06.09.2021 Views

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Witt & Tani, TCPI 4. Negligence St<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

3. Mass torts? If the bellwether strategy violates the parties’ due process rights, what is to<br />

be done in mass torts cases? As U.S. District Judge Jack Weinstein observed in Schwab v. Philip<br />

Morris U.S.A., Inc., 449 F. Supp. 2d 992 (E.D.N.Y. 2006):<br />

In mass fraud cases with hundreds of thous<strong>and</strong>s or millions of injured the cost of<br />

one-on-one procedures is insuperable <strong>and</strong> unsuitable for either a jury or a bench trial.<br />

The consequence of requiring individual proof from each smoker would be to allow<br />

a def0endant which has injured millions of people <strong>and</strong> caused billions of dollars in<br />

damages to escape almost all liability.<br />

Does excluding bellwether trials mean that the resolution of these cases will inevitably happen in<br />

settlements outside of the courtroom—settlements in which the party not holding the cash will be<br />

at a decided disadvantage?<br />

G. Negligence Puzzles<br />

We end our initial treatment of the negligence st<strong>and</strong>ard with three puzzles in the law of<br />

negligence:<br />

1. Should Wealth Matter?<br />

Should the defendant’s wealth matter in setting the reasonable care st<strong>and</strong>ard in a<br />

negligence case? Won’t wealthy actors often be able to go ahead with risky behavior, confident<br />

that the damages suffered by others will have little effect on their own relative wealth? Professors<br />

Ken Abraham <strong>and</strong> John Jeffrey argue the contrary. Wealth, they insist, should not matter if we<br />

want to achieve optimal deterrence:<br />

[T]he defendant’s wealth is irrelevant to deterrence. . . . Deterrence theory is based<br />

on the (usually <strong>and</strong> to one or another extent plausible) assumption that actors weigh<br />

the expected costs <strong>and</strong> benefits of their future actions. Specifically, a potentially<br />

liable defendant will compare the benefits it will derive from an action that risks<br />

tort liability against the discounted present expected value of the liability that will<br />

be imposed if the risk occurs. Whether a defendant is wealthy or poor, this costbenefit<br />

calculation is the same. If, as is likely, a wealthy defendant derives no<br />

greater benefit from a given action than a poor defendant, then both will be equally<br />

deterred (or equally undeterred) by the threat of tort liability. A defendant’s existing<br />

assets do not increase the expected value of a given future action. Therefore they<br />

do not require any adjustment in the level of sanction needed to offset that expected<br />

value. The defendant’s wealth or lack of it is thus irrelevant to the deterrence of<br />

socially undesirable conduct, <strong>and</strong> evidence on the subject is inadmissible in the<br />

typical tort action claiming compensatory damages.<br />

Kenneth Abraham & John Jeffries, Jr., Punitive Damages <strong>and</strong> the Rule of Law: The Role of<br />

Defendant’s Wealth, 18 J. LEGAL STUD. 415, 417 (1989).<br />

250

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!