23.11.2018 Views

Richard H Thaler - Misbehaving- The Making of Behavioral Economics (epub)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

years, there were two kinds <strong>of</strong> shares <strong>of</strong> the merged company Royal Dutch Shell.<br />

Royal Dutch shares traded in New York and the Netherlands, and Shell shares<br />

traded in London. According to the terms <strong>of</strong> the merger agreement that created<br />

this company in 1907, 60% <strong>of</strong> the pr<strong>of</strong>its would go to Royal Dutch shareholders<br />

and 40% would go to Shell shareholders. <strong>The</strong> law <strong>of</strong> one price stipulates that the<br />

ratio <strong>of</strong> the prices <strong>of</strong> the two classes <strong>of</strong> shares should be 60/40 or 1.5. But did the<br />

two share prices always trade at that ratio? No! Sometimes the Royal Dutch<br />

shares traded as much as 30% too low, and other times they traded as much as<br />

15% too high. Noise traders appear to have particular difficulty with multiplying<br />

by 1.5.<br />

In this case, the smart trade is to buy whichever is the cheaper version <strong>of</strong> the<br />

stock and sell the expensive version short. Unlike the case <strong>of</strong> Palm and 3Com,<br />

both versions <strong>of</strong> the stock were widely traded and easy to borrow, so what<br />

prevented the smart money from assuring that the shares traded at their<br />

appropriate ratio <strong>of</strong> 1.5? Strangely, nothing! And crucially, unlike the Palm<br />

example, which was sure to end in a few months, the Royal Dutch Shell price<br />

disparity could and did last for decades.‡ <strong>The</strong>rein lies the risk. Some smart<br />

traders, such as the hedge fund Long Term Capital Management (LTCM), did<br />

execute the smart trade, selling the expensive Royal Dutch shares short and<br />

buying the cheap Shell shares. But the story does not have a happy ending. In<br />

August 1998, because <strong>of</strong> a financial crisis in Asia and a default on Russian<br />

bonds, LTCM and other hedge funds started to lose money and needed to reduce<br />

some <strong>of</strong> their positions, including their Royal Dutch Shell trade. But, not<br />

surprisingly, LTCM was not the only hedge fund to have spotted the Royal<br />

Dutch Shell pricing anomaly, and the other hedge funds had also lost money in<br />

Russia and Asia. So at the same time that LTCM wanted to unwind its position<br />

in Royal Dutch Shell, so did other hedge funds, and the spread moved against<br />

them, meaning that the expensive version got more expensive. Within weeks,<br />

LTCM had collapsed from this and other “arbitrage” opportunities that got worse<br />

before they got better.<br />

<strong>The</strong> LTCM example illustrates what Andrei Shleifer and his frequent coauthor<br />

Robert Vishny call the “limits <strong>of</strong> arbitrage.” In fact, in a paper they published on<br />

this topic in 1997, a year before these events occurred, they quite cannily<br />

described a hypothetical situation much like what LTCM experienced. When<br />

prices start to move against a money manager and investors start to ask for some<br />

<strong>of</strong> their money back, prices will be driven further against them, which can cause<br />

a vicious spiral. <strong>The</strong> key lesson is that prices can get out <strong>of</strong> whack, and smart<br />

money cannot always set things right.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!