08.12.2012 Views

MALARIA ELIMINATION IN ZANZIBAR - Soper Strategies

MALARIA ELIMINATION IN ZANZIBAR - Soper Strategies

MALARIA ELIMINATION IN ZANZIBAR - Soper Strategies

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

which are being explored by the global community, are examined<br />

here as potential solutions to the challenges that Zanzibar will<br />

face in coming years.<br />

Tourism Tax<br />

Generating funding for a health program through taxation is one<br />

form of IFH that is already being tried on a large scale. Taxation<br />

is the basis of the UNITAID model, an international facility<br />

operating since 2006 that uses revenues from an airline ticket tax<br />

to purchase drugs for HIV/AIDS, TB and Malaria. An airline<br />

tax is an attractive funding source because it is based on a steady,<br />

predictable form of revenue and because the tax is progressive—<br />

impacting higher income people the most. Another example of<br />

tax-based financing for health is the “black lung tax,” an excise<br />

tax on the purchase of coal that is used to compensate miners<br />

suffering from black lung disease. A malaria tax would follow<br />

the same principle: just as coal companies generate the burden<br />

of black lung, travelers create the risk of malaria resurgence<br />

and therefore would be required to contribute to the cost of<br />

mitigating that risk through a modest tax.<br />

Both the airline and the black lung taxes are earmarked, meaning<br />

that the revenue they generate is required to go to a specific<br />

purpose (the treatment of ill coal miners in the case of the<br />

latter). Should Zanzibar consider funding its malaria program<br />

partly through taxation, it is essential that this tax be earmarked<br />

and that the purpose is transparent (e.g., by calling it a “malaria<br />

prevention tax”). Earmarked taxes are often criticized because<br />

of the lack of flexibility they impose on public funds—they<br />

prohibit policy-makers from reallocating revenues from the tax<br />

to changing priorities. However, this is precisely the benefit of<br />

such a tax for Zanzibar’s malaria control program. If the revenues<br />

are not earmarked, this source of financing runs the same risks<br />

as traditional funding sources—being diverted from malaria to<br />

other priority programs in response to political pressures. In<br />

order to serve the vital function of preventing malaria resurgence<br />

in Zanzibar, tax revenues must be protected and used exclusively<br />

for this purpose.<br />

A natural opportunity for taxation in Zanzibar is tourism. A<br />

modest tax on airline tickets into Zanzibar could provide a steady,<br />

predictable source of funding for the malaria program and could<br />

be instituted without much risk of a reduction in tourism. The<br />

current taxation of tourism in Zanzibar is quite low ($5) and,<br />

since it is equal for all tourists, is a form of regressive taxation.<br />

A tax on air travel on the other hand would be progressive,<br />

since higher income tourists arrive by plane. We anticipate that<br />

tourists would be willing to pay an additional tax of at least $10<br />

on airline tickets, since: 1) Zanzibar is a highly attractive tourist<br />

destination; 2) this is a very small sum relative to the cost of<br />

traveling to Zanzibar; and 3) maintaining malaria-free status is<br />

in the economic self-interest of travelers. Tourists typically pay<br />

well above $10 for malaria prophylaxis to come to the island.<br />

The home countries of most of Zanzibar’s tourists require a<br />

prescription, and thus a doctor’s visit, for prophylaxis. Tourists<br />

must thus typically pay at least $15-30 for the doctor visit, and<br />

an additional $30 for the medicine—costs that could be avoided<br />

if they were visiting a malaria-free Zanzibar. Thus elimination,<br />

76<br />

even with a $10 tax, would be significant net saving for tourists if<br />

they are able to stop taking prophylaxis. Of course, tourists also<br />

planning to visit the mainland on their trip to Zanzibar will still<br />

have to buy prophylaxis, but the substantial number of tourists<br />

coming only to Zanzibar will be able to avoid these costs.<br />

Tourism in Zanzibar has been increasing over the past two<br />

decades, with an especially rapid increase of nearly 100 percent<br />

since 2003. At roughly 130,000 annual tourists (a tiny fraction of<br />

which come from mainland Tanzania), a malaria prevention tax<br />

of, for example, $10 per visitor would provide the ZMCP with<br />

roughly $1.3 million per year. We use the $10 tax for illustrative<br />

purposes only. The actual level of the tax that is optimal for the<br />

ZMCP would depend on more detailed analysis, as should the<br />

form of the tax (e.g., whether it should be flat for all tourists or<br />

on a sliding scale depending on the cost of airline ticket, type of<br />

accommodations, etc.) Also, revenue generated from the tax will<br />

have to go partially toward the cost of administering it, so actual<br />

funding available for malaria activities will be lower than the total<br />

revenue collected.<br />

160,000<br />

140,000<br />

120,000<br />

100,000<br />

FIGURE 32: ANNUAL NUMBER OF TOURISTS <strong>IN</strong> <strong>ZANZIBAR</strong><br />

80,000<br />

60,000<br />

40,000<br />

20,000<br />

0<br />

1985<br />

1987<br />

1989<br />

1991<br />

1993<br />

1995<br />

1997<br />

1999<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

2003<br />

2005<br />

2006<br />

2007<br />

Annual revenues could be put in a fund and either dispersed<br />

regularly to cover recurring costs of the malaria program (such as<br />

surveillance activities) or kept in an investment fund with good<br />

liquidity and used only when sufficient funds through normal<br />

channels are not available. The latter option is attractive because<br />

it ensures the availability of emergency funds for outbreak<br />

response or when other funding dries up and because it generates<br />

additional interest income. Although a tourist tax for malaria<br />

seems like a natural opportunity for steady, predictable financing<br />

for an attractive tourist destination like Zanzibar, the benefits<br />

and disadvantages of such a tax must be thought through in more<br />

detail. We recommend that, as a next step, the ZMCP and others<br />

conduct a more thorough analysis of a tourist tax for malaria,<br />

considering issues such as feasibility, administrative burden,<br />

revenue potential, etc.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!