23.09.2015 Views

DEVELOPMENT

The pdf-version - Eesti Koostöö Kogu

The pdf-version - Eesti Koostöö Kogu

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

4.1<br />

Economic environment<br />

Jüri Sepp, Clemens Buchen, Helje Kaldaru<br />

Today, two viewpoints of economic development can<br />

be identified within the framework of economics: 1) the<br />

growth theory based on production functions and factors,<br />

and 2) an institutional approach that places importance<br />

on the motivation of individuals. The first course is<br />

characterised, somewhat, by a mechanical approach to<br />

the economy (Leschke 2011, 95–96). The interests and<br />

incentives of the economic subjects are ignored. However,<br />

the efficiency of using production factors may vary<br />

to a great extent under different social conditions. It is<br />

enough to allude to the relatively modest results produced<br />

by developmental aid to date, to be convinced that large<br />

investments may turn out to be a waste of money, if the<br />

social preconditions for development, in the form of purposeful<br />

and functional formal and informal institutions,<br />

are lacking. 1 Essentially, the decisive role of institutions is<br />

demonstrated by the analysis of specific nations’ wealth in<br />

sub-chapter 4.2, where this role is determined indirectly,<br />

as a certain residual value of wealth.<br />

In the context of this study, the intertwining of two<br />

approaches to development theory, within the framework<br />

of the UN human development concept, deserves<br />

special attention. In the 1996 and 2003 Human Development<br />

Reports, a qualitative model was presented to<br />

illustrate the specific connection between human capital<br />

and economic development, which also confirms the<br />

importance of institutions (HDR 1996, 68; HDR 2003,<br />

70). Namely, the reciprocal impact of human capital and<br />

economic development can be viewed as functioning<br />

through several filters or catalysts. The inhibitors and<br />

accelerants in both directions are the private and public<br />

institutions that guide human behaviour. In some states,<br />

a relatively harmonious process of human development<br />

and economic growth becomes evident, while in others,<br />

one or the other development factor becomes an inhibitor<br />

(Sepp, Eerma 2011).<br />

In the following empirical analysis we will try to<br />

focus on those institutions, which clearly have a positive<br />

impact. At the same time, we should not lose sight of the<br />

fact that various institutions may be substantively equivalent,<br />

and develop complicated mutual connections and<br />

dependencies. In this study, the possibilities for making<br />

the quality of institutions measurable from the viewpoint<br />

of economic development are explored 2 . Methodologically<br />

and empirically, this is based on the rankings compiled<br />

by international organisations, which are regularly available<br />

for forming assessments 3 . The best known are three<br />

generalising indicators:<br />

• Economic competitiveness, which is expressed<br />

in the indices of both the World Economic Forum<br />

(WEF) and the International Institute for Management<br />

Development (IMD);<br />

• Economic freedom, which is examined empirically<br />

by the Heritage Foundation (HF) in the U.S. and<br />

the Fraser Institute (FI) in Canada. Entrepreneurial<br />

freedom is measured, in detail, by the World Bank,<br />

in its series called Doing Business. In principle, the<br />

integrated index on the regulation of the commodities<br />

market, compiled by the OECD, can be considered<br />

to be a reverse indicator of economic freedom; 4<br />

• Quality of governance, which the World Bank<br />

measures with its Worldwide Governance Indicators<br />

(WGI), and based on which, economic and political<br />

institutions are also assessed. Assessments of transition<br />

states are provided by the European Bank of<br />

Reconstruction and Development (EBRD). 5<br />

The connections of these three criteria to economic<br />

development differ. Economic freedom and the quality<br />

of governance are essentially directed to opening up the<br />

state’s institutional development potential. However,<br />

competitiveness is a construction in which the achieved<br />

level of development (the ability to earn) and its factors –<br />

the ability to sell and the ability to attract – are combined<br />

(Trabold 1995). Therefore, the general indicators of competitiveness<br />

are relatively endogenous (derived internally),<br />

and as such, are not very informative. However, some of<br />

the sub-indicators (components) of competitiveness pro-<br />

1 Institutions include all the rules and standards that affect cooperation between individuals, and, based on North’s (1990) often quoted<br />

statement, are the social stimulation systems. As influencers of human behaviour, institutions may promote economic growth or inhibit it.<br />

Therefore, any growth theory that is based on production factors will be only a conditional abstraction, if it is not supplemented by an analysis<br />

of the interests and stimuli of the economic agents.<br />

2 Therefore, the data provided by Freedom House is not included, because its main focus is on political conditions.<br />

3 The Ifo Institute’s Institutions Climate Index, which assesses the OECD states would, actually, warrant attention, but unfortunately, its authors<br />

have not considered it necessary to include Estonia. See Eicher ja Röhn (2007) and http://www.cesifo-group.de/ifoHome/facts/DICE/Other-Topics/Basic-Country-Characteristics/Institutions-Climate-Indices/ins-clim-inde-11.html.<br />

We have also not included the data available from<br />

individual researchers, the sustainability of which is questionable, i.e. Kuncic (2012).<br />

4 Unfortunately, this is only a periodically available indicator, the last level of which characterises 2008. See Wölfl et al. (2009) and http://www.<br />

oecd.org/eco/regulatoryreformandcompetitionpolicy/indicatorsofproductmarketregulationpmr.htm<br />

5 http://www.ebrd.com/pages/research/publications/flagships/transition.shtml<br />

150<br />

Estonian Human Development Report 2012/2013

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!