JPI Spring 2018

12.05.2018 Views

As shown in Figure 9 above, Germany was significantly repressing its wages in the years leading up to the crisis meaning, misrepresenting its productivity and domestic labor output. 12 We would expect that as productivity increases, unit labor costs (the cost of labor per unit of output) decreases. One of the more important things to take away from Figure 9 is that the decline in unit labor cost growth was not due to any increase in productivity growth, but to a decline in wage inflation. This wage restraint gave German exporters an extra boost, and a manipulative advantage. Interestingly, German productivity growth since 1998 was average, similar to that of France and Portugal. Ironically, Greece and Ireland actually outpaced the economic juggernauts over a 20-year period. 13 12 Bibow. 13 Bibow. JPI Fall 2017, pg. 30

While this cannot explain the entirety of our recent global financial crisis, it certainly shifts the popular perception of a “lazy South” compromising economic prosperity for the “responsible” North. With wage repression largely contributing to Germany’s competitive gains inside the Euro area in the years leading up to the Recession, it is important to note that, just like inflation differentials, unit labor cost growth differentials are cumulative. If sustained over a number of years, as they were, divergent trends build up to massive distortions in relative competitiveness positions. 14 Dem and Koetter’s model shows indications of financial stress, and Bibow’s data demonstrates the attempted remedies for the then-impending economic ills. Lagging productivity, competition, and political leniency toward economic red flags all contributed to Germany’s moral hazard leading up to the Recession. Although the implications are staggering, Germany was not alone. Below is a table representing U.S. labor participation rates from 1969 until the most recent crisis: Like Germany, we see lagging labor rates, years before the crisis occurred. 15 Interestingly enough, in the table below we also see an increase in loan distribution rates during the same given period. 14 Bibow. 15 Michael Borbely, “U.S. labor market in 2008: economy in recession,” Monthly Labor Review (Mar. 2009): 3-19. JPI Fall 2017, pg. 31

As shown in Figure 9 above, Germany was significantly repressing its wages in the years<br />

leading up to the crisis meaning, misrepresenting its productivity and domestic labor output. 12 We<br />

would expect that as productivity increases, unit labor costs (the cost of labor per unit of output)<br />

decreases. One of the more important things to take away from Figure 9 is that the decline in unit<br />

labor cost growth was not due to any increase in productivity growth, but to a decline in wage inflation.<br />

This wage restraint gave German exporters an extra boost, and a manipulative advantage. Interestingly,<br />

German productivity growth since 1998 was average, similar to that of France and Portugal. Ironically,<br />

Greece and Ireland actually outpaced the economic juggernauts over a 20-year period. 13<br />

12<br />

Bibow.<br />

13<br />

Bibow.<br />

<strong>JPI</strong> Fall 2017, pg. 30

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!