10.09.2021 Views

Dominick Salvatore Schaums Outline of Microeconomics, 4th edition Schaums Outline Series 2006

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

CHAP. 15] THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION 337

into five price classifications: Sellers of type I charge a price of $80 for the TV, type II sellers charge $90, type III charge

$100, type IV charge $110, and type V charge $120. For a single search, the probability of each price is 1/5, and

the expected price is the weighted average of all prices, or $100 [($80)(0,2) þ ($90)(0,2) þ ($100)(0,2) þ

($110)(0,2) þ ($120)(0,2) ¼ $100]. The consumer can now purchase the TV at the price of $100, or she can continue

the search for lower prices. With each additional search the consumer will find a lower price, until the lowest price of

$80 is found. The reduction in price with each search gives the marginal benefit of the search. The consumer will end

the search when the marginal benefit from the search equals the marginal cost.

EXAMPLE 3. The lowest TV price expected from one search for the case in Example 2 is:

Expected Price ¼ $80 þ $40 ¼ $100 (as found in Example 1)

1 þ 1

The approximate lowest expected price from two searches is $80 þ ($40/3) ¼ $93.33. Thus, the approximate marginal

benefit from the second search is $100 2 $93.33 ¼ $6.67. The lowest expected price with three searches is

$80 þ ($40/4) ¼ $90, so that MB ¼ $3.33. For four searches it is $80 þ ($40/5) ¼ $88, so that MB ¼ $2. For five

searches it is $80 þ ($40/6) ¼ $86.67, so that MB ¼ $1.33. If the marginal cost of each additional search for the consumer

is $2, the consumer should, therefore, conduct four searches. The higher is the price of the commodity, and the greater is

the range of product prices, the more searches a consumer will undertake (see Problem 15.5). Because consumers face

different marginal costs of search, they will end the search at different points and end up paying different prices for

the product.

15.3 ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION: THE MARKET FOR LEMONS AND

ADVERSE SELECTION

When one party to a transaction has more information than the other on the quality of the product (i.e., with

asymmetric information), the low-quality product or “lemon” will drive the high-quality product out of the

market. One way to overcome such a problem of adverse selection is for the buyer to get, or the seller to

provide, more information on the quality of the product or service. Such is the function of brand names,

chain retailers, professional licensing, and guarantees.

EXAMPLE 4. Insurance companies try to overcome the problem of adverse selection by requiring medical checkups,

charging different premiums for different age groups and occupations, and offering different rates of coinsurance,

amounts of deductibility, and length of contracts. The only way to avoid the problem entirely is with universal compulsory

health insurance. Credit companies reduce the adverse selection process that they face by sharing “credit histories” with

other insurance companies.

15.4 MARKET SIGNALING

The problem of adverse selection resulting from asymmetric information can be resolved or greatly

reduced by market signaling. Brand names, guarantees, and warranties are used as signals for higher-quality

products, for which consumers are willing to pay higher prices. The willingness to accept coinsurance and

deductibles signals low-risk individuals to whom insurance companies can charge lower premiums. Credit

companies use good credit histories to make more credit available to good-quality borrowers, and firms use

educational certificates to identify more-productive potential employees to receive higher salaries.

15.5 THE PROBLEM OF MORAL HAZARD

The insurance market faces also the problem of moral hazard, or the increase in the probability of an

illness, fire, or other accident when an individual is insured than when he or she is not. The reason is that

with insurance, the loss is shifted from the individual to the insurance company. If not contained, this could

lead to unacceptably high insurance costs. Insurance companies try to overcome the problem of moral

hazard by specifying the precautions that an individual or firm must take as a condition of insurance, and by

coinsurance (i.e., insuring only part of the possible loss).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!