23.09.2015 Views

DEVELOPMENT

The pdf-version - Eesti Koostöö Kogu

The pdf-version - Eesti Koostöö Kogu

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

and pasture land, and this was capitalised over a 25-year<br />

period at an adjusted rate of 4%.<br />

The value of the intangible capital is derived as the<br />

residual of the total value of wealth, which is calculated<br />

using the net present value (NPV) method. This is based<br />

on a principle that comes from the financial theory that<br />

the value of capital is equal to the income flow it creates<br />

in the future. If certain preconditions exist regarding<br />

the future income flow and discount rate, (which in the<br />

World Bank Report is used as the social rate of return<br />

on social investments) it is possible to evaluate the total<br />

value of wealth that its income flow will create. 8 Since,<br />

based on direct calculations, assessments of the value<br />

of tangible capital exist, which are derived from the difference<br />

between the total wealth and tangible capital, it<br />

is possible to obtain an assessment related to the value<br />

of the intangible capital. In principle, an assumption is<br />

made that the existence of various types of assets makes<br />

it possible to produce gross national income of a certain<br />

value, and from this gross value, the value of the assets<br />

is derived, which enables this national income to be<br />

produced. 9 On the other hand, relatively direct figures,<br />

which are based on market evaluations, exist for tangible<br />

assets. Since national income varies more than tangible<br />

capital (the value of produced and natural capital, incl.<br />

per capita) from state to state, it is easy to conclude that,<br />

generally, it is intangible capital that is important in the<br />

determination of a state’s standard of living. Based on<br />

the World Bank’s summary data, in the case of the lowincome<br />

states, 15% of wealth was related to produced<br />

capital and urban land, 30% to natural capital, and 55%<br />

to intangible capital, whereas the average wealth per<br />

capita, in 2005, was $6,523 per capita. In middle-income<br />

states, the corresponding proportions were 20%, 20% and<br />

60%, while the average wealth per capita was $30,662.<br />

In the high-income states, the corresponding proportions<br />

were 15%, 4% and 81%, while the average wealth per<br />

capita was $561,129 per capita (The Changing Wealth of<br />

Nations, 2011, 182-183).<br />

In Table 4.2.2, data is presented about the set of reference<br />

states. Generally, the proportions of wealth related<br />

to produced capital and urban land vary from 15% to<br />

20%; the percentage of natural capital between 1% and<br />

5%; and intangible capital 75% to 85%.<br />

An exception is the states with significant sub-soil<br />

assets, like Chile, where the percentage of natural capital<br />

reaches 18.5%. The relative importance of produced<br />

capital and urban land, compared to the other states, was<br />

somewhat higher in South Korea and the Czech Republic,<br />

where it reached 22.3% and 22.6%, respectively. A totally<br />

unique capital structure can be found in Singapore, where<br />

the rela tive importance of produced capital and urban land<br />

was 45.2%. In the case of this high percentage, a significant<br />

role is also played by the fact that investments made in<br />

Table 4.2.2<br />

Total wealth and its components in 2005.<br />

State<br />

Produced capital<br />

and urban land Natural capital Intangible capital Total Wealth<br />

Per capita<br />

(USD, thousands) %<br />

Per capita<br />

(USD, thousands) %<br />

Per capita<br />

(USD, thousands) %<br />

Per capita<br />

(USD, thousands) %<br />

Austria 104.8 18.4 9.1 1.6 456.8 80.0 570.7 100<br />

Estonia 31.7 19.2 8.2 4.9 125.4 75.9 165.3 100<br />

Netherlands 108.0 18.2 13.2 2.2 472.4 79.6 593.6 100<br />

Ireland 101.9 17.0 11.2 1.9 486.0 81.1 599.1 100<br />

Israel 43.7 13.4 4.8 1.5 278.9 85.1 327.4 100<br />

Canada 86.8 16.1 36.9 6.9 415.0 77.0 538.7 100<br />

South Korea 55.4 22.3 2.6 1.1 190.2 76.6 248.2 100<br />

Lithuania 18.1 13.6 6.0 4.5 108.8 81.9 132.9 100<br />

Latvia 19.3 15.9 7.3 6.1 94.7 78.0 121.3 100<br />

Singapore 136.1 45.2 0.0 0.0 164.9 54.8 301.0 100<br />

Finland 90.9 15.9 19.2 3.4 460.1 80.7 570.2 100<br />

Denmark 132.1 17.8 19.6 2.6 591.2 79.6 742.9 100<br />

Czech Republic 40.9 22.6 4.6 2.5 135.3 74.9 180.8 100<br />

Chile 17.3 16.9 18.9 18.5 65.8 64.6 101.9 100<br />

Hungary 25.7 14.9 6.0 3.4 141.3 81.7 173.0 100<br />

Uruguay 8.9 10.3 8.3 9.6 69.5 80.2 86.7 100<br />

Source: The Changing Wealth of Nations. Measuring Sustainable Development in the New Millennium 2011, 176–182.<br />

8 In principle, the sample W(t) = ∫C(t) r(s) is used, in which W(t) is wealth in period t; C(t) is consumption in period t; r(s) is the timing<br />

coefficient. In this case, in order to eliminate volatility in the calculation of wealth in 2005, the average consumption between 2003 and 2007<br />

was used along with a timing period of 25 years.<br />

9 The study is based on the use of available total and net national income indicators, for which various indicators of saving have been calculated.<br />

The available gross national income is traditionally derived from the gross domestic product (GDP), which appears in such comparisons in<br />

the following manner — the GDP is added to the net income from foreign countries and the current net transfers. The available net national<br />

income is arrived at by deducting the latest depreciation from the gross national income.<br />

Estonian Human Development Report 2012/2013<br />

161

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!