07.12.2015 Views

TECHNOLOGY AT WORK

1Oclobi

1Oclobi

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

10<br />

Citi GPS: Global Perspectives & Solutions February 2015<br />

productivity growth of the late-1990s came to a halt, the view that most of the<br />

benefits from the digital revolution have already been seen has received more<br />

attention.<br />

The changing nature of innovation can<br />

explain why wages have failed to grow in<br />

tandem with productivity<br />

While a decline in the technological dynamism of the rich world would explain the<br />

recent fall in productivity and the growing concentration of wealth highlighted by<br />

Piketty, it does not explain why wages have failed to grow in tandem with<br />

productivity. One explanation is the changing nature of innovation. Although<br />

technology can raise productivity and boost wages, it can also take the form of<br />

capital that substitutes for labour. In that case, productivity growth will simply<br />

enhance capital's share of income, and thus the concentration of wealth.<br />

The Growing Gap between Productivity and Pay – Citi Economics<br />

Figure 3 shows the gap between compensation of workers and their productivity for the United States, considering<br />

data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. The figure compares the total output per hour worked in the economy (a<br />

measure of productivity) against the hourly compensation rate for all workers, both adjusted for inflation. There has<br />

been a growing gap between the two for decades. Since 1980, productivity has grown at an annual average rate of<br />

roughly 2%, compared to just under 1% annual average growth for real hourly compensation.<br />

Figure 4 shows a GDP-weighted average estimate of the so-called productivity gap for 16 advanced economies. 13<br />

Consistent with the US story, the advanced world as a whole has also seen productivity decouple from the<br />

compensation paid to workers. However, the decoupling for the advanced-economy as a whole is not as severe as<br />

it is for the US alone. Since 1980, advanced-economy productivity has grown at an annual average rate of 1.7%,<br />

compared to 1.1% annual average growth for advanced-economy real hourly compensation. This 0.6 percentage<br />

point average growth rate difference between productivity and compensation in the advanced world is still<br />

nonetheless meaningful. It implies that, over time, a greater fraction of output produced per hour worked in the<br />

advanced world has gone to property owners in the form of profits rather than to workers in the form of<br />

compensation – a trend consistent with declining labour shares.<br />

Figure 3. Gap between productivity and pay in the United States<br />

250<br />

Index, 1970=100<br />

230<br />

210<br />

190<br />

170<br />

150<br />

130<br />

110<br />

90<br />

Real Output per Hour Worked<br />

70<br />

Real Compensation per Hour Worked<br />

50<br />

1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010<br />

Source: : BLS, Citi Research<br />

Figure 4. Advanced economy average productivity gap<br />

250<br />

Index, 1971=100<br />

230<br />

210<br />

190<br />

170<br />

150<br />

130<br />

110<br />

90<br />

Real GDP per Hour Worked<br />

70<br />

Real Total Compensation per Hour Worked<br />

50<br />

1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010<br />

Source: European Commission, Citi Research<br />

13 Figure 4 includes data for 16 advanced economies. Relative to those included in<br />

Figure 2 Australia, Austria and Greece were dropped due to data limitations. Output is<br />

deflated with the GDP deflator, whereas compensation is deflated by national consumer<br />

price indexes.<br />

© 2015 Citigroup

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!