13.07.2015 Views

Agricultural Commodity Markets in African Agriculture - ERD

Agricultural Commodity Markets in African Agriculture - ERD

Agricultural Commodity Markets in African Agriculture - ERD

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

First draft. Please do not quote without permission.Comments welcome<strong>Agricultural</strong> Food <strong>Commodity</strong> <strong>Markets</strong> and Vulnerability of <strong>African</strong> Economies 1byAlexander Sarris and George RapsomanikisFood and <strong>Agriculture</strong> Organization of the United NationsMarch 20091. IntroductionThe sudden and unpredictable large <strong>in</strong>creases (spikes) of many <strong>in</strong>ternationally traded foodcommodity prices <strong>in</strong> late 2007 and early 2008 caught all market participants, as well asgovernments by surprise and led to many short term policy reactions that may have worsenedthe price rises. Many governments, th<strong>in</strong>k tanks, and <strong>in</strong>dividual analysts called for improved<strong>in</strong>ternational mechanisms to prevent and/or manage sudden food price rises. Similar calls forimproved discipl<strong>in</strong>es of markets were made dur<strong>in</strong>g almost all previous market price bursts,but were largely abandoned after the spikes passed. The f<strong>in</strong>ancial crisis that started to unravel<strong>in</strong> 2008 has co<strong>in</strong>cided with sharp commodity price decl<strong>in</strong>es, and food commodities havefollowed this general trend. The price volatility has been considerable. For <strong>in</strong>stance, <strong>in</strong>February 2008, <strong>in</strong>ternational wheat, maize and rice price <strong>in</strong>dices stood higher than the sameprices <strong>in</strong> November 2007, namely only three months earlier, by 48.8, 28.3, and 23.5 percentrespectively. In November 2008, the same <strong>in</strong>dices stood at -31.9, -3.2, and 52.3 percent higherrespectively, compared to November 2008. In other words with<strong>in</strong> one year these foodcommodity prices had <strong>in</strong>creased very sharply <strong>in</strong> the first part of the year, and subsequentlydecl<strong>in</strong>ed (except rice) equally sharply. Clearly such volatilities of world prices creates muchuncerta<strong>in</strong>ly of all market participants, and makes both short and longer term plann<strong>in</strong>g verydifficult for all.The high food commodity prices co<strong>in</strong>cided with high prices for petroleum, and many m<strong>in</strong>eralproducts, but not with high prices for many agricultural products of export <strong>in</strong>terest to many<strong>African</strong> countries. Hence, the recent commodity price boom may have not benefited, and <strong>in</strong>fact may have hurt most <strong>African</strong> economies. Given the size of the external shock, one mayquestion how poor agriculture dependent <strong>African</strong> economies fared dur<strong>in</strong>g the crisis, andwhether this type of external shock adds to the already vulnerable and fragile state of many ofthese economies. These are the issues that will form the basis of the <strong>in</strong>quiry <strong>in</strong> this paper.<strong>African</strong> countries have always had exports concentrated <strong>in</strong> primary commodities, and it iswell known that these commodities are characterized by volatile world prices. This impliesthat the terms of trade for most <strong>African</strong> economies have been volatile. Nevertheless the(negative) impact of this <strong>in</strong>stability on economic performance has not been explored at themacro level until recently (e.g. Collier and Dehn, 2001, Guillaumont and Chauvet, 2001,Collier and Goderis, 2007, Guillaumont and Korachais, 2006). Another issue, also wellanalyzed, albeit not resolved, concerns the possible existence of persistent negative trends ofthe prices of primary commodities (for a recent review see Cash<strong>in</strong> and McDermott , 2006).1 Paper presented at the European Report of Development workshop on “Food Crisis and the developmentpotential of the agriculture and commodity sector <strong>in</strong> fragile countries”, held <strong>in</strong> Cambridge, United K<strong>in</strong>gdom,March 17-18, 2009


The comb<strong>in</strong>ed negative effects of negative trend<strong>in</strong>g and unstable terms of trade for <strong>African</strong>economies is one of the reasons for their alleged negative performance.A more recent but less analyzed development has been the <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g food import dependenceof <strong>African</strong> economies, despite ample natural resources for food production. This trend <strong>in</strong> itselfdoes not necessarily imply any problems, as <strong>in</strong>creased food import dependence may be anatural tendency dur<strong>in</strong>g the transition of an agrarian economy to one based more onmanufactur<strong>in</strong>g and services, and can be managed if the export <strong>in</strong>come generated by the nonagriculturalsectors can pay for the <strong>in</strong>creased food imports. Such trends, which have beenobserved <strong>in</strong> several now developed or middle <strong>in</strong>come develop<strong>in</strong>g economies, have been thenatural outgrowth of their transition to more productive and diversified structures, and havebeen characterized by <strong>in</strong>creased agricultural productivity. Africa, however, does not seem tohave followed this trend, as will be po<strong>in</strong>ted out below, and hence its grow<strong>in</strong>g dependence onfood imports seems to suggest another structural development that may contribute tovulnerability.A major issue then of <strong>African</strong> economies fragility and vulnerability is what this <strong>in</strong>creasedexposure to food imports implies about food security, and the impact of external food marketshocks. The issue depends considerably on the degree to which the vulnerable populations <strong>in</strong>Africa are exposed to the <strong>in</strong>ternational market shocks. In other words the issue is whetherfood <strong>in</strong>secure <strong>African</strong> households are exposed to <strong>in</strong>ternational market <strong>in</strong>stability. Here, theevidence, that will be presented below, appears to be that they are very weakly exposed to<strong>in</strong>ternational market signals, at least <strong>in</strong> the short term. The reasons have to do with weak<strong>in</strong>frastructures, high transactions costs, and government policies. This, however, tends toshield vulnerable agriculture dependent <strong>African</strong> households from the <strong>in</strong>ternational markets,while makes them more vulnerable to domestic agricultural <strong>in</strong>come shocks, such as those dueto unfavorable weather events. These, <strong>in</strong> fact maybe more detrimental to these householdsthan the shocks due to external market <strong>in</strong>stability. Hence <strong>in</strong>sulation of food <strong>in</strong>securehousehold from <strong>in</strong>ternational markets can shield them from external shocks but make themmore vulnerable to <strong>in</strong>ternal shocks. The opposite is the case for households that are well<strong>in</strong>tegrated with <strong>in</strong>ternational markets. This, then presents a policy dilemma with respect to theoptimal degree of <strong>in</strong>sulation of food <strong>in</strong>secure households from world markets. Keep<strong>in</strong>g food<strong>in</strong>secure households <strong>in</strong>sulated from world markets makes them less vulnerable to globalshocks but more vulnerable to domestic shocks, and the opposite is the case if the degree of<strong>in</strong>sulation is smaller. The optimal degree of <strong>in</strong>sulation then to two types of shocks mustdepend on the degree of exposure to domestic shocks and global, as well as the relativemagnitude of these shocks. Some thoughts on this issue will be made towards the end of thepaper.The plan of the paper is as follows. In the follow<strong>in</strong>g section we exam<strong>in</strong>e the recent food pricespikes and food market <strong>in</strong>stability <strong>in</strong> order to assess whether there are tendencies differentthan the past ones that may raise new concerns. In section 3 we exhibit some structuralfeatures and trends of low <strong>in</strong>come <strong>African</strong> economies. In section 4 we exam<strong>in</strong>e vulnerabilityto commodity shocks at the household level. In section 5 we discuss <strong>in</strong>ternational food marketprice transmission to domestic markets. In section 6 we exam<strong>in</strong>e the impacts of the recentfood price <strong>in</strong>creases on <strong>African</strong> households. Section 7 concludes with a summary and policyissues.2. Recent commodity price developments <strong>in</strong> perspective.Figure 1 <strong>in</strong>dicates the evolution of monthly nom<strong>in</strong>al <strong>in</strong>ternational prices (<strong>in</strong>dex form) of thema<strong>in</strong> traded food commodities s<strong>in</strong>ce 1990. It can be seen that the ma<strong>in</strong> commodities that havesoared <strong>in</strong> late 2007 and early 2008 were dairy, cereals and oils, while sugar and meat prices


do not appear to have spiked <strong>in</strong> any exceptional way, given the trends s<strong>in</strong>ce 1990. Similarly(and not shown), other agricultural commodities such as the tropical beverages coffee andcocoa, have not exhibited any marked price changes <strong>in</strong> 2007 and 2008, compared to the 1990-2006 patterns. As of mid-2008 these spikes have vanished, with most <strong>in</strong>dices return<strong>in</strong>g tohistorical levels.While, however, the world price changes <strong>in</strong> some of the basic food commodities appearsignificant <strong>in</strong> nom<strong>in</strong>al terms <strong>in</strong> relation to the trends of the past twenty years, when exam<strong>in</strong>ed<strong>in</strong> real terms, prices dur<strong>in</strong>g the recent crisis appear still considerably smaller compared to thepeaks dur<strong>in</strong>g the previous major food crisis of the mid-1970s. Figure 2 <strong>in</strong>dicates the real<strong>in</strong>ternational prices (deflated by the US producer price <strong>in</strong>dex) of the ma<strong>in</strong> cereals andsoybeans from 1957 to 2008. It can be readily seen that for all commodities <strong>in</strong>dicated, the realprices at the height of the crisis <strong>in</strong> 2008 were considerably lower compared to the real prices<strong>in</strong> the mid 1970s.Another salient pattern evident <strong>in</strong> the graphs of figure 2 is that the long term decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> foodcommodity prices, that appears to have been <strong>in</strong> place s<strong>in</strong>ce the late 1950s, seems to havestopped <strong>in</strong> the late 1980s and early 1990s, with the trend l<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g steady, albeit stillfluctuat<strong>in</strong>g patterns. This suggests that there may have been several slowly evolv<strong>in</strong>g factorsaffect<strong>in</strong>g global food markets that gradually created a situation of tightly balanced supply anddemand, where a spike was almost <strong>in</strong>evitable <strong>in</strong> response to small shocks. Several of thesefactors have been discussed and analyzed by many authors and th<strong>in</strong>k tanks, as well as FAO.They <strong>in</strong>clude the follow<strong>in</strong>g.1. Grow<strong>in</strong>g world demand for basic food commodities, due to growth <strong>in</strong> emerg<strong>in</strong>geconomies, such as Ch<strong>in</strong>a and India. This development has been touted considerablyby many observers, but <strong>in</strong> fact it has been occurr<strong>in</strong>g gradually for several years, andcannot account for the sudden price spikes. Furthermore, the rate of growth of thesecountries’ demand or utilization of cereals, the most widely consumed and traded foodcommodities, for food, feed and other non-biofuel uses, has been decreas<strong>in</strong>g ratherthan <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g. In fact this is compatible and predicted by conventional economicwisdom, which <strong>in</strong>dicates that as <strong>in</strong>comes rise, the demand for basic foods rises by lessthan the rise <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>comes.2. Demand of cereals for biofuel production. It is true that a significant amount ofproduction of maize <strong>in</strong> the USA, oilseeds <strong>in</strong> the European Union, and sugar <strong>in</strong> Brazilhave been utilized for biofuel production, often with help from a variety of supportpolicies and mandated alternative energy targets. This has also been occurr<strong>in</strong>g over anumber of recent years, and accounts for a significant portion of market demand forthese commodities, as well as, via substitution, for <strong>in</strong>direct demand for several othercommodities that compete for the same resources, such as land. As this has beenoccurr<strong>in</strong>g for some time, and helped keep prices <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g and strong overall, it isunlikely to have been a major factor for the sudden price spikes, albeit it may have hadamplify<strong>in</strong>g effects <strong>in</strong> an already tight market.3. The rise <strong>in</strong> petroleum prices. Petroleum prices started ris<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> 2004, and cont<strong>in</strong>uedris<strong>in</strong>g all throughout the past few years, before sharply decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> late 2008. Thereasons are largely demand by fast grow<strong>in</strong>g countries with energy <strong>in</strong>tensiveeconomies, such as Ch<strong>in</strong>a and India. The oil price <strong>in</strong>crease, apart from push<strong>in</strong>g costsof agricultural production and transport higher, <strong>in</strong>duced a demand for alternative fuels,which <strong>in</strong> the context of the ris<strong>in</strong>g awareness about climate change created a strongdemand for biofuels. This, <strong>in</strong> turn, translated to <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g demand for agricultural rawmaterial feed stocks for biofuel production. Oil price <strong>in</strong>creases accelerated start<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>


late 2007 and cont<strong>in</strong>ued <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g rapidly until August 2008 when they started arapid decl<strong>in</strong>e. Food commodity prices, especially those for biofuel stocks, seem tohave followed this trend quite closely, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g through the spike period of late 2007-2008 and hence one might <strong>in</strong>duce that there is a close l<strong>in</strong>k between oil prices and foodprices, that may have been one of the ma<strong>in</strong> contribut<strong>in</strong>g factors to the recent food pricespike and subsequent decl<strong>in</strong>e.4. Slow<strong>in</strong>g rates of <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> farm productivity. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the more than thirty yearss<strong>in</strong>ce the last major food price crisis of 1973-75, agricultural prices <strong>in</strong> real terms havebeen decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g due to fast rates of growth of agricultural productivity (both landproductivity as well as total factor productivity). In the more recent period, agriculturehas been neglected <strong>in</strong> most develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, as the World Bank’s 2008 WorldDevelopment Report aptly illustrated. The neglect not only <strong>in</strong>volved lowerproductivity growth, via lower <strong>in</strong>vestments, but also the perception that agriculturalsupplies were not a problem <strong>in</strong> a world of low prices.5. The gradual decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> global food commodity stocks. The ratio of end of seasonworld cereal stocks to global utilization appears to have decreased considerablybetween 2000 and 2008. For two of the major cereal commodities (maize and rice)this decl<strong>in</strong>e can be accounted for by the decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the stocks of Ch<strong>in</strong>a. Furthermore,globalization that l<strong>in</strong>ked markets much more and saw the proliferation of “just <strong>in</strong>time” production methods, may have had the effect of reduc<strong>in</strong>g the overall level ofglobal food commodity stocks. Exclud<strong>in</strong>g Ch<strong>in</strong>a, world cereal stock ratios for mostcereal commodities (except wheat) have not changed appreciably <strong>in</strong> the last 20 years.Nevertheless, several major cereal produc<strong>in</strong>g and trad<strong>in</strong>g countries experiencedsecular decl<strong>in</strong>es <strong>in</strong> end of season stocks. Irrespective of the source of the decl<strong>in</strong>e,however, it is a fact that when commodity markets face lower end of season stocks,they react much stronger to any negative shocks.6. <strong>Commodity</strong> speculation. This factor has been highlighted by many analysts andpoliticians, to the po<strong>in</strong>t of blam<strong>in</strong>g the organized commodity exchanges for the pricespikes. Speculation is an ord<strong>in</strong>ary fact of life <strong>in</strong> all commodity markets, and is anecessary <strong>in</strong>gredient of all commodity trade. Any agent who buys a contract forcommodity (<strong>in</strong> the physical or future markets) with the <strong>in</strong>tention of sell<strong>in</strong>g it later for aprofit can be considered a speculator. Organized commodity exchanges are important<strong>in</strong>stitutions for both market transparency as well as the transfer of market risk fromphysical markets to speculators, and they guarantee transactions via the underly<strong>in</strong>gclear<strong>in</strong>g houses. It is no co<strong>in</strong>cidence that they have evolved and grown over a periodof more that two centuries, as they have been perceived as important <strong>in</strong>stitutions formanag<strong>in</strong>g market risks. The advent of large <strong>in</strong>vestments by commodity funds <strong>in</strong> recentyears has raised new issues about the utility of the organized exchanges as risk transfermechanisms, and about the role of unfettered speculation <strong>in</strong> persistent price rises.Detailed analyses of recent events (Gilbert, 2009) have suggested that there is weakevidence that such <strong>in</strong>vestments have contributed to the commodity price boom.7. Macroeconomic factors. While most commodity market analysts look for commodityspecific fundamental factors to expla<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual commodity price spikes, there aresystemic macroeconomic factors that affect all commodities that have been very<strong>in</strong>fluential. The recent commodity boom has <strong>in</strong>volved most traded commodities andnot only agricultural ones. One of the key factors that fueled such a boom seems tohave been a period of easy money and loose regulation of f<strong>in</strong>ancial transactions, whichresulted <strong>in</strong> a fast expansion of global f<strong>in</strong>ancial liquidity, a weak US dollar, and low


<strong>in</strong>terest rates. It is notable that the previous large commodity boom of 1973-75 wasalso preceded by a period of expand<strong>in</strong>g global liquidity fueled by large US externaldeficits and loose monetary policies, much like <strong>in</strong> recent years. It has been shown byresearch (Abbott, et. al. 2008, Mitchell, 2008) that US dollar depreciation hascontributed around 20 percent to <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> food prices. Frankel (2008), <strong>in</strong> turn, hasmade the argument that low <strong>in</strong>terest rates, themselves <strong>in</strong>duced by monetary expansion,encourages portfolio shift <strong>in</strong>to commodities, and also discourages stockhold<strong>in</strong>g,therefore, contribut<strong>in</strong>g to commodity price rises. There is an additional factor <strong>in</strong>expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the abrupt behaviour <strong>in</strong> food commodity prices <strong>in</strong> the midst of the f<strong>in</strong>ancialcrisis of 2008. Many researchers suggest that commodities – especially commodityfutures – have become a new ‘asset class’. First, returns to commodity futures arenegatively correlated with returns to traditional f<strong>in</strong>ancial assets such as equities andbonds. This relationship <strong>in</strong>dicates that commodity futures offer an attractive vehiclefor portfolio diversification that reduces the volatility of portfolio returns. Second,comparisons between returns of commodity futures with those of traditional f<strong>in</strong>ancialassets, such as stocks and bonds, <strong>in</strong>dicate that <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> commodity futures isprofitable. Futures and stocks have similar returns, amount<strong>in</strong>g to about 5.2–5.6 percentper annum. This is twice as high as the return from <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> bonds. Theseobservations suggest that commodity futures are not only regarded as provid<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>surance aga<strong>in</strong>st price risk for farmers and food processors, but also as an asset whichgenerates returns and can be used to diversify traditional f<strong>in</strong>ancial portfolios. Giventhat the commodity boom of early 2008 came to an abrupt stop <strong>in</strong> late 2008, followedby subsequent strong price decl<strong>in</strong>es, <strong>in</strong> the wake of the global f<strong>in</strong>ancial crisis, withoutsubstantial changes <strong>in</strong> the underly<strong>in</strong>g commodity market fundamentals, suggests thatmacroeconomic factors were important <strong>in</strong> the recent boom.The important po<strong>in</strong>t to highlight is that most of these factors were slow <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g overseveral years, but cumulatively they created a situation of tightly balanced world supply anddemand for many agricultural commodities. Furthermore, they made the demand for theagricultural commodities very price <strong>in</strong>elastic. The demand curve for agricultural (and othercommodities) is price elastic when there are ample supplies (from both production and stocks)but becomes very <strong>in</strong>elastic when the overall supplies are small, and there is low capacity ofthe market to absord or buffer exogenous shocks. As <strong>in</strong>dicated above both the reduction ofglobal stocks, as well as the macro factors that fuelled demand growth, pushed the supplydemand balance of most food agricultural commodities <strong>in</strong> a territory, where small shocks orsmall changes <strong>in</strong> perceptions could have had very strong price effects. In fact the foodproduction shocks that happened were small, exemplified by the fact that global gra<strong>in</strong>production decl<strong>in</strong>ed by only 1.3 percent <strong>in</strong> 2006, but then <strong>in</strong>creased by 4.7 percent <strong>in</strong> 2007,and a further 4.8 percent <strong>in</strong> 2008, despite the fact that some of the major export<strong>in</strong>g countriessuch as Australia experienced very sharp negative production shocks (of the order of 50-60percent <strong>in</strong> both 2005 and 2006). Such production shocks are rather normal <strong>in</strong> global foodcommodity markets, and have occurred on similar scale several times <strong>in</strong> the past, withoutcaus<strong>in</strong>g price spikes. It then appears that production shocks were not the ma<strong>in</strong> factor driv<strong>in</strong>gthe commodity markets, but rather some of the other factors <strong>in</strong>dicated above.A factor that seemed to have contributed considerably to the recent short term price spikes ishoard<strong>in</strong>g tendencies and policies affect<strong>in</strong>g the normal flow of commodities. It is well knownthat the reaction of many private agents as well as governments at the onset of price rises wasdestabiliz<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong> the sense that their actions fuelled the demand for current supplies, led byfears of impend<strong>in</strong>g basic commodity shortages. In other words when market agents realizedthat there were <strong>in</strong>adequate buffers <strong>in</strong> the global markets to ensure smooth supply flows, they


started to behave atomistically, to ensure their own smooth supply flow. This created panicbuy<strong>in</strong>g and hoard<strong>in</strong>g, even when the underly<strong>in</strong>g conditions did not justify it, thus creat<strong>in</strong>g theprice spikes. The case of the global rice market is a good case <strong>in</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t, where, despiteadequate global production and supplies, uncoord<strong>in</strong>ated government actions, such as exportbans, created a short term hoard<strong>in</strong>g panic and an ensu<strong>in</strong>g price spike. The realization <strong>in</strong> mid-2008 that the situation was not as critical as many thought, led to the opposite effect and asharp price decl<strong>in</strong>e followed.In the context of the events of the last two years, it is <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g to exam<strong>in</strong>e the evolution ofworld market price volatility. Figure 3 plots the <strong>in</strong>dices of annualized historic volatilities(estimated by normalized period to period changes of market prices) of nom<strong>in</strong>al <strong>in</strong>ternationalprices of wheat, maize, and rice over the previous five decades. The figures also exhibit thenom<strong>in</strong>al <strong>in</strong>ternational prices on the basis of which the <strong>in</strong>dices of volatility are determ<strong>in</strong>ed. Thereason for the juxtaposition of the two types of <strong>in</strong>formation is to exam<strong>in</strong>e visually therelationship between the level of commodity prices and the market volatility. It has beenknown for along time s<strong>in</strong>ce Samuelson’s classic article (Samuelson, 1957) that <strong>in</strong> periods ofprice spikes, overall supplies are tight, and market volatility should be higher, hence theexpectation is that dur<strong>in</strong>g periods of price spikes the <strong>in</strong>dex of market volatility should exhibita rise as well. .A most notable characteristic of the plots <strong>in</strong> figure 3 is that historic volatility (as an <strong>in</strong>dex ofmarket <strong>in</strong>stability) of most food commodities, while quite variable, appears not to have grownsecularly <strong>in</strong> the past five decades. There also appears to be no clear correlation for mostcommodities between the two major price spike periods, namely 1973-75 and 2007-8 andvolatility. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the first boom period, namely 1973-75, volatilities of wheat and maizeappear to have <strong>in</strong>creased markedly relative to previous trends. However, this is not the casefor rice. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the most recent boom of 2007-8, the volatility of wheat and rice appear tohave <strong>in</strong>creased markedly, but not that of maize. While these observations are just visual andneed to be corroborated with appropriate econometric analysis, they raise some questionsabout the alleged positive relationship between the level of prices and the level of volatility.A closer exam<strong>in</strong>ation of the factors underly<strong>in</strong>g price volatility reveals the follow<strong>in</strong>g. Thereare two factors that traditionally have been considered the ma<strong>in</strong> ones <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>fluenc<strong>in</strong>gagricultural market price <strong>in</strong>stability. These are the variability of production, and the level ofend of previous period stocks. The more variable is agricultural production from year to year,the more one expects to observe large period to period price variations, namely largervolatility. In the same ve<strong>in</strong>, the smaller the end of season stocks, the more any new marketdevelopments are likely to affect prices, and hence the more variable is market price. Trends<strong>in</strong> the coefficients of variation of annual production of wheat, maize and rice, computed forfour ten year periods end<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> 1999, as well as the most recent period 2000-06, and for thefive cont<strong>in</strong>ents, as well as the world as a whole, reveal a marked decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> world productionvariability, and significant reductions <strong>in</strong> production variability of America (North and South)and Asia, which between them account for 60 percent of global production. It is only Africa,which accounts for a small share of global wheat production (only 3.3 percent), whereproduction variability seems to have <strong>in</strong>creased. Similarly for maize, global production appearsalso to have become less variable, with no apparent significant positive trend <strong>in</strong> any cont<strong>in</strong>ent.Global paddy rice production variability also appears to be decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g over time.Turn<strong>in</strong>g to end of season stock levels, the end of season global stocks both absolutely as wellas share of total utilization for wheat, maize, and rice, reveal that global end of season stocksof cereals do not appear to have been <strong>in</strong> 2007-8 much smaller <strong>in</strong> absolute levels than <strong>in</strong> earlierperiods, notably the early-mid 1990s. Stocks <strong>in</strong>creased considerably and reached a peak


around 2000-2001 and then the started decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g. The decl<strong>in</strong>e cont<strong>in</strong>ued until 2004-5 andthese trends occurred both with and without Ch<strong>in</strong>a. After 2005 stocks appear to have<strong>in</strong>creased or at least not decrease <strong>in</strong> absolute terms. Stock to utilization ratios seem to followthe same patterns and turn<strong>in</strong>g po<strong>in</strong>ts both with as well as without Ch<strong>in</strong>a. Also, albeit thereappears to be a negative trend <strong>in</strong> the ratio of stocks to utilization for the world, when oneexam<strong>in</strong>es the whole 30 year period from 1979 onwards, there is no marked negative trend forthe ratios if Ch<strong>in</strong>a is exluded from the world total. In fact for rice, the ratios for the world aswell as without Ch<strong>in</strong>a exhibit a slight positive trend.Turn<strong>in</strong>g now to the newer factors affect<strong>in</strong>g market volatility, the most difficult to analyze isthe <strong>in</strong>fluence of commodity traders <strong>in</strong> organized exchanges. The question is whether theundoubted <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> participation of non-commercial traders <strong>in</strong> the organized futures andother derivative markets, affected the market fundamentals, and <strong>in</strong> particular the level ofprices and volatility. There is very little research on this issue, but some recent empiricalanalysis by Gilbert, (2009) and a policy brief by the Conference Board of Canada (CBS,2008) seem to suggest that is price volatility that attracts non-commercial and other f<strong>in</strong>ancialtraders, and not the other way around.A lot has been said about the <strong>in</strong>fluence of the unstable exchange rate of the US dollar oncommodity markets. It is a fact that <strong>in</strong> recent years the USD exchange rate vas variedconsiderably aga<strong>in</strong>st the currencies of other major trad<strong>in</strong>g countries. For <strong>in</strong>stance the USDdepreciated aga<strong>in</strong>st the Euro by more than 30 percent between 2003 and 2007. It is also thecase, albeit not obvious that s<strong>in</strong>ce the prices of most <strong>in</strong>ternationally traded agriculturalcommodities are quoted <strong>in</strong> USD, a USD depreciation has a considerable <strong>in</strong>fluence on USDprices of traded commodities. Evidence provided by the International Monetary Fundsuggests that if the US dollar had rema<strong>in</strong>ed at its 2002 level, oil prices would have been lowerby US$25 per barrel, and the <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> non-fuel commodity prices would have been lowerby 12 percent (Lipsky, 2008). FAO has estimated that a 1 percent USD depreciation aga<strong>in</strong>stall currencies, ceteris paribus, can have significant upwards <strong>in</strong>fluence on all agriculturalcommodity prices, and for some the relevant elasticity can be as high as 0.8-0.9 (this occursmostly for livestock commodities, where developed countries are the major traders, andexchange rates most variable). Clearly then it appears that the <strong>in</strong>stability of the USD exchangerates must have contributed significantly to market price volatility. Given recent globalf<strong>in</strong>ancial and production developments, the huge <strong>in</strong>ternational f<strong>in</strong>ancial flows they imply fromagents look<strong>in</strong>g for safe heavens, it is likely that this <strong>in</strong>stability will cont<strong>in</strong>ue <strong>in</strong> the future, andhence this is likely to cont<strong>in</strong>ue affect<strong>in</strong>g adversely commodity market volatilities.Apart from the <strong>in</strong>stability of the USD, macroeconomic <strong>in</strong>stability is likely to have contributedconsiderably to commodity markets <strong>in</strong>stability. Gilbert, (2009) <strong>in</strong> his empirical analysis f<strong>in</strong>dsthat both money supply as well as GDP seem to Granger cause commodity prices. The currentf<strong>in</strong>ancial crisis, does not bode well for monetary stability, especially given the significantmonetary expansion that is likely to follow the fiscal stimulus packages now envisioned <strong>in</strong>most large economies. Hence it is likely that macroeconomic factors will cont<strong>in</strong>ue add<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>stability to world commodity markets.The price of petroleum was already alluded to as an important determ<strong>in</strong>ant of agriculturalcommodity prices, especially for those commodities which can be utilized as biofuelproduction stock. Schmidhuber (2006) has shown that when petroleum prices are <strong>in</strong> a certa<strong>in</strong>price range, then oil prices and biofuel stock prices seem to be much strongly correlated. Thishas been empirically substantiated by Balcombe and Rapsomanikis (2008) and for the sugaroil-ethanolnexus. Several analysts have attributed significant <strong>in</strong>fluence on agriculturalcommodity prices from petroleum prices, coupled with biofuel policies (e.g. Mitchell, 2008,


Abbott, et. al. 2008). Despite the rapid fall of petroleum prices <strong>in</strong> late 2008 and early 2009,the underly<strong>in</strong>g demand for oil <strong>in</strong> the medium term is real and likely to <strong>in</strong>crease (OECD-FAO,2008). This is likely to <strong>in</strong>duce a cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g l<strong>in</strong>kage between petroleum prices and biofuelstock prices, albeit not at all periods. As oil prices are likely to be quite unstable given theuncerta<strong>in</strong>ties <strong>in</strong> global economic growth, this most likely will <strong>in</strong>duce <strong>in</strong>stability of theagricultural commodity markets, both for those those products that are directly related tobiofuels, such as maize, sugar, and rapeseed, but also <strong>in</strong> commodities that are substitutes <strong>in</strong>production.The f<strong>in</strong>al factor that is likely to affect commodity market volatility is country policy actionsand reactions to external events. The commodity scare of 2007-8 and the publicity it receivedmade many governments overreact, by measures that were not always effective at achiev<strong>in</strong>gtheir stated objectives. A FAO survey of government actions <strong>in</strong> 77 develop<strong>in</strong>g countriesdur<strong>in</strong>g the 2007-8 period, tabulated the type of measures that were undertaken <strong>in</strong> response tothe global price rises. It was revealed that there are only a few countries whose governmentsdid noth<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> response to the global commodity crisis. Perhaps surpris<strong>in</strong>gly the region wherefew additional policies were adopted appears to be Africa. Nevertheless, discrete and largelyunexpected policy responses, especially through market<strong>in</strong>g boards operations, <strong>in</strong>creaseuncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and weaken the <strong>in</strong>centive for the private sector to engage <strong>in</strong> trade. The presenceand trad<strong>in</strong>g activities of both market<strong>in</strong>g boards and private firms give rise to a dual market<strong>in</strong>gsystem that often <strong>in</strong>creases the fragility of the market. The lack of trust and the poorcoord<strong>in</strong>ation between the public and the private sectors often result <strong>in</strong> food deficits and highdomestic price volatility.The overall conclusion then is that the global food commodity markets are likely to stayvolatile <strong>in</strong> the next few years, until stocks are replenished, petroleum prices stabilize, and theglobal f<strong>in</strong>ancial crisis works itself out. An added risk is that the efforts currently made torenew emphasis on agricultural <strong>in</strong>vestments to boost productive efficiency, especially <strong>in</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g agriculture dependent countries, are derailed by the probably short lived hiatus oflow global food commodity prices.3. Food dependency and food <strong>in</strong>security among <strong>African</strong> economiesOver the past 40 years, and despite significant developments <strong>in</strong> global trade, technology andaid, <strong>African</strong> countries have rema<strong>in</strong>ed very dependent on agriculture. Table 1 <strong>in</strong>dicates thatboth for Africa as a whole and for LDC Africa <strong>in</strong> particular the share of agriculture <strong>in</strong> GDPhas decreased only slightly s<strong>in</strong>ce 1970. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the same period, the share of economicallyactive population employed <strong>in</strong> agriculture, while experienc<strong>in</strong>g significant decl<strong>in</strong>e for Africaas a whole, from 76 percent <strong>in</strong> 1970 to 57 percent <strong>in</strong> 2002-4, <strong>in</strong> LDC Africa the sharedecreased from 83 percent to a still very high 71 percent. Despite this cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g dependence,Table 2 <strong>in</strong>dicates that the shares of agricultural exports <strong>in</strong> total exports of merchandise as wellas total exports of goods and services have decl<strong>in</strong>ed to about half their shares <strong>in</strong> 1970.This decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> agricultural export shares has been accompanied by grow<strong>in</strong>g agriculturalimports. Table 3 <strong>in</strong>dicates that dur<strong>in</strong>g the same period, the share of agricultural imports <strong>in</strong>total imports of goods and services has decl<strong>in</strong>ed, but the share of imports <strong>in</strong> total merchandiseimports has <strong>in</strong>creased, with the exception of North Africa. More significantly, the share ofagricultural imports <strong>in</strong> total exports of goods and services, an <strong>in</strong>dex that can <strong>in</strong>dicate theability of the country to f<strong>in</strong>ance food imports, while decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g from 1970 to 1980 and 1990,has <strong>in</strong>creased considerably from 1990 to 2002-04. This suggests that agricultural (mostlyfood) imports have necessitated a large share of the export revenues of <strong>African</strong> countries.This development has been accompanied by a decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>come terms of trade for LDCs,which are largely <strong>African</strong> countries. Figure 4 <strong>in</strong>dicates that dur<strong>in</strong>g the period 1960-2002 the


<strong>in</strong>come terms of trade, as computed by the ratio of the value of agricultural exports to an<strong>in</strong>dex of import prices (the IMF Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g Unit Value <strong>in</strong>dex), and which measures thepurchas<strong>in</strong>g power of agricultural exports, seems to have evolved totally differently fordeveloped countries, LDCs and other (middle <strong>in</strong>come) develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, with the <strong>in</strong>dexfor the LDC show<strong>in</strong>g a cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g decl<strong>in</strong>e, while that of the developed and other develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries an <strong>in</strong>crease. The basic reason for this development, s<strong>in</strong>ce both groups of countriesface the same <strong>in</strong>ternational prices is the different rates of productivity growth. Figure 4exhibits the trends <strong>in</strong> average yields of cereals for the same three groups of countries. It isclear that <strong>in</strong> the last 20 years productivity <strong>in</strong>creases have been strong <strong>in</strong> developed and otherdevelop<strong>in</strong>g countries, while they have been very weak <strong>in</strong> LDCs.In fact with<strong>in</strong> Africa yields have stagnated most for the LDC group. Figure 5 exhibits yieldsfor basic food commodities <strong>in</strong> various Africa groups and the region as a whole. It can benoted that <strong>in</strong> LDC Africa yields have been particularly stagnant. The conclusion is that the<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g food dependency has not been accompanied by <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> food commodityagricultural productivity <strong>in</strong> Africa.Two other <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g structural developments are <strong>in</strong> order. The first concerns the fact thatdespite the fact, illustrated <strong>in</strong> table 3, that agricultural export dependence has decl<strong>in</strong>ed formost <strong>African</strong> countries, the high commodity dependence of agricultural exports hascont<strong>in</strong>ued. Table 4 exhibits the share of the top four agricultural commodities <strong>in</strong> totalagricultural exports of 32 low <strong>in</strong>come <strong>African</strong> countries over the period 1982-84 to 2002-4(the well known C4 ratio). It can be seen that for most of these countries <strong>in</strong>itial commoditydependence of agriculture was very high, with 20 of the 32 countries exhibit<strong>in</strong>g agriculturalC4 ratio larger than 80 percent. However, over the next twenty years, for more than half ofthese countries their C4 ratio either <strong>in</strong>creased or hardly changed.The second structural development concerns changes <strong>in</strong> the production structure of <strong>African</strong>agriculture. After 1980, almost all <strong>African</strong> countries adopted stabilization and structuraladjustment programs that <strong>in</strong>tended <strong>in</strong> transform<strong>in</strong>g their economic sectors towards moretradable commodities. This was particularly <strong>in</strong>tended for agriculture, which had beencharacterized by many <strong>in</strong>stitutional and market rigidities and government monopolistic<strong>in</strong>terventions. However, two decades after the onset of such programs the share of agriculturalproduction that is accounted for by exportable and importable products <strong>in</strong> Africa does notappear to have changed very much. The average share of the value of exportable production<strong>in</strong> the value of total agricultural production for 24 low <strong>in</strong>come <strong>African</strong> countries <strong>in</strong> 2001-3was estimated by the authors to be 21.8 percent compared to 23.1 percent <strong>in</strong> 1980-82. As forthe share of import substitute products <strong>in</strong> total agricultural production over the same period,this seems to have stayed the same from 24.7 percent <strong>in</strong> 1980-82 to 25 percent <strong>in</strong> 2001-3.Turn<strong>in</strong>g to medium term food outlook, we present some projections of net imports of the FAOCOSIMO model that perta<strong>in</strong> to LDC Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) 2 . Figures 6, 7 and 8 <strong>in</strong>dicatethat based on current estimates, LDC SSA is projected to become an <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g food deficitregion <strong>in</strong> wheat and rice, while <strong>in</strong> the coarse gra<strong>in</strong> sector, a sector that <strong>in</strong>cludes maize, milletand sorghum, LDC SSA is expected to cont<strong>in</strong>ue be<strong>in</strong>g on balance self sufficient. Clearly this2 this group <strong>in</strong>cludes 36 countries of Eastern, Southern and West Africa as follows: Burundi, Comoros, Djibouti,Eritrea, Ethiopia, Madagascar, Malawi, Rwanda, Somalia, Sudan, Uganda, Angola, Central <strong>African</strong> Republic,Chad, Dem Republic of Congo, Equatorial Gu<strong>in</strong>ea, Lesotho, Sao Tome and Pr<strong>in</strong>cipe, Ben<strong>in</strong>, Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso, CapeVerde, Gambia, Gu<strong>in</strong>ea, Gu<strong>in</strong>ea-Bissau, Liberia, Mali, Mauritania, Niger, Senegal, Sierra Leone, Togo,Mozambique, Tanzania, and Zambia


suggests that as LDC Africa becomes more dependent on <strong>in</strong>ternational markets, it willbecome more exposed to <strong>in</strong>ternational market <strong>in</strong>stability.The f<strong>in</strong>al issue concerns the comb<strong>in</strong>ation of undernourishment with high import dependenceon gra<strong>in</strong>s and petroleum, two of the commodity groups that have experienced high pricesrecently. Table 5 exhibits the countries <strong>in</strong> the world with highest levels of undernourishmentand simultaneous high shares of imported petroleum and high shares of imported gra<strong>in</strong>. It canbe seen that most of these countries are <strong>in</strong> Africa.The conclusion of this descriptive exposition is that many LDC countries <strong>in</strong> Africa, especiallythose with large degrees of undernourishment, have become more food import dependent,without becom<strong>in</strong>g more productive <strong>in</strong> their own agricultural food produc<strong>in</strong>g sectors, orwithout expand<strong>in</strong>g other export sectors to be able to counteract that import dependency. Thisimplies that they may have become more exposed to <strong>in</strong>ternational market <strong>in</strong>stability andhence more vulnerable.4. Food dependency and vulnerability to commodity shocks at the household levelRisk and especially the contribution of risk to poverty dynamics are of grow<strong>in</strong>g importance <strong>in</strong>the literature on poverty. Risks contribute to poverty <strong>in</strong> a number of ways. Firstly, risks mayblunt the adoption of technologies and strategies of specialization necessary for agriculturalefficiency (Carter, 1997). For example, households with limited options for consumptionsmooth<strong>in</strong>g grow lower return, but safer crops (sweet potatoes, sorghum and millet) than thericher households which usually have more options for consumption smooth<strong>in</strong>g. Risks maymotivate farmers to apply less productive technologies <strong>in</strong> exchange for greater stability(Morduch, 2002, Larson and Plessman, 2002). The cost of such an <strong>in</strong>come-smooth<strong>in</strong>gstrategy can be high and a farmer may forgo up to 20 percent of his or her expected <strong>in</strong>come toobta<strong>in</strong> a smoother <strong>in</strong>come stream (Dercon, 1996). Secondly, risks may function as amechanism for economic differentiation with<strong>in</strong> a population, deepen<strong>in</strong>g the poverty and food<strong>in</strong>security of some <strong>in</strong>dividuals even as aggregate food availability improves (Carter, 1997).Thus, <strong>in</strong> the absence of risk management <strong>in</strong>struments, risky events may plunge particularlyvulnerable households <strong>in</strong>to poverty. The policy message emanat<strong>in</strong>g out of these <strong>in</strong>sights arethat risks are detrimental to the welfare of (poor) households.A household fac<strong>in</strong>g a risky situation is subject to future loss of welfare. The likelihood ofexperienc<strong>in</strong>g future loss of welfare, generally weighted by the magnitude of expected welfareloss, is called vulnerability. The degree of vulnerability depends on the characteristic of therisk and the household ability to respond to risk through the risk management strategiesdiscussed above. Households face risks namely exposure to uncerta<strong>in</strong> events. To contend withrisks households make use of a number of risk management options. Risks comb<strong>in</strong>ed withresponses lead to outcomes. Thus a household is said to be vulnerable to the outcome of anuncerta<strong>in</strong> event, if it does not have sufficient resources to adequately contend with theoutcome of the event. In other words, the extent to which a household is vulnerable to anuncerta<strong>in</strong> event, namely the extent to which the household can become and/or rema<strong>in</strong> poor,depends on the size of the shock and how effective the household is <strong>in</strong> manag<strong>in</strong>g the uncerta<strong>in</strong>event both ex-ante, as well as ex-post.Households <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g agrarian economies <strong>in</strong> Africa face many risks, but among the manyrisks faced, recent research suggests that commodity price changes (both decl<strong>in</strong>es but also<strong>in</strong>creases), droughts, and health shocks are the major risk factors both <strong>in</strong> terms of thefrequency of their occurrence as well as the severity of their effects (Hoffman, Christiaensenand Sarris, 2007).


The impact of sharp <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> food prices <strong>in</strong> the short run depends very much on whetherpeople are ma<strong>in</strong>ly producers or consumers of food. A low <strong>in</strong>come household that spends alarge proportion of its <strong>in</strong>come on tradable food staples (wheat, rice, maize) is more likely tosuffer a decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> overall welfare. The extent of this decl<strong>in</strong>e depends on the ability of thehousehold to shift consumption towards less expensive foods. On the other hand, householdsthat derive some part of their <strong>in</strong>come from the production and sale of <strong>in</strong>ternationally tradedstaples could benefit from higher world prices, although high fuel and fertilizer prices arelikely to offset some of the ga<strong>in</strong>s households could earn. In Africa, despite beliefs to thecontrary, most households, and especially rural poor households are net staple food buyers.For <strong>in</strong>stance <strong>in</strong> the latest State of World Food Insecurity published by FAO <strong>in</strong> 2008 (FAO,2008) it is <strong>in</strong>dicated that <strong>in</strong> Ghana about 79 percent of all households (72 percent for rural and92 percent for urban) are net staple food buyers. In Malawi the share of net food buy<strong>in</strong>ghouseholds is larger at 93 percent (93 percent rural and 96 percent urban). Table 5 makes thesame po<strong>in</strong>t for several countries <strong>in</strong> Eastern and Southern Africa, and also <strong>in</strong>dicates the bulk ofstaple food sales (maize <strong>in</strong> this case) come from a very small share of producers. Clearly then<strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> staple food prices are more likely than not to have a negative impact on mosthouseholds.5. Price transmission between <strong>in</strong>ternational food commodity markets and domestic<strong>African</strong> marketsA fundamental issue when analys<strong>in</strong>g the impact of the current food price boom is the extent towhich market prices <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries respond to changes <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational food prices.Price transmission from the <strong>in</strong>ternational to domestic food markets is central <strong>in</strong> understand<strong>in</strong>gthe degree to which producers and consumers are affected by <strong>in</strong>ternational price <strong>in</strong>creases and<strong>in</strong> formulat<strong>in</strong>g policies to manage such susta<strong>in</strong>ed price <strong>in</strong>creases.Studies on the transmission of price signals are based on the concept of competitive pric<strong>in</strong>g.The classical paradigm of the Law of One Price suggests that, <strong>in</strong> the long run, pricetransmission is complete with prices of a commodity sold on competitive foreign anddomestic markets differ<strong>in</strong>g only by transport costs, when converted to a common currency.Such a complete price pass-through is atta<strong>in</strong>ed through trade. Changes <strong>in</strong> supply and demand<strong>in</strong> one market will affect prices which <strong>in</strong> turn will <strong>in</strong>stigate trade with other countries. Asarbitrage and trade restores the market equilibrium, prices <strong>in</strong> the domestic market equalizewith those <strong>in</strong> foreign markets – hence the term ‘Law of One Price’.Poor price transmission may arise due to a number of reasons. In general, the implementationof import tariffs, or export taxes will allow <strong>in</strong>ternational price changes to be fully transmittedto domestic markets <strong>in</strong> proportional terms, unless tariffs or taxes are prohibitively high. Veryhigh tariffs or taxes obliterate opportunities for arbitrage and result <strong>in</strong> the domestic and<strong>in</strong>ternational prices mov<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dependently of each other, as if an import or export ban wasimplemented. In the context of the current food price hike, many governments <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries have implemented short-run border measures, such as import tariff reductions orexports bans, <strong>in</strong> order to harness domestic price <strong>in</strong>creases and shield consumers andvulnerable populations from <strong>in</strong>creased food costs. A decrease <strong>in</strong> import tariffs results <strong>in</strong> partlyoffsett<strong>in</strong>g the impact of <strong>in</strong>ternational price <strong>in</strong>creases to the domestic market, as compared tothe previous tariff level, given stable exchange rates. For a net export<strong>in</strong>g country, theimplementation of an export ban will also h<strong>in</strong>der the transmission of price signals from the<strong>in</strong>ternational market, exert<strong>in</strong>g downward pressure to the domestic price level.Policies that aim <strong>in</strong> stabiliz<strong>in</strong>g domestic prices at a certa<strong>in</strong> level are often implemented <strong>in</strong>conjunction with border measures. Government <strong>in</strong>tervention <strong>in</strong> the form of food procurementor sale and <strong>in</strong>ventory management is commonly practiced across <strong>African</strong> countries. Such


policies h<strong>in</strong>der price transmission depend<strong>in</strong>g on governments’ ability and budget to realizefood purchases at certa<strong>in</strong> price levels and manage the food <strong>in</strong>ventories cont<strong>in</strong>uously. Eventhen, depend<strong>in</strong>g on domestic market fundamentals, trade takes place and the <strong>in</strong>ternational anddomestic prices may not be completely unrelated, with the <strong>in</strong>tervention policy result<strong>in</strong>g only<strong>in</strong> slow <strong>in</strong>ternational price pass-through.Apart from policies, domestic markets can also be partly <strong>in</strong>sulated by large market<strong>in</strong>g marg<strong>in</strong>sthat arise due to high transport costs. Especially <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, poor <strong>in</strong>frastructure,transport and communication services give rise to large market<strong>in</strong>g marg<strong>in</strong>s due to high costsof deliver<strong>in</strong>g the locally produced commodity to the border for export or the importedcommodity to the domestic market for consumption. High transfer costs h<strong>in</strong>der thetransmission of price signals, as they may prohibit arbitrage. As a consequence, changes <strong>in</strong>world market prices are not fully transmitted to domestic prices, result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> producers andconsumers adjust<strong>in</strong>g, if at all, partly to shifts <strong>in</strong> world supply and demand.Oligopolistic behaviour and collusion among domestic traders may reta<strong>in</strong> price differencesbetween <strong>in</strong>ternational and domestic prices <strong>in</strong> levels higher that those determ<strong>in</strong>ed by transfercosts. Consumer preferences may also result <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>complete price transmission even undercompetitive and free market conditions. Domestically produced food often has differentattributes than those characteriz<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>ternationally traded food commodities. As consumersprefer the attributes and taste of domestically produced food, the possibilities of substitution<strong>in</strong> consumption between domestic and foreign foods are limited, result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>complete pricetransmission as domestic market shocks cannot be smoothed out by trade with the<strong>in</strong>ternational market.Econometricians describe the data and use it to quantify economic relations which representthe structure of a market <strong>in</strong> a model. These models are used to provide policy advice andgenerate forecasts. Price transmission analysis adheres, more or less, to the above sequence oftasks and it is often based on a statistical toolkit called vector autoregressions, or VARs. 3Vector autoregressions provide the basis for captur<strong>in</strong>g the rich price dynamics <strong>in</strong> both theshort- and the long-run, while <strong>in</strong> the context of price transmission, these models provide abasis for assess<strong>in</strong>g the correlation between prices of different markets, understand<strong>in</strong>g thenature of the relationship between them along time and, consequently exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the extent ofprice pass-through.This k<strong>in</strong>d of analysis falls short from provid<strong>in</strong>g a description of the structure of the marketwhich gives rise to the prices. This is a formidable task, as it entails the modell<strong>in</strong>g of a largenumber of economic relationships. For each country under exam<strong>in</strong>ation, functions thatexpla<strong>in</strong> total utilization, arbitrage, <strong>in</strong> terms of trade volumes and trade flows with partnercountries, as well as public and private <strong>in</strong>ventory behaviour have to be estimated result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>very high data requirements that cannot always be met when analyz<strong>in</strong>g develop<strong>in</strong>g countries’markets.Vector autoregressions have significantly lower data requirements and <strong>in</strong> order to assess pricepass-through one needs data on domestic market and <strong>in</strong>ternational market prices only. Inbrief, VARs and the statistical toolkit allow us to assess price transmission by:• Test<strong>in</strong>g for price co-movement. Co-movement can be thought of as a long run l<strong>in</strong>earequilibrium relationship between prices which is determ<strong>in</strong>ed by arbitrage and marketforces. In fact, co-movement satisfies the transitivity property, so if the <strong>in</strong>ternational3 VARs are simple l<strong>in</strong>ear models and <strong>in</strong> the context of price transmission between two markets they consist of two equations,one for each market price, <strong>in</strong> which the current price of one market is expla<strong>in</strong>ed by its own lags, as well as the lagged pricesof the other market.


price of maize co-moves with the South <strong>African</strong> price of white maize, which, <strong>in</strong> turn isfound to co-move with the price of white maize <strong>in</strong> Mombassa, then these relationshipssuggest that the prices <strong>in</strong> Mombassa co-move with those of the <strong>in</strong>ternational market.• Exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the short-run dynamics and the adjustment to the long-run relationship.In the short run, co-mov<strong>in</strong>g prices may still affect each other or may drift apart, asshocks <strong>in</strong> one market may not be rapidly transmitted to other markets. In this case,market forces will ensure that these divergences from the underly<strong>in</strong>g long-runrelationship are transitory and not permanent. Assess<strong>in</strong>g the rate of adjustment to thelong-run equilibrium provides <strong>in</strong>formation on the speed with which changes <strong>in</strong> prices<strong>in</strong> one market are filtered to the other market. Complete adjustment to shocks <strong>in</strong> shortperiods of 1 or 2 months is not impossible to observe, but it is a characteristic of largeand efficient markets. In develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, with national and regional markets thatare separated by poor transport and communication <strong>in</strong>frastructure, adjustment isslower. For example, <strong>in</strong> export-orientated sectors <strong>in</strong> Africa, such as the Ethiopiancoffee market where price discovery is based on an efficient auction system, fulladjustment of the price of Ethiopian arabica coffee to the <strong>in</strong>ternational coffee pricetakes place <strong>in</strong> 3.7 months.• F<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g the direction of the flow of price <strong>in</strong>formation or the direction of causality.Price <strong>in</strong>formation is vital for the efficient function<strong>in</strong>g of a market. Large physicalmarkets, auctions and commodity exchanges react to new <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> the<strong>in</strong>ternational prices, but also provide <strong>in</strong>formation to smaller physical markets. In manycountries, trade is facilitated by us<strong>in</strong>g prices from futures exchanges as a benchmarkfor sett<strong>in</strong>g the price for physical transactions. As <strong>in</strong>formation flows from one pr<strong>in</strong>cipalmarket to another smaller market, any shocks will also be transmitted and the direction<strong>in</strong> which price <strong>in</strong>formation flows provides additional <strong>in</strong>formation for policyimplementation. 4Price transmission between several maize markets <strong>in</strong> South Africa, Kenya, Zambia, Malawi,Uganda and the <strong>in</strong>ternational market has been tested for this paper. In these countries, withthe exception of Uganda, maize consists of the ma<strong>in</strong> food staple, while all countries areengaged <strong>in</strong> trade <strong>in</strong> the Eastern and Southern Africa regions and, at a lesser extent, with therest of the world. Apart from high transaction costs, there is a number of reasons for whichprice transmission from the <strong>in</strong>ternational market to the markets of these countries may not becomplete.• In Eastern and Southern Africa, consumers prefer white maize rather than the<strong>in</strong>ternationally traded yellow maize. Such limited possibilities <strong>in</strong> substitution <strong>in</strong>consumption may tend to make these markets be<strong>in</strong>g dependent on regional supply anddemand shocks only which cannot be smooth out through trad<strong>in</strong>g with the<strong>in</strong>ternational market. As it is the price of <strong>in</strong>ternationally traded yellow maize that hasbeen experienc<strong>in</strong>g a susta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong>crease, these white maize produc<strong>in</strong>g and consum<strong>in</strong>gcountries may experience <strong>in</strong>creases that are due to regional market conditions ratherthan due to co-movement with the <strong>in</strong>ternational price of maize.• Most of the countries under exam<strong>in</strong>ation implement price stabilization policies. InKenya, the state-run National Cereals and Produce Board (NCPB) is <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong>procurement of domestically produced maize and <strong>in</strong>ventory management. In Malawi4 As shocks <strong>in</strong> smaller markets are caused by the shocks <strong>in</strong> larger markets, the technical term characteriz<strong>in</strong>g this exchange of<strong>in</strong>formation reflects Granger-causality. It is important to note that Granger-causality is related to the flow of price<strong>in</strong>formation between markets and does not refer to economic causal relationships between variables such as the relationshipbetween the quantity demanded and the price of a good.


and Zambia, the <strong>Agricultural</strong> Development and Market<strong>in</strong>g Corporation (ADMARC)and the Food Reserve Agency respectively ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> a strong presence. Pricestabilization policies may blunt the transmission of price signals from the <strong>in</strong>ternationalto the domestic markets.The relationship between prices of yellow and white maize is of central <strong>in</strong>terest for Easternand Southern Africa. Co-movement between the price of locally produced white maize andthat of the <strong>in</strong>ternationally traded yellow maize would imply that these markets are <strong>in</strong>tegratedand consequently, <strong>in</strong> the l<strong>in</strong>g-run, the <strong>in</strong>ternational maize price would be likely to affect pricesthese regions. On the other hand, lack of co-movement would mean that susta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong>the <strong>in</strong>ternational yellow maize price would not be likely to affect the Eastern and Southern<strong>African</strong> white maize markets.South Africa produces and trades both yellow and white maize and its futures exchange, theSouth <strong>African</strong> Futures Exchange (SAFEX) offers an efficient mechanism for trade and price<strong>in</strong>formation exchange <strong>in</strong> a competitive market with m<strong>in</strong>imum government <strong>in</strong>tervention.SAFEX offers futures contracts on both white and yellow maize, while traders <strong>in</strong> SouthernAfrica use it as a benchmark for pric<strong>in</strong>g physical trade.Co-movement was tested between price pairs formed by the South <strong>African</strong> SAFEX spotprices for both yellow and white maize, P SA Y and P SA W respectively, and the price of the USyellow maize No. 2, Gulf, P W . The tests were performed utiliz<strong>in</strong>g data spann<strong>in</strong>g from January1998 to July 2008. The results are shown <strong>in</strong> table 7. There is strong evidence that South<strong>African</strong> prices of both yellow and white maize co-move with the <strong>in</strong>ternational price <strong>in</strong> thelong run. In the short run, there is no significant evidence that <strong>in</strong>ternational prices affect theSAFEX yellow and white maize prices either <strong>in</strong>stantaneously or with some delay of one ortwo months. Price <strong>in</strong>formation flows from the <strong>in</strong>ternational market to both South <strong>African</strong>yellow and white maize prices, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that shocks <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>ternational market are passedthroughto South Africa <strong>in</strong> the long run.Both SAFEX prices adjust to their long run equilibrium with the <strong>in</strong>ternational price slowly,with full adjustment to <strong>in</strong>ternational price shocks or trend tak<strong>in</strong>g approximately between 7and 8 months. On balance, there is strong evidence that the South <strong>African</strong> maize markets are<strong>in</strong>tegrated with the <strong>in</strong>ternational market <strong>in</strong> the long run. The relatively slow adjustment toshocks, however, suggests that this relationship cannot be readily observed, as <strong>in</strong> the short runprices may be perceived as drift<strong>in</strong>g apart, <strong>in</strong> spite of shar<strong>in</strong>g the same underly<strong>in</strong>g long-runtrend.Kenya is an important producer and consumer of maize with a net import<strong>in</strong>g position dur<strong>in</strong>gthe period 1998-2008. South Africa and, to a lesser extent the US account for the larger shareof imports, while other <strong>African</strong> countries <strong>in</strong> the Eastern and Southern <strong>African</strong> regions, such asMalawi, and Uganda, also export maize to Kenya. Import tariffs, the NPBC price support andhigh transaction costs have comb<strong>in</strong>ed to result <strong>in</strong> high maize prices as compared to pricelevels of the <strong>in</strong>ternational market but also of other <strong>African</strong> maize consum<strong>in</strong>g countries.Table 8 exhibits the results of empirical analysis for Kenya. For all markets exam<strong>in</strong>ed, theanalysis provides strong evidence that prices co-move with the <strong>in</strong>ternational price <strong>in</strong> the longrun.In Eldoret and Kisumu, at the eastern part of the country, prices also are found to directlyco-move with the SAFEX white maize price. The tests provide moderate evidence for comovementbetween the market prices of both Nairobi and Mombasa and the South <strong>African</strong>white maize price. Nevertheless, strong evidence of co-movement with the <strong>in</strong>ternationalworld price ensures that prices <strong>in</strong> these markets should, <strong>in</strong> practice co-move with the South<strong>African</strong> prices, but probably at very slow rates of adjustment.


In the short-run from one month to another, Kenyan prices are not affected by shocks <strong>in</strong> eitherthe <strong>in</strong>ternational or the South <strong>African</strong> price. On average, Kenyan maize prices tend to adjustto their relationship with the <strong>in</strong>ternational market price relatively slow, <strong>in</strong> approximatelybetween 6 and 9 months. Adjustment to South <strong>African</strong> market prices is even slower forEldoret and Kisumu, <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the slow response of the South <strong>African</strong> markets to the<strong>in</strong>ternational prices, mentioned above. Prices <strong>in</strong> Kisumu, a border town, appear to adjust toboth <strong>in</strong>ternational and South <strong>African</strong> prices relatively faster than the prices <strong>in</strong> other markets.Kenyan maize markets appear to be well-<strong>in</strong>tegrated with each other. In addition, maize prices<strong>in</strong> Kisumu are also found to co-move with prices <strong>in</strong> Uganda, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>in</strong> the long-run,price signals pass-through from one country to the other.Malawi is an important producer of maize with a net import<strong>in</strong>g trade position for most of theperiod 1998-2008. South Africa is the ma<strong>in</strong> source of imports, however Malawi also importsfrom the US and other countries <strong>in</strong> the region, depend<strong>in</strong>g on the country’s market conditions.Tqable 9 reports the results of the empirical analysis for Malawi. There is strong evidence thatmost of the maize markets <strong>in</strong> Malawi are well-<strong>in</strong>tegrated with both the <strong>in</strong>ternational and theSouth <strong>African</strong> maize markets. With the exception of Mziba and Mch<strong>in</strong>ji, <strong>in</strong> many markets,maize prices were found to be <strong>in</strong> long-run equilibrium with the <strong>in</strong>ternational maize price andthe SAFEX white maize price. It takes approximately 4.7 to 6.6 months for full pricetransmission. On balance, the results <strong>in</strong>dicate that <strong>in</strong> the long-run prices <strong>in</strong> Malawi do followthe underly<strong>in</strong>g trend of both the <strong>in</strong>ternational and the South <strong>African</strong> prices.Short-run effects between maize prices <strong>in</strong> Zambia and the <strong>in</strong>ternational and SAFEX prices arefound to be <strong>in</strong>significant, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that the relationship between prices <strong>in</strong> Zambia and <strong>in</strong> the<strong>in</strong>ternational and the South <strong>African</strong> is determ<strong>in</strong>ed only by their long run equilibrium, while <strong>in</strong>the short-run prices may drift apart due to local market conditions. With the exception ofBangula, adjustment of prices <strong>in</strong> Zambia to the <strong>in</strong>ternational price is revealed to be slow. Onaverage, it takes a period of 4.7 to 7.7 months for the prices to fully adjust to a change <strong>in</strong> the<strong>in</strong>ternational price. Prices <strong>in</strong> Bangula, an area close to the border with Mozambique, adjust to<strong>in</strong>ternational prices with<strong>in</strong> 3.8 months.With<strong>in</strong> the country, prices of different markets, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g Mziba and Mch<strong>in</strong>ji, co-move witheach other, while <strong>in</strong> the short-run, price shocks <strong>in</strong> one part of the country do affect othermarkets, however not to a full extent. In general, adjustment takes place <strong>in</strong> approximately 5months, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that transport costs may h<strong>in</strong>der rapid price transmission with<strong>in</strong> thecountry.Zambia usually imports maize depend<strong>in</strong>g on the climatic conditions that determ<strong>in</strong>e the size ofthe harvest. South Africa consists of the ma<strong>in</strong> source of maize imports, while exports from thecountry are negligible. Table 10 exhibits the results of maize price transmission analysis forZambia. Prices <strong>in</strong> all markets co-move with the South <strong>African</strong> price of white maize. <strong>Markets</strong><strong>in</strong> Kabwe, Kasama and Ndola also appear to be well-<strong>in</strong>tegrated with the <strong>in</strong>ternational markethowever, there is moderate or weak evidence that prices <strong>in</strong> Lusaka, Chipata and Choma are <strong>in</strong>equilibrium with <strong>in</strong>ternational prices <strong>in</strong> a direct manner. Shocks <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational markets areexpected to slowly affect these domestic markets through their relationship with the SAFEXprice of white maize.In the short-run, both <strong>in</strong>ternational and South <strong>African</strong> maize prices were found not to affectmarket prices <strong>in</strong> Zambia, with the relationship between Zambian prices and <strong>in</strong>ternational orSAFEX prices be<strong>in</strong>g determ<strong>in</strong>ed only by their long-run equilibrium. Adjustment to thisequilibrium relationship is estimated to be, <strong>in</strong> general, slow. Prices of most Zambian marketsappear to adjust to their relationship with the South <strong>African</strong> prices <strong>in</strong> approximately 5 to 8months. Prices <strong>in</strong> Ndola are found to adjust to both <strong>in</strong>ternational and South <strong>African</strong> price


shocks quite rapidly <strong>in</strong> the course of 3 months, probably due to Ndola’s position on the borderwith Congo. With<strong>in</strong> the country, domestic markets are found to be well-<strong>in</strong>tegrated betweenthem, <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g that transport costs and other factors do not h<strong>in</strong>der the flow of <strong>in</strong>formationfrom one part of the country to another. The extent of <strong>in</strong>tegration between different markets <strong>in</strong>Zambia, suggests that price shocks <strong>in</strong> one market are expected to be smoothed out quiterapidly <strong>in</strong> approximately 2 months.The overall conclusion of this empirical analysis is that world prices for staple products aretransmitted only imperfectly with<strong>in</strong> <strong>African</strong> countries <strong>in</strong> the short term, albeit eventually theyare transmitted fully after some time. Hence the impact of any world commodity shocks arelikely to be felt with a lag.5. The impact of food price <strong>in</strong>creasesThe impact of the food price rise on households is diverse. Food price <strong>in</strong>creases generatebenefits for net food producers, but significantly worsen the welfare of net food consum<strong>in</strong>ghouseholds, present<strong>in</strong>g a significant threat for the poor. Households react differently to pricesw<strong>in</strong>gs depend<strong>in</strong>g on their ability to expand the production of food, their consumptionpatterns, their <strong>in</strong>itial asset endowment and the manner they diversify <strong>in</strong>come. The constra<strong>in</strong>ts,households face <strong>in</strong> terms of liquidity and access to markets are also important determ<strong>in</strong>ants oftheir behaviour.The net position of households <strong>in</strong> the market, that is whether households are net sellers or netbuyers of food, will, on average, determ<strong>in</strong>e the impact of price changes on <strong>in</strong>come, foodsecurity and poverty. While <strong>in</strong> general, urban households that are net staple food buyers willlose, as they have to pay more to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> adequate diets, rural households, especially thosethat are <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> the production of staple foods may benefit to a certa<strong>in</strong> extent. The shortrun impact of the food price boom on poverty is of particular concern especially <strong>in</strong> low<strong>in</strong>come develop<strong>in</strong>g countries. Undoubtedly, poor urban households constitute the mostvulnerable population group. Non poor urban dwellers will also be negatively affected as nonfarmwages may not be adjusted fast to the <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> the general price level, brought aboutby the food and energy price upsw<strong>in</strong>g.Although, poor rural households are, <strong>in</strong> general, engaged <strong>in</strong> the production of food, they mayalso be negatively affected, especially if their production does not meet their foodrequirements and additional food has to be purchased. Net food sell<strong>in</strong>g rural households willga<strong>in</strong>, however the size of the price w<strong>in</strong>dfall will depend on their ability to <strong>in</strong>crease supply andmarketed surplus. Landless rural households may also benefit, as <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g prices maystimulate supply and the demand for farm labour thus <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g wages and/or employment.The ability to adjust to the new market environment will also determ<strong>in</strong>e household welfareand the impact on poverty and food security. Substitution possibilities <strong>in</strong> consumption mayresult <strong>in</strong> offsett<strong>in</strong>g part of the negative shock, depend<strong>in</strong>g on the extent of staple fooddiversification and relative price changes.For rural households, the extent to which production can respond to <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g prices dependson a number of factors, such as access to markets for output and <strong>in</strong>puts, access to technologyand adequate capital. In develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, markets are often miss<strong>in</strong>g as poor <strong>in</strong>frastructuregives rise to high transaction costs, while access to credit and technology is limited. Farmersare characterized by small hold<strong>in</strong>gs, poor technology and lack of specialization <strong>in</strong> productionwhich h<strong>in</strong>der the response to higher prices. Access to <strong>in</strong>puts, such as fertilizers and seed isalso limited. Input market<strong>in</strong>g cha<strong>in</strong>s are not well developed as private sector participation isplagued due to the small size of markets and their geographical dispersion. These, <strong>in</strong>


conjunction with variable demand and high transaction costs, limit the economies of scale,necessary for the development of market<strong>in</strong>g cha<strong>in</strong>s.The demand for fertilizer is affected by cash constra<strong>in</strong>ts, uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and risk and, dur<strong>in</strong>g thepast two decades, by the persistent low profitability of food production <strong>in</strong> relation to cashcrops. These problems <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>put markets are aggravated by the recent rapid upsurge <strong>in</strong> the<strong>in</strong>ternational price of fertilizers. As fertilizer prices <strong>in</strong>creased faster than food prices,expectations on lower profitability have resulted <strong>in</strong> significant reduction <strong>in</strong> the use offertilizers, h<strong>in</strong>der<strong>in</strong>g supply response and affect<strong>in</strong>g the livelihood of smallholders.Susta<strong>in</strong>ed food price <strong>in</strong>creases will have a significant impact on the rate of poverty. Onaverage, a number of studies suggest that most of the poor are net consumers of food andtherefore, are adversely affected by the food price upsw<strong>in</strong>g (Poulton et al. 2006). Poor ruralhouseholds are often characterized by no or <strong>in</strong>significant marketed surplus. Small land assetsand limited access to <strong>in</strong>puts due to cash constra<strong>in</strong>ts, as well as limited access to outputmarkets due to distance and poor <strong>in</strong>frastructure contrive to the households be<strong>in</strong>gpredom<strong>in</strong>antly net buyers of food.A number of researchers have attempted to measure the implications of the food priceupsw<strong>in</strong>g for poverty <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g and less developed countries (Ivanic and Mart<strong>in</strong>, 2007;Polaski, 2008; Wodon et al. 2008; Wodon and Zaman, 2008). These analyses utilize severaldifferent methodologies and apply them to household survey data from a number ofdevelop<strong>in</strong>g countries. In general, the results suggest that, on average, food price <strong>in</strong>creases willresult <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>creased poverty. Across countries, <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> food prices will have very diverseeffects depend<strong>in</strong>g on the structure of the economy, the l<strong>in</strong>kages of agriculture with othersectors, the households’ net position towards food markets, as well as on the distribution ofhouseholds around the poverty threshold. Nevertheless, <strong>in</strong> most cases, <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> povertyoccur more frequently than reductions.Ivanic and Mart<strong>in</strong> (2008) estimate the impact of food price <strong>in</strong>creases on poverty on a numberof low <strong>in</strong>come countries, utiliz<strong>in</strong>g a Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model and ameasure of poverty def<strong>in</strong>ed by the standard 2007 World Bank World Development Indicators‘dollar-a-day’ expenditure. Although the direction and magnitude of the effect varies acrosscountries, on average, their f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs suggest that the overall impact of higher food prices onpoverty is negative for the majority of countries exam<strong>in</strong>ed. For example, high food prices areexpected to <strong>in</strong>crease poverty <strong>in</strong> Nicaragua, Zambia, Pakistan and Madagascar, while poverty<strong>in</strong> Peru and Vietnam may contract to some extent due to a significant number of householdswhich are net producers of rice. On the whole, apart from a few cases where food price<strong>in</strong>creases led to a reduction of poverty <strong>in</strong> rural areas, <strong>in</strong> most cases the number of poorhouseholds, <strong>in</strong> both urban and rural areas is expected to <strong>in</strong>crease.Wodon et al. (2008) analyze the impact of the food price upsw<strong>in</strong>g on a number of West andCentral <strong>African</strong> countries. Their results suggest that on average, a 50 percent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> theprice of selected food items will result <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the share of population <strong>in</strong> povertybetween 2.5 and 4.4 percent, as a large share of food is imported and the negative impact onfood consumers outweighs the positive effect on the net sellers of locally produced goods.Wodon and Zaman (2008) f<strong>in</strong>d that the impact of <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g food prices on sub-Saharan<strong>African</strong> countries is significant, with a 50 percent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the prices of selected foodsresult<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a 3.5 percent <strong>in</strong>crease the poverty headcount. This result implies that, at anaggregate level, for all sub-Saharan Africa, which has a population of 800 million, the foodprice upturn could have led to an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> poverty of approximately 30 million.


Another study by Polaski (2008) focused on the effect of food price changes <strong>in</strong> India, thecountry with the largest number of poor <strong>in</strong> the world, where over 80 percent of the populationlive on less than US$2 per day. The study sheds light to another dimension of the impact offood price upsw<strong>in</strong>gs on develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, by explor<strong>in</strong>g the l<strong>in</strong>ks between agriculturalprices and the sources of <strong>in</strong>come for both rural and urban poor. The analysis suggests thatlabour markets play a largely positive role <strong>in</strong> transmitt<strong>in</strong>g the price effects to the economy. Asimulation of a 50 percent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the price of rice utiliz<strong>in</strong>g a CGE model suggested thatfood price <strong>in</strong>creases would benefit most poor households and, especially those that identifywith vulnerable social groups and landless who supply their labour to the agricultural sector.The f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs suggest that the poorest households and the most disadvantaged groups couldexperience the largest ga<strong>in</strong>s, up to 6 percent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, while only the richest 10percent of rural households would lose from a price <strong>in</strong>crease. The reason is that food price<strong>in</strong>creases can lead to an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the demand for farm labour and <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong>come for ruralworkers, with illiterate workers and disadvantaged groups be<strong>in</strong>g potentially the largestga<strong>in</strong>ers. The f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs also suggest that the impact on urban households can be diverse, withsome poor households ga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g slightly and others los<strong>in</strong>g slightly. Illiterate urban workers andother vulnerable groups can experience <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>creases, while the results for other urbanworkers showed a mix of small ga<strong>in</strong>s and small losses with no consistent pattern.Additional research carried out under the direction of the authors, exam<strong>in</strong>ed the impact of an<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> food prices on consumption, household food expenditure and poverty <strong>in</strong> Malawi,Zambia and Uganda. The analysis was based on food demand system models that wereestimated utiliz<strong>in</strong>g past household survey data sets and sheds light to the importance of staplefood diversification <strong>in</strong> offsett<strong>in</strong>g the negative effects of food price <strong>in</strong>creases. 5 While everyeffort was made <strong>in</strong> order to analyse the most recent data, the choice of the data sets wasdeterm<strong>in</strong>ed by their richness <strong>in</strong> terms of <strong>in</strong>formation on variables, such as food prices, as wellas on <strong>in</strong>formation that would allow the determ<strong>in</strong>ation of total and agricultural <strong>in</strong>come. For thedemand analysis <strong>in</strong> Malawi and Zambia, we used the Integrated Liv<strong>in</strong>g StandardMeasurement Survey 2004 and the Liv<strong>in</strong>g Conditions Monitor<strong>in</strong>g Survey I 1996 respectively.For Uganda, we used the National Household Survey II 1996. A prelim<strong>in</strong>ary comparison ofthe consumption patterns reflected by these data sets and current national average per capitaconsumption data from FAOSTAT suggested that consumption patterns have not changedsignificantly dur<strong>in</strong>g the last decades, with the possible exception of wheat and cereals otherthan maize, for which consumption has <strong>in</strong>creased particularly by urban households.The household classes for each country are def<strong>in</strong>ed accord<strong>in</strong>g to four factors, namely, foodexpenditure, location, contribution of agricultural activities <strong>in</strong> total <strong>in</strong>come, land ownershipand gender. In more detail, households were classified <strong>in</strong>to food secure and food <strong>in</strong>secure byutilis<strong>in</strong>g thresholds set by the World Bank, and further divided accord<strong>in</strong>g to whether they arelocated <strong>in</strong> urban and rural areas. Food <strong>in</strong>secure rural households are also presented accord<strong>in</strong>gto land ownership, gender and the share of <strong>in</strong>come from all agricultural activities. Rural foodsecure households are divided only accord<strong>in</strong>g to the share of <strong>in</strong>come from all agriculturalactivities. This approach draws attention to the extent to which household characteristics, such5 The empirical work <strong>in</strong>volved the estimation of demand functions for several food items and aggregates, <strong>in</strong> adouble-log specification with quantities of an item consumed been the function of the price of this item, as wellas the prices of all other goods. The estimation was carried <strong>in</strong> two steps, <strong>in</strong> order to take <strong>in</strong>to account the<strong>in</strong>formation conta<strong>in</strong>ed by zero observations. As for a specific food item, only a subset of households consumedpositive quantities, the Heckman two-step estimator was used <strong>in</strong> order to correct for selection bias. The first step<strong>in</strong>volved the estimation of a probit model that was used to predict the probability of a household consum<strong>in</strong>g aparticular food item. In the second step, the demand equations were estimated, <strong>in</strong>corporat<strong>in</strong>g a transformation ofthe predicted <strong>in</strong>dividual probabilities as an additional explanatory variable.


as <strong>in</strong>come diversification and consumption preferences, result <strong>in</strong> more or less vulnerability tofood price spikes.We do not attempt to simulate an <strong>in</strong>crease on all food items due to the lack of specific<strong>in</strong>formation on prices of foods that are locally produced. Instead, we hypothesize a situationwhere only the prices of gra<strong>in</strong>s and meat, food commodities that are <strong>in</strong>ternationally traded,<strong>in</strong>crease by 50 and 20 percent respectively. However, anecdotal <strong>in</strong>formation suggests that theprices of locally produced foods also rose ma<strong>in</strong>ly due to the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> transport costs, aswell as the strengthen<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> demand as consumers substituted gra<strong>in</strong>s for other local staples.For these reasons, our results may not accurately estimate the impact on consumption of<strong>in</strong>creased food prices. A number of additional assumptions are made <strong>in</strong> order to provideestimates on changes <strong>in</strong> the level of poverty. First, we assume that households react to foodprice <strong>in</strong>creases only by decreas<strong>in</strong>g consumption of more expensive foods and substitut<strong>in</strong>g onefood for another. This overlooks that households can smooth consumption by utiliz<strong>in</strong>gsav<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> the form of near-liquid assets, or by <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g their supply of labour both <strong>in</strong>-, aswell as off-farm. Second, it is assumed that produc<strong>in</strong>g households do respond to the price riseby <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g supply. For this reason, our results perta<strong>in</strong> only to the short run.Tables 11 and 12 summarize the results for Zambia and Malawi. In general, our resultsprovide some <strong>in</strong>dication of the extent of the impact of food price <strong>in</strong>creases on poverty.Nevertheless, the value of this particular simulation lies more on the comparisons of theimpact across countries and the importance of <strong>in</strong>come and staple diet diversification. In bothMalawi and Zambia, maize is the most important staple.In Zambia and Malawi, the annual per capita consumption of maize amounts to an average of150 kg and 193 kg respectively. The food price upsw<strong>in</strong>g is expected to result <strong>in</strong> householdsrespond<strong>in</strong>g by reduc<strong>in</strong>g the consumption of foods of which prices <strong>in</strong>creased and exploit<strong>in</strong>gsubstitution possibilities accord<strong>in</strong>g to relative prices. For Zambia and Malawi, the simulationof a multiple price shock (50 percent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the prices of maize and other cereals and of20 percent <strong>in</strong> the price of meat) suggests that consumers reduce the consumption of maize andother cereals by 15.6 and 8.5 percent respectively. The consumption of other cereals, whichdo not constitute staple foods <strong>in</strong> this region, contracts by approximately 20 percent <strong>in</strong> bothcountries. The hypothetical <strong>in</strong>crease of 20 percent <strong>in</strong> the price of meat is expected to result <strong>in</strong>a 16.6 percent reduction <strong>in</strong> its consumption, as the demand of meat is characterized by arelatively high own-price elasticity. On average, poor and food <strong>in</strong>secure households reducethe consumption of maize, the ma<strong>in</strong> staple food, to a lesser extent as compared with non poorand food secure consumers. Evidently, the consumption of other foods <strong>in</strong>creases, with theextent of the changes been determ<strong>in</strong>ed by the estimated cross-price elasticities.In both Malawi and Zambia, the decrease <strong>in</strong> the consumption of maize and other cereals doesnot offset the impact on the price rise on food expenditure. On average, total food expenditure<strong>in</strong> Zambia rises by 8 percent and <strong>in</strong> Malawi by 9.7 percent. For Zambian poor households,food price rises result <strong>in</strong> total food expenditure <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g by 8.6 percent. In Malawi, wheremaize consists of a high share, approximately 40 percent, of total food expenditure, total foodexpenditure <strong>in</strong>creases by 16 percent <strong>in</strong> spite of the contraction <strong>in</strong> consumption.High food prices and the correspond<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> food expenditure result <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> therate of poverty, as households experience a decrease <strong>in</strong> their purchas<strong>in</strong>g power. In Zambia,food prices rises result <strong>in</strong> a 5.4 percent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the number of food <strong>in</strong>secure. Thecorrespond<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the number of food <strong>in</strong>secure <strong>in</strong> Malawi is significantly larger andamounts to nearly 16 percent. Although the majority of producers <strong>in</strong> these countries are netfood buyers, these results reflect the maximum impact of food price <strong>in</strong>creases, as the possible


positive effect on production, or the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the value of food stocks held by the householdare not taken under consideration.The household classifications also reveal the extent to vulnerable population groups, such asthe landless and households headed by women, are affected by the food price upsw<strong>in</strong>g.Nevertheless, such a simulation exercise does not reveal the overall impact of higher foodprices. This becomes more significant if the decrease <strong>in</strong> the well-be<strong>in</strong>g of the already poorhouseholds is considered. Although the above analyses highlight clearly that many non poorhouseholds face <strong>in</strong>creased food expenditure and fall below the poverty threshold, the foodprice upsw<strong>in</strong>g has a significant negative impact on households that are already poor and food<strong>in</strong>secure and deepens poverty.Comparisons of the impact of the food price <strong>in</strong>crease across countries highlight theimportance of staple diet diversification <strong>in</strong> ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g food security dur<strong>in</strong>g food priceepisodes. We assess the role of diet diversification <strong>in</strong> offset<strong>in</strong>g part of the high food priceimpact by conduct<strong>in</strong>g a separate simulation of a 50 percent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the price of maize <strong>in</strong>Zambia, Malawi and Uganda (Table 13).In Uganda, maize consumption amounts to an average of 29 kg per capita, a quantitysignificantly lower than that consumed <strong>in</strong> both Malawi and Zambia. Maize’s share <strong>in</strong> totalfood expenditure amounts to about 8 percent. In addition to maize, Ugandan householdsconsume a variety of staple foods, such as rice, millet, matooke and cassava. Both matookeand cassava are important staples, which are produced domestically and consist to about 20percent of total household food expenditure. Although prices of rice and millet also rose, theprices of matooke and cassava, foods that are not <strong>in</strong>ternationally traded, exhibited weaker<strong>in</strong>creases of about 35 and 20 percent respectively, as compared to an <strong>in</strong>crease of 75 percent <strong>in</strong>the price of maize (Benson, Mugarura and Wanda, 2008).The simulation results suggest that as maize prices <strong>in</strong>crease, its consumption decreasessharply by approximately 30 percent. Both food secure and <strong>in</strong>secure households exhibitsimilar response to the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the price. Total food expenditure rises by a very smallproportion, lead<strong>in</strong>g to less than one percent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the number of food <strong>in</strong>securehouseholds <strong>in</strong> Uganda, as compared to an <strong>in</strong>crease of 13 percent <strong>in</strong> Malawi.An additional simulation of a wider <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> food prices <strong>in</strong> Uganda, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong>the prices of other cereals and matooke by 20 percent, results <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>crease of 2.5 percent <strong>in</strong>the number of poor households. These f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs suggest that the range of domesticallyproduced staples <strong>in</strong> conjunction with the relatively large quantities consumed moderate thenegative impact of the <strong>in</strong>ternational price boom on Ugandan households.The above simulation results are partial equilibrium <strong>in</strong> the sense that both a small number ofprice <strong>in</strong>creases are considered, and also as the full adjustment with<strong>in</strong> the economy is notconsidered. There is little such analysis of commodity price booms. Tables 14 and 15 presentsome results from a paper done by Conforti and Sarris <strong>in</strong> 2008. Their analysis first showedthat the commodity price changes fac<strong>in</strong>g a country like Tanzania amounted to a 6 percent ofGDP negative shock to the economy. The reason for this is that while the agricultural pricerises implied a positive shock, the large petroleum crises imlied an even larger negative priceshock, as Tanzania relies very much on petroleum imports. A CGE model of Tanzania tried totrace these effects through the economy and the households. The results suggest a largenegative impact on GDP and all types of households as <strong>in</strong>dicated <strong>in</strong> the two tables. Clearlythen a positive food price shock does not necessarily imply a positive shock for the economyas a whole, as it may be accompanied by other simultaneous negative shocks.


7 Conclusions and policy implicationsThe above exposition <strong>in</strong>dicated that <strong>African</strong> countries are <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly exposed to<strong>in</strong>ternational staple food commodity markets, while not becom<strong>in</strong>g more productive <strong>in</strong> theproduction of these staples domestically. While this <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>stability does not appearto be grow<strong>in</strong>g over time, it has not dim<strong>in</strong>ished, and given the grow<strong>in</strong>g exposure, presents aloom<strong>in</strong>g challenge to <strong>African</strong> economies. The result is a situation where many of the poorer<strong>African</strong> countries f<strong>in</strong>d themselves <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly vulnerable to the vagaries of the <strong>in</strong>ternationalmarkets. Asian economies that have found themselves <strong>in</strong> similar situations have chosen toisolate their domestic markets, <strong>in</strong> order to provide stable domestic markets for food staples. InAfrica several countries used to have similar policies but these have been abandoned <strong>in</strong> favourof more open and liberal trade regimes, and domestically by the private sector supplant<strong>in</strong>gmost of the former government food parastatals. This development has created a situationwhereby more <strong>in</strong>ternational price variability is transmitted domestically, albeit as was seenearlier quite imperfectly.Food market <strong>in</strong>stability is not uncommon for most <strong>African</strong> households, as the domestic staplecommodity markets normally experience sharp price differences between different periodswith<strong>in</strong> a market<strong>in</strong>g year, and also from year to year. In fact, given the low and slow degrees of<strong>in</strong>ternational market transmission, and the significant domestic climate <strong>in</strong>duced foodproduction shocks, most <strong>African</strong> households experience higher degrees of food price<strong>in</strong>stability than what is evident <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternational markets. For <strong>in</strong>stance Deaton and Laroque(1992) report annual coefficients of variation (CVs) of annual <strong>in</strong>ternational prices of cotton,maize, rice sugar and wheat, computed over 1900-1987 <strong>in</strong> the range of 0.35 to 0.6. Bycomparison Sarris and Karfakis (2008) report domestic CVs of monthly prices of variousagricultural products <strong>in</strong> two regions of Tanzania over a twenty year period (1983-2002) <strong>in</strong> therange of 0.26 to 0.81. To deal with such <strong>in</strong>stability, households <strong>in</strong> Africa have alreadydeveloped a variety of consumption smooth<strong>in</strong>g and other cop<strong>in</strong>g mechanisms. However, suchmechanisms, while effective for small and short lived negative price shocks, may not beadequate for shocks that last longer or are sharper than normal. Such shocks can createirreversible situations, where households are drawn <strong>in</strong>to deeper or more permanent poverty, orassets are depleted to po<strong>in</strong>ts that affect considerably the subsequent growth of household<strong>in</strong>comes.It is <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> this context to contemplate policies to deal with the recurr<strong>in</strong>g external and<strong>in</strong>ternal food market shocks. Policies that aim to manage food price sw<strong>in</strong>gs can be classifiedaccord<strong>in</strong>g to where government chooses to <strong>in</strong>tervene <strong>in</strong> the food supply cha<strong>in</strong>. There are traderelated policies that are implemented at the border and tax reductions that aim to lessen theimpact of high prices at the wholesale or the retail l<strong>in</strong>k of the cha<strong>in</strong>. Domestic market<strong>in</strong>terventions through the management of food <strong>in</strong>ventories also target the wholesale level. Thekey dist<strong>in</strong>guish<strong>in</strong>g feature of most of these policies is that they alter the state of the market,most notably the prices of food and <strong>in</strong>puts, thus affect<strong>in</strong>g all households both poor and nonpoor. The policy choices of the government focus on mitigat<strong>in</strong>g the impact of <strong>in</strong>ternationalprice shocks, thus lett<strong>in</strong>g producers and consumers to adjust to a price different than thatprevail<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>ternational markets. Food safety nets, commonly implemented <strong>in</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, as well as targeted <strong>in</strong>put subsidies aim directly at consumers andproducers respectively. These policies do not directly affect market prices at the nationallevel, as they <strong>in</strong>volve transfers to specific vulnerable population groups and they will not beconsidered here, as we shall concentrate on market policies.Trade policies consist of restrictions on food imports or exports through taxation, quotas orbans and result <strong>in</strong> a change <strong>in</strong> the relative prices of traded goods <strong>in</strong> the economy. These


policies affect all households with the impact be<strong>in</strong>g determ<strong>in</strong>ed by the households’consumption patterns, <strong>in</strong>come level and diversification. Consequently, trade policies havealso distributional implications and un<strong>in</strong>tended effects <strong>in</strong> contrast to, for example, targetedmicro-level policies. Policy <strong>in</strong>struments, such as import tariffs can easily be scaled up ordown <strong>in</strong> order to manage the price sw<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a counter-cyclical manner. For food import<strong>in</strong>gcountries, the temporary reduction <strong>in</strong> tariffs may result <strong>in</strong> offsett<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>ternationalprices, while tariffs can return to their former level when <strong>in</strong>ternational prices fall.In the context of the food price upsw<strong>in</strong>g, both import tariffs reductions, as well as exportrestrictions have been applied by many countries <strong>in</strong> Africa. In general, the reduction or theelim<strong>in</strong>ation of import tariffs on food products has been the most widespread policy responsefor net food import<strong>in</strong>g countries. As world prices <strong>in</strong>creased, many countries lowered appliedtariffs <strong>in</strong>itially, eventually elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g them <strong>in</strong> an attempt to stabilize the domestic food pricelevel. The effectiveness of such tariff reductions is determ<strong>in</strong>ed by the level of <strong>in</strong>itial appliedtariffs, which for most <strong>African</strong> countries is rather small. For example, for a sample of 60 low<strong>in</strong>come food deficit countries (LIFDCs) surveyed <strong>in</strong> 2008 by FAO, applied tariffs on cerealsand key vegetable oils were already fairly low <strong>in</strong> 2006 <strong>in</strong> the range of 8 and 14 percentrespectively. Tariffs were much lower than these averages for a majority of these LIFDCssuggest<strong>in</strong>g that these applied rates, when reduced to zero, were adequate for offsett<strong>in</strong>g only asmall part of the overall rise <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>ternational prices which were higher by at least 50percent <strong>in</strong> 2008 as compared to the 2006 level. Other policies that aim to reduce the cost offood imports <strong>in</strong>clude tax breaks for importers <strong>in</strong> terms of VAT reduction on selected imported<strong>in</strong>termediate of f<strong>in</strong>al food goods.Many develop<strong>in</strong>g countries have implemented some form of export restrictions <strong>in</strong> an attemptto ensure domestic food security. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the WTO rules for export, taxes are allowedwhile export bans are prohibited. Export taxation results <strong>in</strong> the w<strong>in</strong>dfall been allocated to thepublic sector, where the public sector often has poor forward l<strong>in</strong>kages through <strong>in</strong>vestment.Although, export restrictions lower domestic prices and thus support consumers, at the sametime they imply a tax to producers, lower<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>centive to respond to the <strong>in</strong>ternational price<strong>in</strong>crease. In the long run, export restrictions may discourage <strong>in</strong>vestment on agriculture <strong>in</strong>export<strong>in</strong>g countries, hav<strong>in</strong>g negative implications for food security. In the short run, concertedimplementation of export restrictions by important exporters renders the <strong>in</strong>ternational marketunreliable as a source of food and exacerbates <strong>in</strong>ternational price <strong>in</strong>stability harm<strong>in</strong>gconsumers <strong>in</strong> other countries and lead<strong>in</strong>g towards import-substitution and <strong>in</strong>efficientallocation of resources.Many countries <strong>in</strong>itiated cuts <strong>in</strong> taxes <strong>in</strong> a number of food products. Such reductions offsetpart of the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> food prices and provide some relief to poorer consumers who spent alarge share of their <strong>in</strong>come on food. In addition to tariffs, taxes can also be used <strong>in</strong> order tomanage the price sw<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> a counter-cyclical manner. In develop<strong>in</strong>g countries where a VATsystem is <strong>in</strong> place, governments consider apply<strong>in</strong>g different VAT rates to food items. Such taxrelated policies are effective <strong>in</strong> lower<strong>in</strong>g food prices only if the food retail sector iscompetitive. Oligopolistic retailers may exercise their power over the market and <strong>in</strong>creasetheir price marg<strong>in</strong>s, thus h<strong>in</strong>der<strong>in</strong>g the pass<strong>in</strong>g-through of tax reduction to the consumers.Therefore, it is important that a competition authority is present for monitor<strong>in</strong>g retail foodprices and for regulat<strong>in</strong>g and enforc<strong>in</strong>g competition and consumer protection laws. Although,as <strong>in</strong> the case of import tariff reductions, tax reductions will benefit both poor and non-poorconsumer, a degree of target<strong>in</strong>g could be achieved if taxes are reduced selectively on foodsthat are consumed primarily by poor households, such as broken gra<strong>in</strong> cereals. F<strong>in</strong>ally, thereduction <strong>in</strong> taxes will br<strong>in</strong>g about a reduction <strong>in</strong> government revenue that may exacerbate theimpact of the price boom on budget deficit, especially for food import<strong>in</strong>g countries.


Therefore, governments ought to consider carefully the composition of revenue, <strong>in</strong> relation tothe support tax reductions may provide. Several of these trade and tax policies were exam<strong>in</strong>edby Conforti and Sarris (2008) <strong>in</strong> a CGE context. It was shown that they are very <strong>in</strong>effective atmoderat<strong>in</strong>g or revers<strong>in</strong>g the overall impact of foreign price shocks.Market management policies <strong>in</strong>clude measures such as open market operations throughimportation of food <strong>in</strong>to public stocks managed by national market<strong>in</strong>g boards and progressiverelease of food kept <strong>in</strong> reserve with a view to reduc<strong>in</strong>g market prices. Manag<strong>in</strong>g the marketcan also be realized by price controls through adm<strong>in</strong>istrative orders, anti-hoard<strong>in</strong>g measuressuch as restrictions on stockhold<strong>in</strong>g by private traders, as well as restrictions on <strong>in</strong>ter-regionalmovement of foods. Such policies aim to directly manage domestic markets <strong>in</strong> order to ensurefood supplies at pre-determ<strong>in</strong>ed prices.Prior to the 1990s decade, the presence of national market<strong>in</strong>g boards which controlleddomestic prices by manag<strong>in</strong>g public food stocks and coord<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g open market operations <strong>in</strong>both food and <strong>in</strong>put markets was a central characteristic of many <strong>African</strong> countries’ policiestowards agricultural development and self sufficiency. Such open market operations <strong>in</strong>volvedeither direct or <strong>in</strong>direct subsidies, as <strong>in</strong> many cases, food producer prices were guaranteedabove export parity, while governments subsidized consumer prices by releas<strong>in</strong>g foodquantities at low price levels. Most of these practices have been discont<strong>in</strong>ued ma<strong>in</strong>ly due totheir high costs, as well as for not be<strong>in</strong>g market-friendly and conducive to private sectordevelopment. For example, pan-territorial pric<strong>in</strong>g of gra<strong>in</strong>s although <strong>in</strong>creased the share ofproduce delivered by smallholders to the market<strong>in</strong>g boards resulted <strong>in</strong> significantly <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gthe costs of policy, as operations were characterized by high transaction costs. Additionalfiscal demands accrued by food stock-pil<strong>in</strong>g costs, as well as by production variability and thecorrespond<strong>in</strong>g decl<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g volumes of food purchased by market<strong>in</strong>g boards.Inventory management and open market operations through state controlled boards mayfunction well <strong>in</strong> secur<strong>in</strong>g the availability of cheaper food for consumers, while provid<strong>in</strong>gstrong <strong>in</strong>centives to producers. Nevertheless, the costs of state market<strong>in</strong>g operations aresignificant. Past experience suggests that state market<strong>in</strong>g channels <strong>in</strong>curred large operationallosses which were covered by governments or aid donors. Given the significantly high costsassociated with open market operations and the un<strong>in</strong>tended effects, develop<strong>in</strong>g countries,s<strong>in</strong>ce the 1990s, tend to rely more on trade for price stabilization and less on stock operations.Nevertheless, when governments perceive that the <strong>in</strong>ternational market may not be a reliablesource for food at short notice, stockhold<strong>in</strong>g and open market operations are still carried out.State market<strong>in</strong>g board operations have cont<strong>in</strong>ued to play a major role <strong>in</strong> many countries andespecially <strong>in</strong> Eastern and Southern Africa. With<strong>in</strong> the context of susta<strong>in</strong>ed price <strong>in</strong>creases,such policies may be effective <strong>in</strong> lower<strong>in</strong>g consumer prices through domestic purchases orimports at market price level and the subsequent release of stocks at lower prices <strong>in</strong> order toensure the availability of cheaper food. However, such practices are expected to be effective<strong>in</strong> the very short run only, as operat<strong>in</strong>g costs escalate <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> the<strong>in</strong>ternational market prices render<strong>in</strong>g such policy options fiscally unsusta<strong>in</strong>able. In addition totheir high f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g requirements, state market<strong>in</strong>g operations can also result <strong>in</strong> discourag<strong>in</strong>gthe development of the private sector <strong>in</strong> food market management, as well as extrapolat<strong>in</strong>gprice <strong>in</strong>creases, as producers often react to price rises by hoard<strong>in</strong>g.The experience of the food price upsw<strong>in</strong>g provides an opportunity for food import<strong>in</strong>gcountries to reassess the relative reliance on trade and stocks, tak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to account the role ofthe private sector. Jayne, Zulu and Nijhoff (2006) propose that effective coord<strong>in</strong>ation betweenthe public and the private sector would require greater consultation, as well as transparencywith regard to the governments’ <strong>in</strong>tentions about market operations. Given the political nature


of issues that surround food availability and food security <strong>in</strong> some countries, it is unlikely thatgovernments will be will<strong>in</strong>g to reform food markets and cease <strong>in</strong>terven<strong>in</strong>g. In this case, it iscritical that the government and the private sector follow an <strong>in</strong>tegrated approach to marketoperations. A set of clearly def<strong>in</strong>ed and transparent rules, such as price thresholds, fortrigger<strong>in</strong>g government <strong>in</strong>tervention are necessary, as well as the provision of credible<strong>in</strong>formation on export and import decisions, the quantities <strong>in</strong>tended to be purchased <strong>in</strong>, andsold by the government agencies, as well as the respective prices. For example the adoption ofprice band rules, with floor and ceil<strong>in</strong>g prices, outside which government <strong>in</strong>tervention can betriggered may allow efficient private trad<strong>in</strong>g, provid<strong>in</strong>g the appropriate <strong>in</strong>centives for storageand improve market <strong>in</strong>formation. Policy makers may also consider the possibility ofma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g small strategic food reserves, <strong>in</strong>stead of manag<strong>in</strong>g the market through larger<strong>in</strong>ventories should also be explored. Comb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g small-scale open market operations, such asthe release of subsidized food, with social safety nets, effectively targets vulnerablepopulation groups without distort<strong>in</strong>g the market.It is important to note that, with<strong>in</strong> the context of price upsw<strong>in</strong>gs, open market operations canresult <strong>in</strong> lower<strong>in</strong>g the price of food at very high costs and hence the policy may be effectiveonly <strong>in</strong> the short run. In addition, the decisions made by market<strong>in</strong>g boards to import food mayhave negative implications on the private food market<strong>in</strong>g sector, if prior consultations withprivate traders have not taken place.There is no bluepr<strong>in</strong>t approach to manag<strong>in</strong>g food price episodes and policy choice needs toaddress the possible limited access to food or <strong>in</strong>puts, or lack of food availability. Trade andtax measures are the easiest to implement. Nevertheless, given the low level of applied tariffs<strong>in</strong> most develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, they may not be effective <strong>in</strong> stabiliz<strong>in</strong>g domestic prices. Microlevel<strong>in</strong>terventions are likely to need complementary measures at other levels. For example,food price <strong>in</strong>creases alleviated by micro-level <strong>in</strong>terventions can lead to rapid <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong>budgetary expenditures which may need to be offset by <strong>in</strong>creased government borrow<strong>in</strong>g.Nevertheless, if such safety net mechanisms are <strong>in</strong> place, they can be scaled up to effectivelysupport those <strong>in</strong> need. Most micro-level <strong>in</strong>terventions can be designed as universal or targetedprograms. Although, universal food or <strong>in</strong>put subsidies are characterized by high budgetarycosts and non-exclusion of the non vulnerable, targeted programs can be adm<strong>in</strong>istrativelyexpensive and that <strong>in</strong> many cases, the costs may exceed the benefits of target<strong>in</strong>g.


REFERENCES.Abbott, P.C., Hurt, C., Tyner, W.E., (2008). What’s driv<strong>in</strong>g food prices? Issue Report. FarmFoundation. Available at HTTP://WWW.FARMFOUNDATION.ORG/BALCOMBE, K. AND RAPSOMANIKIS, G., (2008). Bayesian estimation and selection ofnonl<strong>in</strong>ear vector error correction models: the case of the sugar-ethanol-oil nexus <strong>in</strong> Brazil,American Journal of <strong>Agricultural</strong> Economics 90(3):658-668.Benson, T., Mugarura, S. & Wanda, K. (2008). “Impacts <strong>in</strong> Uganda of ris<strong>in</strong>g global foodprices: the role of diversified staples and limited price transmission”. <strong>Agricultural</strong> Economics,39: 513–524.Carter Michael (1997), “Environment, technology and the social articulation of risks <strong>in</strong> WestAfrica agriculture” Economic Development and Cultural Change: 45 (3),CASHIN, P., AND MCDERMOTT, C.J. (2006), “PROPERTIES OF INTERNATIONAL COMMODITYPRICES: IDENTIFYING TRENDS, CYCLES AND SHOCKS”, IN A. SARRIS AND D. HALLAM (EDITORS).AGRICULTURAL COMMODITY MARKETS AND TRADE. CHELTENHAM UK, ELGARCBC, (2008). Is Food <strong>Commodity</strong> Securitization Worsen<strong>in</strong>g the World’s Food Problem?Policy Brief, Conference board of Canada, Available atHTTP://WWW.CONFERENCEBOARD.CA/DOCUMENTS.ASP?RNEXT=2662Christiaensen, L. Hoffmann, V., and Sarris A. (2007) “Gaug<strong>in</strong>g the Effect of Shocks onWelfare and Poverty among Tanzanian Households”, World Bank, Africa Region, PolicyResearch Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper No 4406, November.COLLIER, P. AND GODERIS, B. (2007) “ COMMODITY PRICES, GROWTH, AND THE NATURALRESOURCE CURSE: RECONCILING A CONUNDRUM”, CSAE, OXFORD.Collier, P. and Dehn, J., (2001). “Aid, shocks and growth”, World Bank, Policy ResearchWork<strong>in</strong>g Paper No 2688.Conforti, P. and Sarris, A. (2008) “Policy response to a commodity price boom understructural constra<strong>in</strong>ts. The case of Tanzania” paper presented at the 11 th annual GTAPConference on Global Economic Analysis, held <strong>in</strong> Hels<strong>in</strong>ki June 12-14, 2008.Christiaensen, L. & Demery, L. (2007). Down to earth: agriculture and poverty reduction <strong>in</strong>Africa. Directions <strong>in</strong> Development, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DC, The World Bank.Deaton, A., and Laroque, G. (1992), “On the behaviour of commodity prices”, Review ofEconomic Studies 59: 1-23.Dercon S. (1996), “Risks, crop choice and sav<strong>in</strong>gs: Evidence from Tanzania”, EconomicDevelopment and Cultural Change 44(3): 485-513Frankel, J. (2008).” The Effect of MonetaryPolicy on Real <strong>Commodity</strong> Prices, <strong>in</strong> J. Campbell (editor), Asset Prices and Monetary Policy,University of Chicago Press.FAO. State of World Food Insecurity 2008. RomeGilbert, C. L., (2009). “<strong>Commodity</strong> Speculation and <strong>Commodity</strong> Investment”. Unpublishedpaper, forthcom<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Journal of <strong>Commodity</strong> <strong>Markets</strong> and Risk Management.Guillaumont, P. and Chauvet, L. (2001) “Aid and Performance: A reassessment”, Journal ofDevelopment Studies, August.Guillaumont, P. and Korachais, C. (2006) “Macroeconomic <strong>in</strong>stability makes growth less propoor<strong>in</strong> Africa and elseqhere: A prelim<strong>in</strong>ary <strong>in</strong>vestigation”, C<strong>ERD</strong>I Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper No. 38.


Ivanic, M. & Mart<strong>in</strong>, W.(200). Implications of higher global food prices for poverty <strong>in</strong> low<strong>in</strong>comecountries. Policy Research Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper No. 4594, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DC, The WorldBank.Jayne,T.S., Chapoto,A., and Govereh. J. (2007) “Gra<strong>in</strong> market<strong>in</strong>g policy at the crossroads:Challenges for Eastern and Southern Africa”, Paper prepared for the FAO workshop on “StapleFood Trade and Market Policy Options for Promot<strong>in</strong>g Development <strong>in</strong> Eastern and Southern Africa”,FAO, Rome, Italy, March 1-2, 2007Jayne, T., Zulu, B. & Nijhoff, J.J. 2006. Stabiliz<strong>in</strong>g food markets <strong>in</strong> eastern and southernAfrica. Food Policy, 31: 328–341Larson D. and F. Plessman (2002), “Do farmers choose to be <strong>in</strong>efficient? Evidence fromBicol Philipp<strong>in</strong>es”, Policy Research Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper Number 2787, The World Bank,Wash<strong>in</strong>gton D.C,Lipsky, J.P. (2008). <strong>Commodity</strong> prices and global <strong>in</strong>flation. Council on Foreign Relations,New York City, May 8.Mitchell, D., 2008. “A Note on Ris<strong>in</strong>g Food Prices”. Policy Research Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper No.4682. The World Bank, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DC.Morduch J. (2002), “Consumption smooth<strong>in</strong>g across space: Test<strong>in</strong>g theories of risk shar<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>the ICRISAT study region of South India” WIDER discussion paper 2002/55/United NationsUniversity. World Institute for Development Economics Research, Hels<strong>in</strong>ki,OECD-FAO, (2008). <strong>Agricultural</strong> Outlook 2008-2017. Paris and Rome.Polaski, S. (2008). Food prices, poverty, and small-scale farmers: gett<strong>in</strong>g the global traderegime right. Paper presented at FAO Experts’ Meet<strong>in</strong>g on Policies for the EffectiveManagement of Susta<strong>in</strong>ed Food Price Increases, Trade and <strong>Markets</strong> Division, Rome, 10–11July 2008.Poulton, C., Kydd, J., Wigg<strong>in</strong>s, S. and Doward, A. (2006). State <strong>in</strong>terventions for food pricestabilization <strong>in</strong> Africa: Can it work? Food Policy, 31: 342–356.Sarris, A. and Karfakis, P. (2008) “Household vulnerability <strong>in</strong> rural Tanzania” unpublishedpaper, FAO.Samuelson, P.A., (1957). Intertemporal Price Equilibrium: A Prologue to the Theory ofSpeculation, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 79, 181-219; repr<strong>in</strong>ted <strong>in</strong> P.A. Samuelson,Collected Scientific Papers (ed. J.E. Stiglitz)Schmidhuber, J. (2006). ‘Impact of an <strong>in</strong>creased biomass demand use on agricultural markets,prices, and food security: A longer-term perspective’. International Symposium of NotreEurope, Paris. Available at HTTP://WWW.FAO.ORG/ES/ESD/BIOMASSNOTREEUROPE.PDFWodon, Q. & Zaman, H. (2008). Ris<strong>in</strong>g food prices <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan Africa: poverty impactand policy responses. Policy Research Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper No. 4738, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DC, The WorldBank.Wodon, Q., Tsimpo, C., Back<strong>in</strong>y-Yetna, P., Joseph, G., Adoho, F. and Coulombe, H. (2008).Potential impact of higher food prices on poverty. Policy Research Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper No. 4745,Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DC, The World Bank.


Table 1. Africa and dependence on agricultureShare of <strong>Agriculture</strong> <strong>in</strong> GDP1969-71 1979-81 1989-91 2002-04North Africa 19.1 14.7 16.0 13.6Sub-Saharan Africa: LDC 40.2 40.4 37.5 38.8Sub-Saharan Africa: Other 30.6 27.6 27.1 26.6Africa 31.9 29.6 28.7 28.4Share of economically active population <strong>in</strong> agriculture <strong>in</strong> totaleconomically active population1969-71 1979-81 1989-91 2002-04North Africa 0.54 0.43 0.30 0.23Sub-Saharan Africa: LDC 0.83 0.79 0.76 0.71Sub-Saharan Africa: Other 0.68 0.60 0.49 0.41Africa 0.76 0.70 0.63 0.57Source. Authors’calculations from FAO dataTable 2. Africa and agricultural exportsShare of agricultural exports <strong>in</strong> total exports of goods and services1969-71 1979-81 1989-91 2002-04North Africa 24.5 7.3 4.2 3.7Sub-Saharan Africa: LDC 65.5 43.4 38.6 32.4Sub-Saharan Africa: Other 37.4 25.5 20.7 23.5Africa 46.8 29.6 25.1 23.4Share of agricultural exports <strong>in</strong> total merchandise exports1969-71 1979-81 1989-91 2002-04North Africa 33.4 11.8 8.3 6.0Sub-Saharan Africa: LDC 65.6 54.4 46.0 32.5Sub-Saharan Africa: Other 52.1 34.2 26.2 19.3Africa 58.8 44.7 36.9 26.3Source. Authors’calculations from FAO data


Table 3. Developments <strong>in</strong> <strong>African</strong> agricultural import dependence 1970-2004Share of agricultural imports <strong>in</strong> total imports of goods andservices1969-711979-811989-912002-04North Africa 20.4 4.8 3.5 3.4Sub-Saharan Africa: LDC 38.4 22.2 19.6 15.1Sub-Saharan Africa: Other 33.5 20.9 21.4 15.9Africa 33.3 18.5 17.3 13.2Share of agricultural imports <strong>in</strong> total merchandise imports1969-711979-811989-912002-04North Africa 23.9 24.2 23.0 17.5Sub-Saharan Africa: LDC 21.5 22.2 25.9 27.3Sub-Saharan Africa: Other 17.4 14.8 14.2 18.1Africa 20.6 20.3 22.4 23.7Share of food imports <strong>in</strong> total exports of goods and services1969-711979-811989-912002-04North Africa 14.4 18.3 13.2 9.9Sub-Saharan Africa: LDC 37.6 28.2 30.2 34.9Sub-Saharan Africa: Other 14.1 8.7 6.8 11.1Africa 24.1 18.8 17.9 20.9Source. Authors’calculations from FAO data


Table 4. <strong>African</strong> commodity dependenceS hare of 4 m ost im portantcom m odities <strong>in</strong> agriculturalexportsS hare of 4 m ost im portantcom m odities <strong>in</strong>m erchandise exports1982/84 1992/94 2002/04 1982/84 1992/94 2002/04An gola 91.4 100.0 53.8 4.6 0.1 0.0B urundi 94.8 88.5 93.7 91.5 78.4 67.1C ape V erde 0.0 2.2 85.5 0.0 0.2 2.0C ent Afr Rep 81.8 94.8 92.8 46.7 25.1 12.0C had 98.6 93.5 95.5 na 66.2 46.6C om oros 97.7 99.5 99.9 81.7 75.4 naB en<strong>in</strong> 39.9 93.4 85.6 21.3 25.9 37.4E quatorial G u<strong>in</strong>ea 100.0 100.0 100.0 97.0 6.4 0.2D jibouti 64.3 65.7 86.5 29.7 13.3 16.0G am bia 99.5 77.8 88.9 60.2 29.5 naG u<strong>in</strong>ea 80.2 83.0 54.3 4.6 6.2 2.7Lesotho 55.7 79.5 87.5 32.9 7.9 1.2Liberia 97.3 97.4 99.2 23.4 4.5 37.1M adagascar 83.6 69.5 83.7 70.5 31.7 24.3M alaw i 87.5 92.0 87.8 83.8 81.9 78.4M ali 91.7 95.2 92.7 na 63.9 31.5M ozam bique 62.0 75.5 62.6 30.9 25.0 7.7E thiopia 80.8 78.7 73.9 73.6 72.8 56.1E ritrea 0.0 43.2 83.0 na 4.1 2.2N iger 50.2 52.8 48.3 11.7 7.7 10.6G u<strong>in</strong>ea-B isau 50.7 97.6 99.5 34.3 70.9 82.3R w anda 95.1 90.8 92.3 58.7 64.7 48.0S ao Tom e andP r<strong>in</strong>cipe 98.3 99.9 97.7 na 72.2 80.7S enegal 84.0 78.4 54.2 23.9 12.5 7.0S ierra Leone 84.5 66.2 84.8 22.9 6.7 12.6S udan 70.9 65.8 73.0 65.0 70.0 13.2Tanzania 70.4 74.9 47.7 60.8 51.3 17.0Togo 91.0 79.0 61.7 31.3 32.5 16.6U ganda na 74.6 67.3 na 64.6 32.7B urk<strong>in</strong>a Faso 66.9 84.4 84.6 59.8 98.7 72.6C ongo, D em R ep of 84.4 89.9 79.1 9.3 6.1 2.5Zam bia 80.4 44.6 67.9 0.8 1.8 10.2Source. Authors’calculations from FAO data


Table 5. Countries with high levels of undernourishment and with high dependence onimported gra<strong>in</strong>s and petroleumCountriesPetroleum% importedMajor gra<strong>in</strong>s% imported% undernourishmentEritrea 100 88 75Burundi 100 12 66Comoros 100 80 60Tajikistan 99 43 56Sierra Leone 100 53 51Liberia 100 62 50Zimbabwe 100 2 47Ethiopia 100 22 46Haiti 100 72 46Zambia 100 4 46Central <strong>African</strong> Republic 100 25 44Mozambique 100 20 44Tanzania 100 14 44Gu<strong>in</strong>ea-Bissau 100 55 39Madagascar 100 14 38Malawi 100 7 35Cambodia 100 5 33Korea, DPR 98 45 33Rwanda 100 29 33Botswana 100 76 32Niger 100 82 32Kenya 100 20 31Source. FAO


Table 6. Distribution of small-scale farm population accord<strong>in</strong>g to their position <strong>in</strong> thestaple gra<strong>in</strong> market, selected countries.Household category withrespect to ma<strong>in</strong> staple gra<strong>in</strong>:Zambia(maize)Mozambique(maize)Kenya(maize)Malawi(maize)Ethiopia(maize and teff)Sellers only:Percent account<strong>in</strong>g for top50% of total salesPercent account<strong>in</strong>g forbottom 50% of total sales---------------------------- % of rural farm population --------------------------19217Buyers only 33 51 55 na 60Buy and sell (net buyers) 3 7 na 1312Buy and sell (net sellers) 612 na 12Neither buy nor sell 39 24 8 na 2Source: Jayne, Chapoto, and Govereh, 2007132111821651413211100% 100% 100% 100% 100%


Table 7. Results of maize price transmission analysis for South AfricaEvidence for comovementwith:SAFEX yellow maize price, P SA YSAFEX white maize price, P SA WP w , world price strong strongP SA Y, SAFEXyellow maize price- strongCausality P W →P SA y P W →P SA wMonths to fulladjustment to P W 7.8 7.2Source. Authors’ calculations


Table 8. Results of maize price transmission analysis for KenyaEvidence for comovementwith:Nairobi Mombasa Eldoret KisumuP w , world price strong strong strong strongP SA w, South <strong>African</strong>price (white maize)moderate moderate strong strongCausality P w → P P w → P P w , P SA w→P P w , P SA w→PMonths to fulladjustment to P W 6.2 9.1 9.1 6.2Months to fulladjustment to P SA W- - 11.1 7.7Source. Authors’ calculations


Table 9. Results of maize price transmission analysis for MalawiCo-movementwithChipita Karonga Rumphi Mziba Mzuzu Mch<strong>in</strong>jiP w , world price strong strong moderate weak strong weakP SA w, South <strong>African</strong>price (white maize)strong strong strong weak strong weakCausality P w P SA w →P P w , P SA w →P P w , P SA w →P - P w P SA w →P -Months to fulladjustment toP W (P SA w)6.6 (5.0) 4.7 (4.8) (8.3) - 5.5 (6.1) -Salima Mitundu Liwonde Lizulu BangulaCo-movementwithP w , world price weak strong strong strong strongP SA w, South <strong>African</strong>price (white maize)strong strong strong strong strongCausality P SA w →P P w , P SA w →P P w , P SA w →P P w , P SA w →P P w , P SA w →PMonths to fulladjustment toP W (P SA w)(5.3) 5.8 (5.0) 7.7 (6.4) 7.1 (5.5) 3.8 (4.7)Source. Authors’ calculations


Table 10 Results of maize price transmission analysis for ZambiaEvidence for comovementwith:Lusaka Chipata Kabwe Choma Kasama NdolaP w , world price moderate weak strong weak strong strongP SA w, South <strong>African</strong>price (white maize)strong strong strong strong strong strongCausality P SA w → P - P SA w → P P SA → P P w , P SA w → P P w , P SA w → PMonths to fulladjustment to P W - - 4.8 - 5.5 3.2Months to fulladjustment to P SA W7.6 8.3 5.3 6.7 7.7 3.1Source. Authors’ calculations


Table 11 – Zambia: Impact of higher food prices (percentage changes)Quantities consumedFood Expenditure sharesUrbanMaleheadLandlessFood Insecure Food Secure Total populationRuralRuralFemaleheadLandowner>60% <strong>in</strong>come 60%<strong>in</strong>comefromagriculture


Table 12 – Malawi: Impact of higher food prices (percentage changes)Quantities consumedFood Expenditure sharesFood Insecure Food Secure Total populationRuralRuralLandlessLandowner>60% 60%


Table 13 Impact of a 50 percent Increase <strong>in</strong> the Price of Maize <strong>in</strong> Malawi, Zambia andUgandaMalawiZambiaUgandaFood <strong>in</strong>securehouseholdsFood securehouseholdsAll householdsQuantity of maize consumed, kg percapita 163 135 189Actual expenditure share of maize, % 33.00 41.5 25.2Quantity of maize consumed, % change -8.60 -4.79 -11.78Expenditure share of maize, % change 14.34 16.13 12.84Total food expenditure, % change 10.31 15.69 4.63Number of households, % change n/a 13.01 -10.47Quantity of maize consumed, kg percapita 150 150 151Actual expenditure share of maize, % 19.00 21 15Quantity of maize consumed, % change -16.97 -15.52 -18.85Expenditure share of maize, % change 12.95 15.61 9.51Total food expenditure, % change 2.96 3.11 2.63Number of households, % change n/a 4.34 -5.61Quantity of maize consumed, kg percapita 29 15 35Actual expenditure share of maize, % 8 8 8Quantity of maize consumed, % change -29.73 -30.03 -29.6Expenditure share of maize, % change 2.6 2.9 2.5Total food expenditure, % change 0.33 0.94 0.07Number of households, % change n/a 0.76 -0.33Source. Authors’calculations


Table 14. Impacts on macroeconomicaggregates <strong>in</strong> Tanzania, due to commodity pricechanges between 2002-8(million Tz shill<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> BASE and percentage changesfrom BASE <strong>in</strong> the simulation)BASE SimulationGPD 7804.2 -1.3agricultural imports 24.8 -3.4total imports 209.3 -7.0agricultural exports 22.6 35.7total exports 107.8 6.0<strong>in</strong>vestment 1.0 -11.2government sav<strong>in</strong>gs 92.5 30.0unskilled labour employed 2.5 -3.0nom<strong>in</strong>al exchange rate 1.0 -21.1real exchange rate (trd/nontrd) 1.0 2.1Source: Conforti and Sarris, 2008


Table 15. Impacts on welfare of various groups<strong>in</strong> Tanzania, due to commodity price changesbetween 2002-8(Percentage changes from BASE <strong>in</strong> the simulation)SimulationRural Poor -2.0Rural non-poor uneducated -3.0Rural non-poor educated -4.0Urban poor -3.1Urban non-poor uneducated -3.5Urban non-poor educated -5.0Source: Conforti and Sarris, 2008


Figure 1. Recent basic food commodity <strong>in</strong>ternational price <strong>in</strong>dices (1998-2000=100)30025020015010050020092008200720062005200420032002200120001999199819971996199519941993199219911990Source. FAOMEAT DAIRY CEREALS OILS SUGAR


Figure 2. Real bulk food commodity prices 1957-20081400Real Prices: Bulk Commodities (1957-2008)12001000WheatRiceMaizeSoybeans8006004002000195719601963196619691972197519781981198419871990199319961999200220052008Source. FAO


Figure 3. Annualized price volatilities of basic food commoditiesWh e a t6 0 05 0 04 0 03 0 02 0 0v o la t i li t yn o m i n a l p r i c e s1 0 001 9 5 71 9 6 21 9 6 71 9 7 21 9 7 71 9 8 21 9 8 71 9 9 21 9 9 72 0 0 22 0 0 7M a i z e4 0 03 5 03 0 02 5 02 0 01 5 0v o l a t i li t yn o m i n a l p r i c e s1 0 05 001 9 5 71 9 6 21 9 6 71 9 7 21 9 7 71 9 8 21 9 8 71 9 9 21 9 9 72 0 0 22 0 0 7R i c e6 0 05 0 04 0 03 0 02 0 0v o la t i l i t yn o m i n a l p r i c e s1 0 001 9 5 71 9 6 21 9 6 71 9 7 21 9 7 71 9 8 21 9 8 71 9 9 21 9 9 72 0 0 22 0 0 7Source. FAO


Figure 4. Income terms of trade for agriculture have deteriorated for LDCs dur<strong>in</strong>g thelast forty years.Income terms of trade for agriculture92008180$U S B il - L D C s765432LDCsOther develop<strong>in</strong>g countriesIndustrialized countries160140120100806040$U S B il O th er d evelo p <strong>in</strong> g an d In d u strializ ed120001961 1966 1971 1976 1981 1986 1991 1996 2001Source: FAO, State of <strong>Agricultural</strong> <strong>Commodity</strong> <strong>Markets</strong> 2004


Figure 4. Average yields <strong>in</strong> Developed, LDC and other develop<strong>in</strong>g countries4 .54 .03 .5Cereals - weighted average yields: 1985 - 2004Dev'edLDCsODCs3 .02 .52 .01.51.00 .50 .019 8 5 19 9 0 19 9 5 2 0 0 0 2 0 0 5Source. FAO


Figure 5. <strong>African</strong> cereal yield developments <strong>in</strong> basic food commoditiesAverage Yields: Maize86420198019851990199520002005Africa North Africa SSA LDCOther SSASouth AfricaAverage Yields: Rice, Paddy1086420198019851990199520002005Africa North Africa SSA LDCOther SSASouth Africa


Average Yields: Millet & Sorghum6420198019851990199520002005Africa North Africa SSA LDCOther SSASouth AfricaAverage Yields: Roots & Tubers302520151050198019851990199520002005Africa North Africa SSA LDCOther SSASouth AfricaSource. FAO


Figure 6. Wheat production, utilization, net-trade and per-capita food use of SSA LDCcountriesMillion MT15kg per capita251020515010-55-101996 2000 2004 2008 2012 2016Production Utilization Net Trade Per-capita Consumption0Source. FAO


49Figure 7. Coarse* gra<strong>in</strong> production, utilization, net-trade and per-capita food use ofSSA LDC countries.Million MT6050403020100kg per capita908070605040302010-101996 2000 2004 2008 2012 2016Production Utilization Net Trade Per-capita Consumption0*Coarse gra<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong>clude maize, oats, rye, millet, sorghum, barley and other coarse gra<strong>in</strong>sSource. FAO


50Figure 8. Rice production, utilization, net-trade and per-capita food use of SSA LDCcountries.Million MT20kg per capita25152010155010-55-101996 2000 2004 2008 2012 2016Production Utilization Net Trade Per-capita Consumption0Source. FAO

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!