23.09.2015 Views

DEVELOPMENT

The pdf-version - Eesti Koostöö Kogu

The pdf-version - Eesti Koostöö Kogu

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

2006). Thus, it can be asked, are they are welfare states<br />

after all?<br />

Comments: the first two principal components have<br />

been used to compile indices from 16 different indicators<br />

that characterise welfare states. Pre-financial crisis data<br />

from 2000-2008, 22 countries.<br />

Figure 3.1.8 shows a positive connection between<br />

people’s subjective well-being (life-satisfaction) and social<br />

spending; the coefficient of the corresponding correlations<br />

is 0.53. However, this indicator lacks statistical significance,<br />

thus life-satisfaction is more associated with the<br />

equal division of wealth and income than previously<br />

(Figure 3.1.1. and 3.1.3.). Estonia’s position in this respect<br />

is similar to the majority of new EU Member States,<br />

which are characterised by lower social expenditures as<br />

well as lower level of satisfaction than that of old-Europe.<br />

Thus, the generosity of the public welfare expenditures<br />

is not the single criteria for assessment the role<br />

and functions of the welfare state. Based thereon, we can<br />

say that the significance of a welfare state in the development<br />

of well-being is not dependent only on how generously<br />

the state finances social protection. Firstly, the<br />

so-called social contract or legitimate agreement upon<br />

the ideal type of the social model or welfare regime has<br />

to be established. Secondly, the universality of benefits<br />

providing equal opportunities should be ultimate aim. It<br />

is often said that (in addition to efficiency loss) redistribution<br />

and a paternalistic state can crowd out incentives<br />

for individual coping and make us helpless. Testing the<br />

“crowding-out hypothesis” is problematic, thus, we ask<br />

whether individual pro-social behaviour is affected by<br />

the intensity of welfare state. We measure pro-social<br />

behaviour based on the OECD index (2011) that averages<br />

the countries’ responses to three questions asked<br />

by Gallup World Poll (2010) – whether the respondent<br />

has volunteered time, donated money to a charity and<br />

helped a stranger in the last month. Figure 3.1.9 shows<br />

how pro-social behaviour is related to the extent of the<br />

welfare state, that is, with the average value of the social<br />

protection index and the de-commodification index<br />

depicted in Figure 3.1.7.<br />

The crowding-out hypothesis – the belief that a high<br />

degree of government intervention will crowd out voluntary<br />

activity is not supported by any empirical evidence<br />

or solid theoretical foundations (Van Oorshot and Arts<br />

2005). We also indicate that in the comparison of at least<br />

18 European states (see Figure 3.1.9), there is not direct<br />

association between the dimension of the welfare state<br />

and pro-social behaviour. The OECD report (OECD 2011)<br />

states that the Nordic countries, which are at the top of<br />

many social indicators in this publication, were unusually<br />

ordinary performers in terms of pro-social behaviour,<br />

while the Anglo-American ones (U.S., Ireland and Great<br />

Britain) position much higher. The Mediterranean and<br />

Eastern European countries typically had low levels of<br />

pro-social behaviour that is also reflected in Figure 3.1.9.<br />

We show that the outperforming countries are divided<br />

into two groups: liberal and pro-social states plus abundant<br />

welfare and pro-social states. Sadly Estonian is positioned<br />

at the lower end of the case countries -- with very<br />

limited welfare state and minimal pro-social behaviour.<br />

Conclusively, few illustrative facts that contradict some<br />

theoretical frameworks allow us to allude to the country<br />

being at a crossroads. The welfare contributions by the<br />

state are not so limited that it would make people cooperatively<br />

search for alternatives; but, these are also not<br />

enough to promote greater pro-social behaviour.<br />

3.1.4<br />

Conclusions<br />

Our aim was to illustrate the associations between the<br />

indicators of subjective well-being, aggregate concepts<br />

of welfare, various economic indicators and parameters<br />

related to welfare states. However, correlation and association<br />

doesn’t imply causality. We find that the economic<br />

indicators that characterise the development of a state<br />

– GDP and growth, low unemployment and a low Gini<br />

coefficient can be associated with people’s life-satisfaction.<br />

The most influential of these is the Gini coefficient.<br />

The latter indicates that subjective well-being is not just<br />

efficiency and market (wealth) based concept, but rather<br />

on more complex phenomenon, which also contain broad<br />

questions about relative equality and equal opportunities.<br />

The greatest challenge, related to well-being, is the question<br />

of how to reduce the income gap, without significantly<br />

inhibiting efficiency (growth).<br />

We also argue, that well-being and life-satisfaction<br />

indicators as aggregate indices are not replacements<br />

for GDP and the Gini coefficient, as measures of social<br />

progress. Primarily because happiness is relative. Therefore,<br />

when analysing happiness, relying on microdata is<br />

advisable and age, marital status, employment and other<br />

individual-based indicators must be controlled. It is also<br />

disputable whether all individuals perceive well-being<br />

similarly – is this rather security, personal freedom, or<br />

societal norms like equal opportunities. The standards for<br />

happiness and satisfaction may differ by culture, making<br />

international comparisons difficult.<br />

There is no clear-cut answer to the question of<br />

whether public social spending also results in well-being.<br />

Since social expenditures are mostly endogenous (rich<br />

states can spend more) it is difficult to avoid a vicious circle,<br />

in which poverty results in low social expenditures,<br />

which in turns lead to poverty. So far, political agendas<br />

have relied on one main trigger – efficiency – which leads<br />

to the economic growth. And it has been feared that the<br />

welfare state may inhibit growth. Estonia’s real social<br />

expenditures increased after the crisis, but the gap with<br />

the Nordic countries is still increasing. The question of<br />

whether to increase public social contributions, or rely on<br />

private ones instead is still open for Estonia. We believe<br />

that taking a position regarding the future is inevitable,<br />

that this firstly means agreement on the Estonian welfare<br />

state model. This could also help to break current<br />

vicious circle. This is a social contract. If it is decided<br />

that the Nordic model should be the goal, then increasing<br />

the state’s role is unavoidable, and the corresponding<br />

fiscal issues related to how to finance such a turn must<br />

be faced. If the goal is the Anglo-American vision, then<br />

the problem is not only incentivising private contributions<br />

for future provision of social services but also creating<br />

compensating schemes for disadvantaged families such as<br />

pensioners or lower-SES.<br />

112<br />

Estonian Human Development Report 2012/2013

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!