23.09.2015 Views

Estonian Human Development Report

Estonian Human Development Report - Eesti Koostöö Kogu

Estonian Human Development Report - Eesti Koostöö Kogu

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Figure 6.3.1. GDP, government sector costs, billions<br />

of EEK<br />

250<br />

200<br />

150<br />

100<br />

50<br />

0<br />

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006<br />

Source: <strong>Estonian</strong> Statistical Yearbook, 2007, 2008<br />

GDP<br />

the achievement of socially desirable results (for instance,<br />

well-being) the supply side does not suffice, demand is also<br />

required. 34<br />

Nevertheless, social services are often approached primarily<br />

from the supply side. They are treated as something<br />

that is unconditionally beneficial. The conditions<br />

and limitations predicated on the economic side are often<br />

seen as unpleasant restrictions that inhibit useful expenditures<br />

that promote societal development. At the same<br />

time, we must consider that the removal of these restrictions<br />

and the limitless expansion of social expenditures<br />

have a destabilizing effect on the economic environment<br />

that increases uncertainty, reduces investments and ultimately,<br />

reduces the future tax base from which social costs<br />

are financed. Since institutional activities, such as guaranteeing<br />

lawmaking, the judicial system and public procurement,<br />

are financed, to a great extent, from the budget,<br />

institutional development is directed in relation to the tax<br />

burden. Through taxes, the state guarantees resources to<br />

assure institutional efficiency. Therefore, the sufficiency of<br />

the tax burden is measured by the effective performance<br />

of institutions, which is not directly related to any formal<br />

percentage of the GDP. At the same time, the shortage of<br />

institutional resources also becomes a serious problem<br />

when there are insufficient resources for the protection of<br />

health and ownership, for the effective and speedy work of<br />

the courts, and for guaranteeing the security of the country.<br />

In the case of institutions, the risk of overregulation<br />

in sensitive fields, such as the labour market, must also be<br />

taken into account.<br />

As we saw in the previous subchapter, a disparity<br />

between a relatively low level of the quality of life and a<br />

relatively high subjective indicator of well-being is typical<br />

of Estonia. For a long time, it has been typical of Estonia<br />

that this disparity is objectively expressed by a weak<br />

connection between economic growth and an increase in<br />

social costs (see Figure 6.3.1.).<br />

Under conditions of rapid economic growth, in which<br />

GDP in current prices increased from 121.4 billion EEK<br />

in 2002 to 207.1 billion EEK in 2006, government costs<br />

have also increased, including the nominal costs for<br />

health care, education and social protection. At the same<br />

time, the given cost increase has been much more modest<br />

than the economic growth, which shows that their ratio<br />

of GDP decreased (see Figure 6.3.2.). Government costs<br />

decreased as a ratio of GDP from 35.7% in 2002 to 33%<br />

in 2006, education costs from 6.8% to 6.0%, and social<br />

protection costs from 10.0% to 9.6%. Health care costs<br />

remained at the same relatively low level, constituting 4%<br />

of GDP. Therefore, costs in the social field did increase,<br />

but less than GDP on the whole. This also points to the<br />

fact that a balanced budget was maintained and a surplus<br />

achieved during this period due to the relative restriction<br />

of costs in the social sphere. Keeping in mind the<br />

importance of workers’ education and health in the creation<br />

of necessary human capital in the long run, the relatively<br />

significant reduction in the percentage of educa-<br />

Government<br />

sector<br />

costs<br />

Health care<br />

Education<br />

Social<br />

protection<br />

Figure 6.3.2. Ratio of government costs, social protection,<br />

education and health care costs of GDP, %<br />

2006<br />

2005<br />

2004<br />

2003<br />

2002<br />

4<br />

4<br />

4<br />

4<br />

6<br />

6<br />

6.4<br />

9.6<br />

9.8<br />

10.3<br />

9.9<br />

10<br />

6.8<br />

0 10 20 30 40<br />

Source: <strong>Estonian</strong> Statistical Yearbook, 2007, 2008<br />

indicators that primarily characterize economic performance,<br />

such as GDP or economic growth.<br />

By utilizing the concepts of human and social capital,<br />

on the one hand, it is possible to correlate the functioning<br />

of the economic and social spheres, and on the other<br />

hand, to provide an opportunity to analyze the policies<br />

directed at these fields of activity. The majority of social<br />

scientists maintain that investments into human capital<br />

– into health, knowledge and skills, and the policies<br />

directed at them – are just as important as investments<br />

into physical capital. At the same time, this statement is<br />

far from self-evident, because it is not simple to statistically<br />

validate this connection (El Erian and Spence, 2008,<br />

p. 37): it is easier to precisely assess the input that shapes<br />

human or social capital (education costs, years of school<br />

enrolment) than the outputs achieved thereby (ability to<br />

learn, receptivity to innovations, socialization, capacity<br />

for empathy, etc.). It is also important to consider that for<br />

33<br />

33.5<br />

34.2<br />

3.9 6.5 34.6<br />

35.7<br />

Government<br />

sector<br />

costs<br />

Health care<br />

Education<br />

Social<br />

protection<br />

34<br />

India is one of the contradictions of this type that are treated in papers on economic growth theories. World-class engineers and<br />

scientists have been educated there for decades, although its impact on economic development has been very modest. The reason was<br />

that domestic industry did not create sufficient demand for the use of this human capital and a great deal of the brain power left India.<br />

A positive impact developed with the creation of a global software industry, and the demand for the skills that resulted from this. This<br />

caused a broader impact on the entire service sector, especially though demand intermediated by the Internet. The impact of human<br />

capital on economic growth and well-being needed an impulse based on demand in addition to the supply; see The Growth <strong>Report</strong>:<br />

Strategies for Sustained Growth and Inclusive <strong>Development</strong> (2008).<br />

| 132

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!