06.09.2021 Views

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Witt & Tani, TCPI 4. Negligence St<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

mechanism for the compensation of the injured. If we could posit a world in which there are no<br />

transaction costs <strong>and</strong> no informational barriers to determining who is actually injured <strong>and</strong> what<br />

resources are available for payment, the process would be relatively straightforward. The ideal<br />

resolution would be to aggregate all the funds available for asbestos injury, calculate the value of<br />

all the potential claims based upon historic averages of awards, discount for the time benefit <strong>and</strong><br />

lack of risk in administrative resolution (as opposed to the litigation process), <strong>and</strong> distribute the<br />

available funds to the injured on that basis. Assuming accurate forecasting of future claims (in<br />

itself no small matter), full information would yield the total dem<strong>and</strong>, the total compensation<br />

available, <strong>and</strong> what pro rata discount would have to be applied should dem<strong>and</strong> for compensation<br />

exceed available funds. In effect, this is what happens on a smaller scale in the aggregate<br />

settlements that characterize the mature mass tort arena. The question is whether the settlement<br />

structures that have evolved to deal with the large inventory of cases can be replicated more<br />

broadly in some coordinated fashion.<br />

Looking back from this perspective, it is worth noting the consistency with which the<br />

failed attempts at aggregate resolution of asbestos claims have conformed to the same basic<br />

structure for their attempted solutions. Each relied primarily on a payout matrix defined by injury<br />

<strong>and</strong> exposure. Indeed, for all the controversy surrounding each asbestos resolution approach put<br />

forward over the past decade or so, there is almost complete silence on the question of how the<br />

payout matrices were (or will be) structured or how the estimated litigation value of the claims is<br />

to be calculated. Each of the central approaches returns to the same basic structure.<br />

The starting point for the formal aggregate treatment of asbestos cases in litigation is<br />

Cimino v. Raymark Industries. Cimino formalized the intuition that asbestos had long ceased to<br />

be meaningfully addressed through case-by-case adjudication; the evidence in each case was<br />

largely duplicative <strong>and</strong> the valuations of the individualized aspects of the harm incurred could be<br />

predicted with a fair degree of statistical certainty. Cimino attempted to create a trial mechanism<br />

to replicate the settlement grids that had emerged with the concentration of the plaintiffs’ bar in<br />

the 1980s. The key was to reduce each claim to a series of variables . . . that were typically used<br />

in settling cases, but then use those same variables to select representative cases for trial among<br />

the cohort of all asbestos cases then pending in the Eastern District of Texas. Although this<br />

approach was unceremoniously rejected by the <strong>Fifth</strong> Circuit, the Cimino grids were soon to be<br />

integrated into every subsequent aggregate settlement approach. . . .<br />

Alex<strong>and</strong>ra D. Lahav, Bellwether Trials, 76 GEO. WASH. L. REV. 576, 580-89 (2008)<br />

Asbestos is the paradigmatic story of modern mass tort litigation. Although there are some<br />

unique features to the asbestos litigation, it raised for the first time many of the recurring issues in<br />

mass tort litigation. This story has been told at length elsewhere, but it is worth briefly reviewing<br />

to underst<strong>and</strong> why a judge might think binding bellwether trials are the best solution to the<br />

seemingly intractable problems posed by mass torts. . . .<br />

In 1990, Judge Robert Parker, then a federal district court judge for the Eastern District of<br />

Texas, had approximately 3000 wrongful death suits arising out of asbestos exposure before him.<br />

The court could not have tried all these suits in a reasonable time frame, so he adopted an<br />

innovative procedure: binding bellwether trials. He approved a trial plan that was to proceed in<br />

three phases. The first phase provided class-wide determinations of failure to warn <strong>and</strong> punitive<br />

damages. The second phase determined causation. The court intended to have a jury establish<br />

247

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!