12.02.2013 Views

Green defaults - Max-Planck-Institut für Bildungsforschung

Green defaults - Max-Planck-Institut für Bildungsforschung

Green defaults - Max-Planck-Institut für Bildungsforschung

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

1<br />

3<br />

5<br />

7<br />

9<br />

11<br />

13<br />

15<br />

17<br />

19<br />

21<br />

23<br />

25<br />

27<br />

29<br />

31<br />

33<br />

35<br />

37<br />

39<br />

41<br />

43<br />

45<br />

47<br />

49<br />

51<br />

53<br />

55<br />

57<br />

5þ model<br />

Abstract<br />

Journal of Environmental Psychology ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]]<br />

<strong>Green</strong> <strong>defaults</strong>: Information presentation and pro-environmental<br />

behaviour<br />

Daniel Pichert a, , Konstantinos V. Katsikopoulos a,b<br />

a <strong>Max</strong> <strong>Planck</strong> <strong>Institut</strong>e for Human Development, Lentzeallee 94, 14195 Berlin, Germany<br />

b Massachusetts <strong>Institut</strong>e of Technology, Cambridge, MA, USA<br />

There is inconsistency in many people’s choice of electricity. When asked, they say they prefer a ‘green’ (i.e., environmentally friendly)<br />

source for this energy. Yet, although green electricity is available in many markets, people do not generally buy it. Why not? Motivated<br />

by behavioural decision research, we argue that the format of information presentation drastically affects the choice of electricity.<br />

Specifically, we hypothesise that people use the kind of electricity that is offered to them as the default. We present two natural studies<br />

and two experiments in the laboratory that support this hypothesis. In the two real-world situations, there was a green default, and most<br />

people used it. In the first laboratory experiment, more participants chose the green utility when it was the default than when ‘grey’<br />

electricity was the default. In the second laboratory experiment, participants asked for more money to give up green electricity than they<br />

were willing to pay for it. We argue that changing <strong>defaults</strong> can be used to promote pro-environmental behaviour. Potential policymaking<br />

applications of this work are discussed.<br />

r 2007 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.<br />

Keywords: Decision research; Policy making; Pro-environmental behaviour; Defaults; Energy<br />

1. Introduction<br />

YJEVP : 478<br />

Prod:Type:FTP<br />

pp:1211ðcol:fig::2Þ<br />

The way we currently use energy is not sustainable. First,<br />

we are heavily reliant on fossil fuels—such as oil, coal, and<br />

gas—that will one day be depleted (Roberts, 2005). Second,<br />

and perhaps even more importantly, the burning of fossil<br />

fuels is the biggest source of emissions of carbon dioxide,<br />

one of the greenhouse gases that contribute to global<br />

warming. Already fuel prices and temperature have been<br />

rising. Furthermore, the International Energy Agency<br />

(IEA) predicts that the global hunger for energy is likely<br />

to grow in the future (Organisation for Economic Cooperation<br />

and Development/International Energy Agency,<br />

2006). The goal of reducing greenhouse gas emissions, as<br />

formulated in the 1997 Kyoto Protocol, seems hard to<br />

UNCORRECTED PROOF<br />

meet: Developing countries are rapidly approaching the<br />

levels of consumption found in Western countries and<br />

emissions are still growing (albeit at a slower rate) in the<br />

more industrialised nations. The IEA has called for strong<br />

Corresponding author. Tel.: +49 30 82406 416; fax: +49 30 82406 394.<br />

E-mail address: danipu@gmx.de (D. Pichert).<br />

0272-4944/$ - see front matter r 2007 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.<br />

doi:10.1016/j.jenvp.2007.09.004<br />

ED:G:JayaL:<br />

PAGN:Anvar SCAN:<br />

ARTICLE IN PRESS<br />

www.elsevier.com/locate/jep<br />

and coordinated government action (Organisation for<br />

Economic Co-operation and Development/International<br />

Energy Agency, 2006).<br />

The goal of those policies would presumably be to<br />

facilitate the switch to using renewable energy sources such<br />

as water, wind, biomass, and the sun. The European<br />

Commission, for example, is promoting renewable energy<br />

with a broad mix of measures ranging from tax policy to<br />

research and development. 1 The objective is to induce<br />

changes in human behaviour (Gardner & Stern, 2002;<br />

Nickerson, 2003). Since the start of the liberalisation of<br />

European energy markets several years ago, most European<br />

consumers of electricity now have the ‘‘power to<br />

choose’’. This is the title of the official European Union<br />

information brochure, 2 which tells consumers that ‘‘ybecause<br />

your supplier now has to indicate the source of their<br />

1 See the European Commission’s White Paper on Renewable Energy<br />

Sources (1997) or the Directive on the Promotion of Electricity from<br />

Renewable Energy Sources (2001), available at http://ec.europa.eu/energy.<br />

2 Brochure on the Internal Energy Market, available at http://<br />

ec.europa.eu/energy/gas/publications/index_en.htm.<br />

Please cite this article as: Pichert, D., & Katsikopoulos, K. V. <strong>Green</strong> <strong>defaults</strong>: Information presentation and pro-environmental.... Journal of<br />

Environmental Psychology (2007), doi:10.1016/j.jenvp.2007.09.004<br />

59<br />

61<br />

63<br />

65<br />

67<br />

69<br />

71<br />

73<br />

75<br />

77<br />

79<br />

81


1<br />

3<br />

5<br />

7<br />

9<br />

11<br />

13<br />

15<br />

17<br />

19<br />

21<br />

23<br />

25<br />

27<br />

29<br />

31<br />

33<br />

35<br />

37<br />

39<br />

41<br />

43<br />

45<br />

47<br />

49<br />

51<br />

53<br />

55<br />

57<br />

2<br />

bills, you can choose the most environmentally friendly<br />

supplier.’’<br />

Consumers can purchase this so-called ‘green’ electricity<br />

by choosing a green tariff, participating in a green<br />

electricity programme, or contracting with a utility<br />

specialised in trading green electricity (Bird, Wu¨ stenhagen,<br />

& Aabakken, 2002). Choice of carrier, including the<br />

possibility to buy green electricity, has been established in<br />

the United Kingdom, a number of US states, Germany<br />

(where this study takes place), and a number of other<br />

countries (Bird et al., 2002; Clark, Kotchen, & Moore,<br />

2003). By means of labelling and information disclosure,<br />

consumers are now able to know how the electricity they<br />

use is produced (Roe, Teisl, Rong, & Levy, 2001; Truffer,<br />

Markard, & Wu¨ stenhagen, 2001). Note that buying green<br />

electricity does not make a difference in the actual<br />

household electricity supply, but rather in investment<br />

flows. The idea is that increasing demand for green power<br />

will result in fewer conventional fuels and more environmentally<br />

benign energy sources being used.<br />

Have these efforts brought results? In theory, yes:<br />

Opinion polls and market analyses in the United States,<br />

the United Kingdom, and other European countries show<br />

strong public support for green energy (Farhar, 1999;<br />

Laboratory for Energy and the Environment, 2005; MORI,<br />

1996; Roe, Teisl, Levy, & Russell, 2001). Typically 50–90%<br />

of those asked say that they favour renewable energy and<br />

are willing to pay at least a small premium to have it. But,<br />

unfortunately, these statements do not reflect behaviour.<br />

The percentage of people who consume green electricity is<br />

marginal in nearly all countries, for example, 1% in<br />

Ireland, .4% in Finland, 1% in Germany, 2% in Switzerland,<br />

and .5% in the United Kingdom (Bird et al., 2002).<br />

In short, when asked, people prefer green electricity. This<br />

kind of electricity is available in the market, but people do<br />

not buy it. Instead, most of us rely on ‘grey’ electricity, that<br />

is, electricity generated from detrimental or at least<br />

controversial energy sources such as coal or atomic power.<br />

Why is this?<br />

To answer a question about human behaviour, one needs<br />

to use methods from the social sciences such as economics<br />

and psychology (Brewer & Stern, 2005). A number of<br />

researchers have done this. Rowlands, Parker, and Scott<br />

(2004) investigated how socio-demographic characteristics<br />

and awareness about energy issues affect the intention to<br />

switch to a green electricity utility. Clark et al. (2003) made<br />

a contribution in two ways. First, they considered<br />

observed, not intended, behaviour and separately studied<br />

UNCORRECTED PROOF<br />

participants and non-participants in a green electricity<br />

programme in the state of Michigan. Second, in addition to<br />

socio-economic and demographic variables, Clark et al.<br />

(2003) considered the effects of variables measuring<br />

altruistic and environmental attitudes. They found that<br />

all variables had a significant effect on the decision to<br />

participate. Bamberg (2003) followed up on the point of<br />

exactly how environmental concerns affect behaviour. He<br />

found that environmental concern affects the perception<br />

YJEVP : 478<br />

ARTICLE IN PRESS<br />

D. Pichert, K.V. Katsikopoulos / Journal of Environmental Psychology ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]]<br />

and evaluation of information about green electricity<br />

utilities but does not affect the decision to request this<br />

information.<br />

In other words, previous research on why people do not<br />

buy green electricity even though they say they prefer it<br />

looked at personal factors, such as an individual’s income<br />

and attitudes about the natural environment. Here we take<br />

a different approach that looks at those things in a person’s<br />

psychological environment that influence a decision to use<br />

green electricity. 3 Much can be understood about a<br />

person’s decision making when the psychological environment<br />

is studied, if only because it tends to be easier to<br />

observe and to measure its characteristics accurately than<br />

internal traits and attitudes. This approach has been used<br />

successfully to analyse a number of decision situations,<br />

including one similar (in the sense that the psychological<br />

environment has a considerable influence on the making of<br />

the decision) to that of choosing green electricity—the<br />

decision of whether to purchase an over-the-counter pain<br />

reliever (Hanoch, Katsikopoulos, Gummerum, & Brass, in<br />

press).<br />

A major characteristic of the psychological environment<br />

is the format in which information is presented (Gigerenzer<br />

& Hoffrage, 1995). In the choice of a utility, grey and green<br />

electricity are typically presented in a very specific format:<br />

Grey electricity is the default option (it is obtained when<br />

the customer does nothing), whereas green electricity is an<br />

alternative option (to obtain it, the customer needs to<br />

switch). For example, the German electricity market was<br />

opened in 1998. But there was never a tabula rasa during<br />

the liberalisation, that is, a starting point where consumers<br />

actively had to choose between utilities. Instead, consumers<br />

continued to be supplied by their incumbent utility. Even<br />

people moving into a new flat would automatically become<br />

customers of the incumbent utility by turning on a light,<br />

thereby agreeing to a ‘silent’ contract. This incumbent<br />

utility almost always provided grey electricity.<br />

Based on the literature on <strong>defaults</strong>, we hypothesise that<br />

the information presentation format greatly influences the<br />

choice of an electricity utility. If this is true, changing the<br />

format so that green electricity is the default may promote<br />

pro-environmental behaviour in a more effective way than<br />

just trying to persuade people to change. This paper<br />

presents four studies—two ‘‘natural experiments’’ (Harrison<br />

& List, 2004) and two laboratory experiments—that<br />

investigate the influence of <strong>defaults</strong> on the choice of green<br />

electricity. Before we present the experiments, we provide<br />

some background on <strong>defaults</strong>.<br />

2. Defaults<br />

A default is the condition that is imposed when an<br />

individual fails to make a decision (Johnson & Goldstein,<br />

3 Simon (1956) used the term ‘environment’ to label this collection of<br />

things but for the purposes of this paper we will call it psychological<br />

environment to differentiate it from the natural one.<br />

Please cite this article as: Pichert, D., & Katsikopoulos, K. V. <strong>Green</strong> <strong>defaults</strong>: Information presentation and pro-environmental.... Journal of<br />

Environmental Psychology (2007), doi:10.1016/j.jenvp.2007.09.004<br />

59<br />

61<br />

63<br />

65<br />

67<br />

69<br />

71<br />

73<br />

75<br />

77<br />

79<br />

81<br />

83<br />

85<br />

87<br />

89<br />

91<br />

93<br />

95<br />

97<br />

99<br />

101<br />

103<br />

105<br />

107<br />

109<br />

111<br />

113


1<br />

3<br />

5<br />

7<br />

9<br />

11<br />

13<br />

15<br />

17<br />

19<br />

21<br />

23<br />

25<br />

27<br />

29<br />

31<br />

33<br />

35<br />

37<br />

39<br />

41<br />

43<br />

45<br />

47<br />

49<br />

51<br />

53<br />

55<br />

57<br />

2003) or the option that consumers receive if they do not<br />

explicitly request something different (Brown & Krishna,<br />

2004). Many decision-making studies have shown that<br />

<strong>defaults</strong> tend to ‘stick’, that is, people do not switch to<br />

another alternative (e.g. Anderson, 2003; Sunstein &<br />

Thaler, 2003). Johnson and Goldstein (2003) provided a<br />

striking illustration of the power of <strong>defaults</strong>. They showed<br />

that consent rates for organ donation in different<br />

European countries are largely the product of national<br />

<strong>defaults</strong>. Some countries have an opt-in policy (one has to<br />

register to become an organ donor) and others use an optout<br />

policy (one is a donor unless one registers not to be a<br />

donor). The two policies result in large differences in<br />

consent rates. In Austria, for example, 99% of the people<br />

are organ donors whereas in Germany the consent rate is<br />

12%. Johnson and Goldstein (2003) argued that such<br />

differences could not be explained by socio-economic<br />

variables. Generally, although they are free to do so at<br />

any time, most people simply do not change the default.<br />

Default effects have also been found in the participation<br />

in 401(k) retirement plans (Choi, Laibson, Madrian, &<br />

Metrick, 2002; Madrian & Shea, 2001), in insurance<br />

Q1 choices (Johnson, Hershey, Meszaros, & Kunreuther,<br />

1993), in consumer research (Brown & Krishna, 2004;<br />

Park, Youl Jun, & MacInnis, 2000; Puto, 1987), and in<br />

Internet privacy policies (Johnson, Bellman, & Lohse,<br />

2002). Camerer (2000, p. 295) writes: ‘‘Making one option<br />

the status quo or default or endowing a person with a good<br />

(even hypothetically) seems to establish a reference point<br />

people move away from only reluctantly, or if they are paid<br />

a large sum.’’<br />

The influence of the default seems to be even stronger<br />

when consumers are not so familiar with a product and<br />

have little knowledge about it (Sunstein & Thaler, 2003).<br />

This describes the commodity of electricity, which is an<br />

intangible product (it is, in a real sense, difficult to grasp).<br />

Moreover, Western citizens have been described as ‘energy<br />

illiterates’ (Roberts, 2005). Thus, one might expect that<br />

consumers’ preferences are constructed in the sense that<br />

they are developed on the spot and are highly contingent<br />

upon context and information presentation factors (Payne,<br />

Bettmann, & Johnson, 1992; Slovic, 1995).<br />

Why do <strong>defaults</strong> work? Explanations in the literature<br />

often involve biases, that is, departures from what is<br />

considered rational according to standard norms of logic<br />

and probability (Kahneman & Tversky, 1979; Samuelson<br />

& Zeckhauser, 1988). This kind of explanation has been<br />

criticised because such norms can be argued to be<br />

UNCORRECTED PROOF<br />

irrelevant to successful behaviour in the real world (Fasolo,<br />

McClelland, & Todd, in press; Gigerenzer, Todd, & the<br />

ABC Research Group, 1999). Sticking to <strong>defaults</strong> can be<br />

considered rational because it can save time, effort, and<br />

money. Whereas accepting the default is effortless and<br />

requires no time commitment, people intending to switch<br />

have to search for information (e.g. on the Internet or by<br />

asking others), choose from the possible options, and<br />

finally act. In addition, the default may be cheaper as is the<br />

YJEVP : 478<br />

ARTICLE IN PRESS<br />

D. Pichert, K.V. Katsikopoulos / Journal of Environmental Psychology ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]] 3<br />

case with grey electricity, or transaction costs might be<br />

charged: In an early stage of the market liberalisation,<br />

Norwegian customers had to pay a fee in order to switch<br />

(Nordic Energy Regulators, 2005).<br />

There are also good reasons for sticking with the default<br />

that do not have to do with rationality (at least in a strict<br />

sense). For one, it does not seem unreasonable to interpret<br />

the default as a recommendation from the policymaker,<br />

indicating the socially desired behaviour (Johnson &<br />

Goldstein, 2003; McKenzie, Liersch, & Finkelstein,<br />

2006). Similarly, when a company offers a ‘standard<br />

product’ (Brown & Krishna, 2004) as a default option,<br />

the customer might interpret this product as the one that is<br />

known to the company to fit most of its customers. Second,<br />

it is generally difficult for people to perform trade-offs<br />

(Irwin & Baron, 2001) and reconcile conflicting objectives<br />

such as saving money and preserving the environment. This<br />

becomes even harder when some of the objectives have a<br />

moral connotation, as does preserving the environment.<br />

Sticking with the default seems to allow one to bypass a<br />

stressful and awkward decision (even though doing nothing<br />

is also a decision). Finally, people are creatures of habit—<br />

interestingly, the word ‘customer’ historically derives from<br />

‘custom’, meaning ‘habit’. In a way, being a customer<br />

already refers to the psychological attachment to a vendor<br />

or a service.<br />

In summary, the decision-making literature shows that<br />

<strong>defaults</strong> have a strong influence on behaviour. There are a<br />

number of reasons for this effect and they seem applicable<br />

to the choice of an electricity utility. Therefore we<br />

formulate the following Hypothesis:<br />

Hypothesis. Defaults affect the choice of electricity. Thus,<br />

currently, most people use grey electricity because grey<br />

electricity is usually the default. In those cases where green<br />

electricity is the default, most people will use green<br />

electricity.<br />

In the next section, we present two natural experiments<br />

and two laboratory experiments that we used to put our<br />

hypothesis to the test.<br />

3. Studies<br />

The most critical test of our hypothesis is whether people<br />

who are subject to a green default also use green electricity.<br />

It is difficult to find such a naturally occurring situation.<br />

We contacted a number of power suppliers but could not<br />

obtain relevant data. In the end, however, we succeeded in<br />

finding two cases where a group of consumers had a green<br />

default. In the first case, a green default was established in<br />

a small town. In the second case, a supplier used green<br />

electricity as a default when asking its customers to choose<br />

between three different tariffs. In these natural experiments,<br />

the dependent variable is the proportion of<br />

customers choosing green electricity. We use the term<br />

‘‘natural experiments’’ in the sense that we simply observe<br />

naturally occurring ‘‘treatments’’ without further manip-<br />

Please cite this article as: Pichert, D., & Katsikopoulos, K. V. <strong>Green</strong> <strong>defaults</strong>: Information presentation and pro-environmental.... Journal of<br />

Environmental Psychology (2007), doi:10.1016/j.jenvp.2007.09.004<br />

59<br />

61<br />

63<br />

65<br />

67<br />

69<br />

71<br />

73<br />

75<br />

77<br />

79<br />

81<br />

83<br />

85<br />

87<br />

89<br />

91<br />

93<br />

95<br />

97<br />

99<br />

101<br />

103<br />

105<br />

107<br />

109<br />

111<br />

113


1<br />

3<br />

5<br />

7<br />

9<br />

11<br />

13<br />

15<br />

17<br />

19<br />

21<br />

23<br />

25<br />

27<br />

29<br />

31<br />

33<br />

35<br />

37<br />

39<br />

41<br />

43<br />

45<br />

47<br />

49<br />

51<br />

53<br />

55<br />

57<br />

4<br />

ulation (Harrison & List, 2004). A problem with observations<br />

such as these, however, is that they lack experimental<br />

control. For this reason, we added two laboratory<br />

experiments in which we exposed participants to hypothetical<br />

choices under varying conditions. This also allowed us<br />

to look into other dependent variables. We accept that<br />

choices in the laboratory lack real consequences, but we<br />

believe that the four studies together allow the testing of<br />

our hypothesis.<br />

3.1. First natural experiment: a green default in the real<br />

world<br />

Scho¨ nau is a picturesque little town situated in the<br />

southern part of the Black Forest, an area that is politically<br />

dominated by the conservatives, especially in more rural<br />

areas. The influence of the <strong>Green</strong> Party (the German party<br />

that is commonly associated with the promotion of proenvironmental<br />

policies) is comparatively low: In the last<br />

elections for the German Parliament, the Party received<br />

approximately 5% of the ballots cast. We emphasise this to<br />

show that the area can hardly be described as the political<br />

centre of grass-roots environmentalism. In fact, the<br />

opposite might be true.<br />

About 2500 citizens inhabit Scho¨ nau. The unemployment<br />

rate is low. A quick glance at Scho¨ nau’s website<br />

reveals that several small clubs are engaged in the<br />

cultivation of rustic folklore, including traditional costumes,<br />

dances, and songs. What makes Scho¨ nau interesting<br />

for our purposes is that in this town, green electricity is not<br />

the alternative but the default. Here is how it happened.<br />

In the 1980s, a citizens’ initiative was founded in<br />

Scho¨ nau as a reaction to the Chernobyl disaster. The<br />

objective of the group was activism against nuclear power.<br />

Campaigns like these were not uncommon in Germany in<br />

those days but it is remarkable that the activities of<br />

campaigners in Scho¨ nau resulted in proposals to take over<br />

the electricity grid in order to establish an environmentally<br />

friendly energy supply. Needless to say, this venture caused<br />

some conflict. Citizens had to decide if the initiative would<br />

be allowed to manage the Scho¨ nau grid. Before the vote,<br />

the Scho¨ nau city centre witnessed intense campaigns by<br />

both supporters and opponents of the proposal. Finally,<br />

the proposal was accepted by a very close margin (ca. 52%<br />

vs. 48%, turnout ca. 90%). Even more astonishingly, in<br />

1997, the initiative managed to raise enough funds to buy<br />

the grid from its reluctant owner. Recall now that the<br />

German electricity market was opened in 1998. Because the<br />

UNCORRECTED PROOF<br />

deal was clinched 1 year before, the EWS (i.e. the Scho¨ nau<br />

Power Company) became the incumbent utility in Scho¨ nau<br />

and it still is. EWS purchases mainly energy generated from<br />

renewables from newly built facilities and promotes solar<br />

energy. That is, EWS, also called ‘Electricity Rebels’,<br />

stands for a truly green approach.<br />

But as the heat surrounding the citizens’ vote shows, the<br />

Scho¨ nau citizens were polarised with regard to the rebels’<br />

ideas. In fact, one of the managing directors of EWS told<br />

YJEVP : 478<br />

ARTICLE IN PRESS<br />

D. Pichert, K.V. Katsikopoulos / Journal of Environmental Psychology ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]]<br />

us: ‘‘We were really afraid because we did not know what<br />

would happen when the liberalisation started.’’ But those<br />

fears were unnecessary. In 2006 (ca. 8 years after the<br />

market opening), 1669 out of 1683 electricity meters 4 in<br />

Scho¨ nau were still supplied with electricity traded by EWS<br />

(data from EWS). Nearly every customer remained with<br />

the green default. Recall that the share of those participating<br />

in green electricity programs in other German towns,<br />

where there is usually a grey default, is approximately 1%.<br />

3.2. Second natural experiment: a utility-induced green<br />

default<br />

In the case of Scho¨ nau, switching away from the default<br />

requires searching for information about alternative<br />

options. In our second example, this effort is not necessary<br />

as it is the incumbent supplier itself providing a number of<br />

alternatives and asking their customers for a decision. The<br />

company published the data we will present. Wu¨ stenhagen<br />

(2000, in German) previously used these data in a<br />

marketing analysis, but not to make the point we are<br />

making here.<br />

In 1999, Energiedienst GmbH, a company supplying a<br />

grid area in southern Germany, diversified its services,<br />

offering three new tariffs where there had previously been<br />

only one. Letters were mailed to 150,000 private and<br />

business customers. Interesting here is the fact that a green<br />

(waterpower) tariff was used as the default: Customers<br />

wishing to be supplied with the green tariff did not need to<br />

respond. The green tariff was slightly cheaper than the<br />

previous tariff offered by the company. The other two<br />

options were a grey, even more economical tariff (ca. 8%<br />

cheaper), and a more expensive green tariff (ca. 23% more<br />

expensive, including a higher share of electricity generated<br />

from new facilities). Customers preferring one of these two<br />

alternative tariffs had to reply.<br />

Two months after the request was sent, 4.3% of the<br />

customers had decided to switch to the economical tariff,<br />

less than 1% had switched to the premium-priced green<br />

tariff, and .7% reacted by switching to a different supplier.<br />

About 94% of the customers remained with the default<br />

option.<br />

It may be that by using a green default, the company<br />

intended to influence customers’ behaviour in such a way<br />

that they would choose the product the company wanted to<br />

distribute. We do not know. Our point is that here as well<br />

as in the Scho¨ nau natural experiment, the information<br />

presentation format had a dramatic effect on the electricity<br />

people used. More specifically, a green default means that<br />

most people use green electricity.<br />

As already mentioned, natural experiments have their<br />

limitations. In the experiments reported here, (1) some<br />

people simply might not have known that they could<br />

switch, or how to do so; in this case, one cannot exactly say<br />

4 The company’s data records cover electricity meters that are largely,<br />

but not exactly related to the number of households or inhabitants.<br />

Please cite this article as: Pichert, D., & Katsikopoulos, K. V. <strong>Green</strong> <strong>defaults</strong>: Information presentation and pro-environmental.... Journal of<br />

Environmental Psychology (2007), doi:10.1016/j.jenvp.2007.09.004<br />

59<br />

61<br />

63<br />

65<br />

67<br />

69<br />

71<br />

73<br />

75<br />

77<br />

79<br />

81<br />

83<br />

85<br />

87<br />

89<br />

91<br />

93<br />

95<br />

97<br />

99<br />

101<br />

103<br />

105<br />

107<br />

109<br />

111<br />

113


1<br />

3<br />

5<br />

7<br />

9<br />

11<br />

13<br />

15<br />

17<br />

19<br />

21<br />

23<br />

25<br />

27<br />

29<br />

31<br />

33<br />

35<br />

37<br />

39<br />

41<br />

43<br />

45<br />

47<br />

49<br />

51<br />

53<br />

55<br />

57<br />

that those customers ‘‘chose’’ (although this argument<br />

applies more to the first experiment and less to the second<br />

one where the utility informed its customers about the<br />

opportunity to switch). (2) In the first experiment, the<br />

heated debate on the takeover of the grid might have had<br />

effects of its own that are difficult to judge; it may have, for<br />

example, made people more sensitive to the subject of<br />

preserving the environment. (3) We do not have data about<br />

offers from other suppliers in the two experiments, and this<br />

prevents us from disentangling the effect of default from<br />

that of price. (4) Related to this, both experiments looked<br />

at regions with above-average incomes. To address these<br />

limitations, we conducted two laboratory studies, which<br />

allowed more control and tested additional dependent<br />

variables.<br />

3.3. First laboratory experiment: choices<br />

We designed a simple decision task that confronted<br />

people directly with the choice between different electricity<br />

suppliers. The control we gained by using a laboratory<br />

experiment was found in the random assignment of<br />

participants to conditions, the use of a ‘neutral’ condition,<br />

and the implementation of a trade-off (a more expensive<br />

green service vs. a cheaper grey service). We also asked<br />

participants to give reasons for their decisions. Our<br />

prediction was that more people would choose the more<br />

expensive green tariff when it was presented as the default<br />

option than when it was presented as an alternative to the<br />

lower priced grey tariff.<br />

3.3.1. Method and procedure<br />

Analyzing German marketing research, we found that<br />

younger adults, in general, know that they can choose their<br />

electricity supplier, because they are better informed,<br />

relocate more often, and are more familiar with modern<br />

registration procedures using the Internet. However, many<br />

older people are still unfamiliar with the task of choosing<br />

an electricity supplier. This is why our experimenters were<br />

instructed to address young adults (loosely defined as<br />

persons between the ages of 18 and 35 years). 5<br />

We gave participants a short questionnaire that consisted<br />

of two parts. The first part was a short vignette (see<br />

Appendix A). Participants were asked to imagine that they<br />

had moved to another town. In their new flat, they were<br />

confronted with the choice between two electricity suppliers:<br />

one advertising ‘clean electricity’ generated from<br />

environmentally benign renewable energy sources, and<br />

another offering a more economically priced tariff. For the<br />

YJEVP : 478<br />

ARTICLE IN PRESS<br />

D. Pichert, K.V. Katsikopoulos / Journal of Environmental Psychology ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]] 5<br />

latter option, no further information about the origin of<br />

the electricity was given. It was meant to represent a utility<br />

marketing grey energy (in standard electricity tariffs in<br />

Germany, a mix of fossil fuels and nuclear power is<br />

predominant). This design took into account the reality of<br />

marketing, namely, that suppliers distributing grey energy<br />

avoid discussing energy sources, for good reason; for<br />

instance, nuclear power is extremely controversial (we were<br />

not able to find a single utility that advertises cheap nuclear<br />

power). On the other hand, all utilities specialising in green<br />

energy explicitly highlight this information. A manipulation<br />

check (see below) ensured that the participants<br />

interpreted the descriptions in such a way that the grey<br />

service appeared less environmentally benign than the<br />

green one.<br />

The information given about the two companies and<br />

their tariffs is listed in Table 1. The prices are very close to<br />

what a small household in Germany actually pays for<br />

electricity per month. One of the two companies was<br />

introduced as the incumbent utility. The other utility was<br />

presented as a competitor that advertises its offers. To test<br />

for default effects, we used two different versions of the<br />

decision question. In the green condition, the green utility<br />

served as the default, and the grey one was the competitor.<br />

Roles were reversed in the grey condition. The prediction<br />

was that more people would choose the green option in the<br />

green condition.<br />

Furthermore, we added a neutral condition. Here a<br />

choice had to be made between the two utilities without<br />

either of the two being the incumbent. Comparisons were<br />

planned between the grey condition as a benchmark<br />

(representing the usual situation in Germany) and the<br />

green and neutral conditions.<br />

Participants were asked to give a short statement<br />

explaining the reasons for their decision. They also had<br />

to rate both utilities on 7-point scales (ranging from very<br />

negative to very positive), for both their environmental and<br />

pricing policy. Finally, participants had to rank five<br />

attributes (company reputation, environmental impact,<br />

location of provider, quality of service, price) according<br />

to their relevance for choosing an electricity supplier. The<br />

order of the attributes was randomised across participants.<br />

We also gathered demographic data. The completion of the<br />

UNCORRECTED PROOF<br />

5 The study took place in Berlin, and due to the availability of flats in<br />

this city, it is not unusual for 18-year-olds to live in their own flat. Persons<br />

younger than 18 have limited contractual capability in Germany.<br />

However, there is no strong rationale for choosing the age of 35 as the<br />

upper limit for ‘‘young adults’’, which is—in a way—arbitrary. If it is true<br />

that older people are less familiar with the task of choosing an electricity<br />

supplier or simply do not know that they can switch, an age effect can be<br />

predicted. We did not address this prediction in the present study.<br />

Table 1<br />

Options in the first laboratory experiment<br />

Company<br />

name<br />

Information given Monthly<br />

costs<br />

EcoEnergy EcoEnergy sells clean electricity, generated<br />

from renewable energy sources. Contribute<br />

to climate protection and environmental<br />

protection!<br />

Acon We offer low-priced electricity tariffs—you<br />

cannot beat our prices. Save money with<br />

Acon!<br />

h30 (ca.<br />

$39)<br />

h25 (ca.<br />

$32)<br />

Please cite this article as: Pichert, D., & Katsikopoulos, K. V. <strong>Green</strong> <strong>defaults</strong>: Information presentation and pro-environmental.... Journal of<br />

Environmental Psychology (2007), doi:10.1016/j.jenvp.2007.09.004<br />

59<br />

61<br />

63<br />

65<br />

67<br />

69<br />

71<br />

73<br />

75<br />

77<br />

79<br />

81<br />

83<br />

85<br />

87<br />

89<br />

91<br />

93<br />

95<br />

97<br />

99<br />

101<br />

103<br />

105<br />

107<br />

109<br />

111<br />

113


1<br />

3<br />

5<br />

7<br />

9<br />

11<br />

13<br />

15<br />

17<br />

19<br />

21<br />

23<br />

25<br />

27<br />

29<br />

31<br />

33<br />

35<br />

37<br />

39<br />

41<br />

43<br />

45<br />

47<br />

49<br />

51<br />

53<br />

55<br />

57<br />

6<br />

questionnaire took approximately 5 min. Participants were<br />

rewarded with a bar of chocolate.<br />

3.3.1.1. Participants. Participants were recruited in public<br />

places in Berlin and in the laboratory of the <strong>Max</strong> <strong>Planck</strong><br />

<strong>Institut</strong>e for Human Development while waiting to<br />

participate in other experiments. This resulted in a sample<br />

of 225 participants (126 female, 99 male). Mean age was 25<br />

years (SD ¼ 3.7). Persons younger than 18 years or older<br />

than 35 years were removed from the sample, which<br />

resulted in the exclusion of 8 persons. Excluding these cases<br />

from the analysis did not affect the results.<br />

Most of the participants were students (63%). Participants<br />

were randomly assigned to one of the three<br />

conditions. A power analysis was conducted before the<br />

experiment to ensure that the selected sample size would<br />

result in a power of at least .80 for a medium effect size at a<br />

significance level of .05 (Cohen, 1988).<br />

3.3.1.2. Manipulation checks. For environmental impact,<br />

participants rated the green utility (M ¼ 4.9, SD ¼ 1.1)<br />

better than the non-green utility (M ¼ 3.3, SD ¼ 1.1),<br />

t(224) ¼ 14.2, p ¼ .001. The price of the grey utility<br />

(M ¼ 4.8, SD ¼ 1.1) was considered to be better than that<br />

of the green one (M ¼ 3.4, SD ¼ 1.0), t(224) ¼ 14.49,<br />

p ¼ .001. Finally, for the ratings of the five attributes, price<br />

was the most important (M ¼ 1.72, SD ¼ .9), followed by<br />

environmental impact (M ¼ 2.53, SD ¼ 1.3), quality of<br />

service (M ¼ 2.88, SD ¼ 1.1), company reputation<br />

(M ¼ 3.6, SD ¼ 1.2), and local production (M ¼ 4.24,<br />

SD ¼ 1.0).<br />

100.00%<br />

50.00%<br />

0.00%<br />

green utility<br />

non-green utility<br />

YJEVP : 478<br />

ARTICLE IN PRESS<br />

3.3.2. Results<br />

3.3.2.1. Choices. The choices of the participants are<br />

displayed in Fig. 1. In the grey condition, 31 of 75<br />

participants (41%) chose the green utility, whereas 52 of 77<br />

participants (68%) in the green condition chose the green<br />

utility. When the two options were presented in a neutral<br />

format (neutral condition), 67% chose green. A 3 2 w 2<br />

analysis shows that there was an overall effect of condition<br />

on participants’ choices, w 2 (2) ¼ 13.94, p ¼ .001.<br />

To assess which of the effects in the data are statistically<br />

significant, two separate 2 2 w 2 tests were calculated.<br />

Supporting our hypothesis, more participants chose the<br />

green utility in the green condition as compared to<br />

participants from the grey condition, w 2 (1) ¼ 10.52,<br />

p ¼ .001, with a medium effect size (F ¼ .26). Comparing<br />

participants’ choices in the grey and the neutral condition,<br />

more participants chose the green utility in the neutral<br />

condition, w 2 (1) ¼ 9.9, p ¼ .002, F ¼ .26.<br />

3.3.2.2. Reasons. The reasons for the participants’<br />

choices were analysed as follows. We tallied how often an<br />

attribute (such as price or environmental impact) was<br />

mentioned (in a positive or negative way). The most<br />

common reasons and their frequencies are displayed in<br />

Table 2. Two judges carried out the coding independently.<br />

As multiple codes could be assigned to a participant’s<br />

statement, agreement between raters was calculated for<br />

each category separately. Interrater reliability was high<br />

(coefficient k ranged from .72 to .94). Disagreements were<br />

resolved by discussion.<br />

The majority of the participants stated thoughts about<br />

the environment, the price, or both (44%) motivated their<br />

choice. We next wanted to analyse whether different<br />

conditions evoke different thoughts about the issues, but<br />

because there was high variability in the statements, we<br />

were not able to detect systematic differences as a function<br />

of the default. Still, some observations are interesting.<br />

First, 15% of the participants stated that anticipated effort<br />

(such as requesting a new contract) or laziness prevented<br />

them from switching, a tendency supporting the default<br />

option. Second, in the majority of cases, when distrust or<br />

scepticism of a provider was stated, it referred to the<br />

alternative, non-default option (17 of 19 statements;<br />

UNCORRECTED PROOF<br />

grey condition<br />

(n = 75)<br />

D. Pichert, K.V. Katsikopoulos / Journal of Environmental Psychology ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]]<br />

green condition<br />

(n = 77)<br />

neutral condition<br />

(n = 73)<br />

Fig. 1. Choices of carrier across the three conditions.<br />

Table 2<br />

Frequencies of mentioned arguments<br />

Argument Mentioned<br />

(%)<br />

Price considerations 71<br />

Environmental considerations 62<br />

Anticipated efforts caused by switching/laziness a<br />

15<br />

Distrust/scepticism of a provider 12<br />

Given insufficient information about energy sources or<br />

further conditions<br />

9<br />

Criticism of the default itself 2<br />

a Excluded in neutral condition.<br />

Please cite this article as: Pichert, D., & Katsikopoulos, K. V. <strong>Green</strong> <strong>defaults</strong>: Information presentation and pro-environmental.... Journal of<br />

Environmental Psychology (2007), doi:10.1016/j.jenvp.2007.09.004<br />

59<br />

61<br />

63<br />

65<br />

67<br />

69<br />

71<br />

73<br />

75<br />

77<br />

79<br />

81<br />

83<br />

85<br />

87<br />

89<br />

91<br />

93<br />

95<br />

97<br />

99<br />

101<br />

103<br />

105<br />

107<br />

109<br />

111<br />

113


1<br />

3<br />

5<br />

7<br />

9<br />

11<br />

13<br />

15<br />

17<br />

19<br />

21<br />

23<br />

25<br />

27<br />

29<br />

31<br />

33<br />

35<br />

37<br />

39<br />

41<br />

43<br />

45<br />

47<br />

49<br />

51<br />

53<br />

55<br />

57<br />

neutral condition excluded). Third, in the cases where<br />

participants reported insufficient information, most of<br />

them wanted to learn more about the alternative option<br />

(12 out of 16), whereas fewer people stated that they would<br />

gather information about the default company (2 persons)<br />

or about both companies for comparison (2 persons;<br />

neutral condition excluded). Last, it is worth mentioning<br />

that only very few people (2%) criticised the default itself<br />

(‘‘I do not like becoming a customer of a utility<br />

automatically; this is impertinent’’).<br />

3.3.3. Discussion<br />

The results of this experiment support the hypothesis<br />

that people are more likely to choose the green option<br />

when it is presented as the default than when it is presented<br />

as an alternative. Moreover, a similar effect occurred<br />

between the grey default format and a neutral presentation<br />

format without any option being a default. (In reality,<br />

however, this situation is rare, as German energy law<br />

prescribes that incumbent utilities have to provide a ‘basic<br />

supply’.)<br />

The reasons the participants gave for their decisions<br />

provide some indication of why electricity <strong>defaults</strong> work.<br />

Expected inconvenience and uncertainty associated with<br />

switching might prevent people from doing so. Furthermore,<br />

distrust, scepticism, or complaints about insufficient<br />

information referred, in most cases, to the alternative<br />

option. Only a few participants seemed to assume that the<br />

default option had to be assessed or that there could be<br />

something wrong with it. Possibly, many people interpret<br />

the default option as an implicit recommendation in the<br />

sense that if there is a standard established by an authority,<br />

it cannot be (very) wrong.<br />

We have to admit that this experiment is different in<br />

several ways from choosing an electricity supplier in reality.<br />

First, in reality customers might not be directly confronted<br />

with the decision problem, as in the questionnaire. Second,<br />

in the questionnaire, the decision between the options can<br />

be made without any real transaction costs or search costs,<br />

and it has no real consequences. Third, in reality, some<br />

people might not even know that they can choose their<br />

electricity supplier. But all three arguments work in favour<br />

of the default in the real world. In fact, this might explain<br />

why substantially more participants switched in our study<br />

than in real life. The same tendency can be found in the<br />

organ donation study (Johnson & Goldstein, 2003). Our<br />

next experiment looks into the influence of <strong>defaults</strong> in the<br />

laboratory by investigating dependent variables other than<br />

choice.<br />

UNCORRECTED PROOF<br />

3.4. Second laboratory experiment: willingness to pay and<br />

accept<br />

With this experiment we attempted to examine the<br />

influence of <strong>defaults</strong> in the choice of electricity not by<br />

directly testing how often the green utility is chosen but by<br />

asking for the monetary value people attach to the green<br />

YJEVP : 478<br />

ARTICLE IN PRESS<br />

D. Pichert, K.V. Katsikopoulos / Journal of Environmental Psychology ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]] 7<br />

utility. In decision-making research, there are two ways to<br />

measure this value: willingness to pay (WTP) and willingness<br />

to accept (WTA). The main finding is that<br />

WTA4WTP, that is, to give up a good, people want to<br />

be given more money than they are willing to pay to<br />

acquire that good (Kahneman, Knetsch, & Thaler, 1991).<br />

This is called the endowment effect. In a sense, the<br />

endowment effect and the effect of <strong>defaults</strong> are related<br />

because the default is what people are endowed with. We<br />

thus hypothesise that peoples’ WTA for green electricity<br />

will be higher than their WTP for green electricity (the<br />

corresponding hypothesis for grey electricity does not make<br />

so much sense because people do not seem to be willing to<br />

pay any extra amount of money for grey electricity).<br />

3.4.1. Method and procedure<br />

We gave participants a short questionnaire. The first<br />

laboratory experiment showed that participants hesitated<br />

to switch from one company to another. Hence, in this<br />

second experiment, we stressed that no switching costs<br />

would be involved. Furthermore, because some participants<br />

criticised the lack of information in the first<br />

experiment, we added a short introductory explanation<br />

about electricity and its origins (see Appendix B). The<br />

explanation stressed that various opinions exist about the<br />

different forms of electricity supply (in Germany, not only<br />

is the energy from nuclear power controversial, but also the<br />

extension of wind power), so we wanted to survey<br />

customers’ willingness to pay. We used a betweenparticipants<br />

design with two conditions.<br />

In the WTP condition, participants were asked if they<br />

were willing to switch to green electricity given that they<br />

currently have a grey tariff (see vignette in Appendix B). If<br />

so, they were asked to indicate what extra premium they<br />

would be willing to pay for this per month. Participants in<br />

the WTA condition were asked if they would be willing to<br />

switch to grey electricity given that they are supplied with<br />

green electricity by default. Participants willing to switch<br />

were asked to indicate how much cheaper the grey<br />

electricity tariff would have to be to make them switch.<br />

In both cases, participants had the option to state that<br />

they would not switch by checking a ‘‘no’’ box. Following<br />

Irwin, Slovic, Lichtenstein, and McClelland (1993), WTP<br />

was assumed to be 0 for participants checking ‘‘no’’ in the<br />

WTP condition. The interpretation is that they are simply<br />

not willing to pay more for green electricity and thus their<br />

response is ‘‘0’’.<br />

Participants not providing a value in the WTA condition<br />

were excluded from the WTP/WTA comparison (Irwin et<br />

al., 1993) because it is well known that participants in<br />

WTA conditions refuse to provide monetary values for<br />

decisions with moral connotations (Kahneman et al.,<br />

1991). Note that this behaviour might be interpreted as<br />

‘‘I am not willing to switch to grey energy, even if it is for<br />

free or for any compensation you offer’’. However, as this<br />

response indicates support for the green option, the<br />

Please cite this article as: Pichert, D., & Katsikopoulos, K. V. <strong>Green</strong> <strong>defaults</strong>: Information presentation and pro-environmental.... Journal of<br />

Environmental Psychology (2007), doi:10.1016/j.jenvp.2007.09.004<br />

59<br />

61<br />

63<br />

65<br />

67<br />

69<br />

71<br />

73<br />

75<br />

77<br />

79<br />

81<br />

83<br />

85<br />

87<br />

89<br />

91<br />

93<br />

95<br />

97<br />

99<br />

Q2101<br />

103<br />

105<br />

107<br />

109<br />

111<br />

113


1<br />

3<br />

5<br />

7<br />

9<br />

11<br />

13<br />

15<br />

17<br />

19<br />

21<br />

23<br />

25<br />

27<br />

29<br />

31<br />

33<br />

35<br />

37<br />

39<br />

41<br />

43<br />

45<br />

47<br />

49<br />

51<br />

53<br />

55<br />

57<br />

8<br />

frequency of these ‘‘protest answers’’ in the WTA condition<br />

is reported below.<br />

Participants were also asked to make brief statements<br />

about their behaviour. One more question checked whether<br />

participants knew what they were paying in reality. A short<br />

demographic section ended the questionnaire.<br />

3.4.2. Participants<br />

Eighty-eight participants (56 female, 32 male, age<br />

M ¼ 25.0; SD ¼ 3.2) completed a questionnaire in the<br />

laboratory while waiting for other experiments (and were<br />

given a bar of chocolate). Seventy-seven per cent of the<br />

participants were students. To select the sample size, a<br />

power analysis was carried out to ensure that the study had<br />

at least .80 power. We expected a substantial number of<br />

participants (in the WTA condition) to provide no values<br />

due to protest answers (see above), and therefore,<br />

potentially unequal group sizes were taken into account.<br />

3.4.3. Participants not providing values in the WTA<br />

condition (‘‘protest answers’’)<br />

Twenty-three of the 47 participants (43%) in the WTA<br />

condition indicated that they were not willing to accept<br />

compensation for switching (see above). These participants<br />

were not included in the WTA/WTP comparison.<br />

3.4.4. Willingness to pay and willingness to accept<br />

For the remaining 65 participants, mean WTP and WTA<br />

were analysed. Results are displayed in Fig. 2. The<br />

participants’ WTP had a mean value of M ¼ h6.59<br />

(SD ¼ h5.53, n ¼ 41). The mean WTA was M ¼ h13.00<br />

(SD ¼ h7.34, n ¼ 24). A t-test revealed a significant<br />

difference, t(63) ¼ 4.02, p ¼ .001. Cohen’s d was 1.03,<br />

representing a large effect (Cohen, 1988).<br />

€<br />

16<br />

12<br />

8<br />

4<br />

0<br />

YJEVP : 478<br />

ARTICLE IN PRESS<br />

D. Pichert, K.V. Katsikopoulos / Journal of Environmental Psychology ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]]<br />

3.4.5. Switching behaviour<br />

An alternative interpretation is that people checking<br />

‘‘no’’ (in both conditions) were not willing to switch to the<br />

alternative tariff. For this reason, we compared the share of<br />

potential switchers and non-switchers. All 88 participants<br />

were included in the analysis. As reported above, 23 of the<br />

47 participants (43%) in the WTA condition were under no<br />

means willing to switch, whereas 9 of 41 participants (22%)<br />

in the WTP condition refused to switch (i.e. WTP ¼ 0).<br />

The share of ‘‘stayers’’ is higher in the WTA condition,<br />

w 2 (1) ¼ 6.9, p ¼ .009.<br />

3.4.6. Statements<br />

We used the same procedure as in the first laboratory<br />

experiment, again with good interrater agreement (k<br />

ranging from .85 to .95). Statements about the environment<br />

(67% of the participants) or about the price difference<br />

(65%) were predominant, while 48% of the participants<br />

thought about both. But we were not able to detect any<br />

differences that could be attributed to the varying<br />

conditions.<br />

The interpretation of the answers to the question of how<br />

much the participants were paying turned out to be<br />

difficult; most students live in shared flats, and many of<br />

them could not give a precise estimation of their share of<br />

the monthly bill (36% did not know what they were paying<br />

at all; others gave the sum for the whole shared flat). As a<br />

result, the variance of the sums was so high that we decided<br />

to omit further analysis.<br />

3.4.7. Discussion<br />

As hypothesised, participants were willing to pay a small<br />

premium for green electricity but demanded considerably<br />

more in compensation for giving up the green electricity<br />

supply. Note that only 57% of the participants in the WTA<br />

condition were included in the WTP/WTA analysis: the<br />

others stated that they would not switch no matter what<br />

the reduction might be. Overall, the findings support our<br />

hypothesis: once a green default is established, people are<br />

either reluctant to move away from this reference point or<br />

they demand a relatively large sum to do so (since<br />

WTA4WTP).<br />

4. General discussion: can <strong>defaults</strong> promote proenvironmental<br />

behaviour?<br />

We reported four studies that demonstrate a strong<br />

effect of information presentation format, specifically of<br />

the default used, on the choice of electricity utility. In<br />

electricity markets as currently organised, this effect leads<br />

to generation and consumption of energy from unsustainable<br />

sources. Changing the grey default—by establishing a<br />

green default or by just implementing a neutral choice<br />

situation—results in a significantly higher percentage of<br />

customers buying green electricity.<br />

Although we suggested some explanations for why<br />

<strong>defaults</strong> in electricity marketing work and provided some<br />

UNCORRECTED PROOF<br />

WTP (n= 41) WTA (n = 24)<br />

Fig. 2. Stated willingness to pay and willingness to accept for green<br />

electricity in euros. Error bars display standard error.<br />

Please cite this article as: Pichert, D., & Katsikopoulos, K. V. <strong>Green</strong> <strong>defaults</strong>: Information presentation and pro-environmental.... Journal of<br />

Environmental Psychology (2007), doi:10.1016/j.jenvp.2007.09.004<br />

59<br />

61<br />

63<br />

65<br />

67<br />

69<br />

71<br />

73<br />

75<br />

77<br />

79<br />

81<br />

83<br />

85<br />

87<br />

89<br />

91<br />

93<br />

95<br />

97<br />

99<br />

101<br />

103<br />

105<br />

107<br />

109<br />

111<br />

113


1<br />

3<br />

5<br />

7<br />

9<br />

11<br />

13<br />

15<br />

17<br />

19<br />

21<br />

23<br />

25<br />

27<br />

29<br />

31<br />

33<br />

35<br />

37<br />

39<br />

41<br />

43<br />

45<br />

47<br />

49<br />

51<br />

53<br />

55<br />

57<br />

exploratory analyses, we did not pursue this further here.<br />

We focused on showing that they work. More theoretical<br />

research is required, for example, on understanding better<br />

the recommendations that people perceive to be implicit in<br />

<strong>defaults</strong> (McKenzie et al., 2006). Another promising<br />

direction could investigate the finding that people consider<br />

themselves far more responsible for their actions than for<br />

their omissions (Spranca, Minsk, & Baron, 1991).<br />

At any rate, there may be opportunity for applications,<br />

especially at a local level. Imagine a community whose<br />

government plans to launch a new green electricity<br />

programme to decrease the share of conventional power<br />

production from older plants. If this was a legally and<br />

politically feasible option, the community might enrol their<br />

citizens automatically in the programme, thus establishing<br />

a default. Of course citizens would be free to opt out of the<br />

programme any time they wish. Another example might be<br />

a block of flats that is supplied with green electricity when<br />

people move in. Finally, apart from making the more<br />

environmentally benign option the default, it may be worth<br />

trying the least intrusive option of abandoning <strong>defaults</strong><br />

altogether.<br />

We finish by urging for caution because the manipulation<br />

of <strong>defaults</strong> has its limits. There are technical issues,<br />

limitations of default effects, and moral issues. First, it may<br />

be that, from an engineering standpoint, the implementation<br />

of a green default is not possible. For example, it has<br />

been argued that the national energy supply of a country<br />

could not simply be replaced by renewable energy<br />

production from one day to the next even if all the<br />

consumers wanted to buy green power now. In the<br />

Netherlands, for example, suppliers had to stop advertising<br />

green power because it was sold out after 13% of the<br />

customers decided to buy green electricity (Bird et al.,<br />

2002). Perhaps, however, some imagination can be used to<br />

develop creative solutions (e.g. voluntary premiums), since<br />

the central issue is changing investment flows.<br />

Second, note that even though the influence of <strong>defaults</strong> is<br />

strong, if price differences become too large, customers<br />

might react. For example, customers will not remain with a<br />

tariff when it costs $1000 more each month regardless of<br />

whether it is the default or not. Also, when customers<br />

suspect that the vendor or the policy maker wants to force<br />

an option upon them, they might react (Brown & Krishna,<br />

2004).<br />

Third and finally, policy makers intentionally changing<br />

<strong>defaults</strong> may be accused of paternalistic manipulation<br />

(Berg & Gigerenzer, 2007; Klein, 2004; Sunstein & Thaler,<br />

UNCORRECTED PROOF<br />

2003; Thaler & Sunstein, 2003). Of course, to some extent,<br />

institutions always provide starting points and <strong>defaults</strong>.<br />

And, from the environmental perspective, the existing<br />

default is not the most desirable. However, frequent opting<br />

out or switching might cause citizens to experience stress or<br />

unpleasantness. It is not so trivial to impose a default<br />

condition that conflicts with the fundamental values held<br />

by an individual as this might force a person to react. But<br />

when these ethical issues are taken into account, the<br />

YJEVP : 478<br />

ARTICLE IN PRESS<br />

D. Pichert, K.V. Katsikopoulos / Journal of Environmental Psychology ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]] 9<br />

manipulation of default rules actually might cause less<br />

excitement than expected.<br />

Dealing with the ‘‘human factor’’ in sustainable development<br />

and pro-environmental behaviour can yield<br />

theoretical and practical challenges (Gardner & Stern,<br />

2002; Nickerson, 2003; Stern, 2000a, 2000b). Our specific<br />

findings demonstrate that in many cases, what we prefer<br />

depends on the context of choice and how the choice is<br />

presented (Bettman, Luce, & Payne, 1998; Payne et al.,<br />

1992); this has already been demonstrated for human<br />

behaviour in areas such as health, finance, law, and<br />

marketing. When it comes to environmental issues, it is<br />

our conviction that a stronger consideration of insights<br />

from decision-making research will contribute to a better<br />

understanding and encouragement of pro-environmental<br />

behaviour.<br />

Acknowledgements<br />

We would like to thank Yaniv Hanoch, Mark Heitmann,<br />

Daniel Goldstein, Felix Warneken, Stefan Krauss and the<br />

ABC Research Group for their comments and ideas.<br />

Appendix A. Instructions in first laboratory experiment<br />

(translated from German)<br />

Grey condition: ‘‘Imagine you have to relocate to another<br />

town. After you move into your new flat, you receive a<br />

letter from the electric power supplier, Acon. You are told<br />

that by moving into your new flat you became an Acon<br />

customer: ‘Acon is pleased to welcome you as a new<br />

customer. We are responsible for the basic electricity<br />

supply in this residential area. We offer low-priced<br />

electricity tariffs—you cannot beat our prices. Save money<br />

with Acon! Your monthly premium is h25’. You are kindly<br />

asked to fill in some personal data on an attached<br />

document, which you do. A couple of days later a contract<br />

is sent to you.<br />

Some weeks later you find a flyer in you mailbox,<br />

advertising offers from the electric power supplier EcoEnergy:<br />

‘Switch to EcoEnergy! Did you know that you can<br />

easily switch your electricity supplier? EcoEnergy sells clean<br />

electricity, generated from renewable energy sources. Contribute<br />

to climate protection and environmental protection!<br />

Your monthly premium will be h30’’’.<br />

What do you do? (please check box)<br />

& Stay with Acon<br />

& Switch to Ecoenergy<br />

<strong>Green</strong> condition: The vignette described the reverse<br />

situation; that is, the default company offered ‘green’<br />

power and the advertisement was for cheaper electricity<br />

(see text). Although premiums for electricity vary according<br />

to individual consumption, participants were told by<br />

the experimenter to accept the premiums as given for the<br />

sake of simplicity.<br />

Please cite this article as: Pichert, D., & Katsikopoulos, K. V. <strong>Green</strong> <strong>defaults</strong>: Information presentation and pro-environmental.... Journal of<br />

Environmental Psychology (2007), doi:10.1016/j.jenvp.2007.09.004<br />

59<br />

61<br />

63<br />

65<br />

67<br />

69<br />

71<br />

73<br />

75<br />

77<br />

79<br />

81<br />

83<br />

85<br />

87<br />

89<br />

91<br />

93<br />

95<br />

97<br />

99<br />

101<br />

103<br />

105<br />

107<br />

109<br />

111<br />

113


1<br />

3<br />

5<br />

7<br />

9<br />

11<br />

13<br />

15<br />

17<br />

19<br />

21<br />

23<br />

25<br />

27<br />

29<br />

31<br />

33<br />

35<br />

37<br />

39<br />

41<br />

43<br />

45<br />

47<br />

49<br />

51<br />

53<br />

55<br />

57<br />

10<br />

Neutral condition: Here, the vignette had slightly<br />

different wording: ‘‘Imagine you have to relocate to<br />

another town. After you move into your new flat, your<br />

landlord kindly asks you to choose a power supplier. In<br />

this building, two electric power companies offer electricity.<br />

Here is some information about the two suppliers.’’<br />

Then the information about the two companies is given. To<br />

control for order effects, the order of the options was<br />

permutated randomly.<br />

Appendix B. Instructions in second laboratory experiment<br />

(translated from German)<br />

General information: ‘‘Electricity is produced in various<br />

ways. In Germany, conventionally produced electricity is—<br />

for the most part—generated by the burning of fossil fuels<br />

(e.g. coal) and atomic power. So-called green electricity is<br />

generated from renewable energy sources, such as water,<br />

wind, biomass, and to a small degree, the sun. In the<br />

majority of cases, green electricity is more expensive than<br />

conventional electricity. Renewable energy sources are<br />

considered to be more environmentally benign. By the way,<br />

the household electricity that is provided to customers via<br />

the grid is standardised and is technically homogeneous.<br />

Only the way it is generated and fed into the grid might<br />

vary according to the contracted utility. We would like to<br />

emphasise that there are many different opinions about<br />

both conventional methods of electricity generation and<br />

renewable energies.<br />

We have some questions about the electricity prices you<br />

are willing to pay. Please read the questions carefully first.<br />

We would like to encourage you to ‘try’ several numbers in<br />

your head before giving your final answer.’’<br />

WTP condition: ‘‘There are cities in Germany whose<br />

inhabitants are supplied with conventionally produced<br />

electricity. Imagine you live in one of these cities. You are<br />

free to switch to green electricity, if you wish. Then you<br />

would pay a higher monthly premium. Would you be<br />

willing to switch?’’<br />

& NO.<br />

& YES. If yes, what is the maximum additional amount<br />

you would be willing to pay each month?<br />

______ euros<br />

WTA condition: ‘‘There are German cities whose<br />

inhabitants are supplied with green electricity by default.<br />

Imagine you live in one of these cities. You are free to<br />

UNCORRECTED PROOF<br />

switch to conventionally produced electricity, if you wish.<br />

Then you would pay a lower monthly premium. Would<br />

you be willing to switch?’’<br />

& NO.<br />

& YES. If yes, what is the minimum amount by which<br />

your monthly premium would have to be reduced?<br />

______ euros<br />

YJEVP : 478<br />

ARTICLE IN PRESS<br />

D. Pichert, K.V. Katsikopoulos / Journal of Environmental Psychology ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]]<br />

References<br />

Anderson, J. A. (2003). The psychology of doing nothing: Forms of<br />

decision avoidance result from reason and emotion. Psychological<br />

Bulletin, 129(1), 139–167.<br />

Bamberg, S. (2003). How does environmental concern influence specific<br />

environmentally related behaviors? A new answer to an old question.<br />

Journal of Environmental Psychology, 23, 21–32.<br />

Berg, N., & Gigerenzer, G. (2007). Psychology implies paternalism?:<br />

Bounded rationality may reduce the rationale to regulate risk-taking.<br />

Social Choice and Welfare, 28, 337–359.<br />

Bettman, J. R., Luce, M. F., & Payne, J. W. (1998). Constructive<br />

consumer<br />

187–217.<br />

choice processes. Journal of Consumer Research, 25,<br />

Bird, L., Wu¨ stenhagen, R., & Aabakken, J. (2002). A review of<br />

international green power markets: Recent experience, trends, and<br />

market drivers. Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, 6, 513–536.<br />

Brewer, G. D., & Stern, P. C. (Eds.). (2005). Decision making for the<br />

environment: Social and behavioral science research priorities. Panel on<br />

social and behavioral science research priorities for environmental<br />

decision making. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press.<br />

Brown, C. L., & Krishna, A. (2004). The skeptical shopper: A<br />

metacognitive account for effects of <strong>defaults</strong> options on choice.<br />

Journal of Consumer Research, 31, 529–539.<br />

Camerer, C. F. (2000). Prospect theory in the wild: Evidence from the<br />

field. In D. Kahneman, & A. Tversky (Eds.), Choices, values, and<br />

frames (pp. 288–300). New York: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Choi, J., Laibson, D., Madrian, B. C., & Metrick (2002). Defined<br />

contribution pensions: Plan rules, participant decisions, and the path<br />

of least resistance. In J. M. Poterba (Ed.), Tax policy and the economy,<br />

Vol. 16 (pp. 67–114). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.<br />

Clark, F. C., Kotchen, M. J., & Moore, M. R. (2003). Internal and<br />

external influences on pro-environmental behavior: Participation in a<br />

green electricity program. Journal of Environmental Psychology, 23,<br />

237–246.<br />

Cohen, J. (1988). Statistical power analysis for the behavioral sciences.<br />

Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.<br />

Farhar, B. C. (1999). Willingness to pay for electricity from renewable<br />

resources: A review of utility market research (NREL/TP.550.26148).<br />

Golden, CO: National Renewable Energy Laboratory.<br />

Fasolo, B., McClelland, G. H., & Todd, P. M. Escaping the tyranny of<br />

choice: When fewer attributes make choice easier. [Special issue on<br />

Judgement and Decision Making] . Marketing Theory, in press.<br />

Gardner, G. T., & Stern, P. C. (2002). Environmental problems and human<br />

behavior. Boston: Pearson Custom Publishing.<br />

Gigerenzer, G., & Hoffrage, U. (1995). How to improve Bayesian<br />

Q3<br />

reasoning without instruction: Frequency formats. Psychological<br />

Review, 102(4), 684–704.<br />

Gigerenzer, G., Todd, P. M. & the ABC Research Group. (1999). Simple<br />

heuristics that make us smart. New York: Oxford University Press.<br />

Hanoch, Y., Katsikopoulos, K. V., Gummerum, M., & Brass, E. P.<br />

German and American students’ knowledge, perception, and behavior<br />

with respect to over-the-counter pain relievers. Health Psychology, in<br />

press.<br />

Harrison, G. W., & List, J. A. (2004). Field experiments. Journal of<br />

Economic Literature, 42(4), 1009–1055.<br />

Irwin, J. R., & Baron, J. (2001). Response mode effects and moral values.<br />

Q4<br />

Organizational<br />

177–197.<br />

Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 84(2),<br />

Irwin, J. R., Slovic, P., Lichtenstein, S., & McClelland, G. H. (1993).<br />

Preference reversals and the measurement of environmental values.<br />

Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 6, 5–18.<br />

Johnson, E. J., Bellman, S., & Lohse, G. L. (2002). Defaults, framing and<br />

privacy: Why opting in-opting out. Marketing Letters, 13(1), 5–15.<br />

Johnson, E. J., & Goldstein, D. (2003). Do <strong>defaults</strong> save lives? Science,<br />

302, 1338–1339.<br />

Please cite this article as: Pichert, D., & Katsikopoulos, K. V. <strong>Green</strong> <strong>defaults</strong>: Information presentation and pro-environmental.... Journal of<br />

Environmental Psychology (2007), doi:10.1016/j.jenvp.2007.09.004<br />

59<br />

61<br />

63<br />

65<br />

67<br />

69<br />

71<br />

73<br />

75<br />

77<br />

79<br />

81<br />

83<br />

85<br />

87<br />

89<br />

91<br />

93<br />

95<br />

97<br />

99<br />

101<br />

103<br />

105<br />

107<br />

109<br />

111<br />

113


1<br />

3<br />

5<br />

7<br />

9<br />

11<br />

13<br />

15<br />

17<br />

19<br />

21<br />

23<br />

25<br />

27<br />

29<br />

31<br />

33<br />

Johnson, E. J., Hershey, J., Meszaros, J., & Kunreuther, H. (1993).<br />

Framing, probability distortions, and insurance decisions. Journal of<br />

Risk and Uncertainty, 7, 35–51.<br />

Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1991). Anomalies: The<br />

endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias. Journal of<br />

Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 193–206.<br />

Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of<br />

decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263–292.<br />

Klein, D. B. (2004). Status quo bias. Econ Journal Watch, 1(2), 260–271.<br />

Laboratory for Energy and the Environment. (2005). A survey of public<br />

attitudes towards energy and environment in Great Britain. Cambridge,<br />

MA: Massachusetts <strong>Institut</strong>e of Technology, Laboratory for Energy<br />

and the Environment. Available from /http://lfee.mit.edu/publicationsS.<br />

Madrian, B., & Shea, D. (2001). The power of suggestion: Inertia in 401(k)<br />

participation and savings behavior. Quarterly Journal of Economics,<br />

116, 11–49.<br />

McKenzie, C. R. M., Liersch, M. J., & Finkelstein, S. R. (2006).<br />

Recommendations implicit in policy <strong>defaults</strong>. Psychological Science,<br />

17, 414–420.<br />

MORI. (1996). <strong>Green</strong> energy: A survey of public opinions by MORI.<br />

London: The Parliamentary Renewable and Sustainable Energy<br />

Group.<br />

Nickerson, R. S. (2003). Psychology and environmental change. Mahwah,<br />

NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.<br />

Nordic Energy Regulators. (Ed.). (2005). Supplier switching in the Nordic<br />

countries: Current practices and recommendations for the future<br />

development. Available from /http://www.energiamarkkinavirasto.fiS.<br />

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development/International<br />

Energy Agency. (2006). World energy outlook 2006. International<br />

Energy Agency.<br />

Park, C. W., Youl Jun, S., & MacInnis, D. J. (2000). Choosing what I<br />

want versus rejecting what I do not want: An application of decision<br />

framing to product option choice decisions. Journal of Marketing<br />

Research, XXXVII, 187–202.<br />

Payne, J. W., Bettmann, J. R., & Johnson, E. J. (1992). Behavioral<br />

decision research: A constructive processing perspective. Annual<br />

Review of Psychology, 43, 87–131.<br />

YJEVP : 478<br />

ARTICLE IN PRESS<br />

D. Pichert, K.V. Katsikopoulos / Journal of Environmental Psychology ] (]]]]) ]]]–]]] 11<br />

Puto, C. P. (1987). The framing of buying decisions. Journal of Consumer<br />

Research, 14(3), 301–315.<br />

Roberts, P. (2005). The end of oil: On the edge of a perilous new world. New<br />

York: Bloomsbury.<br />

Roe, B., Teisl, M. F., Levy, A., & Russell, M. (2001). US consumers’<br />

willingness to pay for green electricity. Energy Policy, 29, 917–925.<br />

Roe, B., Teisl, M. F., Rong, H., & Levy, A. S. (2001). Characteristics of<br />

consumer preferred labeling policies: Experimental evidence from price<br />

and environmental disclosure for deregulated electricity service.<br />

Journal of Consumer Affairs, 35(1), 1–2.<br />

Rowlands, I. H., Parker, P., & Scott, D. (2004). Consumer behaviour in<br />

restructured electricity markets. Journal of Consumer Behaviour, 3(3),<br />

272–283.<br />

Samuelson, W., & Zeckhauser, R. (1988). Status quo bias in decision<br />

making. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 1, 7–59.<br />

Simon, H. A. (1956). Rational choice and the structure of the<br />

environment. Psychological Review, 63, 129–138.<br />

Slovic, P. (1995). The construction of preference. American Psychologist,<br />

60(5), 364–371.<br />

Spranca, M., Minsk, E., & Baron, J. (1991). Omissions and commissions<br />

in judgement and choice. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology,<br />

27, 76–105.<br />

Stern, P. C. (2000a). Toward a coherent theory of environmentally<br />

significant behavior. Journal of Social Issues, 56(3), 407–424.<br />

Stern, P. C. (2000b). Information, incentives, and proenvironmental<br />

consumer behavior. Journal of Consumer Policy, 22, 461–478.<br />

Sunstein, C. R., & Thaler, R. H. (2003). Libertarian paternalism is not an<br />

oxymoron. University of Chicago Law Review, 70(4), 1159–1202.<br />

Thaler, R. H., & Sunstein, C. R. (2003). Libertarian paternalism.<br />

American Economic Review (Paper and Proceedings), 93(2), 175–179.<br />

Truffer, B., Markard, J., & Wu¨ stenhagen, R. (2001). Eco-labeling of<br />

electricity: Strategies and tradeoffs in the definition of environmental<br />

standards. Energy Policy, 29, 885–897.<br />

Wu¨ stenhagen, R. (2000). Ökostrom—von der Nische zum Massenmarkt.<br />

Entwicklungsperspektiven und Marketingstrategien <strong>für</strong> eine zukunftsfähige<br />

Elektrizitätsbranche. Zürich: vdf-Hochschulverlag.<br />

UNCORRECTED PROOF<br />

Please cite this article as: Pichert, D., & Katsikopoulos, K. V. <strong>Green</strong> <strong>defaults</strong>: Information presentation and pro-environmental.... Journal of<br />

Environmental Psychology (2007), doi:10.1016/j.jenvp.2007.09.004<br />

35<br />

37<br />

39<br />

41<br />

43<br />

45<br />

47<br />

49<br />

51<br />

53<br />

55<br />

57<br />

59<br />

61<br />

63<br />

65<br />

67

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!