06.09.2021 Views

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Witt & Tani, TCPI 10. Damages<br />

R<strong>and</strong>all Bovbjerg <strong>and</strong> his co-authors proposes that pain <strong>and</strong> suffering damages be dealt with by<br />

schedules or matrices that would provide fixed pain <strong>and</strong> suffering awards for particular classes of<br />

injury:<br />

[We propose] three alternative ways to “schedule” amounts allowable for pain <strong>and</strong><br />

suffering <strong>and</strong> other non-economic damages. Scheduling can provide rational<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ards—heretofore unavailable—for valuation, thus improving the tort system’s<br />

current approach, rather than abolishing or arbitrarily limiting nonpecuniary<br />

damages. We propose that these models be legislatively implemented, although<br />

some change might be accomplished by the judiciary alone, perhaps through a<br />

state’s judicial conference. Dollar values for the schedules could be based on past<br />

jury awards, or possibly on findings of the “value of life” research, with legislative<br />

or judicial adjustments to either.<br />

The three scheduling models discussed here are designed for ordinary cases of<br />

bodily harm <strong>and</strong> mental distress. The first reform model creates a matrix of values<br />

that would award fixed damage amounts according to the severity of injury <strong>and</strong> age<br />

of the injured party. However constructed, the matrix’s values would be binding of<br />

jury findings of nonpecuniary damages, although the possibility of unusually severe<br />

or minor cases may call for ranges of values within the matrix, or some other<br />

provision permitting special attention to “outliers.” The second proposal also gives<br />

juries systematic information on appropriate awards based on past experience.<br />

However, rather than a binding matrix of awards, it provides a small set of<br />

paradigmatic injury “scenarios,” with associated dollar values. These values would<br />

serve as nonbinding benchmarks for assessing the case at trial. A jury would be<br />

free to award any amount, but the benchmarks would serve to guide their award <strong>and</strong><br />

review by trial <strong>and</strong> appellate judges. The third approach m<strong>and</strong>ates fixed limits on<br />

awards of non-economic damages, as many state legislatures have already done.<br />

But we suggest replacing today’s dominant approach of placing a single arbitrary<br />

cap on all non-pecuniary awards with a system of flexible floors <strong>and</strong> ceilings that<br />

vary with injury severity <strong>and</strong> victim age. . . .<br />

We prefer matrices or scenarios to a system of floors <strong>and</strong> caps, primarily because<br />

they more comprehensively address the problems of variability <strong>and</strong> predictability in<br />

damage awards. Floors <strong>and</strong> caps, alternatively, deal only with the problem of<br />

extreme outliers, thus preventing excessive over- <strong>and</strong> under-valuation, but<br />

maintaining broad jury discretion (<strong>and</strong> variability in outcomes) for awards within<br />

the range. Whether matrices or scenarios are preferred depends primarily on how<br />

much one thinks non-economic damages should be individualized, how much one<br />

trusts juries to exercise discretion, <strong>and</strong> the importance one attaches to achieving<br />

similar results in similar cases.<br />

Regardless of the scheduling model adopted, the relative levels <strong>and</strong> absolute sizes<br />

of allowances should be based on past award history, as modified <strong>and</strong> promulgated<br />

by state legislatures <strong>and</strong>, possibly, judiciaries. (We also suggest a substantive<br />

change to provide for non-economic loss in wrongful death.) The increase in values<br />

over time should be controlled, so that longer-term predictability is maintained. Our<br />

proposals are all fairer <strong>and</strong> more consistent with past results than the arbitrary flat<br />

caps now frequently enacted by legislatures—but not infrequently invalidated by<br />

635

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!