06.09.2021 Views

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

Torts - Cases, Principles, and Institutions Fifth Edition, 2016a

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Witt & Tani, TCPI 4. Negligence St<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

spent on, say, better weather forecasting would prevent even more deaths <strong>and</strong><br />

injuries?<br />

More generally, critics object to the cost-benefit framework’s use of a monetary<br />

metric to place the pros <strong>and</strong> cons of an action on a common footing. They complain,<br />

for example, that when a power plant pollutes the air, our gains from the cheap<br />

power thus obtained simply cannot be compared with the pristine view of the Gr<strong>and</strong><br />

Canyon we sacrifice. . . .<br />

This view has troubling implications. . . . Scarcity is a simple fact of the human<br />

condition. To have more of one good thing, we must settle for less of another.<br />

Claiming that different values are incommensurable simply hinders clear thinking<br />

about difficult trade-offs.<br />

Notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing their public pronouncements about incommensurability, even the<br />

fiercest critics of cost-benefit analysis cannot escape such trade-offs. For example,<br />

they do not vacuum their houses several times a day, nor do they get their brakes<br />

checked every morning. The reason, presumably, is not that clean air <strong>and</strong> auto<br />

safety do not matter, but that they have more pressing uses of their time. Like the<br />

rest of us, they are forced to make the best accommodations they can between<br />

competing values.<br />

Cass Sunstein articulates a different defense of cost-benefit reasoning, one that focuses on the<br />

architecture of the decision-making process:<br />

Cass Sunstein, Cognition <strong>and</strong> Cost-Benefit Analysis, 29 J. LEGAL STUD. 1059, 1060 (2000)<br />

[C]ost-benefit analysis is best defended as a means of overcoming predictable<br />

problems in individual <strong>and</strong> social cognition. Most of these problems might be<br />

collected under the general heading of selective attention. Cost-benefit analysis<br />

should be understood as a method for putting “on screen” important social facts that<br />

might otherwise escape private <strong>and</strong> public attention. Thus understood, cost-benefit<br />

analysis is a way of ensuring better priority setting <strong>and</strong> of overcoming predictable<br />

obstacles to desirable regulation, whatever may be our criteria for deciding the<br />

hardest questions about that topic. . . . [T]his method, conceived in a particular way,<br />

might attract support from people with varying conceptions of the good <strong>and</strong> the right,<br />

including, for example, neoclassical economists <strong>and</strong> those who are quite skeptical<br />

about some normative claims in neoclassical economics, involving those who do<br />

<strong>and</strong> who do not take private preferences, <strong>and</strong> willingness to pay, as the proper<br />

foundation for regulatory policy.<br />

Sunstein’s support of cost-benefit reasoning sees the method as the best—perhaps the<br />

only—tool to make transparent, rational decisions in regulatory agencies <strong>and</strong> courtrooms. He<br />

claims that cost-benefit analysis actually helps us organize a broad range of value judgments,<br />

whether or not they fit neatly into existing markets.<br />

Sunstein has also used behavioral science research to suggest that our moral intuitions<br />

against utilitarianism, <strong>and</strong> potentially for alternatives like the precautionary principle, are<br />

172

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!