06.09.2021 Views

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Witt & Tani, TCPI 4. Negligence St<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

2. The Restatement. According to the Restatement (Third) of <strong>Torts</strong>, “complying with custom<br />

confirms that the actor has behaved in an ordinary way.” RESTATEMENT (THIRD) OF TORTS: PHYS.<br />

& EMOT. HARM § 13 cmt. a (2010). The Restatement further provides that compliance with<br />

custom is “evidence that the actor’s conduct is not negligent but does not preclude a finding of<br />

negligence.” Id. § 13.<br />

3. When is a practice a custom? Customs may provide evidence of reasonableness. But<br />

what constitutes a custom?<br />

A custom, according to one prominent torts treatise, is “a fairly well-defined <strong>and</strong> regular<br />

usage or way of doing a specific thing, among a group of people such as a trade, calling, or<br />

profession.” 3 FOWLER V. HARPER, FLEMING JAMES, JR. & OSCAR S. GRAY, HARPER, JAMES &<br />

GRAY ON TORTS § 17.3 (3d ed. 2006). The U.S. Supreme Court, in an 1838 action for ejectment<br />

of l<strong>and</strong>, defined custom as “the law or rule which is not written <strong>and</strong> which men have used for a<br />

long time, supporting themselves by it in the things <strong>and</strong> reasons with respect to which they have<br />

exercised it,” being introduced by the people, deriving its authority from the express or tacit<br />

consent of the king, <strong>and</strong> having the force of law. See Strother v. Lucas, 37 U.S. 410, 445-46<br />

(1838).<br />

To count as a custom, a practice must be general, see Wise & Co. v. Wecoline Products,<br />

36 N.E.2d 623 (N.Y. 1941); Alberts v. Mutual Serv. Cas. Ins. Co., 123 N.W.2d 96 (S.D. 1963),<br />

definite, fixed, reasonable, <strong>and</strong> old enough to have been known to parties, see Dial v. Lathrop R-II<br />

Sch. Dist., 871 S.W.2d 444, 449 (Mo. 1994). A custom does not have to be universal. See U.S. v.<br />

Stanolind Crude Oil Purchasing Co., 113 F.2d 194 (C.C.A. 10th Cir. 1940). However, it has to<br />

be known <strong>and</strong> practiced by more than a few people <strong>and</strong> cannot be limited to isolated instances.<br />

See El Encanto, Inc. v. Boca Raton Club, Inc., 68 So.2d 819 (Fla. 1953).<br />

4. Majoritarian default rules. Why defer to custom, as Judge Coxe suggests? One reason<br />

might be that the groups that create customs <strong>and</strong> are responsible for the practices in a given field<br />

have lots of very good information about the relevant field <strong>and</strong> are well positioned—much better<br />

positioned than judges <strong>and</strong> juries—to make informed decisions about which risks are reasonable<br />

<strong>and</strong> which risks are not. An industry practice or custom is something that arises out of those<br />

informed decisions. The case for following custom is strongest when, as in The T.J. Hooper, the<br />

parties are in contractual relationships with one another in which the customs of the relevant<br />

industry are known to all involved.<br />

We might think of industry customs or practices in such cases as default rules of<br />

contractual interpretation, or contract presumptions. The question, one might say, is this: how<br />

would the parties have allocated the losses arising out of the absence of radios on the tugs? In<br />

many circumstances, the answer to this question might be said to lie in the custom of the trade. If<br />

the custom is to have radios, then we might imagine that the preferred arrangement among barge<br />

owners <strong>and</strong> tug boat companies is to have radios—<strong>and</strong> thus that the presumptive or default term of<br />

the contract for cases of losses because of the absence of such a radio would be to allocate the<br />

costs to the tugs. In most cases, the theory goes, the allocation that follows what the parties would<br />

usually do—the so-called majoritarian default—will best reflect the expectations of the parties.<br />

For this argument in contract law more generally, see Robert Scott, Theory of Default Rules, 19 J.<br />

LEGAL STUD. 597, 607-08 (1990).<br />

198

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!