08.09.2015 Views

The Meme Machine

TheMemeMachine1999

TheMemeMachine1999

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

150 THE MEME MACHINE<br />

times in the hope of help in bad times. Research has revealed that many animals<br />

do just this, but there is a catch. If you are going to pay back favours, and avoid<br />

being cheated, you must be able to recognise other individuals. Most animals<br />

cannot do this, but many primates can – as can elephants, dolphins, and even<br />

such unlikely species as vampire bats. Vampire bats have a special problem in<br />

that they are very small and can easily die if they go without a meal of blood for<br />

more than two nights in a row. Fortunately, blood meals can be much bigger<br />

than one bat really needs. So the answer is to share your blood – and keep a<br />

track on who owes what to whom.<br />

Gratitude, friendship, sympathy, trust, indignation, and feelings of guilt and<br />

revenge have all been attributed to reciprocal altruism, as has moralistic<br />

aggression, or our tendency to get upset over unfairness. If we have evolved to<br />

share resources with other humans, but to make sure our genes benefit, then our<br />

feelings are the way evolution has equipped us to do it. On this theory not only<br />

moral sentiments, but ideas of justice and legal systems can be traced to the<br />

evolution of reciprocal altruism (Matt Ridley 1996; Wagstaff 1998; Wright<br />

1994).<br />

Game theory has made it possible to explore how and why various strategies<br />

might evolve. Trivers used a game called the Prisoner’s Dilemma in which two<br />

people are kept apart and told they are accused of a crime with a penalty of, say,<br />

ten years in prison. If both stay silent they can be convicted only on a lesser<br />

charge and both get a shorter sentence, say three years, but if one gives evidence<br />

against the other the defector gets off free. What should they do? Obviously the<br />

best outcome all round is for both to stay silent – but there is a strong temptation<br />

to defect – and what if the other one is tempted? – you might as well be tempted<br />

too. <strong>The</strong>re are many other versions using points, money, or other resources.<br />

<strong>The</strong> important point is that a perfectly rational and selfish person will always<br />

gain by defecting. So how does cooperative behaviour ever come about?<br />

<strong>The</strong> answer is that in a one-off game it never should, but life is not a one-off<br />

game. We meet people again, and form judgements about their trustworthiness.<br />

<strong>The</strong> answer to the Prisoner’s Dilemma lies in repetition. In iterated Prisoner’s<br />

Dilemmas people assess the other’s likely behaviour and then both can gain by<br />

cooperating. Players who have not met before often copy each other,<br />

cooperating with cooperators and not with defectors. Persistent detectors are<br />

shunned, and so lose their chance of exploiting others.<br />

Games like this are also used by economists, mathematicians and computer<br />

modellers. In 1979, the American political scientist Robert Axelrod set up a

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!