10.09.2021 Views

Dominick Salvatore Schaums Outline of Microeconomics, 4th edition Schaums Outline Series 2006

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

CHAP. 9] PRICE AND OUTPUT UNDER PURE MONOPOLY 213

so as not to unduly complicate the table. The MR of $3 recorded at the sales level of 2.5 units is obtained from the change in

TR resulting from the increase in sales from 2 to 3 units; it will be needed later to show the equilibrium level of output for the

monopolist.

The D and MR schedules of Table 9.1 facing the monopolist are plotted in Fig. 9-1. Note that MR is positive as long as

the demand curve is elastic, is zero when e ¼ 1, and is negative when e , 1. This is because when D is elastic, a reduction in

the commodity price will cause TR to increase, so MR (which is given by DTR/DQ) is positive. When D has unitary elasticity,

a fall in price leaves TR unchanged, and so MR is zero. When D is inelastic, a reduction in price will result in a

reduction in TR, and so MR is negative.

9.2 THE MR CURVE AND ELASTICITY

The MR curve for any straight-line demand curve is a straight line which starts at the same point on the vertical

axis as the demand curve but falls at twice the rate as (i.e., it has twice the absolute slope of) the D curve.

Also, the MR at any level of sales is related to the price at the level of sales by the formula MR ¼ P(l 2 1/e),

where e stands for the absolute value of the coefficient of price elasticity of demand at that level of sales.

EXAMPLE 2. From point A to point B, the D curve of Fig. 9-1 falls by two units and has an absolute slope of 1. To locate

the MR corresponding to point B on the D curve, we drop four units from point A, or twice the drop from A to B, to get point

B 0 on the MR curve. Similarly, from A to C, the D curve falls by four units; thus, the MR corresponding to point C (i.e., point

C 0 ) is obtained by dropping another four units from point C (or 8 units from point A). A straight line from point A through

any one of such MR points (as B 0 or C 0 ) will give us the MR curve.

For the demand curve in Fig. 9-1, at point B,

therefore, MR ¼ $6 1

at point C,

e ¼ B 00 G

OB 00 ¼ 6 2 ¼ 3

1

3

e ¼ C 0 G

OC 0 ¼ 4 4 ¼ 1

therefore, MR ¼ $4 1

at point F,

therefore, MR ¼ $2 1

1

1=3

1

1

¼ $6 2 ¼ $4 ( point B 0 )

3

¼ $4(0) ¼ 0 ( point C 0 )

e ¼ F 0 G

OF 0 ¼ 2 6 ¼ 1 3

¼ $2( 2) ¼ $4 (not shown in the figure)

Note that in the case of perfect competition, e ¼ 1 (infinity). Therefore, MR ¼ P(l 2 1/1) ¼ P(l 2 0) ¼ P. Thus, the

marginal revenue curve and the demand curve of the perfectly competitive firm coincide.

9.3 SHORT-RUN EQUILIBRIUM UNDER PURE MONOPOLY: TOTAL APPROACH

The short-run equilibrium output of the monopolist is the output at which either total profits are maximized

or total losses minimized (provided TR . TVC; see Section 8.5).

EXAMPLE 3. In Table 9.2, TR [column (3)] minus STC [column (4)] gives total profits [column (5)]. Total profits are

maximized (at $3.75) and the monopolist is in short-run equilibrium when producing and selling 2.5 units of the commodity

per time period at the price of $5.50.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!