MR Microinsurance_2012_03_29.indd - International Labour ...

MR Microinsurance_2012_03_29.indd - International Labour ... MR Microinsurance_2012_03_29.indd - International Labour ...

10.12.2012 Views

46 Emerging issues 2.2 Social protection in developing countries Social protection can be organized by the State, commercial companies, self-help groups or other players. Most countries have social protection systems run by all of them. State-run social protection schemes are financed either by the contributions of their members or by general tax revenues. Social insurance schemes, in particular, are financed by regular contributions and are usually linked to formal (contractual) labour relationships. They are based on specified rules, often underpinned by law, and provide benefits when a member of the household experiences a sudden shock due to a specific risk that is predefined by law (e.g. old age, a disability, or the death of a breadwinner). Social insurance schemes can thus effectively reduce the vulnerability of households that can afford to pay some regular contribution in exchange for a reduced exposure to risk. Nonetheless, they address only a specific set of risks, which may not always include the risks that constitute the most serious threats for their members. For example, such schemes do not, in general, provide protection against harvest failure resulting from weather-related risks – even though these risks constitute a more serious problem for many rural households than old-age or work injuries, which can be managed through the mutual support of relatives and neighbours. In addition, social insurance generally fails to help the extreme poor, who are unable to pay even very small contributions, and thus tend to be excluded from social insurance schemes. Social transfer schemes help to prevent and alleviate both chronic and transitional poverty. In addition, they normally address all kinds of risks, but they tend to be less powerful in terms of reducing the vulnerability of households. Since they are financed by tax revenues, benefits are usually quite limited and aim to prevent households from falling into severe poverty. However, they are not able to prevent any deterioration in the well-being of richer households because the benefits provided by social transfer schemes fall well short of replacing their former income – something that social insurance schemes are often able to do. There are two types of social transfer schemes: “targeted” and “universal” schemes. Targeted schemes grant benefits only to people in need, while universal schemes pay out to all households. Although the sum of the benefits provided by targeted schemes is, as a rule, considerably smaller than the total expenditure of universal schemes, their budgets are sometimes even higher because of the targeting costs involved (i.e. the costs of identifying eligible households). Likewise, a distinction can be made between cash transfer schemes (e.g. social assistance, social pension and basic income grant), vouchers (e.g. for education or health services), and in-kind transfers (e.g. food rations or free public health care).

Th e potential of microinsurance for social protection In general, non-public social protection schemes are fi nanced by contributions. Th is is particularly the case for schemes that are run by commercial companies (including private insurers, in which case the contributions are “premiums”), by self-help groups (such as savings, credit and insurance groups) and by microfi nance institutions. Even mutual support networks expect their members to give their relatives and neighbours approximately as much as they have received from others, the only exception being the charitable support provided by rich households to the poor for philanthropic reasons (see Table 2.1). Table 2.1 Overview of social protection schemes organized by the various players Organized/ administered by: Financed by members’ contributions Financed by taxes or the voluntary donations (addressing vulnerability and specifi c risks) of other households (addressing transient and chronic poverty and a broad range of risks) Government/public Government/public – Social insurance schemes – Social assistance schemes authority – National provident funds – Universal cash transfer schemes – Public credit schemes – Cash/food-for-education schemes – Cash/food-for-work schemes – “Free” public healthcare systems Commercial/private – Commercial savings schemes companies – Commercial credit schemes – Private insurance contracts Semi-formal self-help – Savings and credit clubs groups – Mutual insurance associations Traditional networks networks Mutual support networks Charitable support provided by the rich to poor households Th e main challenge for social protection policies in developing countries results from the fact that the coverage of many schemes is quite limited, in terms of both scale and scope. Indeed, social insurance schemes reach only a minority of the population (see Figure 2.1). With only a few exceptions, old-age insurance covers no more than 40 per cent of the labour force in middle-income countries and 10 per cent of the labour force in low-income countries (ILO, 2010). At the same time, less than 12 per cent of the population have private health or pension insurance (Drechsler and Jütting, 2005), and less than 5 per cent receive public social assistance benefi ts (Barrientos and Holmes, 2007). Eff orts to extend social insurance coverage are often constrained for fi nancial, administrative and political reasons: 1) Most existing schemes are based on formal employment relationships and contributions are shared by employees and employers. Th ese rules are diffi cult to apply in relation to people in unstable, informal employment, especially those who are self-employed. 2) Social insurance organizations face administrative problems in terms of monitoring the enrolment of workers in the informal economy, collecting their contributions and properly administering their claims. 47

46 Emerging issues<br />

2.2 Social protection in developing countries<br />

Social protection can be organized by the State, commercial companies, self-help<br />

groups or other players. Most countries have social protection systems run by all<br />

of them.<br />

State-run social protection schemes are financed either by the contributions<br />

of their members or by general tax revenues. Social insurance schemes, in particular,<br />

are financed by regular contributions and are usually linked to formal (contractual)<br />

labour relationships. They are based on specified rules, often underpinned<br />

by law, and provide benefits when a member of the household<br />

experiences a sudden shock due to a specific risk that is predefined by law (e.g.<br />

old age, a disability, or the death of a breadwinner). Social insurance schemes can<br />

thus effectively reduce the vulnerability of households that can afford to pay<br />

some regular contribution in exchange for a reduced exposure to risk. Nonetheless,<br />

they address only a specific set of risks, which may not always include the<br />

risks that constitute the most serious threats for their members. For example,<br />

such schemes do not, in general, provide protection against harvest failure resulting<br />

from weather-related risks – even though these risks constitute a more serious<br />

problem for many rural households than old-age or work injuries, which can be<br />

managed through the mutual support of relatives and neighbours. In addition,<br />

social insurance generally fails to help the extreme poor, who are unable to pay<br />

even very small contributions, and thus tend to be excluded from social insurance<br />

schemes.<br />

Social transfer schemes help to prevent and alleviate both chronic and<br />

transitional poverty. In addition, they normally address all kinds of risks, but<br />

they tend to be less powerful in terms of reducing the vulnerability of households.<br />

Since they are financed by tax revenues, benefits are usually quite limited<br />

and aim to prevent households from falling into severe poverty. However, they<br />

are not able to prevent any deterioration in the well-being of richer households<br />

because the benefits provided by social transfer schemes fall well short of<br />

replacing their former income – something that social insurance schemes are<br />

often able to do.<br />

There are two types of social transfer schemes: “targeted” and “universal”<br />

schemes. Targeted schemes grant benefits only to people in need, while universal<br />

schemes pay out to all households. Although the sum of the benefits<br />

provided by targeted schemes is, as a rule, considerably smaller than the total<br />

expenditure of universal schemes, their budgets are sometimes even higher<br />

because of the targeting costs involved (i.e. the costs of identifying eligible<br />

households).<br />

Likewise, a distinction can be made between cash transfer schemes (e.g. social<br />

assistance, social pension and basic income grant), vouchers (e.g. for education or<br />

health services), and in-kind transfers (e.g. food rations or free public health care).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!