13.07.2015 Views

Prices and knowledge: A market-process perspective

Prices and knowledge: A market-process perspective

Prices and knowledge: A market-process perspective

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

54 <strong>Prices</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>knowledge</strong><strong>knowledge</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard in the form of an at least highly informedgovernment when he concludes that welfare improvements can inmany cases be achieved through appropriate combinations of taxes,subsidies, <strong>and</strong> centralization of decision-making (1987:14).At a later point, when in a comparison of government planning<strong>and</strong> <strong>market</strong> allocation he assumes that the government may haveno more information than private individuals, Stiglitz does notargue why even this should be an acceptable assumption. Evenfrom a <strong>perspective</strong> of costly information, it may turn out to beeconomically impossible to put in a government’s h<strong>and</strong>s as muchinformation as exists in a decentralized form in a <strong>market</strong>economy. The assumption becomes even less acceptable for a<strong>market</strong>-<strong>process</strong> <strong>perspective</strong>: Stiglitz does not specify forgovernment any mechanism that will replace the discoveryprocedure provided by prices <strong>and</strong> competition to individuals in a<strong>market</strong> economy.The ambiguities regarding which st<strong>and</strong>ard to use persist over allGrossman <strong>and</strong> Stiglitz’s work, as in much of the literature on theeconomics of information. These ambiguities become particularlynoticeable when, on the one h<strong>and</strong>, Grossman (1981:555; emphasisadded), in his description of Hayek’s argument, says, ‘a plannerwithout all of that information could not have done as well’, <strong>and</strong>, onthe other, Grossman <strong>and</strong> Stiglitz (1976:252; emphasis added), afterarguing about the informational inefficiency of prices, conclude that‘in this case a central planner with all the information can improve onthe competitive equilibrium’. 33Of course, most of these comments can be made from anequilibrium, somewhat Demsetzian, <strong>perspective</strong> that still acceptssome variant of Pareto efficiency as its norm. As the previous chapterstated, a disequilibrium, <strong>market</strong>-<strong>process</strong> approach will adopt adifferent normative st<strong>and</strong>ard. Streit (1984:394) seems to have it inmind when he says:As in other cases of socially useful competition, inefficiency from astatic point of view can be the source of dynamic efficiency. Andfrom this <strong>perspective</strong> of discovery <strong>and</strong> adaptation, the basicallystatic verdict of Pareto non-optimality carries little weight if any. 34From this <strong>perspective</strong>, the hope expressed by Rothschild (1973: 1304)that the economic profession will start ‘to develop st<strong>and</strong>ards ofefficiency <strong>and</strong> equity <strong>and</strong> to begin to ask what sorts of institutional

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!