08.08.2015 Views

Bt Brinjal The scope and adequacy of the GEAC environmental risk assessment

Bt Brinjal: The scope and adequacy of the GEAC ... - Down To Earth

Bt Brinjal: The scope and adequacy of the GEAC ... - Down To Earth

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Socioeconomic Analysis 55<strong>The</strong>se data (Table 5) bear <strong>the</strong> conclusion that Krishna <strong>and</strong> Qiam (2008) have over-estimated <strong>the</strong> value <strong>of</strong> hybrid <strong>Bt</strong> brinjalby about 2-fold. West Bengal presently forbids <strong>the</strong> commercial use <strong>of</strong> <strong>Bt</strong> brinjal. Krishna <strong>and</strong> Qiam (2008) presume that thiswill be overturned. <strong>The</strong>ir estimate <strong>of</strong> an increase in net return <strong>of</strong> Rs.44,074/ha for <strong>Bt</strong> brinjal assumes that small-scale resourcepoorfarmers will adopt hybrid <strong>Bt</strong> brinjal at a similar rate as large-scale commercial producers (Krishna <strong>and</strong> Qiam 2007). <strong>The</strong>previous discussion in this report provides many reasons to expect that small-scale resource-poor farmers will adopt at a lowerrate than large-scale commercial farmers. Kolady <strong>and</strong> Lesser (2005) show to <strong>the</strong> contrary that small-scale resource-poor farmersare predicted to adopt hybrid <strong>Bt</strong> brinjal at a lower rate than large-scale commercial producers. Finally, Krishna <strong>and</strong> Qiam (2007,2008) rely on farmer’s “stated preferences” for hybrid <strong>Bt</strong> brinjal after being given expected benefits <strong>of</strong> hybrid <strong>Bt</strong> brinjal based on<strong>the</strong> Mahyco MST experiments. <strong>The</strong>se inflated benefits may have induced many small-scale resource-poor farmers to state that<strong>the</strong>y would use hybrid <strong>Bt</strong> brinjal. In addition, it is well known that a stated preference is higher than a realised preference. Ino<strong>the</strong>r words, people say <strong>the</strong>y will do something at a much higher rate than <strong>the</strong>y actually do it. Thus, it is unlikely that Krishna<strong>and</strong> Qiam’s (2008) results for West Bengal, Andhra Pradesh <strong>and</strong> Karnataka are accurate for small-scale resource-poor farmers,<strong>and</strong> may only apply to large-scale commercial producers. Even considering only large-scale commercial producers, however,Krishna <strong>and</strong> Qiam’s (2008) estimates for net return are probably twice <strong>the</strong> realistic return for hybrid <strong>Bt</strong> brinjal (compare <strong>the</strong>irRs.44,074 <strong>and</strong> Rs.40, 276 to <strong>the</strong> more accurate Rs.23,439). Overall, it is more likely that hybrid <strong>Bt</strong> brinjal will increase netreturns for large-scale commercial producers by at most Rs.23,439/ha <strong>and</strong> for small-scale resource-poor producers by at mostRs.3,250/ha; <strong>the</strong>se estimates do not double count potential reductions in insecticide use.<strong>The</strong>se data (Table 5) also show that brinjal IPM has been vastly more pr<strong>of</strong>itable than projections for hybrid <strong>Bt</strong> brinjal.<strong>Brinjal</strong> IPM has been about 3-times more pr<strong>of</strong>itable than <strong>Bt</strong> brinjal is projected, <strong>and</strong> has directly improved pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>of</strong> smallscaleresource-poor farmers. Converting 1.5Tk. = 1.0Rs., IPM has returned Rs.34,575 – Rs.94,506/ha in eastern India <strong>and</strong>Bangladesh <strong>and</strong> Rs.82,963/ha in Gujarat. Averaging across <strong>the</strong>se estimates, brinjal IPM has increased pr<strong>of</strong>itability for <strong>the</strong> smallscaleresource-poor farmers who have used it by Rs.66,794/ha. Moreover, as will be discussed below, farmers will retain more<strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> benefit from IPM than <strong>the</strong>y would retain from <strong>Bt</strong> brinjal.Clearly, compared to hybrid <strong>Bt</strong> brinjal, a national policy that promotes <strong>the</strong>proven technology <strong>of</strong> brinjal IPM (such as ICAR 2006) would provide greaterfinancial benefits to <strong>the</strong> millions <strong>of</strong> small-scale resource-poor farmers in Indiaat reduced <strong>risk</strong> to <strong>the</strong> farmers <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> environment. <strong>Brinjal</strong> IPM is also likelyto improve pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>of</strong> large-scale commercial producers. While hybrid <strong>Bt</strong>brinjal may improve pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>of</strong> large-scale commercial producers over <strong>and</strong>above <strong>the</strong> benefits from brinjal IPM, it is not likely to improve pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>of</strong>small-scale resource-poor farmers significantly. To set a rational national policyon brinjal pest control, economic information on traditional BFSB controlpractices, organic production, <strong>and</strong> integrated use <strong>of</strong> neem-based insecticidesis also needed. <strong>GEAC</strong> should consider <strong>the</strong> need for hybrid <strong>Bt</strong> brinjal in <strong>the</strong>context <strong>of</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r comparable agricultural technologies.Finding 28. <strong>The</strong> estimated economic surplus for brinjal IPM is significantly larger than for hybrid <strong>Bt</strong> brinjal.Farmers are expected to receive 63% <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> surplus from brinjal IPM but only 10% <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> surplus from hybrid <strong>Bt</strong>brinjal. Increased public investment, greater promotion, <strong>and</strong> streng<strong>the</strong>ned public policy for brinjal IPM relative to thosefor hybrid <strong>Bt</strong> brinjal will result in greater social benefits in India <strong>and</strong> a major increase in pr<strong>of</strong>itability for small-scaleresource-poor farmers.A technology that causes a large improvement in crop yield <strong>and</strong> is adopted by many farmers will increase <strong>the</strong> supply <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> crop <strong>the</strong>reby depressing its price. At <strong>the</strong> depressed price, farmers will benefit less from having used <strong>the</strong> technology, butconsumers will benefit from <strong>the</strong> reduced cost <strong>of</strong> food. <strong>The</strong> economic surplus is an estimate <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> total social value <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong>technology <strong>and</strong> is based on projected technology adoption rates, changes in crop supply, <strong>and</strong> changes in crop price to <strong>the</strong>

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!