07.12.2015 Views

TECHNOLOGY AT WORK

1Oclobi

1Oclobi

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

74<br />

Citi GPS: Global Perspectives & Solutions February 2015<br />

Macro policy depends on whether actual<br />

GDP can keep up with potential GDP<br />

Everything else being equal, skill-biased technological change would increase<br />

potential GDP by making both capital and labour more productive in the production<br />

process. The question then is whether actual GDP can keep up with potential,<br />

absent policy intervention.<br />

There is some empirical evidence to suggest that if technological change occurs at<br />

the high end of the skill distribution, causing wage gains to be concentrated there,<br />

the answer is no. In that scenario, skill-biased technological change may lead to a<br />

persistent gap of potential GDP over actual GDP, leading to downward pressure on<br />

inflation and thereby to chronically depressed central bank policy rates.<br />

Saving and investment decisions drive the<br />

gap between potential and actual GDP<br />

The mechanism driving the growing gap between potential and actual GDP works<br />

through saving and investment decisions. If skill-biased technological change<br />

occurs at the upper end of the skill distribution, wage gains are likely to be<br />

concentrated where income levels are already relatively high. The academic<br />

literature, on balance, favours the idea that saving rates rise with income. 113 Hence,<br />

skill-biased technological change may result in more income flowing to those with<br />

relatively high saving rates, depressing aggregate consumption demand. Weak<br />

consumer spending may in turn negatively impact capex decisions at firms, which<br />

are a function of future consumer demand. The end result in this stylised example is<br />

that aggregate expenditure in the economy is unable to keep up with the economy’s<br />

potential, leading to subdued wage and inflation pressure and thereby to a<br />

persistently loose stance of monetary policy. 114<br />

In addition, technological change could depress policy rates through a mechanism<br />

unrelated to the wage distribution, by resulting in a decline in the relative price of<br />

investment goods (think cheapening of personal computers). This process has<br />

already been underway for decades. 115 If new technology continues to make certain<br />

goods in the economy relatively cheap, that could result in downward pressure on<br />

overall price inflation, leading to a bias by central banks to favor lower policy rates.<br />

113 For example, in Dynan, Skinner and Zeldes (2006), savings in the bottom income<br />

quintile are roughly zero compared to over 25% of income in the highest quintile.<br />

Consistent results hold for proxies of permanent income, such as levels of educational<br />

attainment and lagged and future earnings obtained from longitudinal surveys.<br />

114<br />

As mentioned, all of this is ‘everything else equal.’ In an open economy setting, capex<br />

decisions are not made solely on the basis of expected future domestic consumer<br />

demand; rising foreign demand could offset the weakness in investment spending<br />

brought on by high domestic saving patterns. Moreover, demographics complicate the<br />

picture greatly. Older people tend to spend more than younger people. Thus, aging<br />

demographics, which are occurring in a number of advanced economies, will likely put<br />

upward pressure on domestic consumer spending, thus leading to an upward bias on<br />

policy rates – see Goodhart and Erfurth (2014). Finally, borrowing constraints matter<br />

greatly. Steve Randy Waldman argues that so long as debt accumulation by lower-wage<br />

earners occurs alongside growing wage inequality, it will negate the consumptiondepressing<br />

effects of growing wage inequality – Waldman (2012). Moreover, Gauti<br />

Eggertsson and Neil Mehrotra describe an overlapping generations model where a<br />

within-generation rise in wage inequality leads to an excess of the supply of savings over<br />

the demand for savings, thereby depressing the real interest rate, provided that those<br />

demanding savings (those in the younger generation and those at the bottom of the<br />

wage distribution in the generation that saw an increase in wage inequality) are credit<br />

constrained – see Eggertsson and Mehrotra (2014).<br />

115 In Buiter, Rahbari and Seydl (2014), we document that since 1970, the average price<br />

of a unit of investment for a broad range of advanced economies has fallen by roughly<br />

17% relative to the price of a unit of GDP and by 20% relative to a unit of personal<br />

consumption (as measured by the PCE deflator).<br />

© 2015 Citigroup

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!