suppliers are not as familiar to him as his other<br />

suppliers are.<br />

Mr. Gazi mentions further that there are approximately<br />

250 customers who come to his<br />

vending sites every day. He divides his stock<br />

of customers into two categories. The first<br />

category (10) consists mainly of retail shop<br />

owners that can be located easily. All actors of<br />

this first category are regular customers. They


52 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Fig. 3: The Venn-diagramme of Mr. Gazi<br />

Source: own draft<br />

Employees<br />

Suppliers<br />

are well known to Mr. Gazi and his employees<br />

and they usually purchase large quantities of<br />

fish. There is usually not much bargaining<br />

with these customers, and most of them get<br />

fish on credit. The second category (11) consists<br />

of all casual customers who are not personally<br />

known to Mr. Gazi and with whom no<br />

social relation exists. For purchasing fish, they<br />

need to participate the auctions. None of them<br />

gets fish on credit.<br />

Beside his employees, his suppliers and his<br />

customers, Mr. Gazi mentions five more actors<br />

or actor groups that are of relevance for<br />

his business performance. The first one is his<br />

The sentimental and instrumental<br />

value of informal relations<br />

Market<br />

Association<br />

Mr. Gazi Scale of Social Proximity: Relevance for Business Performance:<br />

Close – – – – – – – – – – Distant „very low“ – – – – – – – „very high“<br />

The Venn diagramms proved that food wholesalers<br />

in Dhaka are embedded in social networks<br />

linking them to various actors. The<br />

traders maintain ties not only to their suppliers<br />

and customers, but also to other wholesalers, to<br />

banks and local money lenders, to land lords,<br />

local policemen, ward commissioners and municipal<br />

bureaucrats. Regarding the organization<br />

of supply, it was fo<strong>und</strong> that the food traders ba-<br />

5<br />

17<br />

4<br />

Lessor, Land<br />

Owner<br />

8<br />

7 9<br />

6<br />

3 2 1<br />

16<br />

14<br />

15<br />

12<br />

13<br />

10<br />

11<br />

Customers<br />

Business<br />

Partner<br />

Bank,<br />

Moneylender<br />

Government, Dhaka City<br />

Corporation<br />

brother (12), whom he calls his closest business<br />

partner. The second actor is his bank (13)<br />

that he needs to transfer money to his suppliers.<br />

The third actor group is the DCC (14) and<br />

the central government (15), which are relevant<br />

for the trade license and tax that need to<br />

be paid. Furthermore, there is the market association<br />

(9), which runs a credit system. Each<br />

wholesaler usually pays a daily amount of<br />

20.00 BDT into a common pool, which is<br />

available as credit in case of need. The last actors<br />

that Mr. Gazi mentions are the land owners<br />

of the market (17) and his lessor (landlord)<br />

(16)<br />

Source: own interview, 23.2. 2009<br />

sically apply two strategies. On the one hand<br />

they maintain long-standing informally governed<br />

relations to a limited number of suppliers.<br />

On the other hand they maintain relations<br />

to a number of socially distant suppliers<br />

that are governed by formal arrangements.<br />

Even though there are businessmen who pursue<br />

either the first or the second strategy, in<br />

most cases, both are applied at the same time.<br />

Typically, traders are tied to a number of selected<br />

and socially close suppliers from whom<br />

they regularly receive large portions of goods.


Markus Keck / Hans-Georg Bohle / Wolfgang-Peter Zingel: Dealing with insecurity 53<br />

Additionally, they maintain red<strong>und</strong>ant relations<br />

to suppliers that may be harked back to in times<br />

of shortages. Even though the intimate suppliers<br />

are evaluated as much more important<br />

for the merchants’ business performance, it<br />

must be mentioned that both goals, a broadening<br />

and a deepening of their network relations,<br />

are on the businessmen’s agenda.<br />

Given the perishability and seasonality of rice<br />

and fish, the traders’ business performance<br />

turns out to be to large extent a question of the<br />

quality of their networks. While rice can be<br />

stored over months, fish rots within few hours<br />

if not properly cooled and looses its value<br />

within a single day. In the absence of cold<br />

stores, fish merchants bear a much higher risk<br />

of making losses. This fact makes fish wholesalers<br />

even more reliant on strong, trustworthy<br />

business relations and ongoing, frictionless<br />

supplies. A young shop owner explains the<br />

consequences of supply shortfalls: “Sometimes<br />

all of my three suppliers can not deliver fish at<br />

the same day. This happens aro<strong>und</strong> 90 days a<br />

year! I can not do business then in these days”<br />

(Interview 3.4. 2009).<br />

The way how business is carried out is shaped<br />

by the immanent institutions which constitute<br />

the relation. The statement of another fish merchant<br />

helps to <strong>und</strong>erstand the difference between<br />

formal and informal relations that holds<br />

relevance for their dealings with both suppliers<br />

and customers. On the informal relations to his<br />

customers he states: “I usually call my permanent<br />

customers to sell them their preferred fish.<br />

Occasional customers come to me independently.<br />

They buy fish only in case they can<br />

make profit. I have a pure business relation to<br />

them. With my permanent customers this is different.<br />

I tell them the purchase price and my<br />

expenses. I add my personal profit and tell<br />

them the price. And they have to buy [the fish]<br />

for that price. Even though other wholesalers<br />

here at the market have better prices, they<br />

would never buy fish from someone else. Because<br />

they have 100 % trust in me!” (Interview<br />

3.4. 2009).<br />

This statement should not be misinterpreted in<br />

the sense that an attitude of individual profit<br />

maximization would dominate only the formal<br />

market arrangements.An attitude of profit maximization<br />

can also be fo<strong>und</strong> in informal relationships.<br />

The above mentioned statements show<br />

that formal market relationships are mainly<br />

maintained to floating customers and to additional,<br />

sometimes red<strong>und</strong>ant suppliers. Since<br />

both exchange partners hardly know each other,<br />

the transaction is agreed upon on the sheer basis<br />

of prices. In stark contrast to that, the traders<br />

share much more information with their close<br />

exchange partners, such as on the conditions of<br />

acquisition and the quality of goods, their personal<br />

expenses and profit margin. Furthermore,<br />

in formal relationships the exchange partners<br />

themselves as well as the relations to them are<br />

appraised as being of no special value. In fact,<br />

the traders have no special word for this kind of<br />

relationsships; they are either called pure business<br />

relation or it is stated that there would not<br />

exist any relation at all. On the contrary, the<br />

traders evaluate the relationships to their close<br />

partners as being of severe importance. This is<br />

expressed in their everyday language as they<br />

circumscribe these relations with several words<br />

such as trust or faith (biswas), commitment<br />

(protigha or protisruti), courage (utshaho) or<br />

honesty (dan).<br />

It is argued here that basically two aspects are<br />

responsible for this value enhancement of informal<br />

relationsships, that is their sentimental<br />

and their instrumental significance (cf. LI<br />

2007, 236). In regard to the sentimental dimension<br />

of informality, a rather short statement of<br />

a rice trader may serve as eye-opener. On the<br />

question of how he perceives his five most important<br />

suppliers he answered briefly: “To<br />

some extent, we are businessmen. But we are<br />

also brothers [bhai, which literally means<br />

brother, but is generally used to express social<br />

proximity]. We are both, brothers and businessmen.”<br />

(Interview 7.4. 2009). What is designative<br />

in this statement is the fact that the<br />

trader does not perceive the two roles of businessman<br />

and brother as two opponents. He<br />

does not draw a clear cutting line that would<br />

separate them. It is rather both roles that are accepted<br />

as being constitutive of the relationship.<br />

If we consider formal relations as being basically<br />

uni-dimensional, as allowing only few<br />

scope for abnormal behaviour between, for instance,<br />

a seller and a buyer, informal relationships<br />

are more diversified and basically multidimensional.<br />

By the means of iterative interaction,<br />

a pure businessman may thus become<br />

gradually a person with various social roles<br />

such as family head, friend, neighbour, religious<br />

fellow and supplier, each one bringing up<br />

another logic and code of conduct. In this context,<br />

LI (2007, 239) speaks of the versatility of


54 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Table 2: Assessment of Business Relations, Rice Wholesalers<br />

Tab. 2: Assessment of business relations, rice wholesalers<br />

“Please consider the relations to your customers and suppliers: What role plays ... for these relations?”<br />

In Relations to Regular In Relations to Occasional Difference<br />

Business Partners (Mean) Business Partners (Mean) (Mean)<br />

The quality of goods Very important (1.00) Very important (1.00) 0.00<br />

To push prices for personal gain Important (2.18) Important (2.32) 0.14<br />

To follow same religion Not important (3.81) Not important (3.96) 0.15<br />

To be relatives Not important (3.60) Not important (3.88) 0.28<br />

To share same home district Not important (3.67) Not important (3.99) 0.32<br />

The reputation of your partner Very important (1.15) Important (1.86) 0.71<br />

To get credit* Important (2.48) Not important (3.60) 1.12<br />

To <strong>und</strong>erstand other’s business* Important (2.01) Rather not important (3.48) 1.47<br />

To do each other a favour* Very important (1.47) Rather not important (3.03) 1.56<br />

To help in difficult times* Very important (1.50) Rather not important (3.09) 1.59<br />

The balance of favours* Important (1.59) Rather not important (3.43) 1.84<br />

To give credit* Very important (1.42) Rather not important (3.41) 1.99<br />

Source: Own Survey 2009�2010<br />

informal relationships. It is argued that the sentimental<br />

value of informal relations is rooted in<br />

this versatility.<br />

The instrumental value of informality gets<br />

clear, for instance, in cases of supply cuts. In<br />

times of low amounts of available goods, suppliers<br />

apply their credo ‘first partners first’ and<br />

deliver their goods to their most valued customers<br />

only, whereas others are missed out.<br />

Thus, informal business relations help the merchants<br />

to get their goods even in difficult times,<br />

when not only the general supply but also the<br />

number of available suppliers decreases. Similarly,<br />

informal relations are helpful in times of<br />

financial shortfalls. Drawing on joint experiences<br />

with another wholesaler at the same market,<br />

whom he calls a business partner, a fish<br />

trader declares: “In case I run out of money today,<br />

I can go to him and borrow some. The next<br />

day I will give it back, no problem” (Interview<br />

3.4. 2009). It is argued here, that it is this “joint<br />

problem solving attitude” (cf. UZZI 1997, 42<br />

ff.) and a behaviour that is first and foremost<br />

committed to maintain and prolong the relationship<br />

to the partner (cf. LI 2007, 236), that<br />

constitutes the instrumental value of informal<br />

relations in Dhaka.<br />

Source: own survey 2009-2010<br />

Note: The single-factor (one-way) analysis of variance (ANOVA) revealed a significant difference between relations<br />

to regular and occasional business partners in regard to the inherent “joint problem solving attitude” with p


Markus Keck / Hans-Georg Bohle / Wolfgang-Peter Zingel: Dealing with insecurity 55<br />

Table 3: Assessment of Business Relations, Fish Wholesalers<br />

Tab. 3: Assessment of business relations, fish wholesalers<br />

“Please consider the relations to your customers and suppliers: What role plays ... ?”<br />

In Relations to Regular In Relations to Occasional Difference<br />

Business Partners (Mean) Business Partners (Mean) (Mean)<br />

To be relatives Not important (3.59) Not important (3.57) �0.02<br />

The quality of goods Very important (1.00) Very important (1.07) 0.07<br />

To follow same religion Not important (3.71) Not important (3.82) 0.11<br />

To push prices for personal gain Important (2.12) Important (2.33) 0.21<br />

To share same home district Rather not important (3.25) Rather not important (3.49) 0.24<br />

The reputation of your partner Very important (1.35) Important (1.74) 0.39<br />

To get credit* Important (2.46) Not important (3.64) 1.18<br />

The balance of favours* Important (1.71) Rather not important (2.92) 1.21<br />

To <strong>und</strong>erstand other’s business* Important (2.17) Rather not important (3.39) 1.22<br />

To do each other a favour* Important (1.55) Rather not important (2.92) 1.37<br />

To help in difficult times* Very important (1.33) Rather not important (2.76) 1.43<br />

To give credit* Important (1.58) Rather not important (3.47) 1.89<br />

Source: Own Survey 2009�2010<br />

stand each other’s business’, ‘to take credits’,<br />

‘to give credits’, ‘to help each other in difficult<br />

times’, ‘to do each other a favour’, and ‘the<br />

balance of favours’ were evaluated as very important<br />

or important in strong relations, wheras<br />

they played only a marginal or no role in weak<br />

ones. These differences in the evaluation of<br />

business relations to regular and occassional<br />

suppliers and customers clearly indicate the<br />

difference of governance modes that are inherent<br />

in both types of relationships. As such,<br />

these numbers clearly back an <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />

of informal relations that exhibit a profo<strong>und</strong><br />

relevance for the traders’ adaptive capacities.<br />

To sum up, in terms of quantity, rice and fish<br />

wholesalers in Dhaka operate only a small<br />

amount of exchanges via formal market relations,<br />

while the majority of transactions is organized<br />

through informal, trust-based relations.<br />

Based on the empirical evidence presented<br />

above, two basic characteristics of such<br />

relations have been revealed, namely their sentimental<br />

and their instrumental value. The sentimental<br />

value is based on the sharing of more<br />

detailed information and a higher degree of<br />

mutual knowledge. It gradually leads to an ever<br />

growing versatility of relationships and thus to<br />

flexibility, options for action, and an atmos-<br />

Source: own survey 2009-2010<br />

Note: The single-factor (one-way) analysis of variance (ANOVA) revealed a significant difference between relations<br />

to regular and occasional business partners in regard to the inherent “joint problem solving attitude” with p


56 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

analysis has extented to the food system of<br />

Dhaka City only as far as food is brought to the<br />

urban markets, not to the ability of final consumers<br />

to buy food. It has been assumed that it<br />

is the continuous effort of food traders and in<br />

particular their constant investment in informal<br />

business relations, that determines the food<br />

system’s robustness to a large extent. Following<br />

LI (2007), informal relations have been <strong>und</strong>erstood<br />

as comprising institutional arrangements<br />

that are implicitly codified, endogenously<br />

imposed, and dealt with in a flexible, personalized<br />

and thus particularistic manner. Informality<br />

is most prominently expressed in<br />

trustworthy relationships. Informal relations<br />

are related to specific transaction qualities and<br />

an inherent value enhancement that stems from<br />

their sentimental and their instrumental character.<br />

In case of Dhaka’s rice and fish wholesalers,<br />

the sentimental value of informal relations<br />

have been shown to stem from their inherent<br />

versatility, whereas the instrumental<br />

value has been fo<strong>und</strong> to originate from the<br />

traders’ joint problem solving activities and<br />

their commitment to maintain and prolong the<br />

relationship to their partners. As such, informal<br />

relations owe the merchants stable and longterm<br />

returns and thus contribute to their overall<br />

business performance. By adding to the traders’<br />

adaptive capacities, it is the web of mutual<br />

trust and social capital that keeps the food system<br />

of Dhaka running.<br />

Especially in megacities, informality is often<br />

interpreted in negative terms as a clear indicator<br />

for an upcoming or even already prevalent<br />

governance crisis. Such a conceptualization,<br />

however, bears the risk to neglect the inherent<br />

potential of informal governance modes for<br />

people’s adaptive capacities and cities’ future<br />

development. If we want to achieve a better <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />

of the social mechanisms that foster<br />

societies’ resilience, we need to take into<br />

account also those activities of people which<br />

are not formally regulated by the market or<br />

state and which sometimes even circumvent<br />

statutory measures and policies.<br />

Notes<br />

1 Fish markets that were studied are Kawran Bazar, Jatrabari,<br />

Merul Badda, Sultan Shah, Mugdapara, Dipjol<br />

Bazar, Kochukhet, Kaptan Bazar, and New Market.<br />

Rice markets that were studied are Badamtuli, Mohakali,<br />

Jatrabari, Kochukhet, Mirpur 1, Kawran Bazar,<br />

Uttor Badda, Krishi Market, Boro Bazar, Modda Badda,<br />

West Nakhal Para and Mirpur 10 (see Fig. 1). In<br />

addition to the study on food wholesalers, a second<br />

study focused on the third layer of the food system,<br />

with a specific focus on street food vendors, their<br />

livelihoods, and their daily struggles for accessing<br />

public space (see ETZOLD et al. 2009). A third study<br />

was <strong>und</strong>ertaken on poor slum dwellers, their food consumption<br />

patterns, and the impact of the recent food<br />

price hike on their livelihoods (see ZINGEL et al. 2011).<br />

Unfortunately, results of these latter two studies exceed<br />

the scope of this paper.<br />

2 Wholesalers are defined as business organizations<br />

(ADELSTEIN 2010) that are dedicated to the sale of<br />

products to retailers, street food vendors or restaurant<br />

owners, or more generally, to anyone other than final<br />

consumers. Usually, rice is sold in 50 to 80 kg sacks<br />

rather than in smaller portions; fish is sold in b<strong>und</strong>les<br />

of baskets or drums, not per piece or per kg. – Markets<br />

are defined as a composition of wholesalers in direct<br />

spatial proximity to each other at a specific place. In<br />

Dhaka, these markets are sometimes precisely bordered,<br />

as it is the case if they are planned and installed<br />

by the municipality. Sometimes they are somewhat<br />

fuzzy in their extent, as it is the case if they are privatly<br />

installed with shops that are stringed along a road.<br />

References<br />

ADELSTEIN, R. (2010): Firms as social Actors. In: Journal<br />

of <strong>Institut</strong>ional Economics, (6)3, 329-349.<br />

AHMED, R. (2001): Retrospects and prospects of the rice<br />

economy of Bangladesh. Dhaka.<br />

BBS (Bangladesh Bureau of Statistics) (2007): Report<br />

of the household income and expenditure survey 2005.<br />

Dhaka.<br />

BOHLE, H.-G. (2005): Soziales oder unsoziales Kapital?<br />

Das Sozialkapital-Konzept in der Geographischen Verw<strong>und</strong>barkeitsforschung.<br />

In: Geographische Zeitschrift,<br />

(93)2, 65-81.<br />

BOHLE, H.-G./ETZOLD, B./KECK, M. (2009): Resilience<br />

as agency. In: International Human Dimensions Programme<br />

on Global Environmental Change Update<br />

2/2009, 8-13. Internet: http://www.ihdp.unu.edu/file/<br />

get/7170; 12.10.2010<br />

BURT, R. (2001): Structural holes versus network closure<br />

as social capital. In: Lin, N./Cook, K./Burt, R.<br />

(Eds.): Social capital. Theory and research. New York,<br />

31-56.<br />

CARR, E. (2008): Between structure and agency. Livelihoods<br />

and adaptation in Ghana’s Central Region. In:<br />

Global Environmental Change, (19)4, 689-699.<br />

CHEN, M. (2006): Rethinking the informal economy.<br />

Linkages with the formal economy and the formal regulatory<br />

environment. In: Guha-Khasnobis, B./Kanbur,<br />

R./Ostrom, E. (Eds.): Linking the formal and informal<br />

economy. Concepts and policies. New York, 75-92.<br />

COLEMAN, J. (1990): Fo<strong>und</strong>ations of social theory. Cambridge,<br />

London.<br />

DE SOYSA, I./JÜTTING, J. (2007): Informal institutions<br />

and development. How they matter and what makes<br />

them change. In: Jütting, J./Drechsler, D./Bartsch, S./de<br />

Soysa, I. (Eds.): Informal institutions. How social<br />

norms help or hinder development. Paris, 29-43.


Markus Keck / Hans-Georg Bohle / Wolfgang-Peter Zingel: Dealing with insecurity 57<br />

(OECD - Development Centre Studies)<br />

DEVEREUX, S. (Ed.)(2007): The new famines. Why<br />

famines persist in an era of globalization. London/New<br />

York.<br />

DOROSH, P./DE NINNO, C./SHAHABUDDIN, Q. (2004):<br />

Overview of the Bangladesh foodgrain economy. In: De<br />

Ninno, C./Shahabuddin, Q./Dorosh, P. (Eds.): The 1998<br />

floods and beyond. Towards comprehensive food security<br />

in Bangladesh. Dhaka, 13-52.<br />

DOROSH, P./MURSHID, K. (2004): Trade liberalization<br />

and national food security. Rice trade between<br />

Bangladesh and India. In: De Ninno, C./Shahabuddin,<br />

Q./Dorosh, P. (Eds.): The 1998 floods and beyond. Towards<br />

comprehensive food security in Bangladesh.<br />

Dhaka, 101-126.<br />

ERICKSON, P. (2008): Conceptualizing food systems for<br />

global environmental change research. In: Global Environmental<br />

Change, (18)1, 234-245.<br />

ETZOLD, B./KECK, M./BOHLE, H.-G./ZINGEL, W.-P.<br />

(2009): Informality as agency – negotiating food security<br />

in Dhaka. In: Die Erde, (140)1, 3-24.<br />

FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization)(2008): Rice<br />

market monitor. Washington D.C. (April 2008, vol. XI,<br />

issue 1).<br />

FAO (2009a) Rice market monitor. Washington D.C.<br />

(Feb. 2009. vol. XII, issue 1).<br />

FAO (2009b) Rice market monitor. Washington D.C.<br />

(Dec. 2009, vol. VII, issue 2).<br />

FAOSTAT (2010): Database on food production and<br />

trade. Internet: http://faostat.fao.org/default.aspx,<br />

12.10.2010<br />

FPMU (Food Policy Monitoring Unit) (2009):<br />

Bangladesh food situation report, 78. Dhaka.<br />

GIDDENS, A. (1984): The constitution of society. Outline<br />

of the theory of structuration. Cambridge.<br />

GLÜCKLER, J. (2001): Zur Bedeutung von Embeddedness<br />

in der <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong>. In: Geographische<br />

Zeitschrift, (89)4, 211-226.<br />

GRANOVETTER, M. (1973): The strength of weak ties. In:<br />

American Journal of Sociology, (78)6, 1360-1380.<br />

GRANOVETTER, M. (1985): Economic action and economic<br />

structure. The problem of embeddedness. In:<br />

American Journal of Sociology, (91)3, 481-510.<br />

GUYER, J. (1987): Introduction. In: Guyer, J. (Ed): Feeding<br />

African cities. Studies in regional social history.<br />

Manchester, 1-54.<br />

HART, K. (1973): Informal income opportunities and urban<br />

employment in Ghana. In: Journal of Modern<br />

African Studies, (11)1, 61-89.<br />

ILO (International Labor Organization)(1972): Employment,<br />

incomes and equality. A strategy for increasing<br />

productive employment in Kenya. Geneva.<br />

ISLAM, N. (2005): Dhaka now. Contemporary urban development.<br />

Dhaka. (Bangladesh Geographical Society).<br />

ISLAM, N. (2010): Dhaka in 2050. In: CUS Bulletin on<br />

Urbanization and Development, (58/59), 5-10<br />

KECK, M./ETZOLD, B./BOHLE, H.-G./ZINGEL, W.-P.<br />

(2008): Reis <strong>für</strong> die Megacity. Nahrungsversorgung von<br />

Dhaka zwischen globalen Risiken <strong>und</strong> lokalen Verw<strong>und</strong>barkeiten.<br />

In: Geographische R<strong>und</strong>schau, (60)11, 28-37.<br />

KRAAS, F. (2008): Megacities as global risk areas. In:<br />

Marzluff, J./Endlicher, W./Alberti, M./Bradley,<br />

G./Ryan, C./ZumBrunnen, C./Simon, U. (Eds.): Urban<br />

ecology. An international perspective on the interaction<br />

between humans and nature. New York, 583-596.<br />

KRAAS, F./NITSCHKE, U. (2006): Megastädte als Motoren<br />

globalen Wandels. Neue Herausforderungen weltweiter<br />

Urbanisierung. In: Internationale Politik, (61)11,<br />

18-28.<br />

KRAAS, F./MERTINS, G. (2008): Megastädte in Entwicklungsländern.<br />

Vulnerabilität, Informalität, Regier- <strong>und</strong><br />

Steuerbarkeit. In: Geographische R<strong>und</strong>schau, (60)11, 4-<br />

10.<br />

KUMAR, S. (2002): Methods for community participation.<br />

A complete guide for practitioners. London.<br />

LI, P. (2007): Social tie, social capital, and social behavior.<br />

Toward an integrative model of informal exchange.<br />

In: Asia Pacific Journal of Management, (24)2,<br />

227-246.<br />

NORTH, D. (1990): <strong>Institut</strong>ions, institutional change and<br />

economic performance. New York.<br />

NORTH, D. (2005): Understanding the process of economic<br />

change. Princeton/Oxford.<br />

PORTES, A. (1998): Social capital. Its origins and applications<br />

in modern sociology. In: Annual Review of Sociology,<br />

24, 1-24.<br />

PUTNAM, R. (1993): Making democracy work. Civic traditions<br />

in modern Italy. New York.<br />

SCOTT, R. (2008): <strong>Institut</strong>ions and organizations. Ideas<br />

and interest. London.<br />

SEARLE, J. (1995): The construction of social reality.<br />

London.<br />

SIDDIQUI, K./AHMED, J./AWAL, A./AHMED, M. (2000):<br />

Overcoming the governance crisis in Dhaka City. Dhaka.<br />

UN (United Nations - Department of Economic and Social<br />

Affairs, Population Division)(2008): World urbanization<br />

prospects. The 2007 revision. Internet: http:<br />

//www.un.org/ esa/ population/ publications/ wup2007/<br />

2007WUP_Highlights_web.pdf, 12.10.2010<br />

UZZI, B. (1996): The sources and consequences of embeddedness<br />

for the economic performance of organizations.<br />

The network effect. In: American Sociological<br />

Review, (61)4, 674-698.<br />

UZZI, B. (1997): Social structure and competition in interfirm<br />

networks. The paradox of embeddedness. In:<br />

Administrative Science Quarterly, (42)1, 35-67.<br />

WATTS, M. (1983): Silent violence. Food, famine and<br />

peasantry in Northern Nigeria. Berkeley.<br />

World Bank (2007): Dhaka. Improving living conditions<br />

of the urban poor. Dhaka. (The World Bank Office,<br />

Dhaka). Internet: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/<br />

B A N G L A D E S H E X T N / R e s o u r c e s / 2 9 5 7 5 9 -<br />

1182963268987/dhakaurbanreport.pdf, 12.10.2010<br />

ZINGEL, W.-P./KECK, M./ETZOLD, B./BOHLE, H.-G.<br />

(2011): Urban food security and health risks in Dhaka. In:<br />

Krämer, A./Khan, M./Kraas, F. (Eds.): Health in megacities<br />

and urban areas. New York/Heidelberg, 301-319.


Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> Jg. 56 (2012) Heft 1-2, S. 58-79<br />

Pamela Hartmann Kilian, Köln/ Daniel Schiller, Hannover/ Frauke Kraas, Köln<br />

Workplace quality and labour turnover in the electronics industry<br />

of the Pearl River Delta, China<br />

Contrasting employer and employee perspectives<br />

Abstract: Export-oriented manufacturing firms in developing countries need to be highly flexible<br />

in order to respond to demand changes in volatile global markets. By using a modified version of<br />

Atkinson’s flexible firm concept as a framework, it is the aim of this paper (i) to describe the impact<br />

of workplace quality on labour turnover and (ii) to derive implications of this relationship for<br />

upgrading processes. Empirical data are combined from two surveys of migrant workers and electronics<br />

firms in the Pearl River Delta, China.<br />

Keywords: flexible firm, upgrading, workplace quality, labour turnover, China<br />

Introduction<br />

Since the implementation of China’s opening<br />

policy (1978), the Pearl River Delta in the<br />

southern region of the country has developed<br />

into the so-called ‘factory of the world’ for<br />

flexible and wage-sensitive production in<br />

labour-intensive sectors of light industry (EN-<br />

RIGHT et al. 2005). One of the most important<br />

sectors involved in this rise is the electronics<br />

industry, which is responsible for approximately<br />

39 % of the value added of the region<br />

(GDSTATS 2010) and is particularly tightly integrated<br />

into globally organised value chains<br />

(MEYER et al. 2009; MEYER et al. 2012; STUR-<br />

GEON 2002). The Pearl River Delta, with its<br />

large growth dynamic for industrial value<br />

added and its flexible production model, is subject<br />

to strong cyclical deviations, both seasonal<br />

and related to its dependence on exports.<br />

During the most recent global economic and financial<br />

crisis, the growth rate of the gross domestic<br />

product (GDP) in Guangdong fell from<br />

10.5 % in 2008 to 5.8 % in the first quarter of<br />

2009 (YU/ZHANG 2009) – and in Dongguan<br />

even more so, from 14.0 % to -3.5 % (YU/<br />

HUANG 2009).<br />

Moreover, the shortage of workers, which was<br />

already a problem before the crisis (HE 2006;<br />

YANG 2005), has now been making headlines<br />

once again since 2010 following a short interruption<br />

during the crisis years (The Economist<br />

29.7. 2010, KNIGHT et al. 2011). The financial<br />

crisis was only temporarily able to mask the<br />

demographic effects of the one child policy,<br />

which are becoming apparent in that the 18-24<br />

years age group, which is so important for industrial<br />

companies, is shrinking. An additional<br />

problem is the fact that the economic development<br />

of the inland regions of China is providing<br />

increasingly attractive job opportunities for<br />

migrant workers in their home provinces, and<br />

the demands of the younger generation of<br />

workers are beginning to increase. The current<br />

generation is less willing than previous ones to<br />

accept the low quality of jobs, i.e. the often<br />

monotonous, physically straining and dangerous<br />

working conditions, in relation to the financial<br />

rewards, further benefits and qualification<br />

requirements (YUE et al. 2010). Companies<br />

are thus complaining of high rates of<br />

labour turnover, with a personnel substitution<br />

rate of 30-40 % per year being a fairly midrange<br />

figure (HÜRTGEN et al. 2009, 226); for<br />

companies with foreign investment, the<br />

turnover rate is estimated to be between 30 %<br />

and 90 % (PUN/SMITH 2007, 36 ff.), since job<br />

changing, i.e. employees moving to another<br />

company, is triggered initially by minimal differences<br />

in wage costs, and is also generally<br />

possible without any significant difficulties<br />

due to homogeneous and weak regulation, low<br />

qualification requirements and low demands of<br />

the positions on workers.


Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 59<br />

Against this backgro<strong>und</strong>, CHAN (2010a) speaks<br />

of a Chinese paradox consisting of a shortage<br />

of migrant workers in the coastal provinces<br />

and a surplus of labour supply in the rural regions.<br />

In his opinion, the Lewisian turning<br />

point (LEWIS 1954), at which the unlimited<br />

supply of labour from rural areas dries up and<br />

wages steadily begin to increase, has not yet<br />

been reached. The Hukou system and an increased<br />

demand for workers in rural areas<br />

stemming from the 2009 economic stimulus<br />

package have had a particularly distorting effect<br />

on price formation on the job market. The<br />

former worsens the negotiation position of rural<br />

workers in the coastal regions, while the latter<br />

has led to a temporary rise in the number of<br />

non-agricultural job possibilities in rural regions.<br />

CHAN (2010b) does not expect the situation<br />

of workers or the stability of working conditions<br />

to change unless the access to a local<br />

Hukou at the job location is simplified. The<br />

first signs of this are evident in the province of<br />

Guangdong, which is most heavily affected by<br />

the current shortage of workers, in that it is<br />

aiming to provide 1.8 million qualified migrant<br />

workers with a local Hukou within the next<br />

three years (CHAN 2010a).<br />

In the following hypothesis it will be examined<br />

that the labour market in the region is caught in<br />

an inefficient ‘lock-in’ situation, i.e. trapped in<br />

a situation in which the incentive structures do<br />

not lead to investment in qualification on the<br />

part of companies and workers. Workers are<br />

not primarily interested in long-term qualifications,<br />

but rather in short-term income maximisation.<br />

Companies make virtually no investment<br />

in qualification measures and improved<br />

working conditions, since these are not honoured<br />

by increased loyalty on the part of workers,<br />

and, due to the short-term orientation of<br />

the business model, are not necessary either. In<br />

the long term, however, this hampers – and<br />

sometimes even blocks – the upgrading process<br />

towards better quality production and<br />

qualification as well as more stable employment<br />

conditions.<br />

Two questions are at the centre of this investigation:<br />

– To what extent do the quality of jobs and<br />

employee characteristics influence job<br />

changes <strong>und</strong>ertaken by employees and the<br />

labour turnover in companies?<br />

– Does a qualification lock-in exist in the electronics<br />

industry of the Pearl River Delta in<br />

the area of labour-intensive and wage-sensitive<br />

production, and if so, how can this be<br />

overcome?<br />

Firstly, basic theoretical principles concerning<br />

the connection between flexibility and company<br />

success will be discussed, and determinants<br />

for job change will be demarcated. Quantitative<br />

survey data from companies and workers<br />

will be combined methodically. On this basis,<br />

workplace quality and its variation as well as<br />

the influence of workplace quality on the employee<br />

turnover rate of the companies will be<br />

determined, followed by a summary of the results<br />

and a derivation of policy recommendations.<br />

Flexible company organisation<br />

and labour turnover<br />

The term flexibility established itself in this<br />

context in the 1980s and was taken up by international<br />

organisations (e.g. OECD, IMF)<br />

and governments from the 1990s onwards.<br />

This promoted a normative research dialogue<br />

regarding the necessity of flexibilisation of<br />

company organisation and the erosion of normal<br />

working conditions in the course of a farreaching<br />

flexibilisation of companies. As a<br />

counterpoint to this, REILLY (1998) called for a<br />

more detailed differentiation of flexibility requirements<br />

and the empirical investigation of<br />

flexibility potential at the individual, company<br />

and regulation levels.<br />

The flexible firm in the Chinese context<br />

Flexibilisation in the Western context aims to<br />

increase adaptability within an existing political-economic<br />

system. However, this development<br />

must be categorised very differently in<br />

the Chinese context with its gradual socio-economic<br />

transformation to a market economy.<br />

There, the newly formed private economic sector<br />

has been geared towards a high degree of<br />

flexibility from the beginning. It is clearly evident<br />

that the organisation of manufacturing<br />

companies in the Pearl River Delta is characterised<br />

by a tight integration into global production<br />

processes. The volatility of demand<br />

connected to this requires a high degree of<br />

flexibility in terms of production volumes. But<br />

how do these market requirements translate to<br />

the level of company organisation?


60 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Fig. 1: The flexible firm in the context of Chinese low-cost production<br />

Source: own draft, based on ATKINSON 1984, 29<br />

ALBRECHT (2002, 2005) has produced studies<br />

on flexibilisation in German-speaking geography<br />

which refer in their typology of flexibility<br />

to earlier works from the field of company research.<br />

ATKINSON (1984) developed the first<br />

typology of flexibility forms within companies.<br />

According to him, various workforce<br />

groups contribute in different ways to increasing<br />

the flexibility of a company through their<br />

own flexible deployment: the core workforce<br />

of long-term employees should be flexible in<br />

the carrying out of their function. The peripheral<br />

workforce, which makes up the largest<br />

number of employees, is affected by numerical<br />

and financial flexibility (Fig. 1). Numerical<br />

flexibility refers to a varying number of employees<br />

depending on the needs of the company;<br />

financial flexibility concerns the wage policy<br />

of the company being linked to fluctuations<br />

in demand, and in the Western context,<br />

also measures such as commission on profits.<br />

Under certain circumstances though, the advantage<br />

of an efficiently controllable person-<br />

nel volume, which may be achieved through<br />

flexible company organisation, can actually become<br />

a disadvantage. Numerical flexibility, for<br />

instance, involves considerable costs for recruitment<br />

and training. Even though WHITELEY<br />

et al. (2000) estimate these costs to be lower<br />

than those for a regularisation of the workforce,<br />

a high fluctuation can prove to be a liability<br />

for companies in China, especially in a<br />

situation of job surplus and labour shortage<br />

(JIANG et al. 2009).<br />

ATKINSONs flexibility typology has, until now,<br />

only been further differentiated for the Western<br />

investigation context (e.g. REILLY 1998; VAL-<br />

VERDE et al. 2000), which is of little use for the<br />

Chinese context. For example, subcategories of<br />

the peripheral workforce, which are widespread<br />

in the context of the USA and Europe, and particularly<br />

in The Netherlands and Great Britain<br />

(part-time and formalised temporary work, job<br />

sharing, as well as publicly subsidised professional<br />

training within companies), are still


Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 61<br />

generally absent from the manufacturing companies<br />

in China. There, a third, purposely unregulated<br />

segment of the labour market is developing<br />

in the course of the transformation process<br />

between a rural and urban economy: a<br />

market segment of migrant workers (míngōng)<br />

(HEBEL/SCHUCHER 2006). This initiative designed<br />

to mobilise labour resources is well<br />

known as a success factor for China’s economic<br />

boom, but at the expense of social security,<br />

since the migrant workers, of which there<br />

are more than 200 million, must retain their<br />

primary residence in their home towns <strong>und</strong>er<br />

this so-called Hukou system. This means that<br />

access to the social security system at their<br />

work locations has so far remained blocked for<br />

them (health insurance, pension schemes, unemployment<br />

insurance and the subsidised<br />

accommodation market, along with school<br />

education). This results in much lower personnel<br />

costs for companies for these migrant<br />

workers than those for the locally registered<br />

workers, but in wages which are still much<br />

more attractive for the migrant workers than<br />

those in their home regions, thus creating the<br />

basis for the competitive advantage of Chinese<br />

production companies over other production<br />

locations. Activities in low-cost production requiring<br />

little or no qualification, which form<br />

the focal point of employee-based investigations,<br />

are almost exclusively carried out by migrant<br />

workers. Such employment arrangements<br />

are often short-term (up to one year, linshi<br />

zhigong) and rarely mid to long-term (changqi<br />

zhigong) (STAIGER 2008). These considerations<br />

lead to a modified conception of the flexible<br />

firm (Fig. 1).<br />

Due to the high degree of quantitative flexibilisation<br />

in the production companies, it is to be<br />

expected that the workforce is strongly segregated,<br />

also in terms of qualifications. Qualification-based<br />

segregation is defined in this case<br />

as the concentration of employees with a certain<br />

qualification level within a company, although<br />

differing qualification standards certainly<br />

exist between companies (GERLACH et al.<br />

2002). Through outsourcing of production activities,<br />

qualification-based segregation is generally<br />

on the increase (TSERTSVADZE 2005).<br />

Because of the specialisation of Chinese companies<br />

in simpler production activities, segregation<br />

within the global value chain means that<br />

in China, a very small proportion of highly<br />

qualified core workers is juxtaposed in the<br />

manufacturing industry with a large proportion<br />

of poorly qualified migrant workers in the peripheral<br />

workforces for simple production activities.<br />

In contrast, the globally active customer<br />

firms in industrial countries are characterised<br />

by an increasing proportion of highly<br />

qualified employees.<br />

The effects of qualification-based segregation<br />

in internal company learning processes have<br />

not yet been empirically verified. From a conceptional<br />

perspective, however, it can be assumed<br />

that a functional and qualification-based<br />

specialisation that is too one-sided will have<br />

negative effects on learning and will make the<br />

transition of employees from the peripheral to<br />

the core workforce more difficult. Such mobility,<br />

however, would be a starting point for<br />

technological and organisational upgrading<br />

processes, since the building up of basic technological<br />

capabilities is often a result of continual<br />

incremental improvements and knowledge<br />

stemming from experience (KIM 1997), with<br />

the increase of absorptive capacity through<br />

qualified human resources also playing a decisive<br />

role (COHEN/LEVINTHAL 1990). The empirical<br />

investigation of this research project thus<br />

concentrates particularly on the examination of<br />

the peripheral (production and migrant workers)<br />

and their potential role for upgrading<br />

processes.<br />

In accordance with the segregation theory, an<br />

observation of the Chinese electronics industry<br />

clearly shows that the sector is characterised by<br />

a high degree of heterogeneity. On the one<br />

hand, there is the small number of technologically<br />

very active companies which receive almost<br />

unlimited support from the state and have<br />

established international innovation activities,<br />

while on the other hand, there is the vast majority<br />

of companies which possess virtually no<br />

technological competences or absorptive capacity<br />

(ERNST/NAUGHTON 2008). The two sectors<br />

of the branch coexist almost entirely separate<br />

from one another, meaning that knowledge<br />

spillover and the development of a coherent innovation<br />

system cannot realistically be expected<br />

(KROLL/SCHILLER 2011).<br />

Flexibility, workplace quality and labour<br />

turnover<br />

Against the backgro<strong>und</strong> of the transformation<br />

processes in China and their overriding influence<br />

on increased labour turnover, possible determinants<br />

for a change of jobs at the company<br />

level will be discussed, both from an employee


62 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

(supply) and employer (demand) perspective.<br />

Employer perspective: In accordance with the<br />

flexibility maxim, a company aims for an efficiently<br />

directed personnel volume suited to the<br />

current demand situation. The varying need for<br />

labour must thus be seen as the most important<br />

determinant from the company point of view<br />

for labour turnover. In this specific context, it<br />

is managed through contracts and simplified<br />

through a weakly regulated environment (SHEN<br />

2007; LÜTHJE 2008; HÜRTGEN et al. 2009). The<br />

conditions determining workplace quality are<br />

geared to a large extent towards financial flexibility,<br />

and are thus only marginally focused on<br />

the provision of consistent social welfare measures.<br />

Cost advantages are the principal determining<br />

factor behind decisions and generally<br />

entail an achievement-based wage policy in<br />

companies.<br />

Of particular importance in terms of upgrading<br />

processes from the company perspective are<br />

also the human resources available and the<br />

qualification of workers present within the<br />

company. Qualification measures consist here<br />

of education programmes upon entry into the<br />

company or both internal and external further<br />

education programmes provided by the firm.<br />

Qualification of workers in the production area<br />

is potentially beneficial for a transition to the<br />

core workforce and for the reduction of labour<br />

turnover through greater job security, more diverse<br />

spectra of activity and improved income<br />

possibilities. For the empirical investigation,<br />

on the other hand, it can be suspected that the<br />

probability of a job change increases if the expected<br />

educational benefits following a qualification<br />

initiative do not materialise for an individual<br />

employee. Particularly for large labour<br />

markets – such as the Pearl River Delta – the<br />

expectation is that the incentive for companies<br />

to invest in further education diminishes, since<br />

changes in personnel increase following further<br />

education due to the larger number of alternative<br />

employment options for workers, and<br />

because the relevant qualification requirements<br />

can be obtained by companies through the<br />

labour market (BRANDT 2009). However, an<br />

empirical investigation is still required in order<br />

to determine whether this hypothesis derived<br />

from the Western context can be applied to the<br />

Chinese situation.<br />

Employee perspective: Employees (Fig. 1, peripheral<br />

workforce), a heterogeneous research<br />

group, may be categorised according to characteristics<br />

such as age, gender, education and occupation.<br />

When considering labour turnover,<br />

one must take into account how important various<br />

company benefits are to the different<br />

groups of employees and what benefits they indeed<br />

encounter in companies. The conditions<br />

provided in companies can be categorised according<br />

to physical, social and organisational<br />

factors, as well as the company benefits mentioned<br />

above.<br />

In the context of Chinese companies, three aspects<br />

are of particular importance for the <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />

of workplace quality and labour<br />

turnover. Firstly, there has been a change in the<br />

attitude among migrant workers, which still<br />

constitute the largest proportion of poorly qualified<br />

employees. In this case, however, it is not<br />

so much the Lewisian ‘turning point’ which is<br />

able to explain the shortage of labour and rising<br />

wages (CHAN 2010a), but rather the increased<br />

demands of the second generation of<br />

migrant workers in terms of their working conditions<br />

and environment, since alternative vocational<br />

possibilities are now emerging in the<br />

peripheral regions and there is a current tendency<br />

towards a reduction in the importance of<br />

family support in favour of other migration<br />

motives and strategies (FAN 2008; YUE et al.<br />

2010). Secondly, wages are the central argument<br />

for the selection or change of jobs, although<br />

it is not only the amount which plays a<br />

significant role, but also the reliability of wage<br />

payments, since non-payment of wages is the<br />

most common cause of industrial conflict<br />

(SHEN 2007). Thirdly, social welfare benefits<br />

must be categorised differently in China to the<br />

way in which this is done in Europe. Accommodation,<br />

food and recreational activities are<br />

often all provided by the company, although<br />

this is primarily done for the purpose of exercising<br />

better control over employees on the<br />

company site (PUN 2005). Against the backgro<strong>und</strong><br />

of the changing attitude of migrant<br />

workers, this old model of total provision of<br />

amenities is starting to become less attractive.<br />

Data and methods<br />

The data used for the present investigation encompass<br />

the perspectives of both the companies<br />

and the employees and were gathered using<br />

two standardised questionnaires. These<br />

were carried out in cooperation with the De-


Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 63<br />

partment of Urban and Regional Planning of<br />

Sun Yat-sen University in Guangzhou and were<br />

completed at the beginning of 2008. The coupling<br />

of the two sets of survey results is a particularly<br />

fruitful endeavour, especially as it allows<br />

for the capturing of both workplace quality<br />

and job change from the perspective of<br />

employees, as well as the company view of the<br />

workforce and the effects of job changes on the<br />

companies themselves. Several different parameters<br />

were investigated in the course of the<br />

surveys, among both companies and workers<br />

(e.g. wage levels, other benefits, qualification),<br />

in order to achieve a validation of the data<br />

through a comparison of results.<br />

Company data<br />

The data for the company perspective were<br />

taken from a standardised survey of 222 electronics<br />

firms in the Pearl River Delta. The survey<br />

was conducted in cities with a large proportion<br />

of companies from the electronics industry.<br />

The data set encompasses 90 companies<br />

in Dongguan and 116 in Guangzhou. The companies<br />

in Dongguan were selected using the<br />

Guangdong Electronics Company Catalogue<br />

2007; in Guangzhou, a list of companies from<br />

the Municipal Bureau of Statistics was used.<br />

300 questionnaires (150 per city) were distributed<br />

to randomly selected companies following<br />

an introductory telephone conversation in advance.<br />

The response rate was 59 % for Dongguan<br />

and 77 % for Guangzhou. Telephone follow-up<br />

efforts were successful in raising the<br />

quality of survey answers and in reducing the<br />

number of unanswered questions to a minimum.<br />

Due to a lack of structural company information<br />

(e.g. size or owner) in the lists used<br />

to select the samples, a test of representativeness<br />

was not possible. The high response rate,<br />

however, reduces the danger of a systematically<br />

distorted non-answering of questions.<br />

The section of the company survey pertaining<br />

to employees, which is relevant for this study,<br />

contained only closed questions in order to<br />

make it easier to provide answers by telephone<br />

or post. The companies were particularly asked<br />

to make statements about the workers identified<br />

as belonging to the peripheral workforce,<br />

which, in the Pearl River Delta, mostly consists<br />

of migrant workers. Furthermore, a distinction<br />

was often made in the data set during the analysis<br />

between the 114 private Chinese firms and<br />

the 102 foreign companies (including Hong<br />

Kong and Taiwan), since a further aim was to<br />

determine whether the two groups also differ in<br />

terms of workplace quality and flexibility as<br />

they do in terms of technological competences<br />

(SCHILLER 2011).<br />

Employee data<br />

The primary data used for the employee perspective<br />

were taken from a social geography<br />

field study which consisted of both a standardised<br />

survey of 585 workers (of which 566 cases<br />

were suitable for analysis) and a qualitative<br />

collection of data. The latter included 35 interviews<br />

with migrant workers, representatives of<br />

authorities, organisations and employment<br />

agencies as well as participating and non-participating<br />

observations in the factories and the<br />

working environment of low-cost manufacturing.<br />

Considering this large amount of data, this<br />

study will concentrate on the survey data.<br />

The decisive criteria for the selection of the investigation<br />

area and the sample were that it<br />

should be a manufacturing location with a large<br />

proportion of low-cost production in the electronics<br />

industry where the above-mentioned<br />

data could be gathered. This selection process<br />

was faced with the following limitations: 1. a<br />

target group, which can only be captured exploratively<br />

(migrant workers); 2. politically related<br />

restrictions for domestic and foreign<br />

scholars, as well as for the investigation group<br />

in China.<br />

Migrant workers are highly mobile, meaning<br />

that only a small proportion of them are covered<br />

statistically by local authorities, with the<br />

majority only being registered with the companies<br />

which employ them. The choice was made<br />

not to seek access to the subjects via companies,<br />

for example those participating in the<br />

above-mentioned company survey, since no<br />

guarantee could be made that company management<br />

would not influence the statements of<br />

respondents. However, the alternative methods<br />

of gathering data, i.e. in the public sphere, required<br />

legitimisation from public authorities.<br />

The Chinese partner institute of the study<br />

maintains research contacts with Tangxiazhen<br />

in Dongguan, which legitimised the gathering<br />

of the data. With the knowledge that other locations<br />

in the Delta are also specialised in the<br />

electronics industry (e.g. Shilong, Chang’an),<br />

Tangxiazhen was deemed suitable for the data<br />

collection, since the industry there is dominated<br />

by low-cost manufacturing for the export<br />

economy with a large proportion of electronics


64 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

companies. The industrial, demographic and<br />

accompanying socio-economic transformation<br />

processes there are typical for the eastern axis<br />

of the Pearl River Delta (KILIAN et al. 2010).<br />

The sample selection took place in two steps:<br />

First, two areas dominated by the electronics<br />

industry were selected (cluster sampling). The<br />

inner-city industry district 138 (304 valid<br />

questionnaires) has been well established<br />

since the middle of the 1990s. The peri-urban<br />

district Keyuancheng (262 valid questionnaires)<br />

has been occupied by companies since<br />

2005 and is still <strong>und</strong>ergoing development. In<br />

the second step, migrant workers were handed<br />

a questionnaire on the way from the company<br />

site to the shopping street which they filled out<br />

on the spot and returned immediately. Of those<br />

who accepted the questionnaire, the response<br />

rate was 100 %, although some of the questionnaires<br />

were not filled out completely. The<br />

scope of the sample is thus individually labelled.<br />

Workplace quality and labour<br />

turnover<br />

Company perspective<br />

In accordance with the distinction mentioned<br />

above, workplace quality from the company<br />

perspective is measured using the factors income,<br />

social welfare benefits, the design of<br />

employment contracts, training and further education<br />

programmes, and qualification of<br />

workers. The flexibilisation of working conditions<br />

is then investigated using the turnover<br />

rate, the variation in the number of workers<br />

throughout the year, the length of time required<br />

to increase the number of employees by<br />

10 %, as well as typical problems with the<br />

workforce. A differentiation is made between<br />

Chinese and foreign companies, as well as between<br />

Chinese companies at different locations<br />

and of different sizes for selected indicators.<br />

Workplace Quality: The average monthly<br />

wages of the companies surveyed, at approximately<br />

1,300 Yuan, were fo<strong>und</strong> to be well<br />

above the legal minimum wage of 780 Yuan in<br />

Guangzhou and 680 Yuan in Dongguan at the<br />

time of the survey (2007). This suggests that<br />

the labour shortage discussed in the introduction,<br />

which has created particularly strong<br />

competition for qualified workers and for pay-<br />

ment benefits not affecting the basic minimum<br />

wage, for example for overtime, night shift<br />

bonuses, gratuities, had already driven wages<br />

upwards prior to that time. As of May 2010, the<br />

minimum wage was adjusted once again to<br />

1,030 Yuan in Guangzhou and 920 Yuan in<br />

Dongguan (HKTDC 2010). In the survey data,<br />

no significant differences can be fo<strong>und</strong> between<br />

Chinese and foreign companies, which<br />

contradicts the frequently proposed assumption<br />

that foreign companies have an advantage<br />

when competing for labour resources due to<br />

higher wages.<br />

Questions about five benefits provided by<br />

companies over and above the standard wages<br />

revealed that almost 90 % of companies offer<br />

accommodation in a company residential<br />

home, and nearly as many also provide meals<br />

as well as health and accident insurance. Paid<br />

holiday and gifts on festive occasions, especially<br />

at New Year, are much less widespread,<br />

but nevertheless standard at least for half of the<br />

companies surveyed. The social welfare benefits<br />

provided by foreign companies tend to be<br />

slightly greater than those of Chinese companies,<br />

although the differences are only significant<br />

for health and accident insurance. When<br />

combining wages and social welfare benefits,<br />

therefore, only a marginal advantage for foreign<br />

companies could be fo<strong>und</strong>. At this point it<br />

must be taken into consideration that the social<br />

welfare benefits investigated here must be interpreted<br />

differently within the Chinese context<br />

from the way in which they are seen in Europe.<br />

In this regard, PUN (2005) points to the controlling<br />

function of company residential<br />

homes. A high degree of social benefits of this<br />

kind thus characterises those companies which<br />

still follow the classical production model,<br />

which is increasingly coming to be considered<br />

unattractive by the younger generation of migrant<br />

workers.<br />

Two-thirds of employment contracts were individually<br />

negotiated and concluded in written<br />

form. The practice of verbal contracts, which is<br />

illegal <strong>und</strong>er the new Chinese employment<br />

contracts law of 2008 (GEFFKEN et al. 2010) is<br />

now very rare, even among Chinese companies,<br />

although it is still significantly more important<br />

in these firms than in foreign companies.<br />

Due to the minimal importance of verbal<br />

contracts, no investigation has been made as to<br />

their effects on the rate of labour turnover.


Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 65<br />

Tab.1: Selected indicators of workplace quality from the company perspective<br />

Indicator Chinese Foreign<br />

Monthly wage in Yuan 1,304 1,250<br />

F-test (sign.) 0.440<br />

Social welfare benefits<br />

Meals 86 % 79 %<br />

X 2 -test (sign.) 0.192<br />

Accommodation 90 % 87%<br />

X 2 -test (sign.) 0.595<br />

Health/accident<br />

insurance 74 % 86 %<br />

X 2 -test (sign.) 0.024<br />

Paid holiday 68 % 75 %<br />

X 2 -test (sign.) 0.279<br />

Gifts on festive<br />

occasions 45 % 53 %<br />

X 2 -test (sign.) 0.256<br />

Employment contracts<br />

individual written 64 % 66 %<br />

F-test (sign.) 0.691<br />

Individual verbal 11 % 5 %<br />

F-test (sign.) 0.030<br />

Collective 7 % 15 %<br />

F-test (sign.) 0.671<br />

Employment agency<br />

and others 9 % 15 %<br />

F-test (sign.) 0.161<br />

Source: own calculation, company survey 2008<br />

Concerning training and further education, the<br />

following results emerged: much fewer than<br />

half of the companies offer training and further<br />

education measures very frequently. Training<br />

and learning phases occur most often when<br />

new workers commence employment with the<br />

company, while further education is only regularly<br />

offered internally in every fifth company<br />

and externally by every tenth company. Foreign<br />

companies offer significantly more possibilities<br />

in this area of formal training, as well as<br />

in cooperation with external providers of further<br />

education. In the areas of informal training<br />

and internal further education, the differences<br />

are not significant.<br />

Indicator Chinese Foreign<br />

Training and further<br />

education programmes<br />

Formal<br />

training very often (5) 50 % 63 %<br />

programme sometimes/<br />

for new often (3-4) 31 % 29 %<br />

employees never/<br />

rarely (1-2) 19 % 8 %<br />

X 2 -test (sign.) 0.035<br />

Informal very often (5) 45 % 47 %<br />

training of sometimes/<br />

new often (3-4) 41 % 45 %<br />

employees never/<br />

rarely (1-2) 14 % 8 %<br />

X 2 -test (sign.) 0.356<br />

Internal very often (5) 22 % 22 %<br />

further sometimes/<br />

education often (3-4) 33 % 40 %<br />

programmes never/<br />

rarely (1-2) 45 % 38 %<br />

X 2 -test (sign.) 0.499<br />

External very often (5) 11 % 13 %<br />

further sometimes/<br />

education often (3-4) 30 % 42 %<br />

programmes never/<br />

rarely (1-2) 59 % 45 %<br />

X 2 -test (sign.) 0.104<br />

n = 114 n = 102<br />

With regard to educational qualifications as an<br />

indicator for the qualification of employees, it<br />

could be determined that the group of poorly<br />

qualified workers with no more than a completed<br />

intermediate school education is in the<br />

majority. Approximately another quarter have a<br />

completed secondary school education, with<br />

roughly the same number having a vocational<br />

school qualification, while fewer than 10 %<br />

have a university degree. A surprising finding<br />

was that Chinese companies have more highly<br />

qualified employees on average. The differences<br />

are particularly significant in the area of<br />

vocational school qualifications. This may possibly<br />

be explained by the fact that foreign com-


66 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Tab. 2: Selected indicators of job flexibility from the company perspective<br />

Indicator Chinese Foreign Indicator Chinese Foreign<br />

Turnover rate 32 % 40 % Problems with the workforce (continued)<br />

F-test (sign.) 0.072<br />

Job change very often (5) 12 % 13 %<br />

Time required following sometimes/<br />

for a 10% increase participation often (3-4) 35 % 37 %<br />

in the number of in company never/<br />

employees in days 23 22 further rarely (1-2) 54 % 50 %<br />

F-test (sign.) 0.797 education<br />

X 2 -test (sign.) 0.848<br />

Variation of the<br />

number of employees Low degree<br />

throughout the year in % 45 % 41 % of loyalty very often (5) 10 % 7 %<br />

F-test (sign.) 0.379 sometimes/<br />

often (3-4) 33 % 38 %<br />

never/rarely<br />

Problems with the workforce (1-2) 57 % 56 %<br />

X 2 -test (sign.) 0.629<br />

Lack of very often (5) 29 % 26 %<br />

availability sometimes/ High wage very often (5) 6 % 8 %<br />

of poorly qualified often (3-4) 46 % 47 % demands sometimes/<br />

workers never/ often (3-4) 43 % 40 %<br />

rarely (1-2) 25 % 27 % never/<br />

X 2 -test (sign.) 0.899 rarely (1-2) 51 % 52 %<br />

X 2 -test (sign.) 0.754<br />

Lack of very often (5) 25 % 19 %<br />

availability of sometimes/ High level of very often (5) 7 % 7 %<br />

qualified workers often (3-4) 50 % 54 % absenteeism sometimes/<br />

never/rarely 26 % 27 % often (3-4) 27 % 21 %<br />

(1-2) never/rarely (1-2) 66 % 71 %<br />

X 2 -test (sign.) 0.579 X 2 -test (sign.) 0.649<br />

n = 114 n = 102<br />

Source: own calculation, company survey 2008<br />

panies rarely locate their more valuable functions<br />

in China, rather tending to do so in their<br />

native countries or in Hong Kong.<br />

Labour turnover as an indicator for numerical<br />

flexibility: The empirical data produced an average<br />

fluctuation rate of 36 % which roughly<br />

concurs with the values fo<strong>und</strong> in the relevant<br />

literature for China. Compared with reference<br />

values from Germany, this figure is very high.<br />

The German Federal Employment Agency<br />

(2010) quotes a figure of 15 % in 2009 for the<br />

manufacturing industry in Germany. This confirms<br />

that the labour market in the Pearl River<br />

Delta is indeed characterised by a high rate of<br />

turnover. Whether this is a result of the shortage<br />

of workers on the supply side and a high<br />

labour turnover rate due to differences in<br />

wages, or whether it is to do with the demand<br />

side because of a high degree of uncertainty regarding<br />

job security, cannot be answered at this<br />

stage, but will be addressed again later using<br />

the results of the regression analysis.<br />

The fluctuation rate in foreign companies is significantly<br />

higher than in Chinese companies<br />

(Tab. 2). This is also in line with the results of<br />

previous studies (PUN/SMITH 2007) and <strong>und</strong>erlines<br />

the reliability of the survey data. This discrepancy<br />

is primarily a result of the extremely<br />

high rate of fluctuation in Taiwanese companies<br />

(52 %) which display a significantly different<br />

result from other foreign companies. This constitutes<br />

a preliminary indication that foreign<br />

companies, and particularly Taiwanese companies,<br />

are obviously unable to compensate for<br />

the disadvantage in wage levels through additional<br />

social welfare benefits or qualification


Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 67<br />

measures: Chinese workers apparently react<br />

primarily to monetary incentives, while traditional<br />

forms of social welfare benefits, especially<br />

company residential homes, are no longer<br />

perceived as being attractive.<br />

The level of employee numbers also varies<br />

considerably and, seen over the course of the<br />

entire year, is situated within a corridor of variation<br />

which is, on average, 43 % of the average<br />

number of employees wide. A large proportion<br />

of production in the electronics industry is seasonal<br />

business, since a significant share of<br />

sales turnover in the industrial countries occurs<br />

during the Christmas period. There is no significant<br />

difference between Chinese and foreign<br />

firms in this regard. Larger companies<br />

with more than 500 employees can absorb<br />

these fluctuations better; their volatility, at<br />

34 %, is significantly smaller than for companies<br />

with fewer than 100 employees, which arrive<br />

at a value of 54 %. The electronics companies<br />

in the Pearl River Delta generally have<br />

the ability to adapt very quickly to fluctuations<br />

in demand. For a 10 % increase in the number<br />

of employees, they require an average of only<br />

23 days.<br />

A further indicator for workplace quality and<br />

flexibility is provided by the frequency with<br />

which companies report having problems with<br />

the workforce (Tab. 2). The most common<br />

problem mentioned was the shortage of poorly<br />

qualified workers, which was more frequently<br />

spoken about than the problem of acquiring<br />

qualified workers. This confirms the shortage<br />

of all labour resources in the region. Chinese<br />

companies are slightly more frequently confronted<br />

with these two problems, but the difference<br />

is not significant. The third most frequent<br />

problem mentioned by companies was<br />

job change following participation in a further<br />

education programme. This <strong>und</strong>erlines the considerable<br />

readiness to change one’s job based<br />

on wage discrepancies, especially when newly<br />

acquired qualifications open up possibilities to<br />

receive higher wages. The question of whether<br />

there is truly a positive statistical connection<br />

between qualification measures and fluctuation<br />

which ‘punishes’ those companies which invest<br />

in further education will be addressed at a<br />

subsequent point in the investigation.<br />

Employee perspective<br />

As the presented results demonstrate, the<br />

labour turnover discussed from the company<br />

perspective does not affect all employees in the<br />

same manner. First, the sample of 566 migrant<br />

workers surveyed must be described: 52 %<br />

originate from Henan, Hebei and Hunan, three<br />

inland provinces of China, where the minimum<br />

wage is approximately one-third lower than in<br />

Dongguan (CLB 2008). This considerable<br />

wage gap between the regions of origin and occupation<br />

illustrates the attractiveness of the<br />

Delta as a destination for vocational migrants.<br />

57 % of the migrant workers are female, and<br />

only 28 % are married, which is not surprising<br />

considering the low average age (23.8 years).<br />

These figures all roughly correspond to those<br />

fo<strong>und</strong> in other studies on migrant workers in<br />

Shenzhen (e.g. WANG/WU 2010). The qualification<br />

level of the workers surveyed is also<br />

similar to that fo<strong>und</strong> in the company survey;<br />

the majority (53 %) had completed an intermediate<br />

school education.<br />

A comparison of the two data catchment areas<br />

reveals the following differences: Older, male<br />

and married workers are significantly more frequently<br />

fo<strong>und</strong> in the inner city district than in<br />

the newly developed peri-urban area, as are<br />

those employed as salaried workers. The workers<br />

in the peri-urban industrial area, who are<br />

2.5 years younger on average, have more frequently<br />

held a larger number of jobs in the<br />

past, and their current employment relationship<br />

has existed for seven months fewer than that of<br />

those in the inner city industry district. The<br />

peri-urban industrial area thus tends to employ<br />

a younger and also more mobile worker generation<br />

than the inner city industry district 138.<br />

This result may indeed extend the discussion<br />

on the new generation of workers in terms of<br />

their preferred working location (PUN/LU 2010;<br />

YUE et al. 2010).<br />

Flexibility and company benefits: In approximately<br />

two-thirds of cases (66 %), there is a<br />

fixed written contract between employees and<br />

companies, although contracts are often concluded<br />

for a period of only one year (Fig. 1, linshi<br />

zhigong). Long-term employees only received<br />

a contract with the passing of the revised<br />

version of the employment contracts law<br />

(2008), even though they had mostly already<br />

worked for several years in the same company.<br />

47 % of the sample participants were aware of<br />

the new employment contracts law. Their opinion<br />

of it varied in roughly equal numbers between<br />

scepticism regarding the implementation<br />

at the company level and enthusiasm due to the


68 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Tab. 3: Selected employee characteristics<br />

Variables Characteristic Frequency Distribution across industrial χ 2 (sig.)<br />

features areas (%)<br />

Inner city Peri-urban<br />

Occupation* Industrial workers 367 50 50 0.110<br />

(n=444) Salaried employees 77 60 40<br />

Gender Male 243 66 34 0.001<br />

(n=565) Female 322 44 56<br />

Family status Married 160 63 37 0.060<br />

(n=564) Unmarried 404 50 50<br />

Age up to 18 81 42 58 0.001<br />

(n=555) 19 to 24 296 50 50<br />

25 to 29 81 54 46<br />

30 and older 97 72 27<br />

Education Max. intermediate 316 55 45 0.550<br />

(n=561) school qualification**<br />

Above intermediate<br />

school qualification 245 52 48<br />

* analogous to blue-/white collar workers;<br />

** analogous to the Chinese chu zhong, nine compulsory years of schooling<br />

Source: own calculation, employee survey 2008<br />

promise of the eagerly awaited regulation and<br />

strengthened social security. At any rate, the<br />

contracts seemed to provide no effective barrier<br />

concerning numerical flexibility at the time<br />

of the survey, i.e. the rapid entry to and exit<br />

from an employment relationship.<br />

The wage level was fo<strong>und</strong> to be lower than in<br />

the company survey; in both survey areas and<br />

occupational groups, it was reported to be<br />

aro<strong>und</strong> 1,140 Yuan. For this payment, however,<br />

the inner city employees work fewer hours<br />

than those in the peri-urban district (on average<br />

9.6 vs. 9.8 hours/day; with 4.7 vs. 4.0 free<br />

days/month). The conventional assumption,<br />

that a higher level of education and a higher<br />

age are honoured with higher wages was fo<strong>und</strong><br />

to be applicable to this sample as well. Furthermore,<br />

long-term employees earned significantly<br />

more than those employed for a short<br />

period (r = 0.54). A very small, but also significant<br />

correlation (r = 0.13) exists between the<br />

number of previous jobs and the entry wage<br />

level (margin of error of 0.01% in each case).<br />

The wages were reported to be paid punctually<br />

in 80 % of cases.<br />

The industrial conflicts and strikes covered in<br />

other studies (e.g. PUN/LU 2010; SMITH 2006)<br />

are not reflected in these data. However, the<br />

wages do vary depending on the company’s order<br />

situation. The level of monthly wages fluctuates<br />

between the minimum and maximum<br />

figure with an average difference of aro<strong>und</strong><br />

550 Yuan, i.e. approximately half of the average<br />

wage level. In only 18 of 566 cases is the<br />

wage level constant from the beginning. For<br />

65 % of workers, the average wage is above<br />

their starting wage level; 19 % actually earned<br />

more at the beginning of their employment relationship<br />

than their current monthly average.<br />

An explanation for this could be, that in times<br />

of high sales demand, workers are attracted by<br />

offering higher effective wages, which are then<br />

reduced in times of low demand to the level of<br />

the minimum wage. In this manner, company<br />

flexibility externalises market-related uncertainties<br />

by transferring them to workers. The<br />

determinants and fluctuations of the effective<br />

monthly wage will be revisited in the course of<br />

the discussion on reasons for job change.<br />

The spectrum of company benefits (Fig. 2) is<br />

mostly filled with accommodation and meal solutions,<br />

with transport and childcare being a rare<br />

occurrence. In more than 50 % of cases, health


Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 69<br />

Fig. 2: Company benefits<br />

Insurance<br />

Meals<br />

Further education<br />

n = 566<br />

Accomodation<br />

Ventilation<br />

During overtime<br />

Breakfast<br />

Dinner<br />

Lunch<br />

Equipment<br />

Gloves<br />

Work clothing<br />

Protection masks<br />

Goggles<br />

Insurance<br />

Accident insurance<br />

Health insurance<br />

Unemployment insurance<br />

Pension<br />

Other social welfare benefits<br />

Technical training<br />

Vocational training<br />

Other qualifications<br />

Other<br />

Goods for day-to-day use<br />

Transport<br />

Childcare<br />

Other provisions<br />

Source: own calculation, employee survey 2008<br />

25<br />

23<br />

5<br />

23<br />

60<br />

103<br />

82<br />

12<br />

80<br />

106<br />

153<br />

150<br />

127<br />

16<br />

70<br />

242<br />

241<br />

239<br />

187<br />

176<br />

97<br />

246<br />

259<br />

316<br />

274<br />

and accident insurance is offered, and 35 % and<br />

40 % of cases involve offers of company-supported<br />

retirement schemes and unemployment<br />

insurance respectively – a figure which could<br />

conceivably have been much lower.<br />

Further education measures are in place in<br />

aro<strong>und</strong> 40 % of cases - a high figure considering<br />

the expectation that unqualified workers<br />

would generally receive no training. Moreover,<br />

training for industrial workers is similarly<br />

common to that for salaried employees. This<br />

49<br />

62<br />

49<br />

336<br />

80<br />

46<br />

73<br />

106<br />

46<br />

66<br />

348<br />

0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90% 100%<br />

97<br />

142<br />

253<br />

110<br />

263<br />

238<br />

free of charge must be paid for not available<br />

132<br />

276<br />

273<br />

286<br />

179<br />

247<br />

216<br />

251<br />

45<br />

228<br />

206<br />

176<br />

195<br />

190<br />

199<br />

98<br />

106<br />

includes all categories imaginable, from initial<br />

training to further education programmes,<br />

which must be more subtly differentiated for a<br />

more in-depth interpretation.<br />

79 % of those surveyed were living in residential<br />

homes provided by the company, with a<br />

similarly high proportion receiving meals from<br />

the company canteen. As was the case with<br />

wages though, both figures lie beneath those<br />

resulting from the company survey, but both<br />

reveal the same tendency. A dominant charac-<br />

70<br />

81<br />

62<br />

23<br />

28<br />

23<br />

18


70 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Fig. 3: Evaluation of workplace quality by employees<br />

Wage level<br />

Meals<br />

Accommodation*<br />

Reliability of payment<br />

Free time<br />

General satisfaction<br />

Relationship with superiors<br />

Industrial safety<br />

Relationship with colleagues<br />

n = 566<br />

58<br />

60<br />

86<br />

Source: own calculation, employee survey 2008<br />

130<br />

129<br />

137<br />

147<br />

196<br />

teristic of the Chinese manufacturing sector is<br />

the integration of living and working on the<br />

company site. It is disputable, however, to<br />

what extent accommodation and meals may<br />

truly be seen as social welfare benefits. Here,<br />

one must not only consider the above-mentioned<br />

function of these services as an instrument<br />

of control over the workforce, but also<br />

the fact that meals, work clothing and accommodation<br />

all quite frequently require payment<br />

on the part of workers, as well as goods for daily<br />

use, although salaried workers do pay meal<br />

costs themselves significantly more frequently<br />

(0.05) than industrial workers. Over and above<br />

the question of payment, company benefits also<br />

partly serve as a system of occupational<br />

control over workers, an aspect which is dealt<br />

with in detail in studies on the so-called dormitory<br />

labour system (cf. LEE 2005, 17; PUN/<br />

SMITH 2007).<br />

The facilities provided at the company site may<br />

also be counted among company benefits in the<br />

wider sense. An employee of a Japanese company<br />

spoke of table tennis tables, karaoke machines,<br />

free internet access and television.<br />

Courts with basketball hoops are very often to<br />

be fo<strong>und</strong>, although their use could only be documented<br />

in one case; the supposed sport field<br />

342<br />

380<br />

382<br />

386<br />

326<br />

288<br />

339<br />

316<br />

286<br />

161<br />

98<br />

104<br />

70<br />

81<br />

95<br />

66<br />

35<br />

52<br />

34<br />

0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100%<br />

satisfactory acceptable unsatisfactory<br />

seemed to be used more for the purposes of assemblies.<br />

This leisure programme, as is the<br />

case with other free benefits, can be interpreted<br />

as an incentive measure, although the former<br />

certainly seems to be aimed at the<br />

younger, more mobile generation of workers.<br />

The company benefits differ between the two<br />

data catchment areas in that meals and uniforms<br />

are more often free of charge for workers<br />

in the peri-urban industrial area than in the<br />

inner-city district, the former being significant<br />

(0.01). This possibly constitutes an attempt to<br />

compensate for the peri-urban location and the<br />

lack of alternative accommodation.<br />

Evaluation of workplace quality and priorities<br />

of employees: Workplace quality was investigated<br />

using nine of the categories fo<strong>und</strong> to be<br />

relevant in a preliminary study (Fig. 3). In the<br />

case of wage levels, the absolute proportion of<br />

unsatisfied workers is the highest, and is also<br />

proportionally greater than that of satisfied<br />

workers (18 % to 11 %). When one takes into<br />

account the wage fluctuations presented earlier,<br />

this is hardly surprising. Furthermore, the<br />

quality of meals was the second most common<br />

question to be answered with ‘unsatisfied’<br />

(19 % unsatisfied to 11 % satisfied). Considering<br />

the fact that many employees receive their


Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 71<br />

Fig. 4: Subjective priorities for selected aspects of the workplace<br />

Workplace cleanliness<br />

Harmonic working environment<br />

Opportunities for advancement<br />

Flexibility of job entry and exit<br />

Participation in decision-making processes<br />

n = 566<br />

Workplace safety<br />

Training possibilities<br />

Planning security<br />

Source: own calculation, employee survey 2008<br />

entire nutrition from the company canteen, it<br />

indeed seems plausible that low quality of<br />

meals could be a further important determinant<br />

for labour turnover, particularly in the case of<br />

physically exhausting work. This theory, however,<br />

would have to be qualified using a<br />

weighting of various problem areas by the employees.<br />

The employees surveyed appeared to be most<br />

frequently satisfied with the company climate<br />

among colleagues. Safety at the workplace – in<br />

contrast to blatantly negative media reports –<br />

took second place. The relationship to superiors<br />

was evaluated slightly more conservatively,<br />

but nevertheless very positively. The safety<br />

standards at the workplace were either very<br />

high, or the survey participants had experienced<br />

a comparatively poorer conditions previously.<br />

In the inner-city industrial district, respondents<br />

reported significantly more frequently being<br />

unsatisfied with wage levels (0.01) and accommodation<br />

(0.06) than in the peri-urban district.<br />

In the interpretation of these evaluations, one<br />

must take into account which characteristics of<br />

the workplace are indeed important (Fig. 4).<br />

The previously mentioned security aspect and<br />

cleanliness are of immense importance for<br />

workers. The third most important aspect is<br />

training possibilities, and the fifth is opportuni-<br />

461<br />

408<br />

388<br />

385<br />

318<br />

246<br />

243<br />

205<br />

179<br />

187<br />

239<br />

150<br />

103<br />

109<br />

118<br />

0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90%100%<br />

very important important not important no opinion<br />

ties for advancement, a sign that even – or perhaps<br />

especially – the unqualified industrial<br />

workers would at least ideally like to realise<br />

the ambition of a career. The participation in<br />

decision-making processes was most rarely reported<br />

to be very important, although a right to<br />

participate would possibly be considered to be<br />

more important now following the recent increase<br />

in public reporting. This all indicates in<br />

which areas an adaptable management could<br />

act to reduce a labour turnover rate which is<br />

clearly too high.<br />

Effects of workplace quality on labour<br />

turnover<br />

Determinants of the turnover rate at the company<br />

level<br />

The conceptional preliminary discussion revealed<br />

a connection between the flexibility of<br />

employment and company success. Positive effects<br />

of this flexibility are particularly due to<br />

the ability to adapt to fluctuations in the market.<br />

Negative effects arise from the loss of<br />

knowledge and abilities through frequent job<br />

changes. It is thus worthwhile to conduct an<br />

analysis of the indicator of this turnover rate<br />

and its explanation in a multiple regression<br />

model with regard to workplace quality and<br />

flexibilisation. Workplace quality and flexibilisation<br />

are operationalised using the indicators<br />

63


72 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Tab. 4: Descriptive statistics for the variables of the regression model<br />

n Min Max Mean Standard Explanation<br />

deviation<br />

Dependent variable<br />

Turnover rate 200 0 100 36.08 31.74 Employees leaving the company as a<br />

percentage of the total number of<br />

employees<br />

ln (Turnover rate) 200 0 4,61 3.06 1.20 Natural logarithm of the turnover rate<br />

Workforce-related<br />

variables<br />

Monthly wage 216 600 3,000 1,270 423.39 in Yuan<br />

Number of social<br />

welfare benefits 222 1 5 3.71 1.12 Number<br />

Training for new<br />

employees 222 1 5 4.05 1.05 Intensity of formal and informal<br />

education<br />

Further education 222 0 5 2.53 1.43 Intensity of internal and external<br />

further education<br />

Problems with employees 221 1 5 2.86 0.94 Average frequency of six problems<br />

Employees with tertiary<br />

education 212 0 100 32.26 30.65 as a percentage of the total number of<br />

employees<br />

Flexibility-related variables<br />

10 % increase in the<br />

number of employees 209 1 100 22.80 21.96 Duration in days<br />

Fluctuation of the<br />

number of employees 195 0 100 42.96 27.33 Spread of the number of employees<br />

as a percentage of the average<br />

number of employees<br />

Turnover percentage of<br />

industrial countries 211 0 100 27.76 37.93 as a percentage of total turnover<br />

Number of employees 213 1 3 1.91 0.78 1:-1-99, 2: 100-499, 3: 500 and<br />

above<br />

Source: own calculation, company survey 2008<br />

introduced above. An overview of the variables<br />

of the model can be fo<strong>und</strong> in Tab. 4.<br />

For several dimensions, average values were<br />

created from various component indicators: In<br />

the group of independent variables, one can<br />

thus find the number of social welfare benefits<br />

offered, an education index for formal education<br />

(double weighting) and training of new<br />

employees (simple weighting), a further education<br />

index for internal (simple) and external<br />

(double) further education programmes offered<br />

and a problem index (average value) of the frequency<br />

of the six problems with workers.<br />

In addition to the indicators of flexibilisation<br />

already mentioned, the importance of industrial<br />

countries as a key market (as a percentage of<br />

total sales turnover) and the number of employees<br />

are included in the model. The natural<br />

logarithm of the labour turnover rate is used as<br />

a dependent variable, since exponential rather<br />

than linear relationships were fo<strong>und</strong> between<br />

many variables during the data exploration. An<br />

investigation of the correlation coefficients between<br />

the independent variables showed that<br />

these are generally uncorrelated with each other.<br />

Only two coefficients are above 0.3. The<br />

highest coefficient of 0.352 is attained by the<br />

training and further education indices.<br />

For the explanation of the turnover rate, three<br />

multiple regression models were calculated in<br />

which a differentiation was made between<br />

labour resource-related and flexibility-related<br />

variables. The intention here is to pursue the


Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 73<br />

Tab. 5: Determinants of the labour turnover rate using a multiple regression model<br />

Independent variables All variables Workforce-related Flexibility-related<br />

variables variables<br />

stand. stand stand<br />

beta sign. beta sign. beta sign.<br />

Monthly wage -0.135 0.073* -0.136 0.060*<br />

Number of social welfare<br />

benefits 0.112 0.121 0.106 0.128<br />

Training for new employees 0.148 0.049** 0.150 0.042**<br />

Further education -0.030 0.699 -0.033 0.648<br />

Problems with workers 0.175 0.015*** 0.197 0.004***<br />

Employees with tertiary<br />

education -0.226 0.005*** -0.238 0.001***<br />

10 % increase in the<br />

number of employees 0.114 0.107 0.188 0.010**<br />

Fluctuation of the number<br />

of employees 0.158 0.029** 0.158 0.036**<br />

Turnover share of industrial<br />

countries 0.234 0.001*** 0.269 0.000***<br />

Number of employees -0.116 0.140 -0.014 0.858<br />

(constant) 0.000*** 0.000*** 0.000***<br />

Dependent variable ln (Turnover rate) ln (Turnover rate) ln (Turnover rate)<br />

R² 0.300 0.179 0.138<br />

corrected R² 0.254 0.152 0.118<br />

F-Test (sign.) 0.000 0.000 0.000<br />

Number of observations 164 192 171<br />

Significance levels: *** p < 1%, ** p < 5%, * p < 10%<br />

Source: own calculation, company survey 2008<br />

question arising from the conceptual section of<br />

whether labour turnover is caused more by a<br />

surplus of demand for workers and job change<br />

stemming from this, or whether it is more a result<br />

of flexible production methods and the<br />

short-term employment relationships connected<br />

to this. The summarised results of the regression<br />

analysis (Tab. 5) show that the labour<br />

resource-related variables possess a slightly<br />

higher explanation power than those related to<br />

flexibility. Altogether, however, the results<br />

point to the fact that both factors exert an influence<br />

on labour turnover, as indeed was expected.<br />

The explanation power of the complete<br />

model is, at 25.4 %, acceptable for survey data.<br />

The following individual results are particularly<br />

noteworthy against the backgro<strong>und</strong> of the<br />

current situation in the Pearl River Delta.<br />

Among the labour resource-related variables, a<br />

higher average monthly wage reduces labour<br />

turnover, as is to be expected. More surprising<br />

is the fact that employees with a tertiary education<br />

(university or polytechnic) change jobs<br />

less frequently than poorly qualified workers.<br />

Generally, one could have assumed that more<br />

highly qualified workers have a wider range of<br />

employment options. But because of the general<br />

shortage of workers, it seems to be actually<br />

poorly qualified workers in the Pearl River<br />

Delta who react to minimal differences in<br />

wages by changing jobs.


74 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

The most interesting results are those for training<br />

and further education as well as social welfare<br />

benefits. The more comprehensive a training<br />

or education programme offered to new<br />

employees is, the higher the labour turnover<br />

rate. Workers obviously exploit the additional<br />

qualification gained to receive higher wages at<br />

other companies. Further education does not<br />

reduce fluctuation either, indeed having no significant<br />

influence. Social welfare benefits also<br />

prove not to be a substitute for higher wages.<br />

Their influence on labour turnover is positive,<br />

but not significant. This result rather confirms<br />

that the total provision of services for employees<br />

based on the notion of control is indeed becoming<br />

less attractive for the younger generation<br />

of migrant workers.<br />

Among the flexibility-related variables, the<br />

marketing orientation of companies towards<br />

industrial countries possesses the greatest explanation<br />

power. The standardised beta coefficient<br />

is also higher than that of every individual<br />

workforce-related variable. The integration<br />

into global value chains thus seems to demand<br />

a particularly high degree of short-notice adaptation<br />

ability from electronics firms in the Pearl<br />

River Delta, which have a direct effect on<br />

labour turnover. Companies whose employee<br />

numbers fluctuate more strongly during the<br />

year because of seasonal influences naturally<br />

have a higher rate of labour turnover. Despite<br />

the significant differences in the turnover rate<br />

between Chinese and foreign firms (Tab. 2),<br />

these differences disappear in the regression<br />

model when other independent variables are<br />

used (Tab. 5). An additional model calculated<br />

with an owner dummy did not lead to an improvement<br />

of the explanation power or to a significant<br />

influence of the dummy.<br />

In summary, the results of the regression analysis<br />

lead to the conclusion that wage levels are<br />

the principal tool for companies when it comes<br />

to establishing a stable stock of workers. Social<br />

welfare benefits designed to exercise control<br />

over workers and qualification initiatives, on<br />

the other hand, lead to a higher rate of labour<br />

turnover, and are thus not worthwhile for the<br />

company that carries the costs for these measures.<br />

Since companies with more highly qualified<br />

workers are less vulnerable to high labour<br />

turnover rates, a freeloader pattern of behaviour,<br />

in which other companies or the state<br />

f<strong>und</strong> the qualification of workers, is probably<br />

the most successful strategy in the short term.<br />

In the case of one-sided orientation towards<br />

global markets, which have proven to be particularly<br />

susceptible to strong fluctuations in<br />

demand, a diversification into the Asian or local<br />

market seems to have a balancing effect.<br />

These preliminary explanation attempts will be<br />

elaborated upon in the continued course of the<br />

research project along with findings on the<br />

connection between jobs and job changes from<br />

the employee perspective.<br />

Workplace-related job change and mobile<br />

workers<br />

Job change and worker characteristics: The<br />

duration of employment and the number of<br />

previous jobs held are indicators for the mobility<br />

or ‘readiness to change’ of workers. 17 % of<br />

those sampled reported an employment period<br />

of up to two months. This figure must be<br />

viewed in connection with the date of the survey<br />

(22/23 March), which is shortly after the<br />

spring festival (7-10 February), since the<br />

spring festival is a time which often sees significant<br />

job changes. Altogether, 51 % of the<br />

workers had been working for the same company<br />

for a maximum of six months, while only<br />

8 % had been doing so for more than three<br />

years. It is noticeable that the average duration<br />

of employment was longer in the inner-city district<br />

than in the peri-urban district (18.9 vs.<br />

11.2 months) – a discrepancy which is intensified<br />

by the higher average age.<br />

At first glance, the number of jobs has a positive<br />

connection with age, as was expected<br />

(Tab. 6). Among the relatively young workforce<br />

– only 17 % are older than 29 years – the<br />

number of previous jobs held varies in a nonlinear<br />

fashion between the age groups: the 19-<br />

24 age group reported more frequently a larger<br />

number of previous jobs than the 25-29 age<br />

group. Although the average age in the innercity<br />

district is significantly higher, the workers<br />

there reported that they had a similar number<br />

of previous jobs (1.5 in the inner-city district<br />

vs. 1.6 in the peri-urban district). The mobility<br />

of the younger workers is thus generally<br />

greater. The group of more highly qualified<br />

workers was also fo<strong>und</strong> to have a larger number<br />

of previous jobs than those with a lower education<br />

level (Tab. 6), although one must take<br />

into account the fact that education reforms<br />

have led to a generally higher standard of education<br />

for younger workers, and that the shortage<br />

of workers has only been beneficial for<br />

worker mobility since 2004.


Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 75<br />

Tab. 6: Number of previous jobs, differentiated according to age and education level<br />

Previous jobs (%) absolute<br />

0 1 2 >3 numbers<br />

Age<br />

up to 18 71 17 11 1 76<br />

19-24 66 20 11 3 284<br />

25-29 51 30 13 5 76<br />

30 and older 68 20 7 5 93<br />

Total<br />

Education level*<br />

Maximum of an intermediate school<br />

65 21 10 4 529<br />

qualification<br />

Minimum of a secondary school<br />

68 19 10 3 300<br />

qualification 61 23 11 5 235<br />

Total 65 20 10 4 535<br />

*The differences between the two groups are weakly significant on the basis of the Chi²-Test (6 % margin of error).<br />

Source: own calculation, employee survey 2008<br />

With these results, however, one must take into<br />

account the job market-related conditions in<br />

the Pearl River Delta. An increased shortage of<br />

workers has emerged there since 2004. This has<br />

led to a situation in which younger workers<br />

have a wider range of jobs to choose from,<br />

which is a very desirable development from the<br />

point of view of employees. From the perspective<br />

of the companies affected, a high turnover<br />

rate must be considered problematic, particularly<br />

in the case of more highly qualified workers,<br />

since it creates a tendency for more knowledge<br />

to be lost and, in some cases, for greater financial<br />

investment in further education which eventually<br />

proves to be useless for the employer.<br />

Reasons for changing jobs: The company survey<br />

suggests a connection between labour<br />

turnover and wages as well as education level;<br />

secondary data also indicate a surplus of vacant<br />

jobs. In addition, the employee survey provides<br />

reasons for changing jobs on the part of the<br />

workers themselves (Tab. 7). These are related<br />

to workplace quality and flexible company organisation,<br />

but are also partly linked to the residency<br />

status of the workers.<br />

The most common reason for employees to<br />

change jobs was fo<strong>und</strong> to be fluctuation of effective<br />

monthly wages. The second most common<br />

reason was poor hygiene at the workplace<br />

(23 %), with the third being a return to one’s<br />

home region for the period of the Chinese New<br />

Year festival (18 %). This is not surprising for a<br />

number of reasons, but particularly because the<br />

number of vacation days was not contractually<br />

regulated in the private sector until the introduction<br />

of the employment contracts law. Each<br />

worker was entitled to only three days during<br />

the period of the New Year festival, which, in<br />

most cases, was not even enough to cover the<br />

travel time to the workers’ home regions. Most<br />

employees thus consider their employment relationship<br />

to be terminated automatically once<br />

the number of vacation days is exceeded. The<br />

official end of a contract or the acquisition of<br />

another job through friends or relatives were<br />

named less frequently as reasons for a change<br />

of jobs (7 % and 8 % respectively).<br />

The answer frequencies differ between the two<br />

investigation areas only in the point ‘ending of<br />

the contract’, which was named much more<br />

frequently in the inner-city district as a reason<br />

for changing jobs than in the peri-urban district<br />

(10 vs. 43 mentions). More highly qualified<br />

workers responded similarly to poorly qualified<br />

workers. As expected, employees in a<br />

salaried position most rarely named workplace<br />

hygiene (16 %) as the reason for their last job<br />

change. More interesting is the distinction between<br />

men, who much more frequently cited<br />

low wages and workplace hygiene (151 and 90<br />

mentions respectively), and women (128 and<br />

78 mentions). Women, however, much more<br />

frequently cited the journey home for the<br />

spring festival as a reason for the change in<br />

jobs (86 vs. 41 mentions). Of all the age-


76 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Tab. 7: Reasons for changing one’s previous job<br />

Job change due to … (multiple answers) Frequency Percentage Percentage of cases<br />

low wages 280 39 54<br />

poor workplace hygiene (noise, smell, 170 23 33<br />

light, temperature)<br />

end of the employment relationship because of trip<br />

home for the spring festival 127 18 25<br />

acquisition of a new job through friends or relatives 56 8 11<br />

end of the contract 53 7 10<br />

other reasons 40 5 8<br />

Total number of answers 726 100 141<br />

Source: own calculation, employee survey 2008<br />

groups surveyed, furthermore, those over the<br />

age of 30 most frequently gave low wages as a<br />

reason (45 %). This group is obviously the<br />

least ready to accept wage disadvantages; its<br />

members probably more frequently have to<br />

support a family with their income than<br />

younger, single workers.<br />

Conclusion and policy<br />

recommendations<br />

The presentation and contrasting of the empirical<br />

results prove that the electronics industry<br />

in the Pearl River Delta is indeed characterised<br />

by a high degree of labour turnover: It could be<br />

confirmed, firstly, that flexibility in the sense<br />

described by ATKINSON (1984) is a means of organising<br />

companies, which is particularly<br />

made use of by companies embedded in global<br />

value chains. Secondly, workplace-related<br />

characteristics of labour turnover, employee<br />

characteristics and personal reasons for job<br />

change were fo<strong>und</strong> to be important determinants.<br />

Altogether, the two influencing factors<br />

were fo<strong>und</strong> to be of similar importance.<br />

In the area of workplace quality, wage levels<br />

were fo<strong>und</strong> to be the central criterion for<br />

changing jobs. Due to low wages, which are,<br />

on average, well above the legal minimum<br />

wage, but subject to very severe fluctuations,<br />

workers in the lower-income sector react to<br />

even a small difference in wages by changing<br />

employers. The shortage of workers, which is<br />

identified as a central problem by companies,<br />

intensifies this situation. Company benefits do<br />

not offer any significant incentive to remain at<br />

a firm for longer periods of time either - here,<br />

accommodation and meals are most commonly<br />

provided, although meals in particular are very<br />

frequently deemed to be insufficient by employees.<br />

The qualification initiatives offered at the<br />

workplace in the form of training and further<br />

education, which are of importance with regard<br />

to labour turnover and for technological upgrading<br />

processes of companies, possibly also<br />

contribute to a further increase of labour<br />

turnover at the company level. Education level<br />

and low age increase the probability of job<br />

change at the individual level. This connection<br />

seems to be due mostly to the high degree of<br />

sensitivity of workers to wage differences and<br />

the size of the labour market coupled with the<br />

simultaneous shortage of workers. Since it is<br />

not worthwhile in such a situation for an individual<br />

company to provide qualification measures,<br />

an explanation must also be fo<strong>und</strong> here<br />

for the low frequency with which training and<br />

further education programmes are offered. The<br />

empirical investigation provided evidence to<br />

suggest that in the electronics industry of the<br />

Pearl River Delta, a qualification lock-in indeed<br />

exists in the area of labour-intensive and<br />

wage-sensitive production. Frequent job<br />

changes and few possibilities for further qualification<br />

strengthen each other reciprocally,<br />

since workers change employers both in seeking<br />

higher wages and because of the opportunity<br />

achieve this more effectively following the<br />

attaining of a qualification.<br />

In summary, three b<strong>und</strong>les of causes, all connected<br />

with one another, could be fo<strong>und</strong> for<br />

worker shortage and a high rate of labour<br />

turnover:


Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 77<br />

– company influences, shaped by a company<br />

organisation system aiming for numerical<br />

and financial flexibility and reacting to the<br />

necessities of being embedded in global value<br />

chains;<br />

– assessment of the workplace quality determined<br />

by individual characteristics of the<br />

workers (lower age groups, education level,<br />

gender) and their subjective priorities and<br />

evaluations (stage of life, promotion orientation,<br />

family support payments), and<br />

– regional influences shaped by the dynamic,<br />

globalised development of the Pearl River<br />

Delta and its socio-demographic transformation<br />

(internal migration led by migrant<br />

workers), which were not explicit subjects of<br />

this investigation, but are nevertheless important<br />

for the interpretation of the results.<br />

One of the decisive questions for the maintenance<br />

of competitiveness in the region through<br />

upgrading processes is that of how the high<br />

labour turnover rate can be generally reduced<br />

and more smoothly organised for both companies<br />

and workers, and how the significance and<br />

value of qualification can be increased at the<br />

same time. Several state-subsidised flagship<br />

companies have, without doubt, already been<br />

successful in producing considerable technological<br />

innovation (KROLL/SCHILLER 2010),<br />

without the large number of small and medium-sized<br />

companies being able to keep up with<br />

this development. One possibility to change<br />

this lies in the strengthened use of intermediates<br />

on the job market, which are beginning to<br />

appear in the form of a private sector-organised<br />

employment agency and temporary labour<br />

agency branch (XUE et al. 2010). During the<br />

preliminary selection of potential employees,<br />

the organisation of security collateral and the<br />

provision of social welfare benefits, these<br />

agencies could make a mediation contribution<br />

and could also take on responsibilities in the<br />

area of qualification. Over and above this, a<br />

progressing regulation of work at all education<br />

levels would be profitable for both the employee<br />

as well as the employer side of the equation<br />

by increasing the continuity of employment relationships.<br />

This, however, would be a development<br />

which would tend to move away from<br />

the concept of a flexible firm, and which may<br />

not be possible for firms to implement due to<br />

the rapid adaptation required within the global<br />

value chain. Flexibility and upgrading, howev-<br />

er, are connected in an interdependent relationship.<br />

Only a strategic reorientation of companies<br />

towards long-term-focused business models<br />

will be able to lead to appropriately large<br />

investment being made in education and employee<br />

binding, with numerical flexibility no<br />

longer being used as the only option for adapting<br />

to global market fluctuations.<br />

In the case of education and qualification, due<br />

to its character as a public resource, state institutions<br />

are also obliged to a certain degree to<br />

provide or support appropriate programmes.<br />

Here, at the district level, this would be a starting<br />

point for cooperation between companies<br />

and education institutions in the form of regional<br />

qualification alliances. As part of a research<br />

project currently in progress, for example,<br />

a cooperation between ThyssenKrupp in<br />

Zhongshan and a local public further education<br />

institution is being investigated (interview<br />

10.4. 2010). Here, basic questions pertaining to<br />

the organisation of the Chinese education system<br />

are addressed which go beyond the scope<br />

of this paper. The attractiveness of the working<br />

and living environment (“soft location factors”)<br />

are also increasingly moving into the focus<br />

of the second generation of migrant workers,<br />

and particularly of more highly qualified<br />

workers.<br />

The empirical results of the research project<br />

form an image of the specific situation of the<br />

electronics industry in the Pearl River Delta at<br />

the time of the survey. Further research is necessary<br />

in several areas, especially concerning<br />

the importance and organisation of internal and<br />

external company further education, in the<br />

course of which the perspective of companies<br />

should be connected with that of employees.<br />

From the point of view of companies, a more<br />

exact investigation of the effects of labour<br />

turnover and qualification on upgrading<br />

processes and company success would be interesting.<br />

From the point of view of employees,<br />

a focus on more highly qualified workers in the<br />

core workforce would provide a valuable<br />

knowledge supplement. In addition, external<br />

providers of training and further education<br />

should be included as a target group in an investigation.<br />

Acknowledgement<br />

The authors would like to thank two anonymous reviewers<br />

for their helpful comments on an earlier version<br />

of this paper and Kerry Jago for the translation of the


78 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

original manuscript. The empirical research used in this<br />

paper was carried out within the Priority Programme<br />

(SPP) 1233 “Megacities – Megachallenge: The Informal<br />

Dynamics of Global Change” f<strong>und</strong>ed by the German<br />

Research Fo<strong>und</strong>ation (DFG), whose support is<br />

thankfully acknowledged.<br />

References<br />

ALBRECHT, S. (2002). Regionale Arbeitsmärkte <strong>und</strong> Flexibilisierungsprozesse.<br />

Geographische Zeitschrift,<br />

(90)3-4, 180-193.<br />

ALBRECHT, S. (2005). Flexibilisierung der Arbeit: Prozesse<br />

<strong>und</strong> Strategien aus geographischer Sicht. Koblenz.<br />

(Koblenzer Geographisches Kolloquium, 27).<br />

ATKINSON, J. (1984): Manpower strategies for flexible<br />

organizations. In: Personnel management, 16, 28-31.<br />

BRANDT, O. (2009): Lokalisiertes Lernen oder funktionale<br />

Spezialisierung – wie nachhaltig gelingt die Integration<br />

von gering Qualifizierten in den regionalen Arbeitsmarkt?<br />

Antworten aus Niedersachsen. Hannover.<br />

(Diss.)<br />

CHAN, K.W. (2010a): A China paradox. Migrant labor<br />

shortage amidst rural labor supply ab<strong>und</strong>ance. In:<br />

Eurasian Geography and Economics, (51)4, 513-531.<br />

CHAN, K.W. (2010b): The global financial crisis and migrant<br />

workers in China. ‘There is no future as a labourer;<br />

returning to the village has no meaning’. In: International<br />

Journal of Urban and Regional Research, (34)3,<br />

659-678.<br />

CLB (China Labour Watch)(2008): Minimum monthly<br />

wage standards in selected provinces/ municipalities/cities<br />

in China. Internet: http://www. chinalaborwatch.org/2006<br />

Editorials/07-24-2006 Minimum Wage<br />

Chart.htm, 18.10. 2010.<br />

COHEN, W.M./LEVINTHAL, D. (1990): Absorptive capacity:<br />

a new perspective on learning and innovation. In:<br />

Administrative Science Quarterly. 35, 128-152.<br />

ENRIGHT, M./SCOTT, E./CHANG, K. (2005): Regional<br />

powerhouse. The Greater Pearl River Delta and the rise<br />

of China. Singapore.<br />

ERNST, D./NAUGHTON, B. (2008): China’s emerging industrial<br />

economy. Insights from the IT industry. In: Mc-<br />

Nally, C. (Ed.): China’s emergent political economy.<br />

Capitalism in the dragon’s lair. Abingdon, 39-59.<br />

FAN, C. C. (2008): China on the move. Migration, the<br />

state, and the household. London. (Reprint: Routledge<br />

studies in human geography, 21).<br />

GDSTATS (Statistics Bureau of Guangdong Province)<br />

(2010): Guangzhou statistical yearbook 2010. Internet:<br />

http://www.gdstats. gov.cn/tjnj/ml_e.htm, 20.2. 2011.<br />

GEFFKEN, R./MA, D./HSIE, S.-M. (2010): Das chinesische<br />

Arbeitsvertragsgesetz. Hamburg.<br />

GERLACH, K./MEYER, W./TSERTSVADZE, G. (2002): Entwicklung<br />

der qualifikatorischen Segregation im Verarbeitenden<br />

Gewerbe. In: Bellmann, L./Kölling, A.<br />

(Hrsg.): Betrieblicher Wandel <strong>und</strong> Fachkräftebedarf.<br />

Nürnberg, 51-84.<br />

German Federal Employment Agency (B<strong>und</strong>esagentur<br />

<strong>für</strong> Arbeit) (2010): Arbeitsmarkt 2009. Nürnberg. (Amtliche<br />

Nachrichten der B<strong>und</strong>esagentur <strong>für</strong> Arbeit 58,2).<br />

HE, G. (2006): The shortage of peasant workers in the<br />

Pearl River Delta Region. An Explanation based on Todaro<br />

migration model. In: Asian Social Science, (2)12,<br />

41-52.<br />

HEBEL, J./SCHUCHER, G. (2006): Flexibility and security<br />

in China’s emerging ‘Socialist’ market labour regime.<br />

In: Baur, M. / Gransow, B. / Jin, Y. / Shi, G. (Eds.): Labour<br />

mobility in urban China. An integrated labour market<br />

in the making? Berlin, 19-49. (Berliner China-Studien,<br />

46)<br />

HKTDC (Hong Kong Trade Development Council)(2010):<br />

Mounting price pressure on China exports.<br />

Research Report. Hong Kong.<br />

HÜRTGEN, S./ LÜTHJE, B./SCHUMM, W./SPROLL, M.<br />

(2009): Von Silicon Valley nach Shenzhen. Globale Produktion<br />

<strong>und</strong> Arbeit in der IT-Industrie. Hamburg.<br />

JIANG, B./BAKER, R./FRAZIER, G.V. (2009): An analysis<br />

of job dissatisfaction and turnover to reduce global supply<br />

chain risk. Evidence from China. In: Journal of Operations<br />

Management, 27, 169-184.<br />

KILIAN, P./BEISSWENGER, S./XUE, D. (2010): Floating or<br />

settling down? Migrant workers and mega-urban development<br />

in the Pearl River Delta, China. In: Geographische<br />

R<strong>und</strong>schau - International Edition, (6)2, 50-56.<br />

KIM, L. (1997): Imitation to Innovation. Dynamics of<br />

Korea’s technological learning. Boston, MA.<br />

KNIGHT, J.B./DENG, Q./LI, S. (2011). The puzzle of migrant<br />

labour shortage and rural labour surplus in China.<br />

In: China Economic Review (forthcoming).<br />

KROLL, H./SCHILLER, D. (2010): Establishing an interface<br />

between public sector applied research and the Chinese<br />

enterprise sector: Preparing for 2020. In: Technovation,<br />

(30)2, 117-129.<br />

LEE, C.K. (2005): Livelihood struggles and market reform.<br />

(Un)making Chinese labour after state socialism.<br />

Geneva. (ILO Occasional Paper).<br />

LEWIS, W.A. (1954): Economic development with unlimited<br />

supplies of labour. In: The Manchester School,<br />

(22)2, 139-191.<br />

LÜTHJE, B. (2008): Arbeitspolitik in der chinesischen<br />

IT-Industrie. Neue Perspektiven in der Diskussion um<br />

internationale Arbeitsstandards. Frankfurt am Main.<br />

(<strong>Institut</strong> <strong>für</strong> Sozialforschung: Studie im Auftrag der<br />

Hans-Böckler-Stiftung).<br />

MEYER, S./SCHILLER, D./REVILLA DIEZ, J. (2009): The<br />

Janus-faced economy. Hong Kong firms as intermediaries<br />

between global customers and local producers in<br />

the electronics Industry. In: Tijdschrift voor Economische<br />

en Sociale Geografie, (100)2, 224-235.<br />

MEYER, S./SCHILLER, D./REVILLA DIEZ, J. (2012): The<br />

localization of electronics manufacturing in the Greater<br />

Pearl River Delta, China. Do global implants put down<br />

local roots? In: Applied Geography, 32, 119-129.<br />

PUN, N. (2005): Made in China. Subject, power and resistance<br />

among women workers in a global workplace.<br />

Durham.<br />

PUN, N./SMITH, C.J. (2007): Putting transnational labour<br />

process in its place. The dormitory labour regime in<br />

post-socialist China. In: Work Employment Society,<br />

(21)1, 27-45.


Pamela Hartmann Kilian / Daniel Schiller / Frauke Kraas: Workplace quality 79<br />

PUN, N./ LU, H. (2010): Unfinished proletarianization.<br />

Self, anger, and class action among the second generation<br />

of peasant-workers in present-day China. In: Modern<br />

China, (36)5, 493-519.<br />

REILLY, P.A. (1998): Balancing flexibility. Meeting the<br />

interests of employer and employee. In: European Journal<br />

of Work and organizational Psychology, (7)1, 7-22.<br />

STAIGER, B. (Hrsg.)(2008): Das große China-Lexikon.<br />

Geschichte, Geographie, Gesellschaft, Politik, Wirtschaft,<br />

Bildung, Wissenschaft, Kultur. Darmstadt.<br />

SCHILLER, D. (2011): The role of foreign and domestic<br />

firms in regional innovation systems of latecomer countries.<br />

Empirical evidence from the electronics industry<br />

in the Pearl River Delta. Erdk<strong>und</strong>e, (65)1, 25-42.<br />

SHEN, J. (2007): Labour disputes and their resolution in<br />

China. Oxford.<br />

SMITH, T. (Hg.) (2006): Challenging the chip. Labor<br />

rights and environmental justice in the global electronics<br />

industry. Philadelphia.<br />

STURGEON, T. (2002): Modular production networks. A<br />

new American model of industrial organization. In: Industrial<br />

and Corporate Change, (11)3, 451-496.<br />

The Economist (2010): The next China. As the supply of<br />

migrant labour dwindles, the workshop of the world is<br />

embarking on a migration of its own. In: The Economist,<br />

29.7. 2010. Internet: http://www.economist.com/<br />

node/16693397, 12.9. 2010).<br />

TSERTSVADZE, G. (2005): Qualifikatorische Segregation.<br />

Entwicklung <strong>und</strong> Bestimmungsgründe. Eine theoretische<br />

<strong>und</strong> empirische Analyse. Aachen.<br />

VALVERDE, M./TREGAKIS, O. (2000): Labor flexibility<br />

and firm performance. In: International Advances in<br />

Economic Research, (6)4, 649-661.<br />

WANG, M.Y./WU, J. (2010): Migrant workers in the urban<br />

labour market of Shenzhen, China. In: Environment<br />

and Planning A 42. (forthcoming).<br />

WHITELEY, A./CHEUNG, S./QUAN, Z.S. (2000): Human<br />

resource strategies in China. Singapore.<br />

XUE, D./LIN, T./KRAAS, F./KILIAN, P. (2010): Informal<br />

job-seeking agencies and their role in the ‘World Factory’<br />

of the Pearl River Delta. A case study in Tangxia<br />

Township, Dongguan City, Guangdong Province. In:<br />

Geographical Research, (29)10, 1793-1801. (Chinese<br />

with an English summary).<br />

YANG, D.L. (2005): China’s looming labor shortage. In:<br />

Far Eastern Economic Review, (168)2, 19-24.<br />

YUE, Z./LI, S./FELDMAN, M.W./DU, H. (2010). Floating<br />

choices. A generational perspective on intentions of rural<br />

urban migrants in China. In: Environment and Planning,A42,<br />

545-562.<br />

YU, H./HUANG, Y. (2009): Impact of the global economic<br />

crisis on the Pearl River Delta and the Yangtze<br />

River Delta. Singapore. (East Asian <strong>Institut</strong>e Backgro<strong>und</strong><br />

Brief No. 477, National University of Singapore).<br />

YU, H./ZHANG, Y. (2009): New initiatives for industrial<br />

upgrading in the Pearl River Delta. Singapore. (East<br />

Asian <strong>Institut</strong>e Backgro<strong>und</strong> Brief No. 464, National<br />

University of Singapore).


Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> Jg. 56 (2012) Heft 1-2, S. 80-96<br />

Wenying Fu, Guangzhou (China)/ Daniel Schiller/ Javier Revilla Diez, Hannover<br />

Strategies of using social proximity and organizational proximity<br />

in product innovation<br />

Empirical insight from the Pearl River Delta, China<br />

Abstract: In this paper we investigate how the innovation behavior of firms to capitalize on social<br />

proximity with independent firms and organizational proximity with parent companies and<br />

foreign customers contributes to innovation in the Pearl River Delta (PRD), China. While traditional<br />

views often hold that Chinese firms rely heavily on organizational proximity with parent<br />

companies and foreign customers to gain access to knowledge, we aim for insights into whether<br />

localized learning mechanisms based on informal social relations have emerged in the region after<br />

more than thirty years of industrialization. Based on a questionnaire survey of 359 innovative<br />

electronics firms, this paper demonstrates that firms which use social proximity to foster innovation<br />

are emerging in the PRD, and that it is mainly applied by domestic firms as a ‘spying device’<br />

to catch up with the latest technology and market preference in order to trigger new product ideas.<br />

Nevertheless, the achievements of product innovation performance made by applying social proximity<br />

in interactive learning are fairly small, which <strong>und</strong>erpins the instability of the trust-based interactive<br />

learning between firms in the region. The results of the paper provide insight into the development<br />

stage of the regional innovation system in the Pearl River Delta, calling upon an effective<br />

governance infrastructure to be put in place to stabilize interactive learning on the local<br />

scale.<br />

Keywords: social proximity, organizational proximity, guanxi, product innovation<br />

Introduction<br />

Since the opening policy was introduced in<br />

1978, China has seized the opportunity of the<br />

global industrial shift, and some areas along<br />

the eastern coast have experienced dramatic<br />

economic growth. The Pearl River Delta,<br />

which is located on the south-east coast of the<br />

Guangdong province, has developed into one<br />

of the biggest production sites for computers<br />

and electronics due to its advantage of low-cost<br />

and flexible production. The electronics industry<br />

in this region is very export-oriented. The<br />

region manufactures over 50 % of the world’s<br />

desktop computers and 40 % of PC components,<br />

such as PC heads, PC cases and other<br />

semi-manufactured products (see http://www.<br />

gdiid. gd. gov.cn/gdiid /billion /lay2-3.htm).<br />

Moreover, many domestic brands in the Pearl<br />

River Delta have rapidly developed and taken<br />

a considerable share of the global market. The<br />

literature on the regional industrial develop-<br />

ment in latecomer countries such as China emphasizes<br />

the role of multinational enterprises<br />

and the global production network, which they<br />

have organized in the regions (DICKEN, 1976;<br />

DOLLAR, 2005; MORRISON et al., 2008; YEUNG,<br />

2009). In the initial industrializing process<br />

which took place in the Pearl River Delta, it is<br />

indisputable that technology transfer and learning<br />

relied heavily on global lead firms. The low<br />

absorptive capacity of the young local firms in<br />

the Pearl River Delta led to the limited size and<br />

variety of knowledge and expertise on the local<br />

scale, which, as a whole, hindered the interactive<br />

learning among the firms and hence the<br />

opportunities to benefit from each other’s ideas<br />

and skills. Due to the limited expertise and<br />

know-how in the initial industrialization phase,<br />

firms had no opportunity to implement active<br />

innovation and upgrading strategies. Moreover,<br />

the ab<strong>und</strong>ance of cheap land and labor<br />

left no incentives to initiate risky innovation<br />

activities. However, the high-speed growth,


Wenying Fu / Daniel Schiller / Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity 81<br />

driven by foreign direct investment (FDI), has<br />

gradually exhausted the cheap land and labor<br />

in the Pearl River Delta, and has been greatly<br />

constrained by both internal and external factors<br />

in recent years. On the one hand, the high<br />

inflation rate, which leads to the continual<br />

pressure of rising costs, is gradually eroding<br />

the competitive edge in low-cost production.<br />

On the other hand, the export firms are faced<br />

with more trade obstacles in the developed<br />

market due to the protection of the local employment<br />

market after the financial crisis.<br />

Firms either have to meet the high standards of<br />

safety and quality in order to maintain the market<br />

share in developed countries, or they have<br />

to exploit the new market opportunities in the<br />

domestic economy. Against this backgro<strong>und</strong>,<br />

innovation and upgrading are high on the agenda<br />

of both firms and the government. Furthermore,<br />

conditions for interactive learning and<br />

systemic innovation have developed, with the<br />

electronics firms in the Pearl River Delta having<br />

accumulated a certain amount of knowledge<br />

after thirty years of processing operations<br />

and having diversified into numerous product<br />

niches in the electronics industry. It is therefore<br />

important, at this point, to investigate whether<br />

firms are capable of exploiting and commercializing<br />

the knowledge stock through reciprocal<br />

interactive learning. The raising of this<br />

question corresponds to the literature on regional<br />

competitiveness which emerged in the<br />

1990s arguing that the enduring competitiveness<br />

of regions lies in the socialized embedded<br />

process of knowledge production, exploitation<br />

and dissemination.<br />

In the following it is attempted to approach this<br />

question using the concept of proximity. As<br />

MASSARD/MEHIER (2009) suggest, it provides a<br />

conceptually more so<strong>und</strong> measurement of accessibility<br />

than the concept of the externality<br />

of simply being there. Other than physical distance,<br />

relational space based on rules, contracts<br />

and informal social interaction has been taken<br />

into comprehensive consideration. By assessing<br />

the strategies and capability of firms to<br />

capitalize on social proximity via informal<br />

guanxi-networks to foster innovation, rather<br />

than on organizational proximity with parent<br />

companies or foreign customers, insights into<br />

the evolving production system in the Pearl<br />

River Delta from a platform driven by foreign<br />

direct investments to a regional innovation system<br />

are expected during the course of this investigation.<br />

The use of social relations is a strategic move<br />

by firms to achieve trust and <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />

among independent business partners. ZHOU et<br />

al. (2003) demonstrate that firms in the Pearl<br />

River Delta have to maintain intensive interpersonal<br />

interaction with customers due to the<br />

unreliable institutional system. Moreover, informal<br />

and continual interaction among various<br />

economic players, embedded in guanxinetworks,<br />

is an important method of doing<br />

business in Chinese society (LOVETT et al.<br />

1999). Rather than simply applying informal<br />

practice in flexible production to save transaction<br />

costs and thus react quickly to market<br />

needs (NORTH 1990; MEYER et al. 2009), the<br />

capacity to capitalize further on informal social<br />

relations in order to generate and foster innovation<br />

outcome is critical for the emergence of<br />

a regional innovation system in the Pearl River<br />

Delta. However, this localized learning process<br />

based on social assets does not take place automatically<br />

and is <strong>und</strong>er constant pressure of<br />

destruction. Information sharing can be reduced<br />

or biased, as each seeks to gain the most<br />

at the other’s expense, especially for uncertain<br />

and risky innovation activities (CHESBROUGH/<br />

TEECE 1996). The formation and stabilization<br />

of interactive learning in the business sector<br />

depends on market conditions and should be<br />

strengthened by public initiatives and supporting<br />

infrastructure (HEIDENREICH 2004). By<br />

identifying strategic firm behavior of using<br />

proximities to foster innovation, we want to<br />

contribute to the <strong>und</strong>erstanding of the innovation<br />

activities in the Chinese context and shed<br />

light on the direction of policy initiatives to<br />

strengthen the interactive learning activities in<br />

the business sector of the electronics industry<br />

in the Pearl River Delta.<br />

It should be noted that this paper does not intend<br />

to explore exclusively the role of the five proximities,<br />

i.e. geographical proximity, cognitive<br />

proximity, organizational proximity, social proximity<br />

and institutional proximity, as defined by<br />

BOSCHMA (2005). Instead, it focuses on organizational<br />

and social proximity, which are deemed<br />

to be most relevant to the previous discussion of<br />

regional development in the context of latecomer<br />

countries. Moreover, these two forms of proximity<br />

may be addressed by conscious firm<br />

strategies and can thus be achieved through the<br />

efforts of individual firms. In addition, the effect<br />

of geographical and cognitive proximity is controlled<br />

to a certain degree by placing the focus of<br />

the empirical investigation on firms belonging


82 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

to the same electronics sector and co-locating in<br />

the same mega-urban region in China.<br />

Organizational and social proximity in<br />

innovation – the Chinese context<br />

The concept of proximity developed in the<br />

1990s by the French School contributes to the<br />

<strong>und</strong>erstanding of the mechanisms behind the<br />

interactive process of knowledge transfer (KI-<br />

RAT/LUNG 1999; TORRE/GILLY 2000; TORRE/<br />

RALLETT 2005; BOSCHMA 2005; MENZEL<br />

2008). Proximity is a concept that is usually<br />

discussed with innovation, since it plays an<br />

important role in promoting the trust and <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />

when <strong>und</strong>ertaking complex and<br />

highly risky innovation activities. Proximity<br />

carries a plural sense. It goes beyond geographical<br />

proximity, which has a limited role<br />

without the support of other proximities. With<br />

respect to firm strategies in the Chinese context,<br />

firms can, on the one hand, rely on organizationally<br />

proximate partners, such as parent<br />

companies and foreign customers, to gain information,<br />

ideas and supported knowledge<br />

which transcend the limits of geographical<br />

proximity. On the other hand, firms can also<br />

establish trust-based social networks with geographically<br />

proximate independent business<br />

partners, such as domestic customers, univer-<br />

Fig. 1: Knowledge transfer across firm<br />

bo<strong>und</strong>aries<br />

Source: own draft<br />

sities, research institutes and market agencies,<br />

seeking information and knowledge within social<br />

proximity. How information and knowledge<br />

are transferred across firm bo<strong>und</strong>aries to<br />

support the complex innovation process is<br />

shown in Fig. 1. The knowledge transfer organized<br />

within social and organizational proximity<br />

facilitates communication and strengthens<br />

cooperation owing to <strong>und</strong>erstanding and trust<br />

within the proximity bo<strong>und</strong>ary.<br />

Organizational proximity<br />

Organizational proximity refers to the sharing<br />

of reference space and knowledge that is<br />

strengthened by hierarchy and control within<br />

the same organization, such as firm, group and<br />

cooperation networks (BOSCHMA 2005). With<br />

the development of information, communication<br />

and transportation technology, simple colocation<br />

is no longer a necessary determinant<br />

for knowledge transfer. Networks, which even<br />

transcend the bo<strong>und</strong>ary of countries, begin to<br />

play a role as vehicles of knowledge diffusion.<br />

In the third wave of globalization in the 1980s,<br />

the bulk of foreign capital flowed to developing<br />

countries in the form of direct investment<br />

in manufacturing (DOLLAR 2005). Meanwhile,<br />

forms of network coordination involving a<br />

large number of participants have taken the<br />

place of integrated organizational bo<strong>und</strong>aries<br />

at transnational corporations, which ERNST<br />

(2005) specifically described as a “global flagship<br />

network”. This network links the flagship’s<br />

own subsidiaries, affiliates and joint<br />

ventures with its subcontractors, suppliers and<br />

service providers, as well as with partners in<br />

strategic alliances (ERNST 2005, 91).<br />

In order to reduce costs and stay flexible towards<br />

market demands, the flagship organizations,<br />

including the brand firms, contract manufacturers,<br />

first-tier suppliers and large trade<br />

companies, strengthen the core competencies<br />

and, at the same time, outsource volume manufacturing<br />

and other functions along the globally-organized,<br />

networked value chain (ERNST/<br />

KIM 2002). Three factors determine the methods,<br />

that these flagship organizations apply<br />

in order to govern the network (GEREFFI et al.<br />

2005): the complexity of transactions, the ability<br />

to codify knowledge and the capabilities of<br />

the supply base.<br />

New <strong>Institut</strong>ional Economics relates transaction<br />

cost to the institutional environment<br />

(NORTH 1990). When the rules are not guaran-


Wenying Fu / Daniel Schiller / Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity 83<br />

teed by formal institutions such as laws and<br />

regulations, organizational proximity appears<br />

as a reasonable governance mode to curb the<br />

opportunist behavior of business partners, such<br />

as distorting business information, failing to<br />

fulfill commitments or malicious imitation<br />

(HENNART 1993). As a result of incomplete institutional<br />

protection, most of the firms in the<br />

developing countries conduct innovation ‘inhouse’<br />

instead of licensing and assigning contractual<br />

arrangements to unaffiliated firms<br />

(SCHMITZ 1995; SCHMITZ/NADVI 1999). For the<br />

global flagship that organizes production in developing<br />

countries, organizational proximity is<br />

not only conducive to reducing opportunist risk<br />

related to physical and human capital investment,<br />

but also enables the efficient downward<br />

transfer of knowledge, especially the tacit<br />

knowledge owing to the path-dependent nature<br />

of firm routine development (NELSON/WINTER<br />

1982) towards the suppliers and subcontractors<br />

with <strong>und</strong>erdeveloped technological and managerial<br />

capabilities.<br />

Accordingly, organizational proximity provides<br />

two advantages for firms in latecomer<br />

countries. It provides them with access to<br />

knowledge, especially tacit knowledge in the<br />

advanced technological field. The flagship typically<br />

provides the organizationally proximate<br />

subsidiaries, suppliers and subcontractors with<br />

machinery, blueprints, production and quality<br />

control manuals, product and service specification<br />

and training handouts. YEUNG (2009)<br />

states the importance of external network<br />

building in acquiring capabilities in the Asian<br />

context and introduces a concept called “strategic<br />

coupling” to <strong>und</strong>erstand better the evolution<br />

of local and regional firms in their dynamic<br />

articulation in the global production network.<br />

MORRISON et al. (2008) also show that<br />

firms gain technological capabilities from participating<br />

in global value chains. Not only that,<br />

firms in latecomer countries also join the international<br />

production network in order to acquire<br />

tacit knowledge, which is necessary to absorb<br />

and exploit the encoded knowledge, by having<br />

the engineers and managers from foreign partners<br />

train on site. Furthermore, IVARSSON/<br />

ALVSTAM (2005) demonstrate that geographical<br />

proximity with foreign transnational corporations<br />

is crucial for local suppliers to absorb external<br />

technology through regular and ongoing<br />

interaction with their primary foreign customers.<br />

It is possible that the suppliers upgrade and coevolve<br />

with the buyer when the technological<br />

and organizational change enables a more sophisticated<br />

supply chain (YEUNG 2009). In<br />

2004, Lenovo bought the PC operation from<br />

IBM and upgraded from an original equipment<br />

manufacturer (OEM) to an own brand manufacturer<br />

(OBM). In 2004, TCL (Shenzhen) coestablished<br />

a mobile phone joint venture with<br />

Alcatel. In 2007, China Electronic Cooperation<br />

subsidiary Sungfei (Shenzhen) acquired<br />

the mobile phone operation from Phillips.<br />

These are examples of upgrading by enhancing<br />

internal absorptive capacity and strategically<br />

recognizing the coupling chances with global<br />

lead firms. However, organizational proximity<br />

alone has a limited role in upgrading and innovation.<br />

Firstly, many brand owners arrange the<br />

global strategic layout in such a way that<br />

strategic research and development (R&D),<br />

marketing and management are located in their<br />

home countries or in regions in developed<br />

countries where innovation partners and reliable<br />

institutions are available (FEINBERG/GUP-<br />

TA 2004), while functions such as production,<br />

sales and logistics are located in developing<br />

countries (PAN/CHI 1999). Although the internationalization<br />

of R&D activities has grown<br />

significantly since the 1990s (OECD 1998),<br />

technology and knowledge to which domestic<br />

firms have access is still limited and mostly<br />

low-end. Secondly, global buyers tend to promote<br />

incremental product and process upgrading<br />

and oppose upgrading if this creates opportunities<br />

for suppliers to acquire a broader range<br />

of customers (HUMPHREY 2004). Consequently,<br />

the global buyers and traders might be bypassed<br />

by suppliers if the latter gain the ability<br />

to work directly with brand companies in developed<br />

countries.<br />

In the electronics industry, there is a trend of<br />

applying fewer hierarchy relations in the global<br />

chain governance mode. Maturing technology<br />

such as module production that enables the<br />

codifying of knowledge is one of the factors<br />

behind this trend. Moreover, as long as local<br />

firms establish core competences that ensure<br />

the reciprocity of knowledge sharing, it is quite<br />

possible that they are able to capitalize on the<br />

use of social proximity to exploit knowledge<br />

and foster innovation. Social proximity can<br />

thereby be used as a complementary strategy in<br />

fostering innovation in order to overcome the<br />

shortcomings of organizational proximity.


84 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Social proximity<br />

Social proximity relates to trust and commitment<br />

based on kinship, friendship and cooperation<br />

experience (BOSCHMA 2005). It is secured<br />

through informal daily face-to-face interaction<br />

such as meeting, chatting, eating together and<br />

joint entertainment. Trust and commitment are<br />

gradually established in the social interaction<br />

process, which contributes to interactive learning<br />

and cooperation. Social networks are not<br />

spatially bo<strong>und</strong>, but can be sustained and produced<br />

by the ongoing collective interaction of<br />

players located close to each other (BOSCHMA<br />

2005).<br />

Social proximity does not only foster the communication<br />

of tacit knowledge which is difficult<br />

to trade in the market, but also reduces opportunist<br />

behavior through the establishment of<br />

durable relations. Social ties and relations<br />

thereby have an influence on economic outcomes<br />

(GRANOVETTER 1985). Guanxi, as an<br />

informal way of doing business in China, has<br />

received growing attention in the recent organizational<br />

literature (PARK/LUO 2001; RAMA-<br />

SAMY et al. 2006; ZHANG/ZHANG 2006). Similar<br />

to the concept of social proximity, guanxi<br />

refers to informal interpersonal relationships<br />

and exchanges of favors for the purpose of doing<br />

business in traditional Chinese society<br />

(LOVETT et al. 1999). PENG (2003) points out<br />

that the reciprocal and utilitarian types of<br />

guanxi are becoming more important than the<br />

obligatory type in times of institutional transition.<br />

In reciprocal guanxi between friends and<br />

colleagues in particular, the implicit rule of<br />

‘paying back favors’ (Chinese: renqing), due to<br />

the fear of damaging one’s social reputation<br />

and prestige, actually strengthens the constant<br />

social interaction through the idea of exchanging<br />

favors. In the Chinese business world today,<br />

guanxi plays an important role in facilitating<br />

economic exchanges and overcoming administrative<br />

costs in the face of a deficient<br />

institutional framework (PARK/LUO 2001),<br />

such as when starting the business, concluding<br />

contracts, acquiring institutional protection and<br />

responding flexibly to changing demands.<br />

However, its role in innovation has not yet<br />

been analyzed.<br />

The changing role of guanxi, i.e. the Chinese<br />

way of establishing and maintaining social<br />

proximity, in business performance has important<br />

implications for the dynamic regional<br />

competitiveness. The socially and territorially<br />

embedded, collectively interactive learning<br />

process is becoming a prominent feature of<br />

competitive industrial clusters even in a globalized<br />

era (MASKELL 1998; ASHEIM/ISAKSEN<br />

2002). The approach of regional innovation<br />

systems assumes that the localized assets and<br />

processes are the primary source of the innovation<br />

capabilities of the firms. (COOKE et al.<br />

1997; DOLOREUX/PARTO 2005). In a well-functioning<br />

regional innovation system, the local<br />

firms are capable of capitalizing on social<br />

proximity not only to facilitate effective<br />

knowledge transfer, but also to generate innovation<br />

outcomes. However, the prerequisite for<br />

this is that firms are willing and able to apply<br />

social proximity to foster innovation. If clustering<br />

firms all compete fiercely in identical<br />

standardized products, the regional knowledge<br />

base becomes low-level and homogeneous.<br />

Firms are often reluctant to share knowledge<br />

because the imitation cost is low and reciprocity<br />

of interaction is marginal. In this case, social<br />

proximity, such as that between customers<br />

and suppliers, can only be used as a way of sustaining<br />

a flexible and responsive production<br />

system. As a result, the role of social proximity<br />

in fostering innovation is limited, which<br />

leads to rather loose local innovation networks.<br />

When firms are willing to <strong>und</strong>ertake interactive<br />

learning and share knowledge with each other,<br />

guanxi helps in curbing the risk of opportunism<br />

related to innovation, which is specifically defined<br />

by STANDIFIRD/MARSHALL (2000) as the<br />

risks of asset specificity, behavioral uncertainty<br />

and environmental uncertainty. First of all,<br />

guanxi with managers of business partners may<br />

reduce the risk of asset specificity, which refers<br />

to the circumstance in which partners who do<br />

not own and invest specific assets switch suddenly<br />

to other partners in the process of innovation.<br />

Reciprocal guanxi with business partners<br />

is path-dependent to some extent, because<br />

people are less disposed to ruining the precious<br />

guanxi networks for quick profit. Long-term<br />

guanxi acts as a constraint for opportunism,<br />

and this brings mutual trust and assurance for<br />

cooperation. Secondly, guanxi networks with<br />

other partners can reduce the risk of behavioral<br />

uncertainty when sharing knowledge and ideas<br />

with cooperation partners. As an old Chinese<br />

saying goes, ‘you will never be defeated if you<br />

know everything about your opponent’. For<br />

example, if the cooperation partner in innovation<br />

activities wants to steal ideas to develop a<br />

new product ahead of you, and the contracts


Wenying Fu / Daniel Schiller / Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity 85<br />

and legal systems are not able to help or cost<br />

too much, it is safer to know ex ante about the<br />

backgro<strong>und</strong>, reputation and capacity of your<br />

cooperation partner through the guanxi network<br />

from other managers (as intermediaries)<br />

in the industry. Thirdly, guanxi with government<br />

officials can reduce the risk of environmental<br />

uncertainty, as innovation policies are<br />

always unsteady and vague in China. Managers<br />

and entrepreneurs cannot simply rely on government<br />

bulletins as their information channel.<br />

They actually rely more on guanxi when<br />

searching for and confirming information.<br />

They often obtain key information and a detailed<br />

explanation of the policies through<br />

guanxi. Information sorted through guanxi networks<br />

is more reliable and trustworthy, and<br />

thus allows for better informed decisions on investment<br />

in innovation.<br />

However, guanxi networks carry the risk of a<br />

negative lock-in effect. As guanxi networks depend<br />

on the constant exchange of favors, they<br />

are also fragile once the exchange stops. Firms<br />

are locked in with current business partners,<br />

fearing that the destruction of the subtle guanxi<br />

network with a single business partner would<br />

induce the loss of all other partners who are related<br />

to this partner. In this case, firms do not<br />

act as profit-maximizing entities, but rather as<br />

guanxi-satisfying ones. Outdated production<br />

modes and product types might persist and are<br />

harmful for upgrading and innovation (HSU/<br />

SAXENIAN 2000).<br />

Brief summary<br />

For Chinese firms, organizational proximity is<br />

of particular importance. In the early phase of<br />

development, the capability of local firms is<br />

not fully developed due to the weak industrial<br />

base, thus resulting in an ill-functioning<br />

knowledge spillover mechanism on the local<br />

scale. In this phase, hierarchy and control in<br />

the same organizational framework by the foreign<br />

parent company or OEM customer is essential<br />

for organizing production relations, and<br />

this becomes the primary source for local firms<br />

to gain codified and tacit knowledge, mostly in<br />

a passive way. However, organizational proximity<br />

in this phase is not able to trigger innovation<br />

with low-skill assembly operation<br />

aro<strong>und</strong> standardized products among the local<br />

firms.<br />

With the development of the local production<br />

system, local firms have accumulated a certain<br />

level of capability which enables them to absorb<br />

and exploit knowledge. In this case, firms<br />

can either use organizational proximity to seize<br />

the opportunities of value chain upgrading with<br />

the sophistication of the supply chain and technological<br />

diversification, or they can capitalize<br />

on social proximity to form reciprocal innovative<br />

synergy with organizationally distant partners<br />

that have diversified into specific product<br />

lines and market segments. Particularly for<br />

small and medium-sized firms, the collective<br />

learning facilitated by social proximity is essential<br />

for their survival and growth, and is also important<br />

for the development of a self-sustained<br />

local production system (CAPELLO 1999). The<br />

use of organizational and social proximity by<br />

firms is mutually reinforcing. On the one hand,<br />

the ability of local firms to use social proximity<br />

and transform it into innovative synergy and<br />

profit provides a greater incentive for foreign<br />

firms to transfer more advanced technology and<br />

activities to their organizationally proximate<br />

partners in developing countries. Moreover, this<br />

grants the local firms and governments more<br />

bargaining power to negotiate with foreign partners,<br />

which results in more stable manipulation<br />

of strategic coupling. On the other hand, new<br />

information on markets and technology that is<br />

pumped into the local system by firms using organizational<br />

proximity with geographically distant<br />

partners makes local collective learning<br />

more dynamic (BATHELT et al. 2004). This conceptual<br />

process concerning the dynamic interaction<br />

of organizational and social proximity is<br />

illustrated with Fig. 2.<br />

Fig. 2: Dynamism of proximity in regional<br />

development<br />

Source: own draft


86 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Based on the discussion on the role of organizational<br />

proximity and social proximity as a<br />

firm strategy to foster innovation, the following<br />

hypotheses are formulated:<br />

Hypothesis 1: By developing internal capacity<br />

and strategic coupling within the global production<br />

network, it is possible for firms in latecomer<br />

countries to capitalize on organizational<br />

proximity in order to foster innovation and<br />

upgrading. However, firms that rely only on a<br />

vertical hierarchy with global lead firms to<br />

foster innovation have limited potential for upgrading<br />

their position in the value chain.<br />

Hypothesis 2: Most Chinese firms are engaged<br />

in guanxi networks, which are an ongoing<br />

mode of interaction for maintaining social<br />

proximity between business partners. Firms<br />

with limited capabilities and short-term strategies<br />

are only able to capitalize on guanxi for<br />

low-cost and flexible production. On the other<br />

hand, in a mature regional innovation system,<br />

firms are capable of using social proximity to<br />

facilitate the complex interaction in the innovation<br />

process and to foster the innovation<br />

outcomes.<br />

Data and methodology<br />

The electronics industry in the Pearl River<br />

Delta, has been selected as the research area<br />

for this study. The empirical data used to answer<br />

the research question were taken from a<br />

standardized survey of electronics firms in the<br />

Pearl River Delta, Guangdong province, China.<br />

The industrial development in the Guangdong<br />

province is the outcome of a subtle mixture<br />

of global networks, public institutional<br />

framework and unexplored socio-cultural contexts<br />

(BELLANDI/TOMMASO 2005). In this<br />

study, survey data from the firm level are used<br />

to explore the strategies of firms to use social<br />

proximity - i.e. embedded in guanxi networks<br />

between independent business partners - as<br />

well as organizational proximity to global<br />

firms in fostering product innovation. In doing<br />

so, insights are expected to be gained with respect<br />

to the role of ‘global pipelines’ and ‘local<br />

buzz’ that contribute to the innovation dynamics<br />

in this region based on the previous<br />

discussion.<br />

The company survey targeted electronics<br />

firms in four cities in the eastern part of the<br />

Pearl River Delta, where the electronics industry<br />

is dominant (as in Shenzhen and Dongguan)<br />

or developing very quickly (as in<br />

Huizhou and Heyuan). In total, 422 electronics<br />

companies were interviewed during a threemonth<br />

period from September to November<br />

2009. Of the surveyed firms, 359 are <strong>und</strong>ertaking<br />

product innovation activities. These firms<br />

are the analytical basis of this article. Among<br />

these innovating firms, 62 % are domestic<br />

firms and 38 % are wholly foreign-owned<br />

firms or joint ventures. The company survey<br />

was conducted by telephone and post. Questionnaires<br />

were addressed to CEOs or senior<br />

executives of the companies. The telephone<br />

and post method was complemented by a telephone<br />

follow-up aimed at reducing the number<br />

of unanswered questions. The response rate<br />

was 53 %.<br />

Due to a certain amount of missing data, the<br />

sample number in the following analysis is<br />

slightly reduced. The issue of unanswered<br />

questions among the surveyed firms along with<br />

refusals led to the sample selection bias. Firms<br />

that were willing and able to answer the questionnaires<br />

completely usually had a higher level<br />

of human capital or a more formal organizational<br />

routine, which eases the <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />

and communication between firms and the universities<br />

conducting the survey. Moreover,<br />

these firms were more interested in the strategic<br />

plan we promised to provide after the survey,<br />

than the firms that refused or left too many<br />

questions unanswered, which reflects their upgrading-oriented<br />

strategy. In fact, this selection<br />

bias controls for the technological level of the<br />

surveyed firms, ensuring that the innovation<br />

activities they <strong>und</strong>ertake are not limited to lowvalue<br />

innovation and thus require more coordination<br />

and learning in the innovation process.<br />

In order to test the hypotheses, typical innovation<br />

behavior that makes use of the two proximities<br />

in the product innovation process was<br />

firstly identified based on the theoretical discussion<br />

(Tab.1). Firms were asked to rank the<br />

importance (on a scale of 1 to 5 with increasing<br />

importance) of interaction with business partners<br />

in different aspects with regard to acquiring<br />

new innovative ideas and obtaining codified<br />

and tacit knowledge. By means of factor<br />

analysis, two dimensions of proximity for the<br />

interaction with different players were identified.<br />

The results clearly show that the firms are<br />

not only acquiring codified knowledge and tac-


Wenying Fu / Daniel Schiller / Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity 87<br />

Tab. 1: Operationalization of analysis on proximity use in product innovation<br />

New product<br />

ideas (NPI)<br />

Obtaining<br />

codified<br />

knowledge<br />

(NPCK)<br />

Obtaining tacit<br />

knowledge<br />

(NPTK)<br />

Interaction<br />

mode<br />

(NPInteraction)<br />

Source: own survey<br />

Internal efforts<br />

From organizationally<br />

proximate partners<br />

From organizationally<br />

distant partners<br />

Internal efforts<br />

From organizationally<br />

proximate partners<br />

From organizationally<br />

distant partners<br />

Active learning<br />

Received from organizationally<br />

proximate partners<br />

Received from organizationally<br />

distant<br />

partners<br />

Informal guanxi<br />

network<br />

Active searching<br />

Remarks Explained<br />

variance<br />

of each<br />

factor<br />

Own development of ideas; selfabsorption<br />

and learning through<br />

license purchasing and reverse<br />

engineering<br />

Interacting with parent companies and<br />

foreign customers<br />

Interacting with domestic customers,<br />

foreign customers, universities, research<br />

institutions and sales agents<br />

Self-purchasing of equipment and<br />

software<br />

Interacting with parent companies and<br />

foreign customers<br />

Interacting with domestic customers<br />

and foreign customers<br />

Sending staff to domestic customers or<br />

leading domestic firms, foreign customers<br />

or leading foreign firms, and<br />

universities for training<br />

Receiving training and know-how<br />

from people sent by parent company<br />

and foreign customers<br />

Receiving training and know-how<br />

from people sent by domestic customers<br />

and foreign customers<br />

Interacting through guanxi, for<br />

example gaining information on the<br />

reputation and capacity of innovation<br />

partners from other business partners,<br />

relatives and friends in the innovation<br />

process<br />

Searching for information on partners<br />

via internet, exhibition and sales<br />

agents in the innovation process<br />

Total<br />

explained<br />

variance<br />

15 % 60 %<br />

12 %<br />

33 %<br />

24 % 85 %<br />

27 %<br />

34 %<br />

44 % 74 %<br />

13 %<br />

17 %<br />

52 % 79 %<br />

27 %


88 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

it knowledge from parent companies and foreign<br />

customers, but that they are also interacting<br />

with external partners beyond the organizational<br />

hierarchy, for example domestic customers,<br />

universities, research institutions and<br />

sales agents, to obtain new ideas and required<br />

knowledge. The organizational proximity<br />

with parent companies and foreign customers<br />

is closer than that with domestic customers<br />

and external institutes in the context of latecomer<br />

countries, as previously discussed. Also,<br />

the social proximity with domestic customers<br />

and external institutes can substitute<br />

for the lack of organizational proximity<br />

among independent firms and organizations to<br />

some degree in order to enhance trust and <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />

in the innovation process. Combined<br />

with the general question pertaining to<br />

the use of social relations with all business<br />

partners (interaction mode), insight into the<br />

degree of proximity use in the innovation<br />

process can be secured.<br />

In the empirical test, cluster analysis uses the<br />

items shown in Tab. 1 to identify different patterns<br />

of capitalizing on social and organizational<br />

proximity. In cluster analysis, there is<br />

rarely one single best solution. A good cluster<br />

analysis should firstly use as few clusters as<br />

possible, and secondly capture all statistically<br />

and empirically important clusters. We follow<br />

a four-step procedure to ensure the internal<br />

validity of the clustering result (DELMAR et al.<br />

2003). First, hierarchical clustering with<br />

Ward’s method and squared Euclidean distances<br />

was conducted to assess the possible<br />

clustering results. In this step, we arrived at<br />

two to six cluster solutions and derived each<br />

centroid from each cluster solution. The second<br />

step was to use the centroids derived in<br />

the first step to perform the K-means cluster.<br />

The result of the K-means cluster was compared<br />

with that of the hierarchical cluster using<br />

cross tabulation. A significant level in<br />

Lambda lower than 0.05 is considered to be<br />

able to verify the relative stability of the cluster<br />

results across samples. After running these<br />

two procedures, we settled on three clusters<br />

that are internally stable and easy to interpret<br />

from the perspective of innovation behavior<br />

with respect to the use of proximities.<br />

We applied regression analysis to explore further<br />

the exact relationship of the use of proximities<br />

and product innovation performance<br />

by controlling for firm-specific characteristics<br />

such as size, ownership, age and internal absorptive<br />

capacity. The dependent variable in<br />

the regression model is product innovation performance.<br />

In questionnaire data, especially in<br />

developing countries, it is always difficult to<br />

obtain an exact measurement of new products<br />

that is reliable and comparable. Therefore, we<br />

asked firms to evaluate the degree of improvement<br />

of two aspects of production innovation<br />

performance, i.e. product function expansion<br />

and product categories upgrading (on a scale of<br />

one to five with increasing degrees of improvement).<br />

The dependent variable in the regression<br />

is the average score of these two<br />

items. A shortcoming of this variable is that it<br />

has a bo<strong>und</strong> value of one to five. The problem<br />

here is that it is based on a subjective evaluation,<br />

and that those firms that marked the same<br />

score might not be completely similar in their<br />

achievement. The distribution of the composite<br />

score of innovation performance is shown in<br />

Fig. 3. The censoring of the data set can be<br />

clearly seen, since there are far more cases with<br />

scores of three to five, which is to be expected<br />

in questionnaire answers because the firms all<br />

attempt to make a good impression. With this<br />

particular issue of censored data, ordinaryleast-squares<br />

(OLS) regression provides inconsistent<br />

estimates of the parameters (LONG<br />

1997). Therefore, we applied a Tobit regression<br />

which is unaffected by this issue. The independent<br />

variables are defined in Tab. 2.<br />

Fig. 3: Histogram distribution of product<br />

innovation outcome<br />

Source: own survey


Wenying Fu / Daniel Schiller / Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity 89<br />

Tab. 2: Independent variables in product innovation outcome regression<br />

Firm characteristics<br />

Absorptive capacity<br />

Innovation behavior<br />

1 Specific classification of products into the different levels could be referred to appendix C.<br />

Source: own survey<br />

Empirical results<br />

Use of proximity in innovation: the overall<br />

pattern<br />

The results of the cluster analysis, which differentiates<br />

between three types of innovation<br />

behavior related to the capacity of capitalizing<br />

on social and organizational proximity in the<br />

process of product innovation, are demonstrated<br />

in Tab. 3.<br />

Indicators Description<br />

Defined according to Chinese firm size standard, 1<br />

as large firms with no less 300 million Yuan sales<br />

Size<br />

and no less than 2000 employees, otherwise as<br />

small and medium-sized with the value of 0<br />

Ownership<br />

– Socially embedded innovator: Firms in this<br />

group interact frequently with external partners<br />

in combination with their internal capability.<br />

With regard to obtaining codified and<br />

tacit knowledge in the product innovation<br />

1 as firms with foreign participation (wholly owned<br />

or joint venture), 0 as firms with 100 % domestic<br />

participation<br />

Age Years since establishment of the firm<br />

Level of technical staff<br />

Percentage of technical staff that have bachelor<br />

degree or above multiplied by training frequency<br />

Level of managerial<br />

staff<br />

CEO education<br />

Development capability<br />

Initial product<br />

technology<br />

Behavior of using<br />

different proximities<br />

Percentage of managerial staff that have bachelor<br />

degree or above multiplied by training frequency<br />

1 as CEO below bachelor degree<br />

2 as CEO with bachelor degree<br />

3 as CEO with graduate degree (master or doctor)<br />

4 as CEO with bachelor or above combined with<br />

overseas experience<br />

1 as having product development capability, 0 as<br />

not<br />

Defined according to International Standard Industrial<br />

Classification of all Economic Activities, Rev<br />

31, 1 as producing low-tech products when starting<br />

business, 2 as producing medium-tech products<br />

when starting business; 3 as producing high-tech<br />

products when starting business<br />

Defined by the cluster analysis in the next part; included<br />

in the model as a series of dummy variables.<br />

process, firms of this kind tend to rely more<br />

on customers and use the active strategy of<br />

sending people to business partners for acquiring<br />

tacit knowledge. In the interaction<br />

process with these partners, firms in this category<br />

flexibly combine formal active<br />

searching and informal networks (guanxi<br />

with family members, friends and business<br />

partners) when interacting with partners in<br />

the innovation process. Although it is not<br />

possible to specify exactly which interaction<br />

method is applied by the firms when interacting<br />

with each partner (because the related<br />

matrix would be too complex to be answered<br />

by the firms), it is possible to conclude indirectly<br />

that firms in this group rely on social


90 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Tab. 3: Results of cluster analysis*<br />

Socially embedded Organizationally Lame<br />

innovator dependent innovator innovator<br />

NPI_external partner 0.54 0.25 -0.32<br />

NPI_internal 0.52 0.07 -0.31<br />

NPCK_customer 0.60 -0.15 -0.34<br />

NPTK_passive from customer 0.46 0.07 -0.22<br />

NPTK_active learning 0.58 -0.12 -0.35<br />

NPInteraction_informal 0.60 -0.06 -0.33<br />

NPInteraction_formal searching 0.26 -0.01 -0.17<br />

NPI_parent comp. & foreign -0.11 1.01 -0.12<br />

NPCK_parent comp. -0.38 1.96 -0.27<br />

NPCK_self purchase -0.17 0.12 0.10<br />

NPTK_passive from parent comp. -0.47 2.06 -0.16<br />

Number<br />

* Ward’s method/squared Euclidean distance<br />

Source: own survey<br />

104 41 171<br />

proximity to external partners in general during<br />

the process of product innovation to a<br />

greater degree than firms in the other two<br />

clusters. They are actually socially embedded<br />

innovators, and social proximity is not<br />

only used as a way of acquiring codified and<br />

tacit knowledge by interacting with external<br />

partners, but also as a way of triggering new<br />

product ideas, which is a feature of capable<br />

firms in a well-functioning regional innovation<br />

system.<br />

It is worth mentioning that although these<br />

firms are already able to extend the scope of<br />

interactive learning in the innovation process<br />

to capitalize further on social proximity, they<br />

still rely on organizational proximity with<br />

foreign customers to a certain degree in order<br />

to acquire codified and tacit knowledge.<br />

This again supports the mutual reinforcing<br />

effect of social and organizational proximity.<br />

Socially active innovators tend to apply<br />

mixed strategies in using proximity to facilitate<br />

interactive learning.<br />

– Organizationally dependent innovator: In<br />

contrast, organizationally dependent innovators<br />

rely heavily on organizational proximity<br />

to gain access to and absorb knowledge.<br />

They turn to their parent companies to obtain<br />

codified and tacit knowledge in the process<br />

of product innovation, i.e. in a more passive<br />

way due to the hierarchical control. The new<br />

product ideas originate mainly from parent<br />

companies as well as from powerful foreign<br />

customers.<br />

What is again noteworthy is that organizationally<br />

dependent innovators show a certain<br />

tendency to interact with external partners to<br />

prompt product innovation, although to a<br />

lesser degree than socially embedded innovators.<br />

However, the much lower value in informal<br />

interactions indicates that these firms<br />

are not able to capitalize on social proximity<br />

to foster innovation as well as their socially<br />

embedded counterparts. Moreover, their<br />

method of interacting with innovative partners<br />

is not characterized by any particular<br />

feature, which indicates a more passive attitude<br />

towards product innovation compared<br />

to socially embedded innovators.<br />

– Lame innovator: Compared to the previous<br />

two kinds of firms, lame innovators have<br />

low values for all the indicators that are related<br />

to product innovation. Lame innovators<br />

are not actively involved in triggering<br />

new ideas of innovation, nor do they strive to<br />

search for codified and tacit knowledge,<br />

which is important for positive product innovation<br />

outcome. Moreover, they are quite<br />

vague and unsettled in their ways of interacting<br />

with partners in the innovation<br />

process. In short, they are not able to interact<br />

with external players to initiate innovation


Wenying Fu / Daniel Schiller / Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity 91<br />

Tab. 4: Difference in innovation behavior between large firms and small and medium sized<br />

enterprises (SME)<br />

Firm ownership Socially embedded Organizationally Lame innovator Total<br />

innovator dependent innovator<br />

Domestic firms 73 (37 %) 17 (9 %) 105 (54 %) 195<br />

Foreign firms 31 (26 %) 23 (19 %) 66 (55 %) 120<br />

Total<br />

χ<br />

104 (33 %) 40 (13 %) 171 (54 %) 315<br />

2 =9.434, p=0.009<br />

Source: own survey<br />

and do not have the capacity to organize internal<br />

learning.<br />

A look at the number of firms in each cluster<br />

shows that the number of lame innovators exceeds<br />

the sum of socially embedded and organizationally<br />

dependent innovators in our sample.<br />

This is proof of the immature internal absorptive<br />

capacity of most firms in the Pearl<br />

River Delta to benefit from external interaction<br />

in order to trigger innovation. However, the<br />

number of socially embedded innovators is two<br />

times higher than the number of organizationally<br />

dependent innovators. This seems to be an<br />

indication of a maturing regional innovation<br />

system in the Pearl River Delta, where some<br />

local firms are capable of benefiting from localized<br />

knowledge sources by capitalizing on<br />

informal social relations. But it also reflects the<br />

difficulty of most firms in the Pearl River Delta<br />

to ‘couple strategically’ with global firms to<br />

upgrade their position in the value chain. By<br />

studying the relocation issue of Taiwanese personal<br />

computer firms, YANG (2009) also pointed<br />

out that Taiwanese firms in the Pearl River<br />

Delta are less oriented towards the strategic<br />

coupling of local and global knowledge<br />

sources than their counterparts in the Yangtze<br />

River Delta.<br />

Use of proximity in innovation: difference<br />

between domestic and foreign firms<br />

In the interest of a deeper insight into innovation<br />

behavior in terms of proximity use among<br />

the electronics firms in the Pearl River Delta,<br />

investigations of the domestic and foreign<br />

firms were conducted separately. Tab. 4 shows<br />

the distribution of the above-mentioned clustering<br />

groups for domestic and foreign firms.<br />

At first glance, it can be seen that the domestic<br />

and foreign firms do not differ from each other<br />

in the inclination to <strong>und</strong>ertake interactive<br />

learning aiming at fostering product innovation<br />

outcomes. However, the strategies of using<br />

proximity as a way to ensure trust and <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />

in interactive learning differ between<br />

these two groups of firms. Domestic firms<br />

tend to interact with other independent business<br />

partners through the use of social proximity<br />

to gain reliable information and support,<br />

while foreign firms resort more to their organizationally<br />

proximate parent companies and<br />

foreign customers to gain access to innovation-related<br />

knowledge.<br />

The different behavior of using proximities in<br />

different processes of product innovation between<br />

domestic and foreign firms is demonstrated<br />

in Fig. 4 more thoroughly. As shown by<br />

the left part of the figure, foreign firms use<br />

much more organizational proximity to foster<br />

innovation, especially in terms of acquiring<br />

new product ideas. The reason for foreign<br />

firms interacting more with their parent companies<br />

and foreign partners to trigger innova-<br />

Fig. 4: Use of proximities for domestic and<br />

foreign firms<br />

Source: own survey


92 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Tab. 5: Tobit regression on innovation outcome<br />

Independent variables (1) Product innovation (2) Product innovation<br />

outcome1 (average score outcome1 (average score<br />

of evaluation) of evaluation)<br />

Constant 3.01*** 2.64***<br />

(0.282) 6 (0.281)<br />

Level of technical staff 0.0006 0.0006<br />

(0.001) (0.001)<br />

Level of managerial staff 0.0008 0.0008<br />

(0.001) (0.001)<br />

CEO education 0.16** 0.16**<br />

(0.065) (0.065)<br />

Development capability 0.52*** 0.52***<br />

(0.188) (0.188)<br />

Medium-tech vs. 0.19 0.19<br />

Initial low-tech2 (0.174) (0.174)<br />

product High-tech vs. 0.54** 0.54**<br />

technology low-tech2 (0.251) (0.251)<br />

Overall effect5 —* —*<br />

Ownership -0.26** -0.26**<br />

(0.127) (0.127)<br />

Firm size -0.12 -0.12<br />

(0.293) (0.293)<br />

Firm age 0.005 0.005<br />

(0.010) (0.010)<br />

Organizationally Organizationally<br />

Innovation dependent vs. -0.15 dependent 0.23<br />

behavior socially embedded3 (0.246) vs. lame4 (0.234)<br />

Lame vs. socially -0.37** Socially 0.37**<br />

embedded3 (0.170) embedded vs. lame4 (0.170)<br />

Overall effect5 —* —*<br />

Prob > chi2 0.0006 0.0006<br />

Pseudo R square 0.047 0.047<br />

Number of observations 233 233<br />

1 Product innovation outcome refers to improvement in product quality, product function and product categorical<br />

upgrading<br />

2 Initial product as low-tech as the default group, which means low-tech as 0, the other as 1<br />

3 Socially embedded innovator as the default group, which means socially embedded innovator as 0, the other as 1<br />

4 Lame innovator as the default group, which means lame innovator as 0, the other as 1<br />

5 T test of whether the overall effect of the categorical variable is statistically significant<br />

6 Standard errors in parentheses; *p


Wenying Fu / Daniel Schiller / Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity 93<br />

only as a ‘spying device’ to catch up with the<br />

latest technology and market preferences in order<br />

to trigger new product ideas. The more <strong>und</strong>erdeveloped<br />

firm capabilities of domestic<br />

firms compared to those of foreign firms, resulting<br />

in less gain from reciprocity than the<br />

cost of spillover, inhibit them from cooperating<br />

in the product innovation process to share each<br />

other’s codified and tacit knowledge.<br />

Impact of proximities on product innovation<br />

performance<br />

The results of the Tobit regression with innovation<br />

performance as the dependent variable and<br />

innovation behavior and other control variables<br />

as independent variables are shown in Tab. 5.<br />

The results of the cluster analysis are used to<br />

define the innovation behavior as: 1 - socially<br />

embedded innovators, 2 - organizationally dependent<br />

innovators and 3 - lame innovators.<br />

The chi-square likelihood ratio has a p-value of<br />

0.002, which tells us, that the model as a whole<br />

fits significantly better than an empty model.<br />

The main focus of the research question is the<br />

impact of the use of proximity on product innovation<br />

performance. Equation 1 and equation<br />

2 are quite similar, with the exception that<br />

the default group of each dummy variable in<br />

the innovation behavior category is adjusted to<br />

compare the impact of each type of innovation<br />

behavior on innovation performance. If control<br />

variables for firm characteristics and absorptive<br />

capacity are included in the model, socially<br />

embedded innovators possess a better product<br />

innovation outcome than lame innovators<br />

on a significant level of 0.02, while organizationally<br />

dependent innovators do not outperform<br />

the lame innovator in a significant way.<br />

This verifies the second hypothesis that social<br />

proximity is an asset that firms are able to capitalize<br />

on in complex innovation processes.<br />

With the development of local capabilities in<br />

the Pearl River Delta after thirty years of industrialization,<br />

firms are gradually accumulating<br />

the capacity to capitalize on social proximity<br />

to foster product innovation and upgrading.<br />

Nevertheless, it also suggests that firms that<br />

apply the strategies of capitalizing on organizational<br />

proximity to foster innovation encounter<br />

the difficulty of achieving satisfied innovation<br />

outcomes. The limited potential for upgrading<br />

the position in the value chain is revealed for<br />

organizationally dependent innovators, supporting<br />

the first hypothesis.<br />

Nevertheless, it is necessary to examine cautiously<br />

the magnitude of improvement by applying<br />

social proximity in interactive learning.<br />

The coefficients in model 1 and model 2 all<br />

point to a 0.37 degree of improvement on the<br />

average score of evaluation on production<br />

function expansion and category upgrading. To<br />

place it in a practical context, this means that<br />

applying social proximity in interactive learning<br />

promotes the innovation outcome either in<br />

function expansion or category upgrading by<br />

nearly one degree (e.g. from not significant to<br />

slightly significant or from significant to very<br />

significant). In short, the improvement made<br />

by applying social proximity compared to applying<br />

nothing is rather small. Moreover, socially<br />

embedded innovators, which interact<br />

with domestic customers and other knowledge<br />

institutions in the process of product innovation,<br />

do not differ significantly from organizationally<br />

dependent innovators in terms of product<br />

innovation performance.<br />

The results reveal an intriguing feature of the<br />

recent development stage of the regional innovation<br />

system in the Pearl River Delta. Although<br />

socially embedded firms are emerging<br />

in this region, which altogether increases dynamic<br />

innovative synergies on the local scale,<br />

their capacity to transform this social asset fully<br />

into a high innovation performance is not yet<br />

sufficient. Recalling the results in the previous<br />

section which revealed that domestic firms are<br />

reluctant to share codified and tacit knowledge<br />

in the innovation process, this all <strong>und</strong>erpins the<br />

instability of innovative synergies in emerging<br />

regions where small achievements are not sufficient<br />

to compensate for the risk and cost related<br />

to innovation activities. It might be due to<br />

the fact that trust building requires time, especially<br />

in innovation activities that are highly<br />

complex and risky and involve a high level of<br />

spillover effects. All in all, a regional innovation<br />

system is only just burgeoning in the Pearl<br />

River Delta, and calls for a stable and efficient<br />

governance infrastructure to be put in place to<br />

strengthen and stabilize interactive learning in<br />

the business sector.<br />

Discussion and conclusion<br />

The fact that the local firms are interested and<br />

able to capitalize on social proximity to foster<br />

innovation signifies the maturing of a regional<br />

innovation system (COOKE et al. 1997; REVIL-<br />

LA DIEZ 2000). Moreover, the use of organiza-


94 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

tional proximity feeds dynamism into the local<br />

production system as a way of avoiding negative<br />

lock-in effects (ASHEIM/ISAKSEN 2002;<br />

BATHELT et al. 2004). In the context of China,<br />

where low-cost is the common strategy and innovation<br />

capability is doubted, this paper provides<br />

the theoretical implications of the role of<br />

proximity in fostering innovation activities<br />

when sufficient absorptive capacity is gradually<br />

enhanced. The line of thinking that social<br />

capital is an important asset for organizing interactive<br />

learning and markets is well covered<br />

by the institutional and cultural turn in many<br />

disciplines. In new growth theory, productive<br />

new ideas are endogenously shaped by institutional<br />

contexts (ROMER 1986). The approach of<br />

innovation systems proposes that social capital<br />

induces widely spread interactive learning in<br />

the whole economy, hence creating more net<br />

wealth (LUNDVALL 2005). Likewise, the new<br />

institutionalism in economic geography also<br />

embraces the context-dependent epistemology,<br />

considering the possibility that various social<br />

institutions in places determine the evolution<br />

of the economic landscape (CLARK et al. 2003).<br />

As demonstrated by the empirical investigation<br />

in this paper, the informal guanxi networks in<br />

the Chinese context are important social assets<br />

that firms can take advantage of in ensuring effective<br />

interactive learning.<br />

By examining the questionnaire data collected<br />

for the electronics industry in the Pearl River<br />

Delta, the following trends are captured in this<br />

electronics cluster. Firstly, as organizational<br />

proximity plays a limited role in promoting innovation,<br />

the electronics firms have extended<br />

the use of social proximity from low-cost production<br />

activities to <strong>und</strong>ertake interactive<br />

learning in the product innovation process. Despite<br />

the formation of a group of socially embedded<br />

firms, the effect of social proximity in<br />

fostering fruitful interactive learning is still<br />

marginal. Secondly, social proximity is applied<br />

more by domestic firms than by foreign firms,<br />

especially in terms of triggering new product<br />

ideas. However, it is applied less by the domestic<br />

firms to gain support in the innovation<br />

process, such as necessary machinery and technical<br />

know-how. Altogether, social proximity<br />

not only produces marginal effects, but also<br />

has limited scope in strengthening the interactive<br />

learning in innovation, which all points to<br />

the instability of innovation synergies that is<br />

stressed in the regional competitiveness literature.<br />

Even before the financial crisis in 2008, governments<br />

at different levels (province, city, district)<br />

in the Pearl River Delta felt that the strategy<br />

of low-cost production was losing its competitive<br />

edge and had been eagerly promoting<br />

industrial upgrading and innovation. As interactive<br />

learning processes based on social relations<br />

need stabilizing regional orders from the<br />

supporting governance infrastructure (HEIDEN-<br />

REICH 2004), policy focus may be devoted to<br />

widening the scope of social proximity in interactive<br />

learning and improving the effect of<br />

social proximity in fostering innovation, which<br />

has been pointed out from the empirical results<br />

as a weakness of the regional innovation system<br />

in the Pearl River Delta. Actions can be<br />

taken by means of supporting agents or organizations<br />

to foster cooperation among local players<br />

as well as with external players, institutionalizing<br />

the exchange and learning between industry<br />

and academia, regulating the domestic<br />

market which stabilizes the reciprocal learning<br />

among the firms, and providing innovation<br />

f<strong>und</strong>s to resource-limited small and medium<br />

enterprises.<br />

The theoretical literature has extensively discussed<br />

the issue of proximity and its relationship<br />

with learning and behavior, but the empirical<br />

evidence is not yet sufficient to support its<br />

role in innovation in different contexts, especially<br />

that of developing countries. This paper<br />

takes the step of measuring the use of the two<br />

most relevant proximities – organizational<br />

proximity and social proximity – in the context<br />

of China. By responding to the call of researching<br />

the knowledge transfer and learning<br />

process at global and local scales (BUN-<br />

NELL/COE 2001; ASHEIM/ISAKSEN 2002; FREE-<br />

MAN 2002; FROMHOLD-EISEBITH 2007) light<br />

was thrown on the role of proximity on both<br />

scales in attaining trust and <strong>und</strong>erstanding in<br />

the process of product innovation. However,<br />

the complementary role of organizational proximity<br />

with global partners and social proximity<br />

with local partners is not simple. As demonstrated<br />

by HUMPHREY/SCHMITZ (2002), different<br />

degrees of organizational proximity, i.e.<br />

different methods of integration into the global<br />

production system, actually influence the local<br />

upgrading strategies. Therefore, qualitative<br />

studies such as company interviews should be<br />

conducted to provide further insight into the<br />

strategic combination of different proximities<br />

to achieve the optimal innovation outcome.


Wenying Fu / Daniel Schiller / Javier Revilla Diez: Strategies of using social proximity 95<br />

Acknowledgement<br />

The research <strong>und</strong>erlying the results presented<br />

in this paper received f<strong>und</strong>ing from the German<br />

Research Fo<strong>und</strong>ation (DFG) <strong>und</strong>er grant<br />

RE 1720/11-1 within the priority programme<br />

SPP 1233 “Megacities – Megachallenge: Informal<br />

Dynamics of Global Change”. The authors<br />

would like to thank two anonymous referees<br />

for their comments on the paper.<br />

References<br />

ASHEIM, B. T./ISAKSEN, A. (2002): Regional innovation<br />

systems: the integration of local ‘sticky’ and global<br />

‘ubiquitous’ knowledge. In: The Journal of Technology<br />

Transfer, (27)1, 77-86.<br />

ASHEIM, B. T./COENEN, L. (2005): Knowledge bases and<br />

regional innovation systems: Comparing Nordic clusters.<br />

In: Research policy, (34)8, 1173-1190.<br />

BATHELT, H./MALMBERG, A./MASKELL, P. (2004): Clusters<br />

and knowledge: local buzz, global pipelines and the<br />

process of knowledge creation. In: Progress in Human<br />

Geography, (28)1, 31-56.<br />

BELLANDI, M./TOMMASO, M. R. (2005): The case of specialized<br />

towns in Guangdong, China. In: European<br />

Planning Studies, (13)5, 707-729.<br />

BOSCHMA, R. (2005): Proximity and innovation. A critical<br />

assessment. In: Regional Studies, (39)1, 61-74.<br />

BUNNELL, T. G./COE, N. M. (2001): Spaces and scales of<br />

innovation. In: Progress in Human geography, (25)4,<br />

569-589.<br />

CAPELLO, R. (1999): Spatial transfer of knowledge in<br />

high technology milieu. Learning versus collective<br />

learning processes. In: Regional Studies, (33)4, 353-<br />

365.<br />

CHESBROUGH, H. W./TEECE, D. J. (1996): When is virtual<br />

virtuous. In: Harvard Business Review, (74)1, 65-73.<br />

CLARK, G. L./FELDMAN, M. P./GERTLER, M. S. (2003):<br />

The Oxford Handbook of Economic Geography. Oxford,<br />

USA.<br />

COOKE, P./URANDA, M. G./ETXEBARRIA, G. (1997): Regional<br />

innovation systems: <strong>Institut</strong>ional and organizational<br />

dimensions. In: Research Policy, (26), 475-491.<br />

DELMAR, F./DAVIDSSON, P./GARTNER, W. (2003): Arriving<br />

at the high growth firm. In: Journal of Business Venturing,<br />

(18)2, 189-216.<br />

DICKEN, P. (1976): Multiplant business, enterprise and<br />

geographical space. Some issues in the study of external<br />

control and regional development. In: Regional Studies,<br />

(10)4, 401-412.<br />

DOLLAR, D. (2005): Globalization, inequality, and<br />

poverty since 1980. In: World Bank Research Observer,<br />

(20)2: 145-175.<br />

DOLOREUX, D./PARTO, S. (2005): Regional innovation<br />

systems. Current discourse and challenges for future research.<br />

In: Technology in Society, (27)2, 133-153.<br />

ERNST, D. (2005): The new mobility of knowledge: digital<br />

information systems and global flagship networks.<br />

In: Latham,R./Sassen, S. (Eds.): Digital formations. IT<br />

and new architectures in the global realm. Princeton,<br />

S. 89-114.<br />

ERNST, D./KIM, L. (2002): Global production networks,<br />

knowledge diffusion, and local capability formation. In:<br />

Research Policy, (31), 1417-1429.<br />

FREEMAN, C. (2002): Continental, national and sub-national<br />

innovation systems. Complementarity and economic<br />

growth. In: Research Policy, (31)2, 191-211.<br />

FEINBERG, S. E./GUPTA, A. K. (2004): Knowledge<br />

spillovers and the assignment of R&D responsibilities<br />

to foreign subsidiaries. In: Strategic Management Journal,<br />

(25)8-9, 823-845.<br />

FROMHOLD-EISEBITH, M. (2007): Bridging scales in innovation<br />

policies. How to link regional, national and international<br />

innovation systems. In: European Planning<br />

Studies, (15)2, 217-233.<br />

GEREFFI, G./HUMPHREY, J./STURGEON, T. (2005): The<br />

governance of global value chains. In: Review of International<br />

Political Economy, (12)1, 78-104.<br />

GRANOVETTER, M. (1985): Economic action and social<br />

structure. The problem of embeddedness. In: American<br />

Journal of Sociology, (91)3, 481-510.<br />

HEIDENREICH, M. (2004): The dilemmas of regional<br />

innnovation systems. In Cooke, P./Heidenreich,<br />

M./Braczyk, H. J. (Eds.): Regional innovation systems.<br />

The role of governance in a globalized world. London,<br />

363-394. (2nd ed.).<br />

HENNART, J. F. (1993): Explaining the swollen middle.<br />

Why most transactions are a mix of market and hierarchy.<br />

In: Organization Science, (4)4, 529-547.<br />

HSU, J. Y./SAXENIAN, A. (2000): The limits of guanxi<br />

capitalism. Transnational collaboration between Taiwan<br />

and the USA. In: Environment and Planning A, (32)11,<br />

1991-2005.<br />

HUMPHREY, J./SCHMITZ, H. (2002): How does insertion<br />

in global value chains affect upgrading in industrial<br />

clusters? In: Regional studies, (36)9, 1017-1027.<br />

HUMPHREY, J. (2004): Upgrading in global value chains.<br />

Geneva. (ILO).<br />

HOWELLS, J. R. L. (1999): Regional systems of innovation?<br />

Cambridge.<br />

IVARSSON, I./ALVSTAM, C. G. (2005): The effect of spatial<br />

proximity on technology transfer from TNCs to local<br />

suppliers in developing countries. The case of AB<br />

Volvo in Asia and Latin America. In: Economic Geography,<br />

(81)1, 83-111.<br />

KIRAT, T./LUNG, Y. (1999): Innovation and proximity.<br />

Territories as loci of collective learning processes. In:<br />

European Urban and Regional Studies, (6)1, 27-38.<br />

LONG, J. S. (1997): Regression models for categorical<br />

and limited dependent variables. Chapter 7. Thousand<br />

Oaks.<br />

LOVETT, S./SIMMONS, L. C./KALI, R. (1999): Guanxi<br />

versus the market. Ethics and efficiency. In: Journal of<br />

International Business Studies, (30)2, 231-247.


96 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

LUNDVALL, B. A. (1992): National innovation systems.<br />

Towards a theory of innovation and interactive learning.<br />

London.<br />

LUNDVALL, B. A. (2005): Interactive learning, social capital<br />

and economic performance. Paper presented at the<br />

“Advancing Knowledge and the Knowledge Economy”,<br />

Washington, D.C., 10-11 Jan. 2005. Washington, D.C.<br />

MASKELL, P. (1998): Low-tech competitive advantages<br />

and the role of proximity. In: European Urban and Regional<br />

Studies, (5)2, 99-118.<br />

MASSARD, N./MEHIER, C. (2009): Proximity and Innovation<br />

through an “Accessibility to Knowledge” Lens.<br />

In: Regional Studies, (43)1, 77-88.<br />

MENZEL, M. P. (2008): Dynamic proximities. Changing<br />

relations by creating and bridging distances. Utrecht.<br />

(Papers in Evolutionary Economic Geography, Urban<br />

and Regional Research Centre, Universiteit Utrecht,<br />

working papers).<br />

MEYER, S./SCHILLER, D./REVILLA DIEZ, J. (2009): The<br />

Janus-faced economy. Hong Kong firms as intermediaries<br />

between global customers and local producers in<br />

the electronics industry. In: Tijdschrift Voor Economische<br />

En Sociale Geografie, (100)2, 224-235.<br />

MORRISON, A./PIETROBELLI, C./RABELLOTT, R. (2008):<br />

Global value chains and technological capabilities. A<br />

framework to study learning and innovation in developing<br />

countries. In: Oxford Development Studies, (36)1,<br />

39-58.<br />

NELSON, R. R./WINTER, S. G. (1982): An evolutionary<br />

theory of economic change. Bonston.<br />

NORTH, D. C. (1990): <strong>Institut</strong>ions, institutional change,<br />

and economic performance. Cambridge.<br />

OECD (1998): Main science and technology indicators.<br />

Paris.<br />

PAN, Y. G./CHI, P. S. K. (1999): Financial performance<br />

and survival of multinational corporations in China. In:<br />

Strategic Management Journal, (20)4, 359-374.<br />

PARK, S. H./LUO, Y. D. (2001): Guanxi and organizational<br />

dynamics. Organizational networking in Chinese<br />

firms. In: Strategic Management Journal, (22)5, 455-477.<br />

PENG, M. W. (2003): Extending research on network<br />

strategy in emerging economics. Hong Kong. (The Chinese<br />

University of Hong Kong: Strategic Management<br />

Society Mini-Conference).<br />

PORTER, M. E. (1990): The competitive advantage of nations.<br />

New York.<br />

RAMASAMY, B./GOH, K. W./YEUNG, M. C. H. (2006): Is<br />

Guanxi (relationship) a bridge to knowledge transfer?<br />

In: Journal of Business Research, (59)1, 130-139.<br />

REVILLA DIEZ, J. (2000): The importance of public research<br />

institutes in innovative networks. Empirical results<br />

from the Metropolitan innovation systems<br />

Barcelona, Stockholm and Vienna. In: European Planning<br />

Studies, (8)4, 451-463.<br />

ROMER, P. M. (1986): Increasing returns and long-run<br />

growth. In: Journal of Political Economy, (94)5, 1002-<br />

1037.<br />

SCHMITZ, H. (1995): Small shoemakers and Fordist giants.<br />

Tale of a supercluster. In: World Development,<br />

(23)1, 9-28.<br />

SCHMITZ, H./NADVI, K. (1999): Clustering and industrialization.<br />

Introduction. In: World Development, (27)9,<br />

1503-1514.<br />

SMITH, K. (2000): Innovation as a systemic phenomenon:<br />

rethinking the role of policy. In: Enterprise and innovation<br />

management studies, (1)1, 73-102.<br />

STANDIFIRD, S. S./ MARSHALL, R. S. (2000): The transaction<br />

cost advantage of guanxi-based business practices.<br />

In: Journal of World Business, (35)1, 21-42.<br />

TORRE, A./GILLY, J. P. (2000): On the analytical dimension<br />

of proximity dynamics. In: Regional Studies,<br />

(34)2, 169-180.<br />

TORRE, A./RALLETT, A. (2005): Proximity and localization.<br />

In: Regional Studies, (39)1, 47-59.<br />

YANG, C. (2009): Strategic coupling of regional development<br />

in global production networks. Redistribution<br />

of Taiwanese personal computer investment from the<br />

Pearl River Delta to the Yangtze River Delta, China. In:<br />

Regional Studies, (43)3, 385-407.<br />

YEUNG, H. W. (2006): Regional development and the<br />

competitive dynamics of global production networks.<br />

An East Asian perspective. In: Regional Studies, (43)3,<br />

325-351.<br />

ZHANG, Y./ZHANG, Z. G. (2006): Guanxi and organizational<br />

dynamics in China. A link between individual and<br />

organizational levels. In: Journal of Business Ethics,<br />

(67)4, 375-392.<br />

ZHOU, X./LI, Q./ZHAO, W./CAI, H. (2003): Embeddedness<br />

and contractual relationships in China’s transition<br />

economy. In: American Sociological Review, (68)1, 75-<br />

102.


Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> Jg. 56 (2012) Heft 1-2, S. 97-112<br />

Friederike Schröder / Michael Waibel, Hamburg<br />

Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta<br />

Investigating economic restructuring in Guangzhou<br />

Abstract: Against the backgro<strong>und</strong> of current economic upgrading trends in China’s so called “factory<br />

of the world“, the Pearl River Delta, this paper adopts an analytical urban governance perspective<br />

to investigate the role of informality in urban affairs. In the wake of dynamic economic<br />

and urban growth coinciding with rising environmental and social issues, local governments increasingly<br />

re-orientate their urban development strategies and apply flexible modes in responding<br />

to these challenges. The main hypothesis of this paper is that informality in particular is used as a<br />

tool of flexibility and that experimental policies as typical characteristics of the transitional<br />

process in China are widely applied nowadays to attract knowledge-intensive and service-oriented<br />

industries as well as a highly educated, and presumably creative, workforce. The hypothesis is<br />

validated by empirical research analyzing governance processes in development and locational<br />

policies of Guangzhou Science City.<br />

Keywords: urban governance, informality, economic restructuring, Guangzhou. Pearl River Delta<br />

Introduction<br />

The Pearl River Delta (PRD) as the “factory of<br />

the world” and frontrunner of China’s reform<br />

and opening process witnesses a new phase in<br />

the gradual transition process. Immense efforts<br />

have been done to move from a mere focus on<br />

growth and spatial expansion towards restructuring<br />

of the existing urban fabric and the cities’<br />

economic base. There is a policy shift away<br />

from labor-intensive production towards higher<br />

value-added manufacturing and service industries<br />

and to a more knowledge-based economy<br />

in general. This has been going on for some<br />

years already, but gained substantial impetus<br />

due to the global financial crisis, which can be<br />

seen as an important catalyst for economic restructuring<br />

and upgrading in the PRD region.<br />

The growth of the tertiary and quarternary sectors<br />

calls for constant economic and urban redevelopment<br />

processes and adaptation strategies<br />

that allow for different spatial economic<br />

entities to be attractive for companies and the<br />

global as well as the domestic workforce.<br />

Economic restructuring and changing urban development<br />

strategies entail the thesis that these<br />

transformations also bring about a change in ur-<br />

ban governance modes or the way a city or urban<br />

area is governed. Therefore, the <strong>und</strong>erlying<br />

assumption is that a diversifying society, and<br />

particularly the ongoing economic restructuring<br />

process in the PRD, require new formal and informal<br />

institutional arrangements, i.e. changing<br />

modes of urban governance and specific sets of<br />

stakeholder coalitions. We presume that in this<br />

process informality, <strong>und</strong>erstood here as a mode<br />

rather than a sector (ROY/ALSAYAD 2004), is increasingly<br />

used as a tool of flexibility, testing,<br />

and learning, whereas informality – used as a<br />

substitute to fill institutional gaps in the early<br />

phase of transition – has diminished over time<br />

in the course of the reform process.<br />

Economic restructuring implies a re-production<br />

of space. In the PRD, it takes place by comprehensive<br />

planning approaches loosening the<br />

strict division between industrial and urban<br />

space, integrating various urban functions and<br />

by upgrading the urban fabric intended to raise<br />

urban liveability. How is urban space developed<br />

and reproduced? And how are locational policies<br />

implemented against the backgro<strong>und</strong> of a<br />

changing economic base? These are the main<br />

questions to be answered in this paper. They include<br />

questions of who is involved in planning


98 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

and implementation and what are the objectives.<br />

Following these questions, our overall<br />

aim is to analyze urban governance processes<br />

in Guangzhou, China. As an analytical tool, the<br />

integrated framework of urban governance developed<br />

by DIGAETANO/STROM (2003) will be<br />

applied and consequently adapted to the Chinese<br />

context.<br />

For the case study, Guangzhou Science City<br />

(GSC), particularly its physical development<br />

and locational policies as a high-tech park and<br />

urban environment, have been chosen. The role<br />

of informality as potentially flexible device in<br />

these processes will be of special interest. As<br />

priority project of Guangzhou’s municipal<br />

government, designed to upgrade the economic<br />

structure along the value chain, GSC is an extraordinary<br />

example for the interplay of economic<br />

upgrading and comprehensive urban development<br />

strategies. It is currently one of the<br />

most ambitious and prominent urban development<br />

projects in the PRD since the construction<br />

of flagship high-tech industrial parks has been<br />

promoted by the National Development and<br />

Reform Commission in 2008 as a key strategy<br />

of the regional upgrading of Guangdong<br />

province.<br />

The questions and arguments are analyzed and<br />

presented in three main parts. The first analyzes<br />

economic restructuring in the PRD. The second<br />

discusses the concepts of governance and informality<br />

and relates both to the context of China.<br />

The third section applies our research approach<br />

to the case study of Guangzhou Science City<br />

and discusses the role of informality in urban<br />

governance processes in the field of urban economic<br />

restructuring.<br />

Economic restructuring in the<br />

Pearl River Delta<br />

In Europe and North America economic restructuring<br />

has mostly been a necessity of the<br />

fall of regional economies or declining of industrial<br />

centers (HASSINK 2005, 571, FAINSTEIN/<br />

CAMPBELL 2002, 6). In China, and particularly<br />

in the Pearl River Delta with average yearly<br />

GDP growth rates of 14 % between 2000 and<br />

2009 (Tab. 1), rising salaries and living standards,<br />

and a fast growth in urban population<br />

one can barely speak of a declining region.<br />

However, high speed economic and urban development,<br />

hastily built-up infrastructure, the<br />

superimposition of new and old physical structures,<br />

traffic congestion, environmental degradation,<br />

spatial fragmentation and social segregation<br />

take their toll. These processes call the<br />

need for restructuring of the existing urban fabric<br />

and economic base.<br />

The PRD has experienced tremendous economic<br />

growth and spatial transformation since the<br />

late 1970s. It differs from the Yangtze Delta<br />

River (YDR) in the way that its economic development<br />

and urbanization process is mainly<br />

the result of exogenous forces, such as foreign<br />

direct investments (FDI), influences from the<br />

Chinese diaspora of Hong Kong, Singapore,<br />

and other parts of the world, and small to medium-sized<br />

labor-intensive processing manufacturing.<br />

In contrast, the development pace of the<br />

YDR rather results from endogenous dynamisms<br />

and agglomeration advantages from<br />

the major city of Shanghai (HE et al. 2006,<br />

431). Though dominated by external forces, internal<br />

factors – apparently affecting all regions<br />

of China – also play a role in the PRD’s development,<br />

i.e. institutional changes and innovations,<br />

fiscal decentralization and fierce inter-urban<br />

competition. It is the interdependency of<br />

different structural, cultural, and political forces<br />

that have unevenly transformed the economic,<br />

social, physical and spatial landscapes in the<br />

PRD (HE et al. 2006, 436; SHEN 2002, 92) – and<br />

transformation is still going on.<br />

Agricultural diversification and industrialization<br />

of the 1980s and 1990s gives way to a new<br />

phase of economic restructuring with a deliberately<br />

induced shift away from labor-intensive<br />

manufacturing towards knowledge-intensive<br />

industries and a growth of the tertiary sector.<br />

“Building a modern industrial system” (NDRC<br />

2008, 15) is the programmatic device to prioritize<br />

the PRD’s development of modern service<br />

industries (e.g. finance, convention and exhibition<br />

services, scientific research and development),<br />

modernizing and advancing capital- and<br />

technology-intensive manufacturing industries<br />

(e.g. automotive, nuclear and wind power<br />

equipment), and vigorously develop high-tech<br />

industries (biotechnology, pharmaceutical<br />

products, new materials, computer, electronic<br />

and optical products) (loc. cit.). This new phase<br />

of economic restructuring can be dated back to<br />

China’s accession to the World Trade Organization<br />

(WTO) in 2001. The implementation of<br />

economic restructuring policies has gained substantial<br />

impetus in the wake of the “financial


F. Schröder / M. Waibel: Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta 99<br />

tsunami”, as the global financial crisis was labeled<br />

in the PRD, that has laid off thousands of<br />

mostly migrant workers in the labor-intensive<br />

industries of textile, toys, and electronic production.<br />

Chinese governments at the national, provincial,<br />

and local levels (i.e. municipal and district-level<br />

governments) have recognized in recent<br />

years that the economic boom of the last<br />

three decades caused environmental costs and<br />

has raised social exclusion. Thus, there is a tendency<br />

away from a mere focus on economic<br />

growth towards policies promoting an improved<br />

quality of the urban economic and living<br />

environment and of social, health, and educational<br />

infrastructure.<br />

Recent statements made by party leaders illustrate<br />

the political momentum for economic upgrading.<br />

For example, Guangdong Communist<br />

Party Secretary Wang Yang maintained: “Our<br />

growth model of 30 years, which enriched us<br />

rapidly, has come to the end of its cycle. … Our<br />

mission is a tough one. We must convince them<br />

that we must change. The old ways of consuming<br />

resources and importing labor will not<br />

work. Even if we wanted to continue with it,<br />

we would be unable to do so – we are running<br />

out of resources and environmental capital.”<br />

And the Guangzhou Party Secretary Zhu Xiao-<br />

dan argued in a similar way: “We’ve paid a<br />

heavy price for rapid growth. (…) We will support<br />

companies at the high end of the value<br />

chain and use industrial parks as a driving<br />

force.” (KUHN 2009a-e) The deeper meaning of<br />

these quotations becomes clear when one considers<br />

the latest ideological framework formulated<br />

by the Communist Party of China (CPC)<br />

in 2003. In order to adapt and adequately cope<br />

with economic and socio-political challenges<br />

on the one hand as well as to maintain supreme<br />

authority and political legitimacy on the other,<br />

the CPCoffers rathervague, but formative ideological<br />

guidelines phrased <strong>und</strong>er the concept of<br />

“Socialism with Chinese characteristics”. Under<br />

this framework, Hu Jintao, General Secretary<br />

of the CPC and President of the PRC, has<br />

been promoting a new approach to developement,<br />

i.e. the “scientific development concept”.<br />

The stated idea behind this concept and behind<br />

scientific development is to “take people as the<br />

main thing, establish a concept of comprehensive,<br />

coordinated, sustainable development, and<br />

promote comprehensive economic, social, and<br />

human development” (FEWSMITH 2004, 3).<br />

Hence, “scientific development” is ultimately<br />

to lead to the construction of a “harmonious society”<br />

and will thus officially change China’s<br />

focus from mere economic growth to promoting<br />

economic, social, and environmental development<br />

(HEBERER/SCHUBERT 2008, 203;<br />

Tab. 1: GDP growth and per capita GDP in the Pearl River Delta and its two major cities<br />

Guangzhou and Shenzhen<br />

2000 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009<br />

Pearl River Delta (total)<br />

GDP growth (compared<br />

to previous year, %)<br />

Per capita GDP<br />

13.7 15.7 16.8 16.3 12.8 9.4<br />

(in Chinese Yuan)<br />

Guangzhou<br />

GDP growth (compared<br />

20,280 40,336 47,241 55,048 63,065 67,407<br />

to previous year, %)<br />

Per capita GDP<br />

13.3 12.9 14.9 15.3 12.5 11.7<br />

(in Chinese Yuan)<br />

Shenzhen<br />

GDP growth (compared<br />

25,626 53,809 63,184 72,123 81,941 89,082<br />

to previous year, %) 15.7 15.1 16.6 14.8 12.1 10.7<br />

Per capita GDP<br />

(in Chinese Yuan)<br />

32,800 60,801 69,450 79,645 89,587 92,772<br />

Source: Guangdong Statistical Yearbook 2010


100 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

SCHOON 2011). Evidently, those slogans are still<br />

<strong>und</strong>erfed with a great deal of propaganda, but<br />

the implementation of economic restructuring<br />

policies can be certainly regarded as an essential<br />

step towards an economy that is less polluting<br />

and offers a higher quality of life.<br />

Trickled down to the provincial level, the new<br />

guiding principle has led to the most important<br />

cornerstone of economic upgrading and restructuring<br />

in the PRD, the “Plan for the reform and<br />

development of the Pearl River Delta (2008-<br />

2020)” issued by the National Development<br />

and Reform Commission in December 2008<br />

(SCHRÖDER/WAIBEL 2010, 2). Its main aim is to<br />

build up a maturing industrial system by prioritizing<br />

the development of modern service industries,<br />

as well as vigorously speeding up the<br />

development of advanced manufacturing with a<br />

focus on high-tech development. The plan promotes<br />

to substantially increase “gross domestic<br />

expenditure on research and development”<br />

(GERD) investments. Embedded into the central<br />

government’s initiatives such as the<br />

Eleventh Five Year Plan for National Economic<br />

and Social Development of PR China or the<br />

Program for Mid- and Long-term Development<br />

of Science & Technology (2006 to 2020) this<br />

means an envisaged increase of research and<br />

development (R&D) intensity to 2.5 % of GDP<br />

until 2020 1 (loc.cit.).<br />

With regard to this paper’s question of how urban<br />

spaces are developed and locational policies<br />

are implemented against the backgro<strong>und</strong> of<br />

economic restructuring, a very important and<br />

often <strong>und</strong>erestimated factor of relevance for<br />

China’s rapid and constantly high economic<br />

growth over the last 30 years is the pragmatic<br />

and flexible experimental approach. It has been<br />

introduced by the post-Mao regime to test economic<br />

reforms in distinct spatial entities first<br />

and, in the case of success, extend them to other<br />

regions in the country. In the Western conventional<br />

<strong>und</strong>erstanding, legislation takes place<br />

in advance of implementation. In China (and in<br />

other transitional countries such as Vietnam),<br />

the mode of testing or experimenting and therefore<br />

implementation before formal legislation<br />

has proved a pragmatic tool in this rapidly<br />

changing and highly heterogeneous spatial,<br />

structural, and socio-economic environment (LIN<br />

2001, 387; NG/TANG 2004, 181). Reformer Deng<br />

Xiaoping famously characterized this experimental<br />

approach as “groping the stones while<br />

crossing the river”. Experimental forms of gov-<br />

ernance mostly include the informal testing of<br />

strategies or tools before formalizing them. The<br />

Pearl River Delta region is a perfect showcase<br />

for this experimental strategy.<br />

This has also wider implications in terms of urban<br />

governance. As our research shows, the development<br />

of Guangzhou Science City (GSC) is<br />

accompanied by a high flexibility and experimental<br />

character that involves a change in the relationship<br />

between private companies and the local<br />

state. This change became necessary because<br />

state officials needed to cooperate with private<br />

companies to achieve their predetermined development<br />

goals. Before going into the case study,<br />

we will have a closer look at the concepts of urban<br />

governance and informality illustrating their<br />

value for analyzing economic restructuring and<br />

the reproduction of space in Guangzhou.<br />

Narrowing the <strong>und</strong>erstanding of urban<br />

governance and informality<br />

Governance is an ambiguous concept developed<br />

from a discourse mainly in North America and<br />

Western Europe. It deals with socio-economic<br />

interdependencies that have been changing<br />

since the late 1970s (JESSOP 1995, 309; KOOI-<br />

MAN 2005, 150; MAYNTZ 2005, 13). It emphasizes<br />

that the idea of the state as key actor in political<br />

decision-making, its exclusive responsibility<br />

for fulfilling state functions and duties, as<br />

well as its influence on the economy and society<br />

is increasingly changing. This often implies a<br />

shift in <strong>und</strong>erstanding of political processes<br />

away from government towards governance.<br />

Whereas government denotes decision-making<br />

that lies solely within the state and its institutions,<br />

governance refers to altered interrelations<br />

between state, society, and the economy and the<br />

increasing importance of less directive forms of<br />

political regulation (cooperative and non-hierarchical),<br />

e.g., political coordination or negotiation<br />

in networks (PIERRE/PETERS 2000, 12).<br />

Can such an admittedly fuzzy concept, stressing<br />

the increasing role of non-hierarchical forms of<br />

regulation, help to <strong>und</strong>erstand highly state-controlled<br />

processes in urban China? The authors<br />

believe that this question must be answered in<br />

the affirmative. First of all, the emergence of the<br />

governance paradigm stands for the adoption of<br />

a wider analytical perspective in political science.<br />

Secondly, it is maintained that <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />

it as an analytical concept (rather than as


F. Schröder / M. Waibel: Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta 101<br />

manifestation of a postulated changed global reality)<br />

(PIERRE 2005, 451ff.) can create an awareness<br />

of structures and processes influencing policymaking<br />

that would otherwise be overlooked.<br />

Processes describe what actors can do, i.e., regulation<br />

(via incentives or hierarchical command)<br />

or coordination (BENZ et al. 2007, 16; PIERRE/<br />

PETERS 2000, 22). Structures are <strong>und</strong>erstood here<br />

as institutional contexts in which actors are able<br />

to operate (hierarchies, markets, networks, communities,<br />

associations). This allows analyzing<br />

how regulation and coordination occur within a<br />

defined policy field, such as economic restructuring,<br />

or in a spatially distinguished area. With<br />

regard to China’s gradual transition process and<br />

its highly dynamic urban development processes<br />

serving as arena for current economic upgrading<br />

processes, this analytical governance approach<br />

helps to entangle the complex forces <strong>und</strong>erlying<br />

urban affairs in China.<br />

Urban governance<br />

In comparative urban politics, governance is<br />

conceived as a coordination process of political<br />

Fig. 1: Integrative model of urban governance<br />

Source: DIGAETANTO/STROM 2003, 372; modified<br />

decisions in the urban and economic spheres.<br />

Derived from the structural perspective of political<br />

economy, it is based on the notion that governing<br />

procedures at the national, regional, and<br />

local levels; market forces; and economic as<br />

well as social structures set the context of urban<br />

governance (DIGAETANO/STROM 2003, 362).<br />

However, an exclusively structural approach often<br />

lacks an encompassing consideration of the<br />

complex set of influences and processes in urban<br />

affairs, such as cultural impacts as well as<br />

the different actors and stakeholders involved.<br />

This is particularly problematic in China, which<br />

is influenced, among other aspects, by a long<br />

tradition of cultural factors and the influential<br />

role of powerful leaders (such as Mao Zedong or<br />

Deng Xiaoping). The significant deficiency of<br />

single-level explanation is surmounted by the<br />

comprehensive approach of DIGAETANO/STROM<br />

(2003), the biggest advantage of which is the integration<br />

of three middle-range theories, i.e.,<br />

structuralism, culturalism, and rational choice.<br />

With its merit as integrative analytical tool, this<br />

approach will be subject to our analysis of go-


102 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

verning structures in terms of economic restructuring<br />

in Guangzhou.<br />

DIGAETANO/STROM (2003) have highlighted the<br />

importance of each approach, structural, cultural,<br />

and rational-choice, as well as their dynamic<br />

interdependencies. Therefore, they have endeavored<br />

to integrate all three into a single<br />

framework. As an outcome, three interrelated<br />

levels of analysis are identified: (1) The structural<br />

context (e.g. political decentralization,<br />

transition, economic globalization) frames political<br />

decision-making, including over time; (2)<br />

political culture (beliefs, values, symbols) gives<br />

meaning to political organization and decisionmaking<br />

2; and (3) political actors who attempt to<br />

influence governmental decision-making in<br />

ways that benefit themselves and the interests<br />

they represent. In this context, political actors<br />

include all actors participating in urban governance<br />

processes, i.e., public as well as private<br />

and social actors or stakeholders. The three<br />

spheres of analysis trickle down to influence the<br />

institutional milieu, <strong>und</strong>erstood as the set of all<br />

formal and informal institutions that moderate<br />

the different analytical spheres and are crucial<br />

for their integration (Fig. 1).<br />

The role of informality<br />

Informality plays a crucial role when looking at<br />

governance processes, since it is evident that no<br />

political system, not even in the liberal democracies<br />

of Western Europe, functions solely on<br />

the basis of formal structures and processes<br />

(DANIELS 2004). Decision-making or political<br />

systems are not only the sum of formal institutional<br />

structures, but a mixture of formal and informal<br />

institutions (DIGAETANO/STROM 2003,<br />

363). We <strong>und</strong>erstand institutions (both formal<br />

and informal) with regard to the work of NORTH<br />

(1990: 3) as “rules of the game in a society or<br />

[…] the humanly devised constraints that shape<br />

human interaction”.<br />

Informality in urban and economic development<br />

processes takes place within a complex set of relationships<br />

between different actors, regulations,<br />

and ways of decision-making. It is thus <strong>und</strong>erstood<br />

here as interaction-related institution<br />

defining informality according to social or economic<br />

interaction. This interaction-related informality<br />

is associated with “contractual relationships<br />

between different individuals or organizations<br />

(tiers of government may be among them,<br />

but do not embody the state as producer of legal<br />

norms)” (ALTROCK et al. 2008, 5). It describes<br />

all forms of political activities that are not traceable<br />

and laid down in written documents. These<br />

may be debates and discussions that find consideration<br />

in decision-making processes beyond<br />

a legal framework as well as all interaction between<br />

individuals and organizations, that accompany<br />

planning processes or contracts, but<br />

are not written down. Interaction-related informality<br />

can contribute to mutual <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />

without explicit interaction and thus reduce<br />

complexity while enhancing flexibility (loc.<br />

cit.).<br />

Despite a seemingly clear distinction between<br />

formal and informal constraints, no single political<br />

procedure can be characterized as being of<br />

either formal or informal character altogether<br />

(KIRCHBERGER 2004, 10). Thus, informality is<br />

not necessarily contradictory to formal processes<br />

or official rules, neither should it be <strong>und</strong>erstood<br />

as a deviation from the norm (i.e., formal<br />

institutions). Close and complex links between<br />

and overlaps of formal and informal spheres exist<br />

in all political systems. This makes it rather<br />

difficult to distinguish clearly between formal<br />

and informal (loc.cit. 11), a factor that has to be<br />

kept in mind when investigating decision-making<br />

processes. Governance analysis reveals the<br />

specific strength of the formal-informal modes<br />

of a political system, as well as their interrelations,<br />

which shed light on the „real function“<br />

(KÖLLNER 2005, 27) of a political system and<br />

are therefore of eminent importance for analysis.<br />

To <strong>und</strong>erstand how a city is governed with<br />

its different policies and strategies can only be<br />

<strong>und</strong>erstood when both formal and informal rules<br />

and negotiations are analyzed (loc.cit.; see also<br />

KIRCHBERGER 2004).<br />

Informality – part of the game in<br />

the Pearl River Delta<br />

In the Pearl River Delta (PRD), a very active<br />

state has been experimenting with flexible<br />

deregulation within rigid institutional settings<br />

since the start of the reform process more than<br />

30 years ago. As a result, informality is constantly<br />

being produced, which <strong>und</strong>erlines ROY’s<br />

(2009, 826) argument that informality is located<br />

within the scope of the state rather than outside<br />

of it. Though formal political institutions mature<br />

and become increasingly effective, informality<br />

remains robust and important in Chinese socioeconomic<br />

politics (FUKUI 2000). However, informal<br />

institutions, like any socio-economic


F. Schröder / M. Waibel: Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta 103<br />

phenomenon, have changed and have been<br />

transformed over time and space (ALTROCK<br />

2012; FUKUI 2000, 13; WAIBEL 2008).<br />

The prominence of informality in China is<br />

closely related to the country’s political culture.<br />

Thus, one rather conventional explanation<br />

why informal institutions are so pervasive in<br />

China is suggested by PYE (1985): “In most situations,<br />

whether in the party, the bureaucracy,<br />

or in nongovernmental institutions such as<br />

schools and factories, too many people are<br />

waiting in line for advancement and too few<br />

options exist for the formal procedures to do<br />

the job of selection. Therefore everyone must<br />

prudently seek guanxi ties […]. Within the<br />

Chinese bureaucracy the formal regulations<br />

tend to be overly constrictive, producing cumbersome<br />

procedures and little effective action.<br />

[…] hence the informal structures of power<br />

built through the guanxi networks often serve<br />

as the most effective way of getting the state’s<br />

business done.” In such a context, informality<br />

is mostly attributed to excessive state regulations<br />

(ROY/ALSAYYAD 2004, 13). Doubtlessly,<br />

the fact that the PRD has one of the most complex<br />

administrative systems in the world with<br />

multiple jurisdictions is conducive to such<br />

kinds of informality (ENRIGHT et al. 2005, 233).<br />

A more comprehensive analysis of specific<br />

Chinese informal institutions made by social<br />

scientists over the last three decades has revealed<br />

a multiplicity of factors explaining their<br />

origin (KIRCHBERGER 2004, 17), including:<br />

– The particular cultural path of institutions<br />

based on the Confucian tradition and the political<br />

culture formed by the socialist revolution.<br />

One example of the historical continuities<br />

is the duality between the formal Confucian<br />

respect for thoughtful, selfless, and<br />

public-minded manners on the one hand and<br />

the self-seeking, interest-driven, and exchange-mediated<br />

behavior in actual life on<br />

the other.<br />

– The importance of interpersonal relationships,<br />

so-called guanxi. Political influence is<br />

applied through subtle, culturally sanctioned<br />

behavior by way of exchanges of favors and<br />

repayment of commitment (FUKUI 2000,<br />

15 f.).<br />

– There is a lack of a rule-of-law tradition.<br />

– The closely interlinked party-state structure,<br />

which creates structural latitude. It is characterized<br />

by the parallel party-state structure,<br />

which allows for and encompasses diverse<br />

and often opaque linkages between vertical<br />

and horizontal lines of authorities (HEBERER/<br />

SCHUBERT 2004; HEILMANN 2004).<br />

However, the list might be arbitrarily continued.<br />

What is distinctive in the way informality<br />

is used in China is that there is an amalgamation<br />

of formalities and – importantly – a pragmatic<br />

use of informal relationships. Informality will<br />

most likely not disappear altogether. On the<br />

contrary, it is the way in which informality is<br />

practiced that changes over time.<br />

Apparently, the Chinese state and its local representatives<br />

at various levels engage in an ambiguous<br />

set of practices concerning the role of<br />

informality. ALTROCK/SCHOON (2009) coined<br />

the term “conceded informality” for this phenomenon.<br />

The term emphasizes the pro-active<br />

state that tolerates informal practices where<br />

they are functional (see also WAIBEL 2008;<br />

2009; WAIBEL/GRAVERT 2009). This cooptation<br />

of informal structures to serve formal government<br />

has a long tradition in China. Conceded<br />

informality seeks to abandon the dichotomy between<br />

formal and informal. LEAF (2005) speaks<br />

of cooperative governance between formal and<br />

informal structures, for example. The extent to<br />

which informality is tolerated, used, or promoted<br />

depends on a variety of determinants such as<br />

the power of the state to formulate regulations<br />

and policies; the availability of resources in the<br />

public sector; global, national, and regional<br />

economic competitiveness; and global influences<br />

on socio-cultural aspects. Specific patterns<br />

and attitudes dealing with informality in<br />

China, and in the PRD in particular, have been<br />

identified by ALTROCK/WAIBEL (2010) and<br />

SCHOON (2010):<br />

– The state “fights” informality, when its major<br />

political objectives are threatened.<br />

– The state “tolerates” informality, when it<br />

serves development.<br />

– The state “promotes” informality, when it<br />

produces new strategic knowledge.<br />

– The state “utilizes” informality, when flexible<br />

guiding principles serve as political strategy.


104 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

This listing shows that the state and its local<br />

representatives take a tactical approach in using<br />

their position as rule-setters. For example, they<br />

may accept informal bottom-up initiatives and<br />

subsequently formalize them, e.g., as an adequate<br />

response to newly emerging problems or<br />

niches, or they can forbid them and, as a consequence,<br />

ban informal institutions. Another more<br />

simple reason for informality in the PRD can be<br />

the lack of state power to efficiently filter<br />

through all spheres of institutions, markets, and<br />

society from the very beginning of the transitional<br />

process (ALTROCK/WAIBEL 2010, 12).<br />

The role of informality in China has wide implications<br />

for urban governance, hence the way<br />

economic restructuring and the accompanied<br />

reproduction of urban areas. Flexible and experimental,<br />

testing and learning arrangements<br />

are expected to being applied by local state and<br />

private (i.e. companies) actors for the implementation<br />

of economic restructuring policies.<br />

Changing urban governance in<br />

the Pearl River Delta<br />

In China, urban governance is characterized by<br />

a high degree of state, especially local government,<br />

control in urban policies (NG/TANG 2004,<br />

175). Since the implementation of market reforms<br />

in the late 1970s, the central government<br />

does no longer exercise an all-embracing topdown<br />

control over economy and society<br />

(CHAN/HU 2004, 10; NG/TANG 2004, 175; XU/<br />

WANG 2002, 250). In fact, economic, administrative,<br />

and fiscal decentralization has taken<br />

place throughout China since the start of the reform<br />

process, although politically, there has<br />

been no significant sign of devolution (CHIEN<br />

2008, 3). The combination of new market elements<br />

and decentralized state apparatus has offered<br />

ab<strong>und</strong>ant flexibility especially for local<br />

governments in pursuing extrabudgetary revenues<br />

to facilitate entrepreneurialism in urban<br />

development (WU 2002, 1075). Though still<br />

strong, the predominant role of the central state<br />

has been softened in many aspects of urban<br />

change, new players from the private sector appeared<br />

in shaping the urban landscape. The<br />

prevalent mono-player arena has changed towards<br />

a multiplayer arena with multifaceted interactions<br />

of central and local governments, domestic<br />

and foreign investors and businesses (HE<br />

et al. 2006, 432). All in all, the transition from<br />

planned to market economy, the policy of open-<br />

ing up and increasing integration into the world<br />

market, as well as learning processes and capacity<br />

building within the country have directed<br />

changes in the control, provision, and coordination<br />

mechanisms over time (WUTTKE 2009,<br />

11). In other words, the gradual implementation<br />

of the reform process in China is causing constant<br />

change in the “rules of the game”. This<br />

implies changing governance arrangements, as<br />

well.<br />

In particular, local governments, i.e. municipal<br />

and urban district governments, have become<br />

key actors of economic and urban regulation<br />

processes. Increased competition between<br />

cities vying to attract companies and investments,<br />

but also environmental degradation and<br />

social and spatial fragmentation are significant<br />

challenges for China’s metropolises. This in<br />

turn requires the constant adaptation of urban<br />

development strategies. The increased importance<br />

of local governments and of private companies<br />

for overall economic welfare has<br />

strengthened their role in decision-making. The<br />

autonomy allows them – to a certain degree –<br />

to <strong>und</strong>ertake independent planning, political<br />

decisions, as well as legislative and executive<br />

governmental functions. Moreover, despite its<br />

function as regulatory instance, the local state<br />

authorities have gained responsibility in the<br />

promotion of local economic growth and, for<br />

the first time, had to apply location policies of<br />

their own to lure companies and capital. This<br />

forces them to involve stakeholders, their<br />

needs and aspirations and thus adapt a demandside<br />

approach guiding of their locational policies.<br />

How this rather customer-oriented approach<br />

is implemented will be shown in the<br />

subsequent section of this paper.<br />

The realignment of state, market and society with<br />

a changing role of local governments has been<br />

explained by different authors as the local state<br />

incrementally following the logic of economicentrepreneurial<br />

action (cf. “autonomous local<br />

governments”, LAQUIAN 2005; “local state corporatism”,<br />

OI 1992, 1995; “entrepreneurial city”,<br />

JESSOP/SUM 2000; WU 2002, 2003; WU et al.<br />

2007; “local developmental state”, ZHU 2004).<br />

Case study of Guangzhou Science City<br />

Methodology<br />

The integrated framework of urban governance<br />

developed by DIGAETANO/STROM (2003) has


F. Schröder / M. Waibel: Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta 105<br />

been applied to the case study of the Guangzhou<br />

Science City (GSC) development and its<br />

locational policies. Concretely, how the reproduction<br />

of this urban area and its locational<br />

policies are governed in order to enforce economic<br />

restructuring is analyzed by looking at<br />

the relationships and interactions between different<br />

actors and stakeholders in the public and<br />

private sectors (governing relations, in the terminology<br />

of DiGaetano/Strom), the way decisions<br />

are made (governing logic), the impact of<br />

key decision-makers, and their political objectives.<br />

The analysis is based on qualitative, semi-structured<br />

interviews conducted in 2009 and 2010.<br />

Two main groups of interviewees were selected<br />

for interviews. The first, stakeholders, consisted<br />

of individuals with a potential stake in the development<br />

and locational policies of GSC, such<br />

as members of governmental bodies, planning<br />

bureaus, companies located within GSC, and<br />

residents, among them villagers affected by<br />

eviction, living in the area of interest; the second,<br />

experts, was made up of professionals<br />

such as academic staff and planning experts that<br />

were not directly involved in locational policies,<br />

but have in-depth knowledge regarding the<br />

case study. Interviews with experts proofed to<br />

be especially valuable for qualifying the wider<br />

economic, political context. Altogether, 35 interviews<br />

were conducted; of which eleven with<br />

experts and 24 with stakeholders. The research<br />

is complemented by an intensive review of governmental<br />

documents, newspaper articles and<br />

scientific literature.<br />

According to our research experience, in China,<br />

governance is frequently equated with participation<br />

in the realm of civil society. Having been<br />

warned that in China, research in the field of<br />

governance is often mis<strong>und</strong>erstood as looking<br />

for incidences of corruption, we frequently used<br />

the term “urban management” doing interviews,<br />

particularly when talking to political<br />

leaders.<br />

Guangzhou Science City – a symbol of<br />

economic upgrading<br />

Guangzhou Science City (GSC) has been selected<br />

as a showcase project, which represents a<br />

spatial cluster of the higher value-added sector<br />

and stands for the attempt to upgrade the local<br />

economy (HE 2006, 205; WANG/HUANG 2007,<br />

18). From an analytical governance perspec-<br />

tive, its development is rather innovative. In<br />

contrast to earlier developments, it is the result<br />

of a comprehensive urban development strategy<br />

and therefore represents much more than a<br />

mere economic entity with high-tech focus: The<br />

formerly strict division of industrial and urban<br />

residential and commercial areas is loosened.<br />

Besides building a new administrative center as<br />

well as living area, the entire district, in which<br />

GSC is located, has been planned as comprehensive<br />

urban environment to become an integral<br />

part of the whole metropolis. Moreover, as<br />

part of the Plan for the reform and development<br />

of the Pearl River Delta (2008-2020) promoting<br />

the restructuring of the PRD’s economic<br />

base, GSC is a very illustrative example for the<br />

interplay of economic upgrading and comprehensive<br />

urban development strategies.<br />

Located in the eastern part of Guangzhou and<br />

comprising a total planning area of nearly 45<br />

km 2 , GSC constitutes the linchpin of the<br />

Guangzhou high-tech industrial development<br />

zone (GHIDZ). As part of Guangzhou’s Urban<br />

development concept plan established in 2000,<br />

the city’s east is intended to serve as a center for<br />

high-tech development (XU/YEH 2003). The<br />

area has been strategically important for<br />

Guangzhou’s economy since the early 1980s,<br />

encompassing four national-level special economic<br />

areas (Guangzhou Economic and Technological<br />

Development District GETDD,<br />

Guangzhou Hi-Tech Industrial Development<br />

Zone GHIDZ, Guangzhou Free Trade Zone<br />

GFTZ, and Guangzhou Export Processing Zone<br />

GEPZ). These economic areas were merged <strong>und</strong>er<br />

a single joint administration in 2002 and renamed<br />

the Guangzhou Development District<br />

(GDD) (SCHRÖDER/WAIBEL 2010, 70).<br />

As priority project for economic upgrading<br />

along the value chain, GSC is supposed to<br />

develop into a flagship high-tech park with a<br />

focus on information technology, bioscence,<br />

pharmaceutical, and environmental industries.<br />

Besides building a new center and a residential<br />

area, the area as a whole is planned as a comprehensive<br />

urban environment, including the<br />

provision of the social, educational, and administrative<br />

infrastructure elements required to<br />

make it an integral part of the overall city (HE<br />

2006, 205). In this regard, it not only serves as<br />

a location for the attraction of knowledge-intensive<br />

companies, but is also designed to attract a<br />

qualified white-collar workforce to work and<br />

live in this area. Further, it is anticipated that


106 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

GSC will relieve the core city and contribute to<br />

a more polycentric urban development.<br />

Governance in the development phase of GSC<br />

The analysis of governing relations, governing<br />

logic, political objectives, and key stakeholders<br />

in the development of GSC reveals a mode of<br />

strongly (local) government-led initiation as<br />

well as implementation. However, needs and<br />

interests of companies but also of inhabitants<br />

have been increasingly considered. This has not<br />

taken place via direct participation but in panels<br />

and mostly informal exchange where experts,<br />

selected elites, and companies take part in. Surveys<br />

served to give insights on the needs of local<br />

population, which were included in the<br />

planning process (TANG et al. 2008; WUTTKE et<br />

al. 2010).<br />

Guangzhou municipality and its relevant administrative<br />

bodies already initiated the project<br />

of GSC in 1998, led the master planning and selected<br />

the site. Together with district-level government<br />

bodies they were responsible for project<br />

implementation. However, key decisions<br />

have been finalized by high officials (on municipal<br />

and district level), whose personal development<br />

visions apparently influenced the<br />

planning proposals. A common occurrence in<br />

China’s urban planning is the involvement of so<br />

called experts as consultants from outsourced<br />

or privatized urban management research institutes<br />

or planning bureaus to aid in shaping the<br />

economic reforms (LEAF/HOU 2006; TANG et al.<br />

2008; WONG et al. 2006). Accordingly, Chinese<br />

research and planning institutes were directly<br />

approached by governing bodies to participate<br />

in functional planning and design of the master<br />

plans for GSC.<br />

Besides municipal and district planning departments,<br />

private and international planning bureaus<br />

were allowed to participate in the development<br />

process as well. This is a new phenomenon<br />

as a result of strategic planning,<br />

established in Guangzhou in the year 2000.<br />

Strategic planning has emerged as an important<br />

tool to respond quickly to the development and<br />

control needs of local governments (LEAF/HOU<br />

2006, 569; SCHRÖDER/WAIBEL 2010, 74). It has<br />

been arisen from initiatives by local municipal<br />

governments supplementing conventional master<br />

planning which was considered as static and<br />

inadequate to respond to rapid socio-economic<br />

and urban spatial change. The Guangzhou Concept<br />

Plan 2000 was the first strategic tool for<br />

urban development implemented in China<br />

(WANG et al. 2001, 5; WU/ZHANG 2007, 719).<br />

This procedure is a perfect example of experimental<br />

governance in China. First tested in<br />

Guangzhou and subsequently Hangzhou (Concept<br />

Plan of Hangzhou), these two plans are<br />

now being followed by other cities in China.<br />

Strategic planning as it is <strong>und</strong>erstood and practiced<br />

in China is <strong>und</strong>ertaken to support localized<br />

economic targets in line with attracting and<br />

Fig. 2: Changing involvement of key stakeholders during the development process of<br />

Guangzhou Science City<br />

Source: own design


F. Schröder / M. Waibel: Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta 107<br />

guiding capital investment. It addresses more<br />

flexible aspects of urbanization such as development<br />

directions, which are soft, rather vague<br />

formulated as future targets in urban development<br />

and land use. These directions are beyond<br />

what is considered by the physical planning orientation<br />

of formal statutory planning (LEAF/<br />

HOU 2006, 569).<br />

Moreover, semi-private or special purpose associations<br />

have been involved to take over<br />

functions that were formerly the prerogative of<br />

the administration; most importantly in the development<br />

of GSC these are investment consultancies.<br />

They not only served as negotiation<br />

part in the realm of the district government<br />

when it came to relocation processes of villages<br />

located within the planning bo<strong>und</strong>aries. They<br />

also have close relationships with companies<br />

located in the area. They share believes and experiences<br />

with local governments and give suggestions<br />

due to their in depth knowledge about<br />

companies’ and their workforces’ needs. Together<br />

with the governments’ own mostly informal<br />

exchanges with companies and with overseas<br />

experiences, these suggestions form the<br />

basis of decision-making processes in the case<br />

of developing GSC. Face-to-face communication,<br />

e.g. during regular meetings within companies<br />

or symposiums with businesses, is used<br />

to learn about changing needs and demands of<br />

companies, workforce and inhabitants (mostly<br />

white collar). Collected needs and aspirations<br />

are condensed and presented to the local People’s<br />

Congress (PC) and the Chinese People’s<br />

Source: WAIBEL/SCHRÖDEr 2009<br />

Political Consultative Conference (CPPCC) to<br />

be discussed and revised. Accordingly, planning<br />

strategies are constantly revised and adapted.<br />

In sum, though not formal involved in the development<br />

process, non-state actors such as experts,<br />

companies and white-collar workforce<br />

are apparently indirectly involved building-up<br />

informal arrangements with governing bodies<br />

and therefore influencing changing urban development<br />

strategies (see Fig. 2). However, these<br />

informal arrangements are open to a small group<br />

of selected people, only. For example, the ordinary<br />

population of the villages located within<br />

Luogang District has not been included: About<br />

60,000 of them had been relocated in the course<br />

of the development of GSC since 2004. However,<br />

participation was limited to a survey on their<br />

housing conditions <strong>und</strong>ertaken on behalf on the<br />

management committee as well as to exclusionary<br />

negotiations with the village heads.<br />

All in all, it can be said, that the deliberate use<br />

of informal arrangements in the development of<br />

GSC served local officials to learn from exogenous<br />

experiences via interactions with foreign,<br />

returning overseas Chinese, and domestic investors.<br />

In this regard, investment, especially<br />

foreign direct investment can not only be regarded<br />

as a driver for economic growth but also<br />

an important channel of knowledge diffusion<br />

for changing urban governance processes<br />

(CHIEN/ZHAO 2008). There is a close connection<br />

between urban development strategies and<br />

locational policies of GSC since the compre-<br />

Fig. 3: Residential-, leisure- and work-spaces in Gouangzhou Science City


108 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

hensive development approach adopted for establishing<br />

GSC can be viewed as part of an<br />

overall strategy to enhance the area’s attractiveness<br />

for investors and white-collar people to<br />

work and live in GSC.<br />

Locational policies and the role of informality<br />

in Guangzhou Science City<br />

The raison d’être of special economic areas in<br />

China is to attract investors and therefore to<br />

gain revenues. In times of economic restructuring,<br />

it no longer suffices for the management<br />

bodies to offer a fenced mono-functional industrial<br />

area, as was the case 20 years ago. Nowadays,<br />

the message of economic upgrading and<br />

advancement along the value chain is the most<br />

important driver in locational policies. As a result,<br />

clean and liveable urban environments<br />

with a lot of greenery and flagship architecture<br />

are introduced to a highly competitive market.<br />

This is especially true for GSC. Here, locational<br />

policies can be seen as an interplay of three<br />

important tools: (1) hard incentive schemes; (2)<br />

a comprehensive approach in designing the<br />

physical outline of the area; and (3) soft incentive<br />

schemes. Hard incentive schemes are<br />

means from the classical toolbox of economic<br />

development and investment attraction. In<br />

GSC, these include the provision of technical<br />

infrastructure such as roads, gas, electricity,<br />

etc., economic incentives such as tax reductions<br />

and tax holidays, low or no land use fees, including<br />

discounted rentals, low energy costs,<br />

and physical infrastructure such as an incubator<br />

center for start-up companies to rent out lab and<br />

office space or a special f<strong>und</strong>ing program for attracting<br />

start-up companies.<br />

GSC is planned for development into a comprehensive<br />

urban area. It is intended that “urban<br />

liveability” and “quality of life” will be created<br />

by the integration of various urban functions<br />

specifically, housing, education, leisure and<br />

amenities, and generous provision of greenery<br />

and space in general (Fig. 3). The simple assumption<br />

behind this new approach in regard to<br />

the physical outline of GSC is that the more<br />

qualified (white-collar and presumably creative)<br />

workforce working in knowledge-intensive<br />

companies and living in the area is expected<br />

to have different needs and aspirations concerning<br />

the urban environment than lowerqualified<br />

(blue-collar) people working in laborintensive<br />

industries.<br />

Eventually, soft incentive schemes are formed<br />

aro<strong>und</strong> different informal, flexible, and trustbuilding<br />

services provided by the zone management<br />

and semi-private or special purpose associations<br />

such as investment consultancies. In<br />

GSC, these include openness regarding information<br />

policies towards companies, pragmatism,<br />

service orientation, and particularly<br />

network promotion activities. The latter encompasses<br />

various different layers of communication<br />

between companies, between companies<br />

and organizations (e.g., chambers of commerce,<br />

investment consultancies), and between companies<br />

and the government that serve to enhance<br />

relationships and knowledge diffusion. This<br />

mainly takes place in informal meetings at<br />

lunch, dinner, during breaks at conferences or<br />

club events such as a yearly golf tournament organized<br />

by the Guangzhou Multinational Corporation<br />

Club (MNCC). The primary aim of the<br />

network promotion activities is to increase<br />

communication between companies with the<br />

aim of fostering some kind of “innovative milieu”.<br />

Our research fo<strong>und</strong> that this multi-layered,<br />

complex net also serves another important<br />

purpose: It allows the management body to get<br />

information on the needs and aspirations of<br />

companies and their workforce. This information<br />

gained by interaction-based informality is<br />

highly appreciated, because it allows development<br />

strategies and location policies to be frequently<br />

adjusted in order to remain attractive<br />

for the companies. In this respect, learning<br />

processes may be <strong>und</strong>erstood here as “learning<br />

by interacting” (LIEFNER 2008). Such learning<br />

processes are evidently crucial drivers for the<br />

flexible adaptation of governance processes towards<br />

economic restructuring (SCHRÖDER/WAI-<br />

BEL 2010, 78).<br />

A soft incentive feature that may be less publicized,<br />

but was often mentioned during our interviews<br />

with companies is the zone management’s<br />

pragmatism and service orientation. In<br />

this context, pragmatism means a flexible approach<br />

in dealing with (formal) regularities. A<br />

striking example for this is the management<br />

body’s pragmatic dealing with registration policies.<br />

Apparently, enterprises are not necessarily<br />

obliged to be physically located within the area<br />

of GSC itself. Apparently, it is sufficient just to<br />

be classified as a high-tech company by the<br />

government to enjoy the zone’s preferential<br />

policies. Furthermore, the zone management of<br />

GSC has a high reputation for its service orientation,<br />

efficiency, and professionalism, and tries<br />

to resolve any issues arising for companies


F. Schröder / M. Waibel: Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta 109<br />

within a few days. Further services include<br />

training courses for start-up companies in the<br />

fields of business development, tax regulations,<br />

and acquisition of financial support. Apparently,<br />

the specific, increasingly institutionalized interaction<br />

between management body and the<br />

companies over time in the area of GSC has<br />

contributed to – in terms of SCHAMP (2003, 151)<br />

– time- and space-specific institutional arrangements<br />

that rest on path dependencies but at the<br />

same time have the potential of establishing<br />

new structures for action.<br />

Our research reveals that comprehensive urban<br />

planning and soft incentive schemes are becoming<br />

more and more important in the course<br />

of economic upgrading, and that these factors<br />

can provide a decisive local advantage in competition<br />

with other spatial economic entities.<br />

This has been confirmed by interviews with<br />

stakeholders and experts. Hard incentive<br />

schemes have become increasingly ubiquitous<br />

among special economic areas all over China,<br />

and have therefore become less significant as a<br />

location factor. Anyway, the significance of<br />

these zones decreased after China’s WTO entry<br />

was followed by the gradual reduction of preferential<br />

policies and economic incentives. Certainly,<br />

the fierce competition between special<br />

economic areas has promoted the deliberate use<br />

of informal arrangements and therefore higher<br />

flexibility regarding the governance of economic<br />

entities in China.<br />

Conclusion<br />

It has been illustrated that the shift from laborintensive<br />

towards higher value-added and capital-intensive<br />

industries is actively promoted by<br />

national, provincial, and local governing bodies<br />

in China’s “factory of the world”, the Pearl River<br />

Delta. The upgrading process apparently requires<br />

new urban development strategies and<br />

locational policies as well as innovative governance<br />

constellations. In the tradition of the Chinese<br />

transitional process, which is based on experimental<br />

approaches, informality is being<br />

produced and applied in a flexible way. By analyzing<br />

the development of GSC and its locational<br />

policies, this paper has argued that interaction-based<br />

informality is used as a tool of<br />

flexibility as well as of experimental policies attracting<br />

knowledge-intensive industries and a<br />

highly educated workforce. The pursuit of competiveness<br />

and the importance of learning are<br />

immanent features of this process. Since hard<br />

incentives, such as the provision of a reliable<br />

technical infrastructure, are no longer unique<br />

selling propositions, new strategies have to be<br />

identified as means of distinction. The management<br />

body of GSC is applying a wide range of<br />

rather informal strategies in its development<br />

strategies and location policies. This is apparently<br />

happening despite a very clear and highly<br />

transparent regulatory framework guiding investments<br />

and development procedures.<br />

Thus, the competitiveness of GSC results to a<br />

large extent from high flexibility and service<br />

orientation towards incoming companies, mostly<br />

negotiated in informal interactions. Here, informality<br />

as a mode of flexibility serves as a<br />

strategy in locational policies to create a local<br />

competitive edge. Further, informality is used<br />

as tool for testing and learning. The selective involvement<br />

of private actors and stakeholders in<br />

the development and locational policies of GSC<br />

has been cited as an example. So far, this informal<br />

procedure has mostly taken place via particularistic<br />

and personalized exchanges or, to<br />

use the terminology of DIGAETANO/STROM<br />

(2003), through a rather clientelistic governance<br />

mode. If this approach proves successful<br />

in the long run, we may safely expect it to be<br />

formalized, and then maybe even to become<br />

less selective. This would imply a change of<br />

governance mode towards non-exclusive<br />

arrangements.<br />

Moreover, the use of informality produces new<br />

strategic knowledge in terms of comprehensive<br />

urban development as well as in terms of upgrading<br />

strategies towards a knowledge-based<br />

economy. In this way, the management body of<br />

Guangzhou Science City deliberately uses informality<br />

as a mode of learning. All in all, we<br />

would like to reiterate the important point that it<br />

is the hybrid interconnectedness between informal<br />

and formal practices that makes the location<br />

policies of special economic entities successful.<br />

Therefore, simplistic connotations such<br />

as that of the formal-informal divide, or the implicit<br />

idea of formality as the norm and informality<br />

as a deviation from the norm, are obsolete<br />

when dealing with current urban realities in<br />

China and elsewhere.<br />

Looking at the development of governance and<br />

informality over time in the course of China’s<br />

reform period, it can be stated that in the early<br />

stage of the transitional process, status-related


110 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

informality was widely used as an alternative or<br />

substitute for an inadequate or lacking legislative<br />

framework and non-existing local capacity<br />

(subsumed here <strong>und</strong>er the concept of “institutional<br />

gaps”). In the further course of the reform<br />

period, during the advanced transitional<br />

process, however, informality may be more and<br />

more regarded as a complement to formal<br />

arrangements and to formal ways of interaction<br />

(ALTROCK 2011; WAIBEL 2009).<br />

Linking governance with the notion of informality<br />

reveals the importance of institutions<br />

within the complex and highly dynamic urban<br />

environment of China’s transitional process. In<br />

order to add to the picture of urban governance<br />

and informality in urban China, research on<br />

other policy fields as well as on further spatial<br />

and sectoral arenas is no doubt indispensable.<br />

Grasping informality in China by means of an<br />

analytical governance framework such as the<br />

model of DiGaetano/Strom is certainly a challenge.<br />

First of all, it has to be reflected whether<br />

such a model, developed in a Western context,<br />

is appropriate for analyzing informal processes<br />

in China. Certainly, this framework has to be<br />

adapted to the situation in China. The field research<br />

and subsequent application has shown<br />

advantageous and disadvantageous aspects. Di-<br />

Gaetano/Strom’s model of urban governance is<br />

enticing because of its comprehensive scope,<br />

which integrates three middle-range theories,<br />

i.e., structuralism, culturalism, and rational<br />

choice. But this comprehensive approach calls<br />

for the consideration of a multitude of aspects<br />

(e.g. structures and processes, culture, institutions,<br />

actor-relations) in urban affairs. In this<br />

way, it reveals challenges in research that might<br />

finally lead to a lack of theoretical and empirical<br />

depth. Furthermore, the specific case of China<br />

reveals characteristics such as the political<br />

system (socialism with Chinese characters), the<br />

important role of personal networks (guanxi),<br />

the parallel party-state-system, that require particular<br />

consideration when analyzing urban<br />

governance in China. All of these particularities<br />

are difficult to cover using the DiGaetano/Strom<br />

model which shows the limits of its<br />

applicability.<br />

However, we should highlight the fact that the<br />

model also has its merits. For example, its<br />

breadth proved to be a distinct advantage, because<br />

it helps to embrace complexities in urban<br />

affairs. These complexities are due to the plurality<br />

and often opaqueness of national, provin-<br />

cial, municipal, and even district strategies as<br />

well as the multi-faceted relations between the<br />

government, the corporate sector, and the<br />

emerging civil society, to name but a few challenges.<br />

The model grasps the major and complex<br />

influences affecting urban affairs. Each approach<br />

alone would not be sufficient for mapping<br />

the dynamic interdependencies and<br />

interrelations between structures (and processes),<br />

culture, and actors. At the same time, the<br />

model reduces the fuzziness of concepts such as<br />

governance and informality, whose ambiguous<br />

nature is certainly a challenge regarding conceptualization<br />

and empirical operationalization.<br />

Also, aspects of temporality are included within<br />

the framework, particularly in the structural<br />

context layer. These merits are especially important<br />

for analyzing urban governance within<br />

the highly dynamic urban environment of transitional<br />

China.<br />

Notes<br />

1 In comparison, the average GERD (gross domestic expenditure<br />

on R&D) in the European Union in 2007<br />

was 1.8 %, in Germany and Japan 2.5 %, 3.5 % respectively.<br />

2 The division between informal institutions and political<br />

culture is often misleading. In this respect, we propose<br />

to follow the <strong>und</strong>erstanding of KIRCHBERGER<br />

(2004, 11). According to her, all observable regular but<br />

not formally codified behavior patterns that apply to<br />

interaction between different actors are considered “informal<br />

institutions”. In contrast, behavior patterns that<br />

are not directly observable, internalized moral concepts,<br />

and individual socializations are considered<br />

“political culture” (ibid.). Following this line of argumentation,<br />

the widespread guanxi as the traditional<br />

network of personal relations in China would be related<br />

to political culture whereas a not formalized negotiation<br />

process over political affairs would relate to informal<br />

institutions.<br />

References<br />

ALTROCK, U. (2012): Conceptualizing informality: Some<br />

thoughts on the way towards generalization. In McFarlane,<br />

C./ Waibel, M. (Eds.): Urban Informalities: Reflections<br />

on the Formal and Informal. Farnham. (forthcoming).<br />

ALTROCK, U./PILLATH, C.-H./WAIBEL, M. (2008): Governance<br />

over time: Spatial Differentiation and temporal<br />

change of urban development and redevelopment in a<br />

context of multiple transitions and informal growth in<br />

the PRD. DFG Priority Programme 1233: “Megacities -<br />

Megachallenge: Informal Dynamics of Global Change”.<br />

(Unpublished research project proposal).


F. Schröder / M. Waibel: Urban governance and informality in China’s Pearl River Delta 111<br />

ALTROCK, U./SCHOON, S. (2009): The Governance of Urban<br />

Regeneration in Southern China. Liverpool. (Paper<br />

presented at the AESOP Conference, 15-18 July 2009,<br />

Liverpool, UK).<br />

ALTROCK, U./WAIBEL, M. (2010): The governance of<br />

spatial and economic restructuring. Informal dynamics<br />

of the maturing mega-city. DFG Priority Programme<br />

1233: “Megacities-Megachallenge: Informal Dynamics<br />

of Global Change”. (Unpublished research project proposal).<br />

BENZ, A./LÜTZ, S./SCHIMANK, U./SIMONIS, G. (2007):<br />

Einleitung. In: dies. (Hrsg.): Handbuch Governance.<br />

Theoretische Gr<strong>und</strong>lagen <strong>und</strong> empirische Anwendungsfelder.<br />

Wiesbaden, 9-26.<br />

CHAN, R. C. K./HU, Y. (2004): Urban governance. A theoretical<br />

review and an empirical study. In: Asian Geographer,<br />

(23)1-2, 5-18.<br />

CHIEN, S.-S. (2008): Urban/regional governance, Chinese<br />

style. A perspective of asymmetric decentralization.<br />

Berlin. (International Essay Competition and Workshop<br />

on „Collective Identities, Governance and Empowerment<br />

in Megacities“, Urban Planet Conference Series organized<br />

by the Irmgard-Coninx-Fo<strong>und</strong>ation in cooperation<br />

with the Humboldt-University and the WZB, 11th –<br />

16th June 2008, Berlin).<br />

DANIELS, P.W. (2004): Urban challenges: the formal and<br />

informal economies in megacities. In: Cities, (21)6, 501-<br />

511.<br />

DIGAETANO, A./STROM, E. (2003): Comparative urban<br />

governance. An integrated approach. In: Urban Affairs<br />

Review, (38)3, 356-395.<br />

ENRIGHT, M. J./SCOTT, E. E./ CHANG, K.-M. (2005): Regional<br />

powerhouse. The Greater Pearl River Delta and<br />

the rise of China. Singapore.<br />

FAINSTEIN, S./CAMPBELL, S. (2002): Introduction. Theories<br />

of urban development and their implications for policy<br />

and planning. In: Fainstein, S./Campbell, S. (Eds.):<br />

Readings in urban theory. Malden a.o., 1-15.<br />

FEWSMITH, J. (2004): Promoting the scientific development<br />

concept. In: China Leadership Monitor, Summer<br />

2004, (11), 1-10.<br />

FUKUI, H. (2000): Introduction. On the significance of<br />

informal politics. In: Dittmer, Li/ Fukui, H./ Lee, P.N.S.<br />

(Eds.): Informal politics in East Asia. Cambridge a.o., 1-<br />

19.<br />

Guangdong Statistical Yearbook (2010): National economic<br />

accounts. Internet: http://www.gdstats.gov.cn/tjnj/<br />

e3.htm (3. 8. 2011).<br />

HASSINK, R. (2005):0 Guest editorial: The restructuring<br />

of old industrial areas in Europe and Asia. In: Environment<br />

and Planning A, (37), 571-580.<br />

HE, S./LI, Z./WU, F. (2006): Transformation of the Chinese<br />

city, 1995-2005. Geographical perspectives and geographers’<br />

contributions. In: China Information, (20)3,<br />

429-456.<br />

HE, Y.-G. (2006). Guangzhou Science Park. An ideal<br />

place for “Two Suitable”. The planning and experience<br />

in construction management of Guangzhou Science<br />

Park. In: National Territorial Construction Bureau of<br />

Guangzhou Development District (Ed.): 20 years in<br />

Guangzhou Development Zone. Guangzhou, 204-214<br />

(Chinese).<br />

HEBERER, T./SCHUBERT, G. (2008): Politische Partizipation<br />

<strong>und</strong> Regimelegitimität in der VR China. Band I: Der<br />

urbane Raum. Wiesbaden.<br />

HEILMANN, S. (2004): Das politische System der Volksrepublik<br />

China. Wiesbaden. (2. Aufl.)<br />

JESSOP, B./SUM, N.-L. (2000): An entrepreneurial city in<br />

action: Hong Kong’s emerging strategies in and for (inter)urban<br />

competition. In: Urban Studies, (37)12, 2287 -<br />

2313.<br />

JESSOP, B. (1995): The regulation approach, governance<br />

and post-fordism. Alternative perspectives on economic<br />

and political change? In: Economy and Society, 24(3),<br />

307-333.<br />

KIRCHBERGER, S. (2004): Informelle Regeln der Politik<br />

in China <strong>und</strong> Taiwan. Hamburg.<br />

KOOIMAN, J. (2005): Governing as governance. In:<br />

Schuppert, G.F. (Hrsg.): Governance-Forschung. Vergewisserung<br />

über Stand <strong>und</strong> Perspektiven. Baden-Baden,<br />

149-172.<br />

KUHN, R. (2009a): Guangdong. Re-envisioning<br />

Guangzhou. Internet: http://www.businessweek.com/<br />

globalbiz/content/jul2009/gb2009076_009429.htm<br />

(12.4.2010).<br />

KUHN, R. (2009b): Guangdong visions. A talk with<br />

Wang Yang. Internet: http://www.businessweek.com/<br />

globalbiz/content/jun2009/gb2009065_691758.htm<br />

(12.4. 2010).<br />

KUHN, R. (2009c): Guangdong visions. Forging China’s<br />

future.Internet:http://www.businessweek.com/globalbiz/<br />

content/aug2009/gb2009084_539590.htm (12.4. 2010).<br />

KUHN, R. (2009d) Guangdong visions. Responding to<br />

the crisis. Internet: http://www.businessweek.com/<br />

globalbiz/content/jun2009/gb20090615_39380.htm<br />

(12.4. 2010).<br />

KUHN, R. (2009e) Guangdong visions. The way forward.<br />

Internet: http://www.businessweek.com/globalbiz/<br />

content/oct2009/gb2009101_302976.htm (12.4. 2010).<br />

LAQUIAN, A. A. (2005): Beyond metropolis. The planning<br />

and governance of Asia’s mega-urban regions.<br />

Washington D.C./Baltimore.<br />

LEAF, M. (2005): Modernity confronts tradition. The<br />

professional planner and local corporatism in the rebuilding<br />

of China’s cities. In: Bishwapraya, S. (Ed.):<br />

Comparative Planning Cultures. New York, 91-111.<br />

LEAF, M./HOU, L. (2006): The “Third Spring” of urban<br />

planning in China: The resurrection of professional planning<br />

in the post-Mao era. In: China Information, (20)3,<br />

553-585.<br />

LIEFNER, I. (2008). Ausländische Direktinvestitionen<br />

<strong>und</strong> internationaler Wissenstransfer nach China. In:<br />

Geographische R<strong>und</strong>schau, (60)5, 4-11.<br />

LIN, G. C. S. (2001): Metropolitan development in a<br />

transitional socialist economy. Spatial restructuring in<br />

the Pearl River Delta, China. In: Urban Studies, (38)3,<br />

383-406.<br />

MAYNTZ, R. (2005): Governance Theory als fortentwickelte<br />

Steuerungstheorie? In: Schuppert, G.F. (Hrsg.):


112 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Governance-Forschung. Vergewisserung über Stand <strong>und</strong><br />

Entwicklungslinien. Bd. 1. Baden-Baden, 11-20.<br />

NDRC (National Development and Reform Commission)<br />

(2008): The outline of the plan for the reform and<br />

development of the Pearl River Delta (2008-2020). Internet:<br />

http://en.ndrc.gov.cn/ (5.8. 2009)<br />

NG, M. K./TANG, W.-S. (2004): Theorising urban planning<br />

in a transitional economy. The case of Shenzhen,<br />

People’s Republic of China. In: Town Planning Review,<br />

(75)2, 173-203.<br />

NORTH, D. C. (1990): <strong>Institut</strong>ions, institutional change,<br />

and economic performance. Cambridge/New York.<br />

OI, J. C. (1992): Fiscal reform and the economic fo<strong>und</strong>ations<br />

of local state corporatism in China. In: World<br />

Politics, (45)1, 99-126.<br />

OI, J. C. (1995): The role of the local state in China’s<br />

transitional economy. In: The China Quarterly, 144,<br />

1132-1149.<br />

PIERRE, J. (2005). Comparative urban governance. Uncovering<br />

complex causalities. In: Urban Affairs Review,<br />

(40)4, 446-462.<br />

PIERRE, J./PETERS, B. G. (2000): Governance, politics<br />

and the state. New York.<br />

PYE, L. W. (Ed.)(1985): Asian power and politics. The<br />

cultural dimension of authority. Cambridge, MA.<br />

ROY, A./ ALSAYYAD, N. (2004): Prologue/dialogue. Urban<br />

informality. Crossing borders. In: Roy, A./AlSayyad,<br />

N.: Urban informality. Transnational perspectives from<br />

the Middle East, Latin America and South Asia. Lanham/Lexington,<br />

1-6.<br />

ROY, A. (2009): The 21st-century metropolis. New geographies<br />

of theory. In: Regional Studies, (43)6, 819-830.<br />

SCHAMP, E. W. (2003): Raum, Interaktion <strong>und</strong> <strong>Institut</strong>ion.<br />

Anmerkungen zu drei Gr<strong>und</strong>perspektiven der deutschen<br />

<strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong>. In: Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong>,<br />

(47)3-4, 145-158.<br />

SCHOON, S. (2010): Governability, borders and urban citizenship.<br />

Part: Governability. Kassel. (Unpublished interim<br />

report, University of Kassel, Germany).<br />

SCHRÖDER, F./WAIBEL, M. (2010): Urban governance of<br />

economic upgrading processes in China. The Development<br />

of Guangzhou Science City. In: Internationales<br />

Asienforum - International Quarterly for Asian Studies,<br />

(41)1-2, 57-82.<br />

SHEN, J. (2002): Urban and regional developement in<br />

post-reform China. The case of Zhujiang Delta. In:<br />

Progress in Planning, 57, 91-140.<br />

TANG, B.-S./ WONG, S. W./ LAU, M. C. H. (2008): Social<br />

impact assessment and public participation in China. A<br />

case study of land requisition in Guangzhou. In: Environmental<br />

Impact Assessment Review, (28)1, 57-72.<br />

WAIBEL, M. (2008): Mega-urban growth, informality<br />

and the issue of governability. Towards theorising specific<br />

informal dynamics in a wider context. Berlin. (International<br />

Essay Competition and Workshop on „Col-<br />

lective Identities, Governance and Empowerment in<br />

Megacities“, Urban Planet Conference Series organized<br />

by the Irmgard-Coninx-Fo<strong>und</strong>ation in cooperation with<br />

the Humboldt-University and the WZB, 11 – 16 June<br />

2008, Berlin).<br />

WAIBEL, M. (2009): The model of the “Transitional Urban<br />

Development Cycle”. Explaining complex interrelationships<br />

between urban informality, governability, and<br />

restructuring policies. Berlin. (Workshop “Urban Development<br />

in a Globalising World – Overcoming the Formal-Informal<br />

Divide”, organized by the Irmgard-Coninx-Fo<strong>und</strong>ation<br />

in cooperation with the Humboldt-University<br />

and the WZB, 12-13 June 2009, Berlin).<br />

WAIBEL, M./GRAVERT, A. (2009): B/ordered spaces and<br />

social exclusion in Vietnam. Housing conditions of labor<br />

migrants in the face of global economic integration. In:<br />

TRIALOG - Journal for Planning and Building in the<br />

Third World, 101, 39-44.<br />

WANG, M.-H./DUAN, X.-F./TIAN, L. (2001): The practice<br />

of concept planning for the City of Guangzhou. In: Focus<br />

Report, (25)3, 5-10 (Chinese).<br />

WANG X. L./HUANG, R.-B (2007): The empirical study<br />

about Guangzhou’s science and technology originality<br />

condition. In: Science and Technology Management Research,<br />

(5), 15-19 (Chinese).<br />

WONG, S.-W./TANG, B.-S./HOREN, B. V. (2006): Strategic<br />

urban management in China. A case study of Guangzhou<br />

Development District. In: Habitat International, 30, 645-<br />

667.<br />

WU, F. (2002): China’s changing urban governance in<br />

the transition towards a more market-oriented economy.<br />

In: Urban Studies, (39)7, 1071-1093.<br />

WU, F. (2003): The (post-)socialist entrepreneurial city<br />

as a state project. Shanghai’s reglobalisation in question.<br />

In: Urban Studies, (40)9, 1673-1698.<br />

WU, F./XU, J./YEH, A. G.-O. (2007): Urban Development<br />

in post-reform China - State, market, and space.<br />

London, New York.<br />

WUTTKE, C./SCHRÖDER, F./XIAO, L. (2010): Contemporary<br />

planning issues in a pioneering city. The governance<br />

of urban redevelopment in Shenzhen, China. In: Pacific<br />

News, (33), 9-12.<br />

WUTTKE, C. (2009): Urban Governance in der Volksrepublik<br />

China. In: Geographische Zeitschrift, (97)2-3,<br />

130-150.<br />

XU, J./YEH, A. G. O. (2003): City profile (Guangzhou).<br />

In: Cities, (20)5, 361-374.<br />

XU, X./WANG, X. (2002): Characteristics of governance<br />

in China - based on the practice in the Pearl River Delta.<br />

In: Wong, K.-y./Shen, J. (Eds.): Resource management,<br />

urbanization and governance in Hong Kong and the Zhujiang<br />

Delta. Hongkong, 249-257.<br />

ZHU, J. (2004): From land use right to land development<br />

right. <strong>Institut</strong>ional change in China’s urban development.<br />

In: Urban Studies, (41)7, 1249-1267.


Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> Jg. 56 (2012) Heft 1-2, S. 113-120<br />

Buchbesprechungen<br />

BATHELT,HARALD/GLÜCKLER, JOHANNES:The<br />

relational economy. Geographies of knowing<br />

and learning. Oxford: Oxford University Press<br />

2011, X+298 p., £ 24,99 (paperback), £ 65,-<br />

(hardcover).<br />

Mit der „relationalen <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong>“<br />

liegt seit fast einem Jahrzehnt ein neuer Entwurf<br />

<strong>für</strong> ein gr<strong>und</strong>legendes Verständnis des<br />

Wirtschaftens im Raum vor, an dem die beiden<br />

Autoren dieses Bandes an vorderster Stelle<br />

mitgewirkt haben. Das Buch folgt der verbreiteten<br />

Idee der kumulativen Publikation, nämlich<br />

die zuvor in verschiedenen (anglophonen<br />

<strong>und</strong> deutschen) Zeitschriften publizierten<br />

Gedanken <strong>und</strong> empirischen Erfahrungen der<br />

Autoren systematisiert zusammenzufassen.<br />

Hier hat es seine Berechtigung. Es wird eine<br />

Kohärenz verfügbar, die man sich davor mühsam<br />

hätte erarbeiten müssen. Obwohl beide<br />

Autoren sich auf „German research traditions“<br />

berufen (6), erheben sie seit langem international<br />

ihre Stimme in englischer Sprache. In deutscher<br />

Sprache sind ihre Positionen aus ihrem<br />

weit verbreiteten Lehrbuch (BATHELT/GLÜCK-<br />

LER 2002, 2003) bekannt.<br />

Der Gr<strong>und</strong>gedanke des Relationalen lautet: Es<br />

gibt keine (ökonomische) Handlung eines Akteurs<br />

ohne eine Beziehung zu (einem) anderen<br />

Akteur(en). Daher ist jede economic action<br />

auch zugleich eine social action. Dieser Ansatz<br />

stellt das Individuum mit seinem „praktischen“<br />

Handeln in den Mittelpunkt, ist also einer Mikroperspektive<br />

verb<strong>und</strong>en. Aus dem sozialen<br />

Handeln reproduzieren sich <strong>Institut</strong>ionen als<br />

handlungsleitende Rahmen; wird Raum hergestellt;<br />

es entstehen Prozesse, die das Lokale mit<br />

dem Globalen verbinden <strong>und</strong> zugleich an das<br />

Vorherige geb<strong>und</strong>en „pfadabhängig“ sind; <strong>und</strong><br />

es wird eine „proaktive“ Politik erforderlich<br />

(alles 6 f.). Die Vorstellung, wir lebten in einer<br />

Wissensgesellschaft, bewegt die Autoren dazu,<br />

Wissensprozesse als zentralen Gegenstand der<br />

relationalen <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> zu verstehen.<br />

Allerdings in ziemlich eklektischer Form:<br />

Dies ist – anders als der Subtitel vermuten lässt<br />

– keine umfassende Geographie des Wissens.<br />

Das Buch ist in vier Teilen aufgebaut. Teil 1<br />

legt die Gr<strong>und</strong>lagen des relationalen Denkens.<br />

Akteure handeln nur in Beziehungen zu anderen,<br />

<strong>und</strong> dieses Handeln kann man auf eine<br />

„geographische Perspektive“ (geographical<br />

lense) herunterbrechen. Unter Bezug auf Giddens<br />

Strukturationstheorie ist soziales Handeln<br />

eingebettet in Strukturen, <strong>für</strong> die <strong>Institut</strong>ionen<br />

stehen. Deren „context matters“, was zu einer<br />

eingeschränkten Handlungsfähigkeit des Akteurs<br />

in „Pfadabhängigkeit“ <strong>und</strong> Kontingenz<br />

führt (32). Wer ist der Akteur? Praktisch fühlen<br />

sich die Autoren der „geography of firms“ verb<strong>und</strong>en<br />

(vi) <strong>und</strong> diskutieren das Handeln von<br />

Unternehmern oder Unternehmen bzw. deren<br />

Experten. Welche Handlungen? Solche, die mit<br />

dem Erwerb, der Nutzung <strong>und</strong> der Verbreitung<br />

von unternehmerisch verwendbarem Wissen<br />

verb<strong>und</strong>en sind. Mit dieser Einschränkung stehen<br />

die Autoren nicht allein: Auch im Fach<br />

fehlt es an einer Empirie über das Wissen von<br />

„Nicht-Experten“ – beispielsweise von Bauern,<br />

Arbeitern, Hausfrauen, Politikern. Leider<br />

legen die Autoren eine vergleichbare Konkretisierung<br />

<strong>für</strong> den Kontext, in dem die Akteure<br />

handeln, nicht offen. Doch die empirischen<br />

Aussagen machen eine Eurozentrierung sowie<br />

den Bezug zur gegenwärtigen neoliberal geprägten<br />

„flexiblen“ <strong>Wirtschafts</strong>weise offenk<strong>und</strong>ig.<br />

Die beiden folgenden Teile des Buches vertiefen<br />

in sechs Kapiteln wichtige geographische<br />

Konstrukte sowohl konzeptionell als auch empirisch<br />

in ausführlichen Fallstudien. Teil 2 diskutiert<br />

Cluster als eine spezifisch geographische<br />

Konfiguration von Akteuren <strong>und</strong> fragt<br />

nach den Wissensprozessen in Clustern, zwischen<br />

Clustern <strong>und</strong> zu anderen (“globalen“)<br />

Orten. Teil 3 betrachtet explizit den Aufbau<br />

globaler Vernetzungen in Wissensprozessen;<br />

zuerst bei der Internationalisierung des Unternehmens<br />

sowie der Organisation globaler unternehmensinterner<br />

Wissensflüsse, dann durch<br />

Analyse der Rolle internationaler Messen als<br />

ereignisschaffende Orte, an denen Aufbau <strong>und</strong><br />

Pflege von Beziehungen zwischen Akteuren<br />

möglich werden. In diesen Kapiteln stellen die<br />

Autoren – gewissermaßen (pfad-)abhängig von<br />

ihren eigenen empirischen Erfahrungen – Fallstudien<br />

über Unternehmen aus Beratung <strong>und</strong><br />

TV sowie der Chemieindustrie vor. Das sind<br />

sehr spezifische Branchenkontexte, über die


114 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

die Autoren allerdings gelegentlich mit ihren<br />

Schlussfolgerungen weit hinausgehen.<br />

Das Buch schließt mit dem vierten Teil zur „relationalen<br />

<strong>Wirtschafts</strong>-Politik“. Das meint die<br />

Umsetzung des analytisch gewonnenen Wissens<br />

einerseits in Regionalpolitik <strong>und</strong> andererseits<br />

in Fachpolitik. Dieser Teil des Buches ist<br />

der kürzeste; er lässt den Leser einigermaßen<br />

ratlos zurück. Für die Regionalpolitik lässt sich<br />

eigentlich aus einem so strikten Konzept des<br />

individuellen Akteurs <strong>und</strong> seines „eingebetteten“<br />

Handelns wenig ableiten, was nicht längst<br />

vertieft in der Governance-Debatte zur Regionalpolitik<br />

diskutiert worden wäre. Zudem geben<br />

weder das Konzept des ex post analysierten<br />

„situativen“ Handelns noch die Fallstudien<br />

Ziele, Normen oder Ähnliches her, auf das man<br />

Handlungsempfehlungen aufbauen könnte.<br />

Der disziplinäre Ausblick bezieht sich vor allem<br />

auf Gegenstände <strong>und</strong> aktuelle Themen, die<br />

in Gesellschaften der hoch entwickelten Länder<br />

diskutiert werden – explizit Klimawandel<br />

<strong>und</strong> erwartete Ressourcenknappheit. Die argumentative<br />

Weiterführung der relationalen <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

kommt hier zu kurz <strong>und</strong><br />

scheint in einem lock-in gefangen. Vielleicht<br />

liegt die größte Schwäche des Buches darin,<br />

sich immer <strong>und</strong> überall gegenüber der (neo-)<br />

klassischen deutschen Raumwirtschaftslehre<br />

abgrenzen zu müssen. Für den deutschen Leser<br />

ist es hier leicht zu folgen, denn die Autoren<br />

diskutieren oft auf der Gr<strong>und</strong>lage deutscher<br />

wirtschaftsgeographischer Literatur der vergangenen<br />

beiden Jahrzehnte. Dennoch erscheint<br />

diese Sicht dem Rezensenten als unterkomplex.<br />

Es ist eine dualistische Sicht auf die<br />

Fachwelt – ihr da draußen, wir da drinnen –,<br />

die eine vertiefende Auseinandersetzung mit<br />

der inzwischen vielfach vorliegenden Kritik<br />

am Konzept der relationalen <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

verhindert (z.B. durch Autoren wie Peter<br />

Sunley oder Henry Yeung; in deutscher<br />

Sprache z. B. VON FRIELING 2005). Davon gibt<br />

es genug, <strong>und</strong> sie bezieht sich vor allem auf<br />

eine als unzureichend empf<strong>und</strong>ene Durchdringung<br />

des Kontextes, in dem die Akteure „situativ“<br />

<strong>und</strong> „kontingent“ handeln; wobei der<br />

Kontext sowohl gesellschaftstheoretisch als<br />

auch sozialpsychologisch <strong>und</strong> kulturell gemeint<br />

sein kann – Letzteres etwa die noch in<br />

der Einleitung genannten „values, interpretive<br />

frameworks“ (vi) oder soziale Deutungsmuster<br />

bezeichnend.<br />

Die relationale <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> zeigt ihre<br />

Stärke gerade dann, wenn sie die Interaktivität<br />

der Handelnden selbst thematisiert. Angesichts<br />

der Vorliebe <strong>für</strong> qualitative Forschungsmethoden,<br />

die die Autoren anfangs äußern, ist<br />

es schon etwas paradox, dass die überzeugendsten<br />

empirischen Teile des Buches aus den<br />

quantitativen Netzwerkstudien im Beratungsmilieu<br />

bestehen (Kap. 6, 8, 10). Hier wird die<br />

Leistungsfähigkeit des Ansatzes – soziales<br />

Handeln über Vertrauen <strong>und</strong> Reputation <strong>und</strong><br />

„seiner“ Methode der quantitativen sozialen<br />

Netzwerkanalyse – genau <strong>und</strong> modern demonstriert.<br />

Auch die Beispiele fehlenden interaktiven<br />

Handelns, mangelnder Möglichkeiten<br />

<strong>für</strong> „buzz“ <strong>und</strong> „pipelines“, verweisen auf die<br />

Berechtigung der relationalen Perspektive<br />

(Kap. 7). Die Kap. 5 <strong>und</strong> 9 befassen sich dagegen<br />

mehr mit gegebenen Kontexten des Handelns;<br />

zum einen mit dem (hier nicht begründeten)<br />

Regierungshandeln beim Aufbau chinesischer<br />

Chemiekomplexe, zum anderen mit der<br />

Messe als ermöglichender Ort von sozialer Interaktion.<br />

Die „schwarze“ Seite der Vernetzung<br />

wird nicht einmal randlich angesprochen: Exklusion<br />

(von Wettbewerbern, Bevölkerungsgruppen),<br />

ungleiche Aneignung (von Einkommen)<br />

<strong>und</strong> Teilhabe (an Entscheidungen), blockierende<br />

Netze (lock-in) <strong>und</strong> ihre Wirkung<br />

auf Stagnation <strong>und</strong> Niedergang; letztlich also –<br />

entgegen der Forderung der Autoren – eine<br />

Diskussion um die situative Analyse der Nutzung<br />

von Macht.<br />

Folglich gilt es, noch viel konzeptionell nachzudenken<br />

<strong>und</strong> empirisch zu tun, wenn man die<br />

relationale <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> als ein aktuelles<br />

Projekt der scientific community verstehen<br />

will. Das Buch ist dazu eine – in sympathisierender<br />

Kritik – anregende Pflichtlektüre<br />

<strong>für</strong> alle Fachwissenschaftler. Der klare didaktische<br />

Aufbau der Teile <strong>und</strong> die Zusammenfassungen<br />

am Ende jeden Kapitels machen es<br />

auch <strong>für</strong> Masterkurse einsetzbar – wenn man<br />

um kritische Literatur ergänzt. Die sozialen<br />

Netzwerkanalysen mögen junge Wissenschaftler<br />

zu entsprechenden Arbeiten anregen. Die<br />

Autoren hegen schließlich berechtigt die Hoffnung,<br />

international weitere Aufmerksamkeit<br />

unter den Sozialwissenschaften zu gewinnen.<br />

Jedenfalls gibt das Buch als erste internationale<br />

Zusammenfassung des Konzepts der relationalen<br />

<strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong> wichtige Anstöße<br />

zur wissenschaftlichen Debatte.


Literatur<br />

BATHELT, H./GLÜCKLER, J. (2002., 2003): <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong>.<br />

Ökonomische Beziehungen in räumlicher<br />

Perspektive. Stuttgart. (2. korr. Aufl.)<br />

VON FRIELING, H.D. (2005): Die gesellschaftstheoretischen<br />

Gr<strong>und</strong>lagen der relationalen <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

– soziale Kosmologie <strong>und</strong> naturalistische Metaphern.<br />

In: Geographische Zeitschrift, (93)2, 82-99.<br />

Eike W. Schamp, Frankfurt am Main<br />

STEINECKE, ALBRECHT: Themenwelten im<br />

Tourismus. München: Oldenbourg Verlag<br />

2009, 362 S., € 39,80.<br />

Nach wie vor zählt der Tourismus zu den globalen<br />

Wachstumsbranchen. So geht die World<br />

Tourism Organization (WTO) der UN <strong>für</strong> das<br />

Jahr 2025 von weltweit 1,6 Mrd. Ankünften,<br />

inklusive der Geschäftsreisen (aber ohne den<br />

Binnentourismus mitzurechnen) im internationalen<br />

Reiseverkehr aus, was im Vergleich zu<br />

heute in etwa einer Verdoppelung gleichkäme.<br />

Lag 1971 der Anteil der fünf Top-Destinationen<br />

noch bei ca. 70 %, entfielen allerdings im<br />

Jahr 2008 nur mehr 31 % der grenzüberschreitenden<br />

Reisebewegungen auf die führenden<br />

fünf Staaten. Der Wettbewerb wächst <strong>und</strong> reife<br />

Destinationen verlieren zusehends an Boden.<br />

Als eine Reaktion darauf kann gerade <strong>für</strong><br />

Tourismusregionen, welche am Ende ihres<br />

Destinationslebenszyklus stehen, die Etablierung<br />

kommerzieller Themenwelten im Speziellen<br />

betrachtet werden. Auch allgemein ist<br />

die Thematisierung des Raumes durch Nutzung<br />

endogener Potenziale <strong>und</strong> in der Regel<br />

begleitet von darauf abgestellten Events (vgl.<br />

z.B. die ostschweizerische Ferienregion „Heidiland“,<br />

die die große Popularität der Heidi-<br />

Romane von Johanna Spyri zur Etablierung<br />

ihrer Dachmarke nutzt) ein Fakt, der damit in<br />

Zusammenhang steht. Freilich ist neben einer<br />

gerade in unseren Breiten unzweifelhaften<br />

Marktsättigung die generelle Emotionalisierung<br />

des Konsums <strong>und</strong> die Erlebnisorientierung<br />

der Freizeitgesellschaft ebenfalls mit verantwortlich<br />

da<strong>für</strong> zu machen. Denn Tourismus<br />

ist ein von der Nachfrage getriebenes Geschäft.<br />

Nun sind die teilweise als Kommerztempel<br />

scharf kritisierten künstlichen Themenwelten<br />

gar nicht so neu. Denn illusionär gestaltete Gebäudlichkeiten<br />

finden sich nicht nur, <strong>und</strong> dort<br />

besonders konzentriert, entlang des Strip im<br />

jungen Las Vegas. Seit mehr als 200 Jahren<br />

Buchbesprechungen<br />

115<br />

gehören sie zum architektonischen F<strong>und</strong>us der<br />

europäischen Kulturgeschichte. Beredtes Beispiel<br />

hier<strong>für</strong> ist etwa die im Münchner Schlosspark<br />

zu Nymphenburg anzutreffende Magdalenenklause,<br />

welche im Jahr 1725 als bewohnbare<br />

Ruine errichtet wurde. Trotzdem ist sowohl<br />

die Dimension <strong>und</strong> Marktstellung als auch die<br />

räumliche Verbreitung touristischer Themenwelten<br />

<strong>und</strong> den darin anzutreffenden Inszenierungstechniken<br />

heutzutage so prominent, dass<br />

es höchste Zeit <strong>für</strong> eine Monographie wie die<br />

vorliegende auch in deutscher Sprache <strong>und</strong> mit<br />

bevorzugt mitteleuropäischen Fallbeispielen<br />

bedurfte. Dabei bezieht der Autor durchaus die<br />

internationale Literatur zum Thema kenntnisreich<br />

mit ein.<br />

Der Verfasser folgt einer vornehmlich auf Fallstudien<br />

bezogenen Betrachtung <strong>und</strong> legt die jeweiligen<br />

spezifischen Charakteristiken ausgewählter<br />

Themenwelttypen zu folgenden Sachverhalten<br />

kompetent dar:<br />

– Freizeit- <strong>und</strong> Themenparks (wie z.B. das Disney<br />

Resort Paris oder der Europa-Park Rust<br />

als mit Abstand meistbesuchter Themenpark<br />

Deutschlands);<br />

– Themenhotels <strong>und</strong> -restaurants (wie z.B. die<br />

„Irish Pubs“ eines irischen Brauereikonzerns<br />

oder die „Hard Rock Cafés“);<br />

– Urban Entertainment Center (wie z.B. das<br />

Centro Oberhausen als größtes innerhalb<br />

Deutschlands);<br />

– Markenerlebniswelten oder „brand parks“<br />

(wie z.B. die Autowelt Wolfsburg oder das<br />

Legoland im bayerisch-schwäbischen Günzburg);<br />

– Zoologische Gärten/Aquarien (wie z.B. der<br />

Erlebniszoo Hannover).<br />

Dabei dekliniert der Autor die betreffenden<br />

Kapitel seines Werks jeweils mit einer einleitenden<br />

Definition, der historischen Entwicklung,<br />

den Merkmalen <strong>und</strong> international festzustellenden<br />

aktuellen Trends durch. Das Werk<br />

benennt nicht nur gelungene Vorhaben, sondern<br />

bezieht auch gescheiterte Projekte <strong>und</strong><br />

Gründe <strong>für</strong> deren Misserfolg mit ein (41). Hierbei<br />

ist eine wesentliche Vorbedingung <strong>für</strong> den<br />

Erfolg von Themenwelten eine hohe Bevölkerungsdichte<br />

im Umfeld (Erreichbarkeitsradius<br />

von 1,5 – 2 St<strong>und</strong>en Fahrzeit) <strong>und</strong> Nachfragepotenzial.<br />

Auch andere <strong>für</strong> Raumwissenschaftler<br />

zentrale Standortbedingungen werden angeführt<br />

(74, 151). Gut gefällt dem Rezensenten,<br />

dass nach jedem Abschnitt Zwischenfazits als


116 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Kastentexte die zentralen Botschaften zusammenfassen.<br />

Hierbei sind die vielschichtig präsentierten<br />

Inhalte nicht allein <strong>für</strong> Freizeit- <strong>und</strong><br />

Tourismusforscher lesenswert, sondern auch<br />

<strong>für</strong> Stadt- <strong>und</strong> teilweise auch Handelsgeographen<br />

interessant (252 ff.). Das Buch erscheint<br />

insofern in jeder Hinsicht lesenswert, auch<br />

wenn man die am Schluss stehende gewagte<br />

Hypothese des Verfassers „Mit dieser Entwicklung<br />

werden die Grenzen zwischen (angeblich)<br />

künstlichen Themenwelten <strong>und</strong> den (angeblich)<br />

authentischen Realwelten hinfällig.“<br />

(282) nicht unbedingt teilen muss.<br />

Hubert Job, Würzburg<br />

SCHERRER, CHRISTOPH (Ed.): China’s labor<br />

question. München: Rainer Hampp Verlag,<br />

2011, vii+221 pp., € 27,80. (e-book available:<br />

http://www.global-labour-university.org/<br />

fileadmin/books/CLQ_full_book.pdf).<br />

“China’s labor question” is a collection of papers<br />

based on presentations at a panel of alumni<br />

from a Master’s-level programme at a conference<br />

in Berlin in 2010 and has been replenished<br />

with additional invited contributions. Addressing<br />

a rapidly evolving issue of clear topical<br />

interest, the initiators of the volume have<br />

been keen to expedite publication, responding<br />

to “great interest among trade unionists and<br />

academics in learning more about workers’<br />

struggles in China” (vi). The initiative to publish<br />

junior researchers’ work speedily is laudable,<br />

for it is in my view an excellent element<br />

of training that allows budding researchers to<br />

gain valuable experience of publishing; for a<br />

group of young scholars, all non-native speakers<br />

of English, to cut their teeth on an English<br />

publication is the best possible preparation for<br />

the struggles of the academic world.<br />

Considering the importance of Chinese workers<br />

for the world economy, who manufacture a<br />

large proportion of the consumer goods for the<br />

European and North American markets, the<br />

reader approaches the book with considerable<br />

expectation. Systematic syntheses, fresh views<br />

and the application of new, critical approaches<br />

to dynamically changing data on economy,<br />

work and society are certainly needed, since<br />

the scholarly field has had a hard time catching<br />

up with developments. The book, although<br />

bold and refreshing in some respects, unfortunately<br />

does not meet these expectations. The<br />

kaleidoscopic character of the book is a defi-<br />

nite draw-back as it merely raises a large number<br />

of “challenges” without reaching a central<br />

idea of the processes of change in “labour relations.”<br />

I shall make this point with reference to<br />

two of the contributions.<br />

The book starts out with Hansjörg Herr’s<br />

analysis of high economic growth and its consequences<br />

for employment in China. The intention<br />

is excellent, but it starts out with eerily<br />

irrelevant approaches to economic growth, like<br />

the “neoclassical model” and “new growth theory,”<br />

which are rejected for a number of reasons,<br />

partly because the theories are flawed in<br />

themselves, partly because they are not measuring<br />

the phenomena presenting themselves in<br />

China other than in very abstract terms, and<br />

partly, I would add, because economic policy<br />

making in China defeated the presumptions of<br />

conventional economic theory. The attempt to<br />

explain growth with inequality, harking back to<br />

Simon Kuznets and his famous curve, is also rejected;<br />

interestingly, Hansjörg Herr <strong>und</strong>erstands<br />

that “Chinese leaders even seemed to<br />

follow the idea that increasing inequality is a<br />

good thing,” but he fails to follow up on this<br />

and concludes that the Kuznets curve “does not<br />

bear up,” mainly due to points of no relevance<br />

to the Chinese case. Instead he marries Joseph<br />

Schumpeter’s and Milton Keynes’ ideas in a<br />

“monetary development model” hoping to explain<br />

high economic growth rates in China.<br />

The model involves a cycle of credit-investment-income-savings<br />

and dictates that the productive<br />

(rather than speculative) nature of investments<br />

(as guided through the central bank)<br />

is crucial for economic growth. In the case of<br />

China, the risky reliance on international export<br />

processing incomes and the low domestic<br />

consumption rates have long been identified as<br />

potential obstacles to growth. The fact that<br />

high rates of social inequality stymy domestic<br />

consumption brings the author back to the conclusion<br />

that “the Chinese government has neglected<br />

the distribution question for too long.”<br />

The reader is left with very little <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />

of China and a lot of chaff about debunked theories.<br />

And yet Herr does have a point that he<br />

could have pursued and measured: Exactly<br />

how the Chinese authorities systematically<br />

used the transition from one mode of planning<br />

to another and the manipulation of institutions<br />

like ownership (including the privatisation of<br />

state assets), household registration, land<br />

rights, enterprise reform and regulation and so<br />

on to achieve growth. That the policy since


2003 has been more focused on fairness does<br />

not indicate that the authorities are pursuing<br />

social equality, but rather that some of the inequalities<br />

arising from earlier policies have lost<br />

their usefulness and that the authorities promote<br />

other goals to consolidate economic<br />

growth, in that process not shying away from<br />

utilising other types of inequality. His bland<br />

conclusion that the Chinese success story can<br />

be ascribed to a “productive combination of<br />

government interaction and market forces”<br />

could have been the starting point and he could<br />

have used much more space on systematically<br />

discussing how the strong Chinese state managed<br />

to do what economics text books of any<br />

persuasion, even the works by Joseph Stiglitz,<br />

tell us is impossible. In stead of telling us that<br />

China’s “capitalist model is a specific and<br />

unique one,” he could have told us in what<br />

sense it is specific and what is so unique about<br />

it. Alas, he did not.<br />

Frido Wenten’s contribution on “restructured<br />

class relations” since 1978 seeks to use a historical-materialist<br />

approach to bring out an <strong>und</strong>erstanding<br />

of social change. He homes in on<br />

the most important aspects that could provide<br />

answers, but fails to grasp them (and f<strong>und</strong>amentally<br />

mis<strong>und</strong>erstands crucial aspects). He<br />

points at the rural reforms, i.e. the introduction<br />

of the household responsibility system which<br />

between 1978 and 1983 transferred agricultural<br />

production back to rural households, he mentions<br />

the boost in rural incomes due to increase<br />

in state procurement prices and <strong>und</strong>erstands the<br />

rapid growth of the rural non-agricultural enterprise<br />

sector, as well as the huge rural-urban migration<br />

flows as “supply of cheap labour” to urban<br />

industry. He also <strong>und</strong>erstands the general<br />

issues of state-owned enterprise reform. However,<br />

he wrongly believes that the processes<br />

were “privatisation.” To the contrary, the state<br />

actively promoted the rural enterprise sector<br />

mainly as a collective sector, condoning new<br />

private enterprises as “red-cap companies,”<br />

changing the names of the “commune and<br />

brigade enterprises” into “township and village<br />

enterprises,” leading to township and town government<br />

control over the sector (the “local state<br />

coropratism,” as this has been termed by observers,<br />

dominated from the mid-1980s until<br />

sometime between 2005 and 2007, when townships<br />

and towns lost most of their economic<br />

functions). The efficiency gains the government<br />

sought to achieve in state owned enterprises<br />

had nothing to do with privatisation or capital-<br />

Buchbesprechungen<br />

117<br />

ism, and the “Democracy Wall Movement” had<br />

no working class agenda; Wei Jingsheng’s claim<br />

for a “fifth modernisation” was for “democracy”<br />

in an ideal and broad sense and certainly<br />

not for “democracy in enterprises”; the movement<br />

learnt from not only Lech Wałęsa’s Solidarność,<br />

but also studied texts by Rudolf Bahro,<br />

Milovan Djilas and many others in translations<br />

produced for exclusive use within the top ranks<br />

of the Chinese Communist Party – they did not<br />

seek worker solidarity against encroaching capitalism,<br />

but a critical <strong>und</strong>erstanding of power in<br />

socialist states. The idea that the late 1980s<br />

were characterised by worker activism (sparked<br />

by high inflation and also by the localised experiments<br />

with state-owned-enterprise reform<br />

in Liaoning), linking up students and workers,<br />

and ending in the “Tiananmen-massacre” compresses<br />

very diverse issues into an overly simplistic<br />

narrative of a working-class struggle that<br />

never took place. In the analysis of the state<br />

owned enterprise reform, Wenten fails to grasp<br />

the process of transition, seeing it more as a<br />

struggle than as a systemic change. Discussing<br />

the rural-urban labour migration as a major<br />

source of “primitive accumulation,” Wenten inadvertently<br />

strikes the central point, but sadly<br />

fails to make it the crux of what could have<br />

been an exciting analysis, thinking of it merely<br />

as the “subjective agency of migrant workers,”<br />

missing the point that their agency is bo<strong>und</strong>ed<br />

by the deliberate and careful calibration of administrative<br />

and other institutions by China’s<br />

central and local “developmental state” administrations<br />

within the parameters of their regulation<br />

of core market players. As for the Hu Jintao-era<br />

that began in 2003 and is nearing its end<br />

in 2012, Wenten believes that it mainly sought<br />

to address instability (partly due to worker activism<br />

and public protests) by backtracking and<br />

creating more social justice to make amends for<br />

the capitalist overdrive perpetrated by the Jiang<br />

Zemin leadership 1989-2002. Wenten does not<br />

systematically identify how proactive government<br />

policy making since the late 1990s and in<br />

particular during the Hu Jintao-era have gradually<br />

changed modes of capital accumulation,<br />

upgrading of technology and skills, location of<br />

industry, relations between agriculture and other<br />

sectors, and administrative and market structures<br />

of resource allocation and investment. By<br />

abandoning the basic political-economy principles<br />

of an historical-materialism approach and<br />

focusing on the affective aspects of worker activism,<br />

protest and social injustice, Wenten’s account<br />

does not reveal the direction of China’s


118 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

political-economy system, but only concludes<br />

that “social conflict” will continue into the future.<br />

I shall not discuss all the contributions in the<br />

book, although several are better focused and<br />

demonstrate a better empirical balance. In any<br />

case, what can be learned from this master<br />

class?<br />

– First, the authors should have let the manuscript<br />

be read by people with experience in<br />

the field of scholarship, willing to be genuinely<br />

critical, and they should have taken<br />

their advice and criticism seriously; the main<br />

lesson is that critique that allows one to<br />

change the manuscript before publication is<br />

something one learns from, while post-publication<br />

critique by reviewers only leads to<br />

grief.<br />

– Second, the authors should get to the core<br />

point and avoid empty theoretical deliberations.<br />

They should avoid using loose concepts<br />

or irrelevant theories.<br />

– Third, the authors should put away their personal<br />

sym- and antipathies, for nothing is<br />

more disturbing than misplaced solidarity<br />

and dissonant claims of unity, even if they<br />

are only hidden away in the subtext: Chinese<br />

working people can do without clammy embraces.<br />

– Fourth, the authors should avoid poaching<br />

other people’s interview quotes, taking them<br />

out of context. In particular Wenten sins<br />

against this principle.<br />

– Fifth, the authors should be meticulous when<br />

referring to other people’s work, avoiding to<br />

impute or infer meanings not expressed.<br />

Again, Wenten’s is prone to draw wrong conclusions<br />

from the works he refers to.<br />

– Sixth, the authors should be dispassionate,<br />

try to see the big picture and at the same time<br />

<strong>und</strong>erstand the actual dynamics at play. For<br />

example: Private ownership or the household<br />

registration system are not good or bad, they<br />

are facts the significance of which changes<br />

over time and varies across situations. Collective<br />

bargaining has no intrinsic merit, for<br />

its value is entirely determined by its context.<br />

Judging phenomena in China as everywhere<br />

else, one needs to see them in context, not<br />

isolated.<br />

– Seventh, the authors should get their work<br />

properly language edited in several iterations<br />

by people who are used to their field of<br />

scholarship. When English is the language of<br />

publication, the citation styles and all other<br />

detail must follow English conventions, even<br />

if the publisher is in Germany.<br />

The point I want to make is that a lot of enthusiasm<br />

and hard work has gone into this book,<br />

and that most of the f<strong>und</strong>amental flaws could<br />

have been avoided by more careful processes<br />

of pre-publication peer review, editing, and<br />

better scholarly practices. For example, some<br />

of the mistakes in Wenten’s work are not uncommon<br />

among young scholars, and better advising<br />

and mentoring should have smoothed<br />

them out. I fo<strong>und</strong> the book hard to read and<br />

hard to review, and I considered declining to<br />

review it at all. The fact that I do review it and<br />

choose to be emphatic and blunt about its flaws<br />

is that I hope that my comments at least can be<br />

of use, for I do believe that this type of publication<br />

is important, and that in the future we<br />

can make sure that young researchers are guided<br />

and supported by critical peer reviewers,<br />

their advisors, as well as commissioning editors,<br />

language editors and copy editors to better<br />

learn the skills of publishing internationally.<br />

We need new cohorts of highly skilled researchers,<br />

and the only way to achieve that is<br />

by providing both support and criticism. Even<br />

if the publication would be delayed by a year in<br />

order for it to become academically stronger<br />

and more credible, that year would be well<br />

spent.<br />

Flemming Christiansen, Duisburg-Essen<br />

ZIMMERMANN, GERD R.: Die Besiedlung Madagaskars<br />

durch „Indonesier“. Nackenheim/<br />

Rhein: Edition Matahari 2010, 6 Abb., 119 S.,<br />

€ 31,40.<br />

In seiner inzwischen schon klassischen Definition<br />

hat Anthony Giddens Globalisierung als<br />

Intensivierung weltweiter sozialer Beziehungen<br />

bezeichnet, durch die entfernte Orte so<br />

miteinander verb<strong>und</strong>en werden, dass Ereignisse<br />

an einem Ort durch Vorgänge geprägt werden,<br />

die sich an einem viele Kilometer entfernten<br />

Ort abspielen – <strong>und</strong> umgekehrt. Der aktuellen<br />

Globalisierung, die durch Prozesse räumlicher<br />

Verdichtung <strong>und</strong> zeitlicher Beschleunigung<br />

gekennzeichnet ist, kommt sicher gegenüber<br />

historisch weiter zurückliegenden Vorgängen<br />

eine neue Qualität zu. Aber Migrationen<br />

<strong>und</strong> Verflechtungen über große Distanzen hinweg<br />

finden sich auch bereits lange vor Beginn<br />

der europäischen Kolonialisierung der Welt.


Ein solches Beispiel ist zweifellos die Besiedlung<br />

Madagaskars durch Auswanderer aus der<br />

Inselwelt des heutigen Indonesien. Sie haben<br />

dabei seit Begin der Zeitrechnung, wahrscheinlich<br />

in mehreren Schüben, nicht nur Distanzen<br />

von über 6.000 km überw<strong>und</strong>en, sondern vermutlich<br />

auch bis zum 10. Jahrh<strong>und</strong>ert, vielleicht<br />

sogar bis zum 14. Jahrh<strong>und</strong>ert, Beziehungen zu<br />

ihren südostasiatischen Herkunftsräumen unterhalten.<br />

Auch wenn vieles mangels schriftlicher<br />

Quellen hypothetisch bleibt, etwa ob der Indische<br />

Ozean direkt überquert, oder ob küstennahe<br />

Routen gewählt wurden, es besteht kein<br />

Zweifel daran, dass die „Indonesier“ die Kultur<br />

Madagaskars nachhaltig geprägt haben. Der<br />

Autor demonstriert in seiner verdienstvollen<br />

Studie eindrucksvoll, wie ein explizit geographischer<br />

Zugang die bisher dominierende linguistische<br />

<strong>und</strong> ethnologische Forschung zum<br />

Thema erkenntnisfördernd, gerade auch im<br />

Sinn der Generierung fruchtbarer Forschungshypothesen,<br />

bereichern kann. Dies betrifft unter<br />

anderem Fragen nach den Herkunftsräumen der<br />

Migranten im heutigen Indonesien, in Madagaskar<br />

nach den Beziehungen zwischen verschiedenen<br />

Einwanderergruppen <strong>und</strong> zwischen<br />

Küste <strong>und</strong> Hochland sowie nach der Ausbreitung<br />

von Kulturelementen wie etwa dem Nassreisanbau.<br />

Die Studie zeigt exemplarisch, dass<br />

es bereits lange vor der europäischen „Entdeckung“<br />

der Welt Verflechtungen über große<br />

Distanzen <strong>und</strong> über lange Zeiträume gegeben<br />

hat, die zu bis heute nachwirkenden, sozial <strong>und</strong><br />

auch politisch bedeutsamen kulturellen Hybridisierungen<br />

geführt haben. Es ist zu wünschen,<br />

dass die beigefügten Übersetzungen der Zusammenfassung<br />

ins Englische, Französische,<br />

Indonesische <strong>und</strong> Madagassische der internationalen<br />

Rezeption der ausgesprochen lesenswerten<br />

Studie förderlich sind.<br />

Helmut Schneider, Duisburg-Essen<br />

JOB, HUBERT/ WOLTERING, MANUEL/ HAR-<br />

RER, BERNHARD: Regionalökonomische Effekte<br />

des Tourismus in deutschen Nationalparken.<br />

Bonn-Bad Godesberg: B<strong>und</strong>esamt <strong>für</strong><br />

Naturschutz 2009, 186 S. € 18,-. (Naturschutz<br />

<strong>und</strong> Biologische Vielfalt, Band 76).<br />

Die Diskussion um die erwarteten <strong>und</strong> tatsächlichen<br />

Beiträge von Großschutzgebieten, namentlich<br />

Nationalparken, zur Regionalentwicklung<br />

ist keineswegs neu. Im Gegenteil wird<br />

darüber seit längerem kontrovers debattiert,<br />

Buchbesprechungen<br />

119<br />

um so mehr als mit dem gegenwärtigen paradigmatischen<br />

Wandel des Gebietsschutzes das<br />

Verhältnis von Naturschutz <strong>und</strong> Regionalentwicklung<br />

immer stärker in den Fokus rückt. Im<br />

Zentrum steht dabei die Vorstellung, großräumige<br />

Schutzgebiete könnten im Sinne eines integrative<br />

Ansatzes insbesondere in Mitteleuropa<br />

wertvolle Beiträge zur Regionalentwicklung<br />

beisteuern. Dem Tourismus galt <strong>und</strong> gilt dabei<br />

besondere Aufmerksamkeit, vor allem weil<br />

Nationalparke bereits per Gesetz auch als Vorranggebiete<br />

<strong>für</strong> die Erholung fungieren. Die<br />

diesbezüglichen Erwartungen sind gemeinhin<br />

hoch, ohne dass allerdings lange Zeit hinlänglich<br />

gesichert schien, welche ökonomischen<br />

Wirkungen vom Tourismus, insbesondere in<br />

monetärer Hinsicht tatsächlich auszugehen<br />

vermögen.<br />

Schon 2009 hat eine Arbeitsgruppe um Hubert<br />

Job von der Universität Würzburg eine Studie<br />

zu den regionalökonomischen Effekten des<br />

Tourismus in deutschen Nationalparken vorgelegt,<br />

die inzwischen vielfach zitiert wird. Aus<br />

guten Gründen soll an dieser Stelle ein weiteres<br />

Mal eine Empfehlung zur Lektüre des Bandes<br />

ausgesprochen werden, dessen Rezeption<br />

eine Versachlichung verspricht, vor allem aber<br />

eine große Zahl belastbarer Daten zur weiteren<br />

Diskussion um den Nationalparktourismus in<br />

Deutschland bereitstellt.<br />

Auf der Basis einer touristischen Wertschöpfungsanalyse,<br />

der aufgr<strong>und</strong> ihrer offenk<strong>und</strong>igen<br />

Vorteile der Vorrang gegenüber anderen,<br />

konkurrierenden Konzepten der Wirkungsforschung<br />

im Tourismus gegeben wurde, präsentieren<br />

Job <strong>und</strong> seine Kollegen eine Fallstudienuntersuchung<br />

sechs ausgewählter „typischer“<br />

Nationalparke in Deutschland. Im Zuge diverser<br />

empirischer Erhebungen in den jeweiligen<br />

Schutzgebieten, die methodisch konsistent,<br />

aber gleichermaßen aufwendig <strong>und</strong> mühevoll<br />

erscheinen, konnten Daten gewonnen werden,<br />

deren Interpretation nunmehr <strong>für</strong> die ausgewählten<br />

Parke, namentlich Bayerischer Wald,<br />

Eifel, Hainich, Kellerwald-Edersee <strong>und</strong> Niedersächsisches<br />

Wattenmeer, sowie als Schätzung<br />

auch <strong>für</strong> alle deutschen Nationalparke<br />

Aussagen zum Umfang der regionalökonomischen<br />

Wertschöpfung des Tourismus erlauben.<br />

Die Konzeption der vom B<strong>und</strong>esamt <strong>für</strong> den<br />

Naturschutz in Auftrag gegebenen Studie ist<br />

dabei nicht ganz neu, da Job <strong>und</strong> andere bereits<br />

2005 <strong>und</strong> zuvor 2003 ähnliche Pilotstudien<br />

durchgeführt hatten. Ursprünglich geht das


120 Zeitschrift <strong>für</strong> <strong><strong>Wirtschafts</strong>geographie</strong><br />

Heft 1-2 / 2012<br />

Untersuchungskonzept auf die Schweizerin<br />

Irene Küpfer zurück, die schon 2000 eine entsprechende<br />

Studie zum Schweizerischen<br />

Nationalpark vorlegen konnte. Die Novität der<br />

Gesamtschau aller Nationalparke als „Flaggschiffe“<br />

des Gebietsschutzes in Deutschland ist<br />

deswegen gleichwohl kaum zu übersehen!<br />

Die Ergebnisse geben den vielfachen Vermutungen<br />

Recht, dass der Nationalparktourismus<br />

sehr wohl beträchtliche Beiträge zur ökonomischen<br />

Wertschöpfung auf regionaler Ebene beizusteuern<br />

vermag, die gleichermaßen Einkommens-<br />

<strong>und</strong> Beschäftigungseffekte umfassen.<br />

Diese variieren, wenig überraschend, von Nationalpark<br />

zu Nationalpark, wobei <strong>für</strong> den vergleichsweise<br />

jungen Nationalpark Eifel die<br />

größten Wirkungen konstatiert werden. Entscheidend<br />

ist hierbei die Definition der Nationalparkbesucher<br />

im engeren Sinne, also der<br />

Gäste, die das Schutzgebiet ausdrücklich wegen<br />

des Prädikats Nationalpark besuchen. In einem<br />

Schutzgebiet wie dem Nationalpark Niedersächsisches<br />

Wattenmeer, das lange vor seiner<br />

Erklärung zum Nationalpark eine klassische<br />

Urlaubsdestination war, müssen diese Wirkungen<br />

notwendigerweise geringer ausfallen.<br />

Die Präsidentin des B<strong>und</strong>esamtes <strong>für</strong> Naturschutz,<br />

Beate Jessel, hat in ihrem Vorwort die<br />

Bedeutung der vorliegenden Studie <strong>für</strong> die<br />

weitere Debatte um die Bedeutung von Nationalparken<br />

in ihrer Funktion als Tourismusdestinationen<br />

<strong>für</strong> die regionale Wirtschaft vorrangig<br />

peripherer ländlicher Räume herausgestellt.<br />

Dass zudem mit der Studie auch detailliertere<br />

Kenntnisse zur Besucherstruktur <strong>und</strong><br />

Motivation von Gästen gewonnen werden<br />

konnten, ist ein beachtlicher „Nebeneffekt“ der<br />

Untersuchung, der vor allem <strong>für</strong> die weiteren<br />

Bemühungen im Rahmen eines professionellen<br />

Destinationsmanagements <strong>für</strong> die Nationalparke,<br />

aber auch andere Großschutzgebiete von<br />

erheblichem Wert sein dürfte. Die Gründung<br />

der Dachmarke „Nationale Naturlandschaften“<br />

kann beispielhaft <strong>für</strong> die Richtung stehen, in<br />

welche sich das Marketing der Großschutzgebiete<br />

bei der Herausstellung ihrer unverwechselbaren<br />

Alleinstellungsmerkmale in Zukunft<br />

weiter entwickeln sollten.<br />

Indes sei abschließend vor möglicher Euphorie<br />

angesichts der vorgelegten Ergebnisse gewarnt.<br />

Mögen diese gerade <strong>für</strong> periphere ländliche<br />

Räume auch vielversprechend erscheinen,<br />

so sollte doch keineswegs von einem Au-<br />

tomatismus regionalökonomischer Wirkungen<br />

des Tourismus ausgegangen werden. Wie unter<br />

anderen Luisa Vogt (2008) eindrucksvoll nachweisen<br />

konnte, sind dem Tourismus als vermeintlichem<br />

Motor der Regionalentwicklung<br />

in der ländlichen Peripherie häufig enge Grenzen<br />

gesetzt. Von entscheidender Bedeutung<br />

sind vor allem das zur Verfügung stehende<br />

Humankapital, Kooperationsbereitschaft, aber<br />

auch infrastrukturelle Voraussetzungen sowie<br />

ein professionelles Destinationsmanagement,<br />

um auch in der Peripherie entsprechende Entwicklungseffekte<br />

erzielen zu können. Nationalparke<br />

bieten in dieser Hinsicht sicherlich Vorteile<br />

gegenüber anderen Konstellationen, inwieweit<br />

die Ergebnisse der vorliegenden Studie<br />

allerdings verallgemeinerbar sind, insbesondere<br />

im europäischen Kontext, bedarf<br />

zweifellos noch der weiteren Forschung. In<br />

diesem Sinne wäre ein Blick auf vergleichbare<br />

Studien in anderen Ländern <strong>und</strong> deren Ergebnisse<br />

wünschenswert gewesen; hierauf gehen<br />

Job <strong>und</strong> Kollegen allerdings nicht weiter ein.<br />

Ohnehin sollten im Blick auf die ökonomischen<br />

Effekte des Tourismus, die zweifellos im Fokus<br />

der hier rezensierten Untersuchung standen, die<br />

weiteren Anliegen des Naturschutzes nicht aus<br />

dem Blick geraten. Dies ist auch <strong>und</strong> gerade aus<br />

der Perspektive eines integrativen Gebietsschutzes<br />

essentiell. Erholung <strong>und</strong> Freizeit in der Natur,<br />

Förderung der Ges<strong>und</strong>heit, persönliche Erbauung<br />

<strong>und</strong> Weckung von Kreativität, sowie die<br />

Beiträge zur Umweltbildung sind wesentliche<br />

gesellschaftliche Leistungen von Nationalparken,<br />

deren Stellenwert es <strong>für</strong> die Zukunft zu<br />

wahren <strong>und</strong> zu stärken gilt. Hiermit ist letztlich<br />

eine ideelle Gr<strong>und</strong>satzfrage angesprochen. So<br />

bedarf es angesichts der konkurrierenden Interessen,<br />

denen sich Schutzgebiete nach wie vor<br />

ausgesetzt sehen, so hat Reinhard Piechockie<br />

kürzlich in seinem ebenso lesenswerten Buch<br />

zur Ideengeschichte des Naturschutzes „Landschaft<br />

– Heimat – Wildnis“ unterstrichen, einer<br />

Doppelstrategie des Naturschutzes: Dieser muss<br />

wertvolle Naturlandschaften weiterhin bewahren<br />

<strong>und</strong> zugleich dem Menschen als Erfahrungsräume<br />

mit touristischer Qualität öffnen. Nur so<br />

wird auch die Akzeptanz <strong>für</strong> mehr <strong>und</strong> bessere<br />

Schutzgebiete, namentlich Nationalparke weiter<br />

wachsen können. Genau hierin könnte der eigentliche<br />

Gewinn liegen, der mit den regionalökonomischen<br />

Effekten von Nationalparken,<br />

nicht nur in Deutschland, zu erzielen ist.<br />

Ingo Mose, Oldenburg

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!