13.07.2015 Views

Prices and knowledge: A market-process perspective

Prices and knowledge: A market-process perspective

Prices and knowledge: A market-process perspective

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Notes 12527 Unlike in Demsetz’s framework, these mistakes <strong>and</strong> inefficiencies are due to‘sheer’ ignorance.28 Buchanan (1985:15–16) may be referring to this (although he mayreally have a more Schumpeterian framework in mind) when hedescribes as the ‘diachronic efficiencies of the <strong>market</strong>’ that‘competition in nonideal <strong>market</strong>s generates incentives for behaviorthat tends toward the more perfect satisfaction of the conditions of theideal <strong>market</strong>…’.3 Equilibrium prices <strong>and</strong> information1 Also: ‘the merit of perfect competition is that it would cause prices totransmit information reliably…’ (Scitovsky 1954:150); ‘a fundamental resultof competitive analysis is that <strong>market</strong> prices contain all of the informationrequired for consistent <strong>and</strong> efficient decision-making by firms <strong>and</strong>individuals’ (Kihlstrom <strong>and</strong> Mirman 1975:357).2 Grossman (1976, 1978); Grossman <strong>and</strong> Stiglitz (1976, 1980); Grossman(1981). Many of these essays have been reprinted in Grossman (1989). Avery similar approach to Grossman <strong>and</strong> Stiglitz’s appears in Green (1973,1977).3 See Fama (1970).4 For a recent summary of Grossman’s work in this area, see Kreps (1988).5 The two quoted passages reflect frequently encountered interpretations ofHayek’s argument. See, for example, Sowell (1980:38, 75, 79, 80); Arrow(1974:158); Frydman (1982); Hahn (1984b: esp. 128); Hirshleifer <strong>and</strong> Riley(1979:1412); McAfee <strong>and</strong> McMillan (1987:699–700, 732–3); Schotter(1985:39–40, 41–2); Kohler (1982:28 ff.), <strong>and</strong> Dolan (1983:62).6 See, for example, Hurwicz (1960, 1972, 1973, 1977, 1984). Also see Almon(1963); Calsamiglia (1977); Davis <strong>and</strong> Whinston (1966); Marschak (1959,1972); Mount <strong>and</strong> Reiter (1974); Osana (1978); Reiter (1977). For arelatively recent survey <strong>and</strong> more bibliography, see Groves <strong>and</strong> Ledyard(1987).7 Most of this literature uses the term ‘information’ in the measurable sensemeant in ‘information theory’. It is in this context that Arrow (1974:159)complains about the lack of ‘a more definitive measure of information <strong>and</strong> itscosts, in terms of which it would be possible to assert the superiority of theprice system over a centralized alternative’.8 For critical comments on this point, see Lavoie (1986).9 In fact, Grossman <strong>and</strong> Stiglitz (1976:248) seem to believe that Hayek is alsosaying so.10 See Streit (1984) for some criticisms of this argument.11 The classic article on ‘breakdown’ <strong>and</strong> ‘thinness’ of <strong>market</strong>s is Akerlof(1970).12 Some problems with this example will be pointed out below.13 Implicitly, Grossman <strong>and</strong> Stiglitz must assume this ‘invisible h<strong>and</strong>’ to be ableto obtain the information costlessly. Otherwise, it would only becomeoptimally informed.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!