Dominick Salvatore Schaums Outline of Microeconomics, 4th edition Schaums Outline Series 2006

fagbohunmichael
from fagbohunmichael More from this publisher
10.09.2021 Views

250 PRICE AND OUTPUT UNDER MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY [CHAP. 10(4) Even in markets in which there are many small sellers of a good or service (say, gasoline stations) a change inprice by one of them affects nearby stations significantly and evokes a response. In such cases, the oligopolymodel is the more appropriate model to use.Despite these serious criticisms, however, the monopolistic competition model provides some important insights,such as its emphasis on product differentiation and selling expenses, that are applicable to oligopolistic markets.OLIGOPOLY DEFINED10.9 (a) Define oligopoly. (b) What is the single most important characteristic in oligopolistic markets and(c) to what problem does it lead? (d) What does oligopoly theory achieve?(a) Oligopoly is the form of market organization in which there are few sellers of a commodity. If there are onlytwo sellers, we have a duopoly. If the product is homogeneous (e.g., steel, cement, copper), we have a pureoligopoly. If the product is differentiated (e.g., cars, cigarettes), we have a differentiated oligopoly. For simplicity,in the text and in that which follows we deal mostly with a pure duopoly. Oligopoly is the most prevalentform of market organization in the manufacturing sector of modern economies and arises for the samegeneral reasons as monopoly (i.e., economies of scale, control over the source of raw materials, patents,and government franchise).(b) The interdependence among the firms in the industry is the single most important characteristic setting oligopolyapart from other market structures. This interdependence is the natural result of fewness. That is, sincethere are few firms in an oligopolistic industry, when one of them lowers its price, undertakes a successfuladvertising campaign, or introduces a better model, the demand curve faced by other oligopolists will shiftdown. So the other oligopolists react.(c) There are many different reaction patterns of the other oligopolists to the actions of the first, and unless anduntil we assume a specific reaction pattern, we cannot define the demand curve faced by our oligopolist. So wehave an indeterminate solution. But even if we assume a particular reaction pattern so that we may have adeterminate solution, this is only one out of many possible solutions.(d ) Because of the situation outlined in (c), we do not now have a general theory of oligopoly. All we have arespecific cases or models, a few of which are discussed in Sections 10.6 to l0.11. These few models, however,do accomplish three things: (1) they show clearly the nature of oligopolistic interdependence, (2) they pointout the gaps that a satisfactory theory of oligopoly must fill, and (3) they give some indication as to how verydifficult this branch of microeconomics really is and how long we may have to wait to get a general theory ofoligopoly. In short, oligopoly theory is one of the least satisfactory segments of microeconomics.THE COURNOT, BERTRAND, AND EDGEWORTH MODELS10.10 Assume that (1) there are only two firms, A and B, selling a homogeneous commodity produced at zerocost, (2) the total market demand function for this commodity is given by QD ¼ 240 2 10P, where P isgiven in dollars, and (3) firm A enters the market first, followed by firm B, but each always assumes, indetermining its best level of output, that the other will hold output constant.With reference to the above, (a) show with the aid of a diagram how duopolists A and B reach theequilibrium point. (b) What price will each charge when in equilibrium? How does this compare withthe monopoly price? With the perfectly competitive price? (c) What quantity will each produce when inequilibrium? How does this compare with the monopoly output? With the perfectly competitive output(d) How much profit will each duopolist make when in equilibrium? How does this compare with themonopoly profits? With the case of perfect competition? (e) What would happen to the equilibriumindustry output and price if one more firm entered this industry? If many more firms came in?(a)Assumptions 1, 2, and 3 given in this problem define the Cournot model. The way duopolists A and B reachtheir equilibrium point is shown in Fig. 10-13. Before duopolist B enters the market, duopolist A will maximizetotal profits at point A on D ¼ d A . This is the monopoly solution. When duopolist B enters the industry, Bwill sell at point B on d B . Duopolist A reacts by selling at point A 0 on dA 0 . The process will continue until eachduopolist will be in equilibrium at point E on d E .

CHAP. 10] PRICE AND OUTPUT UNDER MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY 251Fig. 10-13(b)(c)When in equilibrium, duopolists A and B will charge a price of $8. The monopoly price is $12 (givenby point A). The perfectly competitive price is zero (so that for each firm in long-run equilibrium,TR 2 TC ¼ 0).When in equilibrium, the duopolists will produce 80 units each, for a total of 160 units. This is 4/3 of themonopoly output of 120 units given by point A, and 2/3 of the perfectly competitive output of 240 units(when in long-run equilibrium).(d ) When in equilibrium, the duopolists will make $640 of profit each, for a total of $1280. This compares with atotal profit of $1440 under monopoly and zero profit under perfect competition.(e)If one more firm entered the industry, each of the three firms will produce 60 units or 1/4 of the total perfectlycompetitive output when in long-run equilibrium (so all three of them together will produce 180 units or 3/4ofthe total perfectly competitive output). The price would then fall to $6 (see Fig. 10-13). As more and morefirms enter the industry, the long-run equilibrium industry output and price approach the long-run perfectlycompetitive equilibrium output (of 240 units) and price (of zero dollars).This entire analysis can be extended to cases where costs of production are not zero.10.11 What would happen if, in determining the best level of output, each of the duopolists in Problem 10.10assumes that the other holds price (rather than output) constant?Prices will be undercut by each firm until they are driven down to the competitive level. For example, inFig. 10-13, before duopolist B enters the market, duopolist A will maximize total profits at point A on D ¼ d A .If duopolist B enters the market and assumes that duopolist A will hold the price constant, duopolist B cancapture the entire market by selling at a lower price, say at $11 per unit (see Fig. l0-13). This is so because theproduct is homogeneous. Duopolist A, having lost all sales and on the assumption that duopolist B keeps theprice at $11, lowers its price, say to $10, and will sell the entire quantity of 140 units in the market (see Fig.l0-13). Duopolist B now reacts and the process continues until the perfectly competitive price of $0 and outputof 240 units is established. This is the Bertrand model.10.12 Suppose that (1) there are two firms, A and B, selling a homogeneous commodity produced at zero cost,(2) d A and d B in Fig. l0-14 are duopolist A’s and duopolist B’s demand curves respectively, (3) themaximum output of each firm is 500 units per time period, and (4) each firm in attempting to maximizeits TR or total profit assumes that the other firm holds its price constant. Determine: (a) what happens if

CHAP. 10] PRICE AND OUTPUT UNDER MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY 251

Fig. 10-13

(b)

(c)

When in equilibrium, duopolists A and B will charge a price of $8. The monopoly price is $12 (given

by point A). The perfectly competitive price is zero (so that for each firm in long-run equilibrium,

TR 2 TC ¼ 0).

When in equilibrium, the duopolists will produce 80 units each, for a total of 160 units. This is 4/3 of the

monopoly output of 120 units given by point A, and 2/3 of the perfectly competitive output of 240 units

(when in long-run equilibrium).

(d ) When in equilibrium, the duopolists will make $640 of profit each, for a total of $1280. This compares with a

total profit of $1440 under monopoly and zero profit under perfect competition.

(e)

If one more firm entered the industry, each of the three firms will produce 60 units or 1/4 of the total perfectly

competitive output when in long-run equilibrium (so all three of them together will produce 180 units or 3/4of

the total perfectly competitive output). The price would then fall to $6 (see Fig. 10-13). As more and more

firms enter the industry, the long-run equilibrium industry output and price approach the long-run perfectly

competitive equilibrium output (of 240 units) and price (of zero dollars).

This entire analysis can be extended to cases where costs of production are not zero.

10.11 What would happen if, in determining the best level of output, each of the duopolists in Problem 10.10

assumes that the other holds price (rather than output) constant?

Prices will be undercut by each firm until they are driven down to the competitive level. For example, in

Fig. 10-13, before duopolist B enters the market, duopolist A will maximize total profits at point A on D ¼ d A .

If duopolist B enters the market and assumes that duopolist A will hold the price constant, duopolist B can

capture the entire market by selling at a lower price, say at $11 per unit (see Fig. l0-13). This is so because the

product is homogeneous. Duopolist A, having lost all sales and on the assumption that duopolist B keeps the

price at $11, lowers its price, say to $10, and will sell the entire quantity of 140 units in the market (see Fig.

l0-13). Duopolist B now reacts and the process continues until the perfectly competitive price of $0 and output

of 240 units is established. This is the Bertrand model.

10.12 Suppose that (1) there are two firms, A and B, selling a homogeneous commodity produced at zero cost,

(2) d A and d B in Fig. l0-14 are duopolist A’s and duopolist B’s demand curves respectively, (3) the

maximum output of each firm is 500 units per time period, and (4) each firm in attempting to maximize

its TR or total profit assumes that the other firm holds its price constant. Determine: (a) what happens if

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!