06.09.2021 Views

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Witt & Tani, TCPI 10. Damages<br />

Fourteenth Amendment in Weinberger v. Weisenfeld, 420 U.S. 636 (1975) (striking down the<br />

different treatment of widows <strong>and</strong> widowers under the Social Security Act as a violation of the<br />

Equal Protection Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment). For more on this theme, see Witt, From<br />

Loss of Services to Loss of Support, supra.<br />

The Death Case Paradox<br />

Bizarrely, in tort cases, killing a plaintiff can be far cheaper for the defendant than injuring<br />

the plaintiff severely. In McDougald v. Garber, 73 N.Y.2d 246 (1989) above, the initial damages<br />

awarded by the jury were $9.7 million, of which $1 million was for conscious pain <strong>and</strong> suffering<br />

<strong>and</strong> over $2 million was for ongoing custodial <strong>and</strong> nursing care. If Mrs. McDougald had died<br />

during the operation, neither of those elements of the damages would have been awarded—<strong>and</strong><br />

there are no additional categories of damages that would have been added instead.<br />

Given the incredibly high cost of a lifetime of intensive medical care <strong>and</strong> nursing services,<br />

the pecuniary damages associated with severe injury can dwarf the wrongful death claims. Is this<br />

structure justified because it takes into account the societal costs of caring for people with severe<br />

impairments, or absurd because it creates perverse incentives for tortfeasors? If you wanted to<br />

“solve” the death case paradox, how would you fix it?<br />

B. Damages in Practice<br />

So far, our discussion of torts has largely focused on only a few actors: a plaintiff, a defendant, a<br />

judge. In practice, actually hammering out a settlement of damages involves many more players with<br />

unique interests <strong>and</strong> perspectives: the plaintiff’s lawyer, the insurance carriers for the defendant <strong>and</strong> the<br />

plaintiff, the jury, <strong>and</strong> others. The dynamics among this larger cast of characters shape the reality of the<br />

torts system in interesting <strong>and</strong> surprising ways.<br />

1. Plaintiffs’ Lawyers <strong>and</strong> the Contingency Fee<br />

In practice, tort damages are mediated heavily by the contingency fee: a fee for legal services paid<br />

as a percentage (usually around one-third) of total damages the plaintiff receives. On the one h<strong>and</strong>, some<br />

argue that the contingency fee is an essential way to provide legal services to clients who do not have the<br />

cash on h<strong>and</strong> to pay a lawyer—especially after suffering an injury that may have caused high medical<br />

expenses <strong>and</strong> unemployment. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the contingency fee has been blamed for spiraling tort<br />

costs <strong>and</strong> concentrating excessive power in the h<strong>and</strong>s of plaintiffs’ lawyers.<br />

Richard Posner lays out the argument for contingency fee as follows:<br />

Suppose a person has a claim of $100,000 <strong>and</strong> a 50 percent probability of<br />

vindicating it if he has a good lawyer. The expected value of the claim is $50,000<br />

<strong>and</strong> would justify him expending up to that amount in lawyer’s fees to protect the<br />

asset. . . . But suppose the claim is his only asset. Ordinarily this would be no<br />

problem; one can borrow a substantial sum against an asset as collateral. But it is<br />

not always possible to borrow against a legal claim. Banks <strong>and</strong> other lending<br />

641

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!