30.01.2013 Views

european journal of social sciences issn: 1450-2267 - EuroJournals

european journal of social sciences issn: 1450-2267 - EuroJournals

european journal of social sciences issn: 1450-2267 - EuroJournals

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

European Journal <strong>of</strong> Social Sciences – Volume 5, Number 3 (2007)<br />

From a textbook perspective, competitive markets are relatively uncomplicated and easily<br />

understood; no uncertainty with complete information, complete resource mobility, products or<br />

services which are homogenous among rival firms, and a large number <strong>of</strong> buyers or sellers in the<br />

market so each firm is a price-taker. This view assumes, <strong>of</strong> course, zero transaction costs, i.e., the costs<br />

<strong>of</strong> discovering, contracting, monitoring and enforcing market exchanges. With this assumption, the<br />

determination <strong>of</strong> demand collapses into a relatively easy calculation. However, as Leibenstein pointed<br />

out:<br />

“Microeconomics is not concerned with the internal workings <strong>of</strong> the organization. The<br />

problem <strong>of</strong> internal efficiency is assumed away by postulating the existence <strong>of</strong> a<br />

production function, combined with the maximization postulate. Once we imagine that<br />

the firm knows the relationship between inputs and outputs, we can magically get the best<br />

results, then nothing more need be said. Although such a simplification <strong>of</strong> reality is useful<br />

for some types <strong>of</strong> theory construction, at present, it seems desirable to try to develop<br />

theories on a more realistic basis.” (1987, p.3)<br />

When we enter the actual world <strong>of</strong> economic transactions and competitive markets,<br />

environmental forces such as degrees <strong>of</strong> uncertainty, instability, complexity, information asymmetries,<br />

and positive transaction costs prevail, therefore nothing must be taken for granted or simply assumed<br />

away. Strategic positioning, product differentiation, and organizational culture do play a critical role in<br />

the attainment <strong>of</strong> a competitive advantage in the market. The unique, difficult to imitate, internal<br />

resource configuration <strong>of</strong> a firm provides it with an edge in the competitive market (Barney, Wright &<br />

Ketchen, 2001). This implies that the strategic development and employment <strong>of</strong> a firm’s human<br />

resources are key to acquiring a competitive advantage. These ideas have helped shape new visions for<br />

the function <strong>of</strong> a firm’s human resource department.<br />

The Basic Linkage <strong>of</strong> Derived Demand and Human Resource Planning Process<br />

Although commonly cited throughout most labor economics texts, “the demand for labor is derived<br />

from the demand in the product/service market” is the mantra which <strong>of</strong>ten masks the complexities <strong>of</strong><br />

this relationship and is one that must be fully understood for effective competition.<br />

At its most elementary level, the derived demand principle states that a firm’s demand for<br />

human resources is derived from the firm’s product or service market. This proposition provides a<br />

pathway that links a firm’s resource market with it product/service market. The basic implication <strong>of</strong><br />

this principle is that the firm’s human resource planning process is simply an algebraic count: given a<br />

forecast <strong>of</strong> product demand, the quantity <strong>of</strong> labor services is simply calculated from the umber <strong>of</strong> units<br />

sold or forecast to be sold. Since most organizations can generalize the headcount required per unit<br />

volume production, the personnel requirements seem as straightforward as the raw materials<br />

requirements. However there are many conditions and factors in the product/service market that<br />

influences and shape the quantity and mix <strong>of</strong> labor services demanded by the firm.<br />

Planning for Derived Demand<br />

In the strategic human resource management planning process, the mix and quantity <strong>of</strong> labor services<br />

required can potentially span a large and variable range <strong>of</strong> skills and talents. Furthermore, simple<br />

changes or shifts in the amount forecast can have dire consequences with respect to the pr<strong>of</strong>itability,<br />

cost, effectiveness and efficiency <strong>of</strong> the firm.<br />

For example, in the service related markets, firms tend to be labor intensive and it is not<br />

unusual for the firm to spend anywhere from forty to eighty cents <strong>of</strong> each revenue dollar for<br />

employees. In manufacturing these costs can range from thirty-five to sixty percent <strong>of</strong> revenue<br />

(Henderson, 2005). Swings in pr<strong>of</strong>itability and efficiency are relatively sensitive to shifts in such labor<br />

costs. With an overestimate <strong>of</strong> demand for human resources, the firm may take on substantially more<br />

90

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!