06.09.2021 Views

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Witt & Tani, TCPI 9. Liability without Fault?<br />

virtues <strong>and</strong> vices than the plaintiff. Barker, 573 P.2d at 452. Few courts, if any, followed Barker<br />

in this. See, e.g., Ray v. BIC Corp., 925 S.W.2d 527, 532-33 (Tenn. 1996).<br />

2. Risk-utility <strong>and</strong> consumer expectations. Other features of Barker have produced<br />

controversy, too. Barker offers the two answers we discussed above to the puzzle of how to<br />

underst<strong>and</strong> when a product is defective for purposes of strict liability determinations under the<br />

Second Restatement’s section 402A. The first is the risk-utility balancing test that compares the<br />

costs <strong>and</strong> benefits of the challenged design feature. On first glance, this approach might seem to<br />

reproduce the basic cost-benefit reasoning of Learned H<strong>and</strong>’s approach to the negligence<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard. But look closely at the end of the Barker opinion: the question, as the Barker court puts<br />

it, is whether in “hindsight” the product’s costs outweigh its benefits. This, as we noted, is an ex<br />

post Learned H<strong>and</strong> test, one that asks about the risks <strong>and</strong> utility of the product in question not<br />

knowing what a reasonable manufacturer would have known at the time of the product’s design,<br />

but knowing what we know now. In this sense, it is not a negligence approach at all, or at least<br />

not a fault-based approach at all, because one can hardly fault a manufacturer for failing to act on<br />

the basis of information that was not reasonably available to it at the time of design <strong>and</strong><br />

manufacture. The insight of Barker’s ex post cost-benefit analysis is that the absence of<br />

information at the time of product design may not be sufficient reason to relieve manufacturers of<br />

the costs of their product design decisions. If the manufacturer or designer of the product is in a<br />

better position to generate the kinds of information required to make products safe for consumer<br />

use, perhaps we should adopt the ex post rather than the ex ante view. See, for example, Halphen<br />

v. Johns-Manville Sales Corp., 484 So. 2d 110 (La. 1986), where the Louisiana Supreme Court<br />

deemed a product design defective because “the danger-in-fact of the product, whether<br />

foreseeable or not, outweigh[ed] the utility of the product.” Id. at 114.<br />

The second approach in Barker to determining defectiveness is the consumer expectations<br />

approach that we noted above. If a reasonable consumer would have expected the product to be<br />

safer than it is, then the product is defective for purposes of the strict liability of 402A. This<br />

approach has the virtue of not reproducing the cost-benefit test of the negligence st<strong>and</strong>ard (even as<br />

modified in Barker). But its difficulty is that using consumer expectations as the touchstone of an<br />

analysis designed around the premise of consumers’ relative ignorance in the marketplace seems<br />

perverse. If there are product designs that could have made a product safer, why should we<br />

expect consumers to know about them rather than a manufacturers’ expert engineers <strong>and</strong><br />

designers?<br />

What have the courts done? Some courts have refused to take up the cost-benefit test’s<br />

invitation to “open-ended balancing” of risk <strong>and</strong> utility. The Montana Supreme Court, for<br />

instance, rejected the cost-benefit analysis <strong>and</strong> held that if a design fails the consumer expectation<br />

test, then “strict liability may be imposed even if the seller has ‘exercised all possible care,’ <strong>and</strong><br />

even though the product was faultlessly manufactured.” Malcolm v. Evenflo Co., 217 P.3d 514,<br />

520 (Mont. 2009).<br />

A number of courts have stuck with a test “centered on the reasonable expectations of the<br />

ordinary consumer.” Connor v. Skagit Corp., 638 P.2d 115 (Wash. 1981); Massey v. Conagra<br />

Foods, Inc., 328 P.3d 456 (Idaho 2014). But even here, some courts insist that we have not<br />

completely left costs <strong>and</strong> benefits behind. These courts insist that consumer expectations are the<br />

critical question, but regard risk <strong>and</strong> utility as “a guide in determining the expectations of<br />

consumers in complex cases.” Delaney v. Deere & Co., 999 P.2d 930, 944 (Kan. 2000). How<br />

559

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!