10.09.2021 Views

Dominick Salvatore Schaums Outline of Microeconomics, 4th edition Schaums Outline Series 2006

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

122 THEORY OF PRODUCTION [CHAP. 6

6.5 THE MARGINAL RATE OF TECHNICAL SUBSTITUTION

The marginal rate of technical substitution of L for K (MRTS LK ) refers to the amount of K that a firm can give

up by increasing the amount of L used by one unit and still remain on the same isoquant. The MRTS LK is also

equal to MP L /MP K . As the firm moves down a isoquant, the MRTS LK diminishes.

EXAMPLE 6. In moving from point B to point C on isoquant I in Fig. 6-3, the firm gives up 3 units of K for one additional

unit of L. Thus, the MRTS LK ¼ 3. Similarly, from point C to D on isoquant I, the MRTS LK ¼ 2. Thus, the MRTS LK

diminishes as the firm moves down an isoquant. This is so because the less K and the more L the firm is using (i.e., the

lower the point on the isoquant), the more difficult it becomes for the firm to substitute L for K in production.

EXAMPLE 7.

Table 6.2.

Table 6.3 gives the MRTS LK between the various points on the negatively sloped portion of the isoquants in

Table 6.3

Isoquant I Isoquant II Isoquant III

L K MRTS LK L K MRTS LK L K MRTS LK

2 11 4 13 6 15

1 8 3 10 5 12

2 5 3.0 4 7 3.0 6 9 3.0

3 3 2.0 5 5 2.0 7 7 2.0

4 2.3 .7 6 4.2 .8 8 6.2 .8

5 1.8 .5 7 3.5 .7 9 5.5 .7

6 1.6 .2 8 3.2 .3 10 5.3 .2

7 1.8 9 3.5 11 5.5

Note that the MRTS LK between two points on the same isoquant is given by the absolute (or positive value of the) slope of

the chord between the two points, while the MRTS LK at a point on the isoquant is given by the absolute slope of the isoquant

at that point. The MRTS LK is also equal to the MP L /MP K . For example, if the MP K is 1 2

at a particular point on an isoquant

while the MP L is 2, this means that one unit of L is 4 times more productive than one additional unit of K at this point. Thus,

the firm can give up four units of K by using one additional unit of L and still produce the same level of output (remain on the

same isoquant). Therefore, the MRTS LK ¼ MP L /MP K ¼ 2/(1/2) ¼ 4 at the given point.

6.6 CHARACTERISTICS OF ISOQUANTS

Isoquants have the same characteristics as indifference curves: (1) in the relevant range isoquants are

negatively sloped, (2) isoquants are convex to the origin and (3) isoquants never cross.

EXAMPLE 8. The relevant portion of an isoquant is negatively sloped. This means that if the firm wants to use less K, it

must use more L to produce the same level of output (i.e., remain on the same isoquant). The firm will not operate on the

positively sloped range of an isoquant because it could produce the same level of output by using less of both L and K. For

example, point A on isoquant I in Fig. 6-4 involves both more L and more K than at point B (also on isoquant I). If we draw

lines separating the relevant (i.e., the negatively sloped) from the irrelevant (i.e., the positively sloped) portions of the isoquants

in Fig. 6-3, we get “ridge lines” OY and OX of Fig. 6-4. The range of isoquants between the ridge lines corresponds to

stage II of production for L and K (see Problems 6.13 and 6.14).

In the relevant range, isoquants are not only negatively sloped but also convex to the origin because of diminishing

MRTS LK . In addition, isoquants cannot cross. If two isoquants crossed, the point of intersection would imply that the

firm could produce two different levels of output with the same combination of L and K. This is impossible if we

assume, as we do, that the firm uses the most efficient production techniques at all times.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!