07.12.2015 Views

TECHNOLOGY AT WORK

1Oclobi

1Oclobi

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

76<br />

Citi GPS: Global Perspectives & Solutions February 2015<br />

Australia. In contrast, the United Kingdom and Japan have seen wages at the<br />

bottom and top of the skill distribution rise roughly in tandem, consistent with the job<br />

polarisation story. In other advanced economies such as Spain and France, wages<br />

at the bottom of the skill distribution have actually accelerated more quickly than at<br />

the top. The wage data for emerging markets tell a similar country-specific story<br />

(Figure 59).<br />

The large degree of heterogeneity of low- versus high-skilled wage trends across<br />

countries points toward institutional differences that may be playing a role. In<br />

particular, improving worker productivity from new technology is not the only force<br />

driving wage trends, especially at the bottom of the skill distribution where politicaleconomy<br />

factors such as union participation and the generosity of unemployment<br />

compensation also likely play a determinant role.<br />

Figure 58. Ratio of real high-skilled average hourly wage rate to real<br />

low-skilled average hourly wage rate<br />

Figure 59. Ratio of real high-skilled average hourly wage rate to real<br />

low-skilled average hourly wage rate<br />

1.3<br />

1.2<br />

1.1<br />

Index, 1995=1<br />

1.6<br />

1.5<br />

1.4<br />

1.3<br />

1.2<br />

Index, 1995=1<br />

Brazil Hungary<br />

Mexico Poland<br />

Russia Turkey<br />

1.0<br />

1.1<br />

0.9<br />

0.8<br />

Canada<br />

Spain<br />

Japan<br />

Germany<br />

United Kingdom<br />

United States<br />

0.7<br />

1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009<br />

Note: The wage data comes from the WIOD Socio-economic Accounts, in which skills<br />

are defined on the basis of educational attainment. The hourly wage rate is calculated<br />

as total labor compensation divided by total hours worked. The wage data are deflated<br />

using national consumer price data.<br />

Source: WIOD Socio-economic Accounts, Citi Research<br />

1.0<br />

0.9<br />

0.8<br />

0.7<br />

0.6<br />

1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009<br />

Note: The wage data comes from the WIOD Socio-economic Accounts, in which skills<br />

are defined on the basis of educational attainment. The hourly wage rate is calculated<br />

as total labor compensation divided by total hours worked. The wage data are deflated<br />

using national consumer price data.<br />

Source: WIOD Socio-economic Accounts, Citi Research<br />

There is some evidence that wage inequality<br />

between high- and low-skilled workers is<br />

rising in some countries because of<br />

increasing automation<br />

The bottom line is that there is some evidence that wage inequality between highand<br />

low-skilled workers is rising in some countries, likely driven in part by increasing<br />

automation in the workplace. Whether this translates into persistent output gaps and<br />

chronically depressed policy rates is still an open question. It is interesting to note,<br />

however, that financial markets, which are forward looking, have to some extent<br />

priced in low interest rates well into the future. Indeed, stock prices seem high in<br />

many advanced economies (Figure 60), but not if there has been a sizeable change<br />

in the discount rate due to lower expected policy rates. Home prices, which are also<br />

sensitive to forward-looking assumptions about policy rates, are also high in some<br />

countries (Figure 61), though home price movements have been more disparate<br />

than stock price movements since the 2008 financial crisis.<br />

© 2015 Citigroup

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!