13.07.2015 Views

Vol 7 No 1 - Roger Williams University School of Law

Vol 7 No 1 - Roger Williams University School of Law

Vol 7 No 1 - Roger Williams University School of Law

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

eing the ultimate criterion.187 The economic efficiency approachat points seems to ignore political and social aspects <strong>of</strong> themarket.188 In Australia, section 2 <strong>of</strong> the Trade Practices Actprovides: “The object <strong>of</strong> this Act is to enhance the welfare <strong>of</strong>Australians through the promotion <strong>of</strong> competition and fair tradingand provision for consumer protection.”189David McGowan has recently written190 about the competingrationales <strong>of</strong> U.S. antitrust law in light <strong>of</strong> the Micros<strong>of</strong>t191decision. He ponders whether the decision is really aboutguaranteeing the existence <strong>of</strong> smaller firms and competition in themarket place or whether it is about total economic efficiencyanalysed through producer and consumer equations and evidencedin optimal costs and pricing.192 He argues that Judge Jackson inthe Micros<strong>of</strong>t case seemed to want to invoke both notions.193 Hequestions whether “innovation,” as invoked in antitrust reasoning,is a pursuit <strong>of</strong> many small players in the market or the pursuit <strong>of</strong>best possible outcomes in terms <strong>of</strong> economic welfare.194So what is it that we really want from antitrust law—diversity or optimal consumer welfare? The two are notnecessarily congruent. If we choose diversity as the touchstone,the exploitation <strong>of</strong> intellectual property rights will be defined inthis light and we may see courts more willing to facilitate abroader range <strong>of</strong> access to informational products than we wouldunder an economic efficiency approach. And if we marry a culturaltheory <strong>of</strong> intellectual property law with a cultural theory <strong>of</strong>antitrust law, we are almost certain to see differently constructeddigital property rights than if economic theory were the187. See Phillip E. Areeda & Herbert Hovenkamp, Antitrust <strong>Law</strong>: An Analysis <strong>of</strong>Antitrust Principles and Their Application, 8-11, 51-57, 94-137 (2d ed. 2000) (calling fora multi-dimensional approach, yet arguing for the primary importance <strong>of</strong> consumerwelfare over rivalry <strong>of</strong> small business—although economic theory is said to be limited);Robert H. Bork, The Antitrust Paradox 15-134 (1978).188. See United States v. Aluminum Co. <strong>of</strong> Am., 148 F. 2d 416, 428-29 (2d Cir.1945); United States v. Associated Press, 52 F. Supp. 362, 370-72 (S.D.N.Y. 1943); seealso Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra note 187, at 97-115; Bork, supra note 187, at 50-56;Louis B. Schwartz, “Justice” and Other <strong>No</strong>n Economic Goals <strong>of</strong> Antitrust, 127 U. Pa. L.Rev. 1076 (1979).189. Trade Practices Act, 1974, § 46.190. See McGowan, supra note 185.191. United States v. Micros<strong>of</strong>t Corp., 87 F. Supp. 2d 30 (D.D.C. 2000).192. See McGowan, supra note 185, at 766-76.193. Id.194. Id.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!