13.07.2015 Views

poverty and geographic targeting in egypt - Economic Research ...

poverty and geographic targeting in egypt - Economic Research ...

poverty and geographic targeting in egypt - Economic Research ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

POVERTY AND GEOGRAPHIC TARGETING IN EGYPT:EVIDENCE FROM A POVERTY MAPPING EXERCISERania Roushdy <strong>and</strong> Ragui AssaadWork<strong>in</strong>g Paper 0715November 2007The authors would like to acknowledge the cooperation of the Central Agency for PublicMobilization <strong>and</strong> Statistics (CAPMAS). Thanks are due to Khaled Maher for runn<strong>in</strong>g theanalysis syntax files at CAPMAS. We also express our thanks to the Center for <strong>Economic</strong>,Juridical <strong>and</strong> Social Studies <strong>and</strong> Documentation (CEDEJ) for mapp<strong>in</strong>g the study results us<strong>in</strong>gGeographic Information System (GIS) <strong>and</strong> design<strong>in</strong>g the maps published <strong>in</strong> this paper. Manythanks are due to Dr. Ghada Barsoum, Population Council, for provid<strong>in</strong>g overall supervisionto this study <strong>and</strong> help<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the analysis of the results. Thanks are also due to MiralBreebaart, Population Council, for her dist<strong>in</strong>guishable efforts <strong>in</strong> the preparation <strong>and</strong> analysisof the Population Census data. F<strong>in</strong>ally, we would like to express our special appreciation toDr. Heba El-Laithy, Cairo University, for her valuable comments dur<strong>in</strong>g the implementationof this study.Rania Roushdy & Ragui Assaad, Population Council, West Asia <strong>and</strong> North Africa RegionEmail: rassaad@pccairo.org <strong>and</strong> rroushdy@pccairo.org


AbstractThis study produces, for the first time, a f<strong>in</strong>ely detailed <strong>poverty</strong> map for Egypt, The <strong>poverty</strong>estimates produced <strong>in</strong> this study go substantially further <strong>in</strong> terms of <strong>geographic</strong> disaggregationthan previously produced estimates. Us<strong>in</strong>g small-area estimation approach, the papercomb<strong>in</strong>es the full coverage of the 1996 Population Census <strong>and</strong> the detailed <strong>in</strong>formation on<strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> expenditure available from the 1999/2000 Household Income ExpenditureConsumption Survey to estimate per capita consumption for all localities nationwide. Theresults show that <strong>poverty</strong> is spatially concentrated <strong>in</strong> Egypt. There exist substantial disparities<strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>cidence of <strong>poverty</strong> between localities. Also, the with<strong>in</strong>-governorate distribution of poor<strong>and</strong> rich localities varies markedly. The f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs of this paper suggest that the <strong>geographic</strong>dimension of <strong>poverty</strong> should be carefully considered when <strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> the poor <strong>in</strong> Egypt.ملخصتصوغ هذه الدراسة،‏ للمرة الأولى،‏ خريطة مفصلة رائعة عن الفقر في مصر،‏ فمن حيث التقسيم الجغرافي،‏ تشملهذه الدراسة تقديرات خاصة بالفقر تتخطى بشكل آبير المدى الذي وصلت إليه التقديرات السابقة.‏ وباستخدام تقييميعتمد على نطاق صغير،‏ تجمع هذه الورقة بين التغطية الكاملة للتعداد السكاني(‏ 1996) والمعلومات المفصلة عنلتقييم معدل استهلاك الفردالدخل والإنفاق التي وفرها مسح الدخل والإنفاق والاستهلاك الأسريعلى مستوى الجمهورية.‏ وتُظهر النتائج أن الفقر متمرآز في حيز معين في مصر؛ وأن ثمة تباين آبير فيمعدلات انتشار الفقر في المناطق المختلفة وفي توزيع المناطق الفقيرة والغنية داخل نفس المحافظة.‏ وتقترح نتائجهذه الورقة أخذ البعد الجغرافي للفقر في الاعتبار عند التعامل مع الفقراء في مصر(2000-1999)1


1. IntroductionPoverty is spatially concentrated <strong>in</strong> many countries all over the world, mak<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>geographic</strong>dimensions of <strong>poverty</strong> a central aspect of various public policies <strong>and</strong> a vital facet <strong>in</strong> numerous<strong>poverty</strong> researches. In several develop<strong>in</strong>g countries <strong>poverty</strong> maps have been utilized to drivepublic policies, guide the division of resources, <strong>and</strong> design <strong>poverty</strong> alleviation programs.However, the usefulness of these <strong>poverty</strong> maps has often been limited by the lack ofdisaggregate-level data on household resources.<strong>Research</strong> has shown that for <strong>geographic</strong> <strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> to be efficient, the unit of analysis needs tobe quite small; such as a village or a district. Household <strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> expenditure surveys aregenerally the ma<strong>in</strong> source of <strong>in</strong>formation on spatial patterns of <strong>poverty</strong>, but the sample size ofthese surveys often only allows the estimation of <strong>poverty</strong> for few aggregate regions with<strong>in</strong> acountry. The only household dataset that does not suffer from this small sample problem istypically the population census data; however, the census data often lacks <strong>in</strong>formation onhousehold <strong>in</strong>come or expenditure (Bigman <strong>and</strong> Fofack 2000). Recently, a two-stepestimation approach, called the “small-area estimation” technique, has been <strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong>tothe <strong>poverty</strong> literature. This methodology comb<strong>in</strong>es both data sources <strong>in</strong> a way that takesadvantage of the full coverage of the census data <strong>and</strong> the detailed welfare <strong>in</strong>formationobta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> household surveys to derive <strong>poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>equality estimates at a level ofdisaggregation far below that allowed by the household surveys samples. Small-areaestimation technique has been <strong>in</strong>itially explored by Hentschel et al. (1999) to derive adisaggregate <strong>poverty</strong> map for Ecuador. Afterwards, it has been frequently revised to allow forvarious characteristics of the disturbance term <strong>in</strong> the first step of the estimation (see Elbers etal. (2002) for a detailed description of the revised methodology). In several countries, thismethodology has been used to produce disaggregated <strong>poverty</strong> maps. M<strong>in</strong>ot et al. (2000) is anearly application of the methodology that comb<strong>in</strong>es the 1992/93 Vietnam Liv<strong>in</strong>g St<strong>and</strong>ardSurvey <strong>and</strong> the 1994 Agricultural Census data to generate estimates of rural <strong>poverty</strong> for 534rural districts <strong>in</strong> Vietnam. Later on, M<strong>in</strong>ot et al. (2003) estimates several <strong>poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>equality measures for all prov<strong>in</strong>ces, districts <strong>and</strong> communes of Vietnam, us<strong>in</strong>g the 1997/98Vietnam Liv<strong>in</strong>g St<strong>and</strong>ard Survey <strong>and</strong> the 1999 Population Census. Astrup <strong>and</strong> Dessus (2001)constructed a <strong>poverty</strong> map for the West Bank <strong>and</strong> Gaza. The authors estimated the <strong>in</strong>cidenceof <strong>poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> 132 localities, by comb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Palest<strong>in</strong>ian Household Survey <strong>and</strong> the 1997Palest<strong>in</strong>ian Census. Additionally, household surveys <strong>and</strong> census data have been comb<strong>in</strong>ed toproduce disaggregate <strong>poverty</strong> maps for Guatemala, Nicaragua, Panama, Peru, South Africa,Mozambique, Malawi <strong>and</strong> Cambodia (see Hentschel et al.,2000; Henn<strong>in</strong>ger <strong>and</strong> Snel, 2002;Simler <strong>and</strong> Nhate, 2003).In Egypt, as <strong>in</strong> many countries, there has been an extensive literature on measur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>poverty</strong>,<strong>and</strong> welfare distribution, as well as on the l<strong>in</strong>kage between <strong>poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> many demographic<strong>and</strong> socioeconomic characteristics (e.g., El-Laithy, Loksh<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> Banerji, 2003; Haddad <strong>and</strong>Ahmed, 2003; Datt <strong>and</strong> Jolliffe, 2005). The lack of direct <strong>in</strong>formation on householdresources at a f<strong>in</strong>ely disaggregated level has directed researchers to explore alternativewelfare <strong>in</strong>dicators, which are available at the local level <strong>and</strong> which are believed to becorrelated with local <strong>poverty</strong> conditions. However, there has always been a dispute onwhether these proxies provide an accurate picture of the household liv<strong>in</strong>g st<strong>and</strong>ard.Alternatively, other research has focused on produc<strong>in</strong>g direct <strong>in</strong>come <strong>poverty</strong> estimates; but,due to the above mentioned data limitation problem, these estimates have been produced onlyat relatively aggregate levels with<strong>in</strong> Egypt, such as at the governorate- or region-levels. Tothe best of our knowledge, none of the previous studies used the small-area estimationtechnique to produce local-level <strong>poverty</strong> estimates for all localities <strong>in</strong> Egypt. The ma<strong>in</strong>objective of this paper is to estimate per capita consumption at the village/neighborhood-level2


nationwide <strong>in</strong> Egypt, by comb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g detailed <strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> expenditure <strong>in</strong>formation availablefrom the Egypt 1999/2000 Household Income <strong>and</strong> Expenditure Consumption Survey(HIECS) with the extensive coverage of the 1996 Egyptian Population Census.This paper is organized <strong>in</strong>to 6 sections. Follow<strong>in</strong>g this <strong>in</strong>troduction, Section 2 describes thedata used <strong>in</strong> this study. Section 3 discusses the small-area estimation methodology. Section 4presents <strong>and</strong> discusses the estimation results <strong>and</strong> the characteristics of the produced maps.Section 5 presents conclud<strong>in</strong>g remarks, limitations <strong>and</strong> future work. Policy implications arediscussed <strong>in</strong> Section 6.2. DataEgypt is divided <strong>in</strong>to 27 governorates, which are often grouped <strong>in</strong>to 5 to 7 major regions(Urban Governorates, Urban Lower Egypt, Rural Lower Egypt, Urban Upper Egypt, RuralUpper Egypt, Urban Frontiers, <strong>and</strong> Rural Frontiers). Table 1 <strong>in</strong> the Appendix listsgovernorates belong<strong>in</strong>g to each of these regions. The Urban regions <strong>in</strong> Egypt are divided <strong>in</strong>todistricts, each called qism. Each qism is divided <strong>in</strong>to several urban neighborhoods, calledshiakha. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, rural regions districts are called markaz, <strong>and</strong> each markaz isdivided <strong>in</strong>to several villages.Two household datasets are used <strong>in</strong> this paper to estimate <strong>in</strong>come <strong>poverty</strong>: the 1999/2000Household Income <strong>and</strong> Expenditure Consumption Survey (HIECS) <strong>and</strong> the 1996 PopulationCensus. Both datasets were collected by the Central Agency for Public Mobilization <strong>and</strong>Statistics (CAPMAS) <strong>in</strong> Egypt. The HIECS consists of a nationally representative sample of47,949 household (226,117 Individuals). About 28,754 of those household are urban, while19,195 are rural. HIECS is a household budget survey that conta<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong>formation ofconsumption expenditures on more than 550 items of goods <strong>and</strong> services. The HIECS isgenerally considered the major source of <strong>in</strong>formation on household <strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> expenditure<strong>in</strong> Egypt.Both the HIECS <strong>and</strong> the Census conta<strong>in</strong> considerable <strong>in</strong>formation on the householdmembers’ demographic <strong>and</strong> socioeconomic characteristics, the basic hous<strong>in</strong>g conditions,ownership of durables, access to basic services <strong>and</strong> the neighborhood <strong>in</strong>frastructure.However, detailed <strong>in</strong>formation on the household <strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> expenditure is only provided <strong>in</strong>the HIECS.Due to confidentiality reasons, the full household records of both the Census <strong>and</strong> the HIECSwere not available to us. Nevertheless, for the Census, we got access to data aggregated atthe village/shyakha-level (5312 village/shyakha) 1 , while for the HIECS, we got access to thecluster-level or primary sampl<strong>in</strong>g unit level (600 PSU). 2 Additionally, we got access to a 10percent sample of household record data from the Census. This 10 percent sample consists of1,270,144 households (about 5.9 million <strong>in</strong>dividuals) selected us<strong>in</strong>g systematic sampl<strong>in</strong>g.Variables needed <strong>in</strong> the analysis, which cannot be produced directly from the Censusvillage/shiakha-level data, were produced by special cross-tabulations us<strong>in</strong>g the 10%1It should be noted that about 148 of those localities are excluded from the analysis because some of therequired variable are miss<strong>in</strong>g. A soft copy of the Census village/shiakha level data was provided to us by bothCEDEJ <strong>and</strong> Infonex Egypt. CEDEJ provided us with the village-level employment <strong>and</strong> demographic data,while Infonex provided the data on access to services <strong>and</strong> ownership of durable goods.2Our request to get a copy of the HIECS <strong>in</strong>dividual/PSU-level data was rejected by CAPMAS due to theconfidentiality of <strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> expenditure data. However, we managed to reach an agreement with CAPMAS torun the syntax files of our analysis on the HIECS PSU-level data at CAPMAS <strong>and</strong> receive a pr<strong>in</strong>tout of theresults.3


household-level sample. Examples <strong>in</strong>clude variables comb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g occupation, employmentstatus <strong>and</strong> sector, <strong>and</strong> variables describ<strong>in</strong>g the household head's characteristics.3. Estimation MethodologyThe small-area estimation technique is used <strong>in</strong> this paper to comb<strong>in</strong>e the rich <strong>in</strong>formation onhousehold <strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> expenditure available from the HIECS <strong>and</strong> the complete coverage ofthe Census data, <strong>in</strong> order to estimate locality-level <strong>poverty</strong> <strong>in</strong> Egypt 3 . The small-areaestimation methodology typically <strong>in</strong>volves the follow<strong>in</strong>g three stages (for detailed descriptionof this methodology, see Elbers et al. (2002) <strong>and</strong> M<strong>in</strong>ot et al. (2003)):3.1 Identify<strong>in</strong>g household characteristics available <strong>in</strong> both the HIECS <strong>and</strong> the CensusThis stage <strong>in</strong>volves compar<strong>in</strong>g the HIECS <strong>and</strong> Census questionnaires to identify commonhousehold variables found <strong>in</strong> both datasets. Generally, this is not a major constra<strong>in</strong>t on theanalysis, because a large set of variables is available <strong>in</strong> both datasets. In this paper, thechoice of the f<strong>in</strong>al set of explanatory variables is based on a thorough review of the <strong>poverty</strong>literature <strong>and</strong> a careful <strong>in</strong>vestigation of the relationship between the common set ofexplanatory variables <strong>and</strong> <strong>poverty</strong> measures. The explanatory variables employed <strong>in</strong> theanalysis could be grouped <strong>in</strong>to three categories: (1) demographic, social <strong>and</strong> economiccharacteristics of the household; (2) hous<strong>in</strong>g conditions <strong>and</strong> access to basic services; (3)ownership of durables goods (See Table A1 <strong>in</strong> the Appendix for the list <strong>and</strong> description ofselected explanatory variables <strong>and</strong> their correlation coefficients with per capita consumption).These three groups of household characteristics are represented by 47 variables <strong>in</strong> theregression analysis. Additionally, dummy variables for governorates, urban/rural residence,<strong>and</strong> the <strong>in</strong>teraction between governorate <strong>and</strong> urban rural residence are <strong>in</strong>cluded among theexplanatory variables, <strong>in</strong> order to account for localities structural differences that are notcaptured by the observed localities characteristics.3.2 Estimat<strong>in</strong>g per capita consumption us<strong>in</strong>g the HIECS dataThis stage is the first step of the two-step small-area estimation approach. In this first-step,household survey data is used to econometrically estimate different measure of householdwelfare as a function of the chosen common set of household characteristics. In mostprevious research, the household is typically the unit of analysis <strong>in</strong> regression modelsestimated <strong>in</strong> this stage 4 ; however, as mentioned above, due to data restrictions we were onlyable to access the cluster-level data of the HIECS. To overcome this data limitation, <strong>in</strong> thefirst-step of the estimation, we estimate the cluster-level welfare. 5 A log-l<strong>in</strong>ear function ofper capita consumption <strong>in</strong> cluster i, y i , is estimated us<strong>in</strong>g the HIECS data 6 :3The term "locality" is generically used <strong>in</strong> this paper to refer to various levels of local geography. In someoccasions locality will refer to markaz, mad<strong>in</strong>a, or qism; <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong> others it will refer to village or shiakha.4For example, Elbers et al. (2002) <strong>and</strong> Hentschel et al. (2000) use log-l<strong>in</strong>ear models <strong>and</strong> household-level data toestimate household per capita consumption <strong>and</strong> generate unbiased estimates of the headcount <strong>poverty</strong> rates.M<strong>in</strong>ot (2000), M<strong>in</strong>ot <strong>and</strong> Baulch (2002), <strong>and</strong> Astrup <strong>and</strong> Dessus (2001) use a probit model <strong>and</strong> household recorddata to estimate the likelihood of <strong>poverty</strong>. M<strong>in</strong>ot et al. (2003) use the household Vietnam Liv<strong>in</strong>g St<strong>and</strong>ardSurveys data to first estimate a log-l<strong>in</strong>ear equation of the household per capita consumption; then use a 33percent sample of the household-level census data to estimate three measures of <strong>poverty</strong> (<strong>in</strong>cidence, depth,severity) <strong>and</strong> three measures of <strong>in</strong>equality (G<strong>in</strong>i coefficient, Theil’s L <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>and</strong> Theil’s T <strong>in</strong>dex) at the districtlevel.5If micro-level census data are not available, biases are <strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong>to the analysis <strong>in</strong> terms of both the <strong>poverty</strong>estimates <strong>and</strong> the st<strong>and</strong>ard errors (See M<strong>in</strong>ot <strong>and</strong> Baulch, 2005). Hence, one would expect that us<strong>in</strong>g cluster-4


ln y=iX i′β + εiwhere X i is a vector of cluster-level characteristics of cluster i; <strong>and</strong> ε i is a disturbance termthat is distributed as N(0, σ 2 ). Of course, some of the explanatory variables selected <strong>in</strong> thefirst stage are endogenous, which would bias the estimation results. For <strong>in</strong>stance, theownership of durables are particularly among the set of endogenous variables, s<strong>in</strong>ce it isclosely determ<strong>in</strong>ed by the household liv<strong>in</strong>g st<strong>and</strong>ard <strong>and</strong> thus by the <strong>poverty</strong> status (Astrup<strong>and</strong> Dessus 2001). However, as discussed <strong>in</strong> M<strong>in</strong>ot (2000), the possible endogeneity of someof the explanatory variables is less of a concern <strong>in</strong> the current analysis s<strong>in</strong>ce the ma<strong>in</strong>objective here is to predict the level of <strong>poverty</strong> (or ln y i ), rather than to study the determ<strong>in</strong>antsof <strong>poverty</strong> or to assess the impact of each explanatory variable.3.3 Predict<strong>in</strong>g per capita consumption for all localities of Egypt us<strong>in</strong>g the Census dataIn this stage, the regression model developed <strong>in</strong> the previous step <strong>and</strong> the village/shiakhalevelCensus data are used to predict per capita consumption. In contrast to the HIECSsample, the national-wide nature of the Census allows us to estimate per capita consumptionfor all localities of Egypt. 7The f<strong>in</strong>al step, after predict<strong>in</strong>g the locality-level per capita consumption, is to transform thepredicted nom<strong>in</strong>al values <strong>in</strong>to real region-equivalent figures. This f<strong>in</strong>al step is crucial toallow for appropriate cross-region comparison, s<strong>in</strong>ce significant differences <strong>in</strong> consumptionpatterns <strong>and</strong> prices exist across regions of Egypt (El-Leithy <strong>and</strong> Osman, 1997). Per capitaregion-specific <strong>poverty</strong> l<strong>in</strong>es, estimated <strong>in</strong> El-Laithy <strong>and</strong> Loksh<strong>in</strong> (2002) us<strong>in</strong>g the data fromthe 1999/2000 HIECS, are used here to produce region-equivalent values of per capitaconsumption. Those <strong>poverty</strong> l<strong>in</strong>es account for the regional differences <strong>in</strong> relative food <strong>and</strong>non-food prices, expenditure patterns, <strong>and</strong> activity levels. To produce those <strong>poverty</strong> l<strong>in</strong>es, theauthors divided Egypt <strong>in</strong>to the seven regions mentioned above. Table A2 <strong>in</strong> the Appendixshows the developed per capita region-specific <strong>poverty</strong> l<strong>in</strong>es (see El-Laithy <strong>and</strong> Loksh<strong>in</strong>,2002, for a detailed description of the <strong>poverty</strong> l<strong>in</strong>es estimation methodology).The <strong>poverty</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e of the Metropolitan governorates, PL 1 , is set as the reference category. Thepredicted nom<strong>in</strong>al per capita consumption, PCC ig , of locality i <strong>in</strong> region g (g=2,…,7) isadjusted accord<strong>in</strong>gly to obta<strong>in</strong> the predicted region-equivalent per capita consumption,EPCC ig , as follows:PL1EPCCigPCCig×PL= Data from this f<strong>in</strong>al step has been mapped us<strong>in</strong>g a Geographic InformationgSystem (GIS) to visually represent the national rank<strong>in</strong>g of all localities. 8level average <strong>in</strong> the first-step of the estimation <strong>in</strong>troduces even more aggregation biases <strong>in</strong>to the analysis. Thiswill be explored <strong>in</strong> details <strong>in</strong> future work.6This paper uses consumption data to measure cluster welfare. Consumption is often preferred over <strong>in</strong>comewhen measur<strong>in</strong>g welfare, s<strong>in</strong>ce consumption data is likely to be subject to less fluctuation over time <strong>and</strong> to fewermeasurement errors (see Deaton 1997).7The analysis of this paper is based on the assumption that there have not been major changes <strong>in</strong> the Egyptianeconomy dur<strong>in</strong>g the period 1996 (the Population Census year) <strong>and</strong> 2000 (the HICES year). In other words, byus<strong>in</strong>g the small-area estimation technique, we are implicitly assum<strong>in</strong>g that the coefficients describ<strong>in</strong>g therelationship between consumption <strong>and</strong> the set of explanatory variables has been stable dur<strong>in</strong>g this period. Thisis most likely to be the case for most of the explanatory variables (e.g., adult education <strong>and</strong> occupation).Stability tests could be employed here. This is left for future work.8Mapp<strong>in</strong>g the estimation result us<strong>in</strong>g GIS was conducted by CEDEJ.5


4. Poverty Mapp<strong>in</strong>g ResultsThis section presents the results of the two-step small area estimation methodology. Theresults of the first-step, the least squares estimates of the cluster-level equation of log percapita consumption us<strong>in</strong>g the HIECS data, are presented <strong>in</strong> Table 1. The model goodness offit measure (R2=0.9177) is high. It expla<strong>in</strong>s more than 91 percent of the variation <strong>in</strong> clusterlevelper capita consumption.9 The results of this table confirm our expectation thathousehold members’ enrolment rates <strong>and</strong> employment status, <strong>and</strong> household head's educationlevel <strong>and</strong> employment stability are significantly correlated with <strong>poverty</strong>.10 Also, asexpected, a large group of the household durables is a good predictor of <strong>poverty</strong> level.Cluster-level average possession of a car, refrigerator, VCR, satellite dish <strong>and</strong> personalcomputer appears to be associated with higher level of per capita consumption. Moreover,localities <strong>in</strong> the governorates of Alex<strong>and</strong>ria, Port Said, Suez, Dumyat <strong>and</strong> South S<strong>in</strong>ai are lesslikely to be poor.Our <strong>poverty</strong> mapp<strong>in</strong>g exercise provides villages/shiakha-level, district-level, governoratelevel,<strong>and</strong> urban/rural-level <strong>poverty</strong> rank<strong>in</strong>g—accord<strong>in</strong>g to the predicted RPCC. Figure 1presents the full national-level distribution of village/shiakha RPCC <strong>in</strong> Egypt. Figures 2 <strong>and</strong>3 are examples of the with<strong>in</strong>-governorate <strong>and</strong> with<strong>in</strong>-district spatial distribution of RPCC.The poorest the locality the darker it is represented on the maps. These figures confirm that<strong>poverty</strong> is spatially distributed <strong>in</strong> Egypt. It is clear from Figure 1 that poor localities aremostly widespread <strong>in</strong> Upper Egypt, particularly <strong>in</strong> the Suhag, Assiut, Beni Suef, Fayoum <strong>and</strong>Q<strong>in</strong>a governorates.Table 2 presents the Census-based governorate-level predictions of RPCC. On thegovernorate-level, South S<strong>in</strong>ai <strong>and</strong> Port Said have the highest RPCC, while Suhag appears tobe the poorest governorate. Table 3 <strong>and</strong> Figure 4 summarize the distribution of poorest <strong>and</strong>richest villages/shiakhas <strong>in</strong> Egypt accord<strong>in</strong>g to their predicted RPCC by governorate. Table 3shows the governorates that have localities with<strong>in</strong> the poorest 100, poorest 1000, <strong>and</strong> richest1000 localities. The poorest 50 villages <strong>in</strong> Egypt are ma<strong>in</strong>ly <strong>in</strong> the governorates of Suhag (33villages) <strong>and</strong> Assiut (14 villages). Marsa Matrouh, North S<strong>in</strong>ai <strong>and</strong> Beni Suef jo<strong>in</strong> these twogovernorates <strong>in</strong> the category of the poorest 100 villages. The table confirms that the poorestlocalities <strong>in</strong> Egypt are predom<strong>in</strong>antly <strong>in</strong> Upper Egypt.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the village/shiakha-level predicted RPCC results (not shown here), the poorestvillage/shiakha <strong>and</strong> poorest district <strong>in</strong> Egypt are <strong>in</strong> the governorate of Suhag. AwlaadShaluul (<strong>in</strong> the district of Suhag) is the poorest village <strong>and</strong> the district of Dar al-Salam is thepoorest district nationwide. In contrast, although <strong>in</strong> Table 2 the governorate of Cairo isranked the sixth accord<strong>in</strong>g to the governorate-level predicted RPCC, the richest localitynationwide <strong>in</strong> Egypt is <strong>in</strong> Cairo: Al-Gabalaaya shiakha (<strong>in</strong> Al-Zamalik district) is the richestvillage/shiakha <strong>in</strong> Egypt <strong>and</strong> Al-Zamalik is the richest district.Figure 2 presents both the national-level rank<strong>in</strong>g (left map) <strong>and</strong> the with<strong>in</strong>-governorate-levelrank<strong>in</strong>g (right map) of the poorest governorate, Suhag. The national-level rank<strong>in</strong>g map,which is just a zoomed-<strong>in</strong> version of Figure 1, shows all Suhag as one dark spot. On the rightside map, darker spots (or localities fall<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the lowest qu<strong>in</strong>tile of the PRCC distribution)are quite dispersed all over Suhag; but are, relatively, more concentrated around the South-9For simplicity, from this section onwards, the paper refers to “localities with lower average per capitaconsumption” as “poorest localities”. However, the reader should be aware that <strong>poverty</strong> is not only a functionof average consumption but also the distribution of consumption.10The results of this step should be <strong>in</strong>terpreted with caution. As mentioned above, the estimated coefficientsmay be biased <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>consistent, s<strong>in</strong>ce some of the explanatory variables are endogenous to the <strong>poverty</strong> status.However, as discussed above, this problem is less of a concern <strong>in</strong> the context of the present analysis.6


East part of the governorate where Dar al-Salam district falls. A closer view of the district ofDar al-Salam is shown <strong>in</strong> Figure 3. The national-, governorate-, <strong>and</strong> district-levels rank<strong>in</strong>g ofDar al-Salam are demonstrated <strong>in</strong> this figure. On the district-level rank<strong>in</strong>g map of Dar al-Salam, four areas appear to particularly fall <strong>in</strong> the bottom qu<strong>in</strong>tiles of the RPCC, which arethe City of Dar al-Salaam, <strong>and</strong> the three villages of al-Naghaameesh, al-Balaabeesh al-Mustagida, <strong>and</strong> Awlaad Saalam Bahari.It is clear form Table 3 that none of the Lower Egypt localities appears among the bottom100 category. The poorest locality <strong>in</strong> Lower Egypt is ranked the 237 th , which is the village ofKafr 'Abdallah 'Azeeza (M<strong>in</strong>ya al-Qamh district) <strong>in</strong> Sharkia. Moreover, the poorest localities<strong>in</strong> Egypt are predom<strong>in</strong>antly rural. Only three urban neighborhoods (shiakhas) are rankedamong the bottom 100 localities <strong>in</strong> Egypt: two shiakhas <strong>in</strong> Assiut (al-Madaabigh wa Gebaanaal-Muslimeen <strong>and</strong> al-Ghoneim City), <strong>and</strong> one <strong>in</strong> Suhag (Dar al-Salaam City). Also, only 26urban neighborhoods show up among the bottom 1000 localities <strong>in</strong> Egypt. In comparison,about 62 percent of the richest localities <strong>in</strong> Egypt are urban neighborhoods.Figure 4 shows the distribution of the poorest 1000 <strong>and</strong> richest 1000 localities <strong>in</strong> Egypt, as apercentage of the total number of localities with<strong>in</strong> each governorate. The governoratesrank<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> this figure differs from that presented <strong>in</strong> Table 3. The table shows Cairo as thegovernorate with the highest <strong>in</strong>cidence of top <strong>in</strong>come localities, <strong>and</strong> Suhag with the highest<strong>in</strong>cidence of low <strong>in</strong>come localities. Look<strong>in</strong>g at the percentage of richest localities with<strong>in</strong>each governorate (Figure 4), Dumiat comes first <strong>and</strong> Suhag <strong>and</strong> Assiut come last. About 99percent of villages/shiakhas <strong>in</strong> Dumiat appear among the richest 1000 localities <strong>in</strong> Egypt, <strong>and</strong>none of its localities appears among the poorest 1000 localities. In each of Suhag <strong>and</strong> Assiut,about 90 percent of the localities are among the poorest 1000 category, while less than onepercent belongs to the richest group.Due to the unavailability of the household-level data, we are unable to provide reliableestimates of local-level <strong>in</strong>equality measures. Nevertheless, to get an idea of the with<strong>in</strong>governorate<strong>in</strong>equality, we sketch <strong>in</strong> Figure 5 the distribution of village/shiakha predictedRPCC by governorate. In most of the governorates, the distribution of RPCC appears to bestrongly concentrated around the governorate median with quite a few outliers. Thevillage/shiakha RPCC distribution appears to be, relatively, more widely spread <strong>in</strong> Red Sea,North S<strong>in</strong>ai, <strong>and</strong> the Metropolitan governorates. Outliers are, particularly more obviouslydispersed away from the distribution mean <strong>in</strong> Alex<strong>and</strong>ria, Cairo, <strong>and</strong> Giza. In contrast,outliers are very limited <strong>in</strong> Q<strong>in</strong>a, Aswan, <strong>and</strong> Luxor. Surpris<strong>in</strong>gly, almost all of the outliersappear<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the figure are at the top of the governorates PRCC distribution. Based on theresults presented <strong>in</strong> Table 2 <strong>and</strong> Figure 4, we cannot reject the often highlighted presumptionthat <strong>in</strong>equality is less severe <strong>in</strong> poor communities. To accurately test this presumptionhousehold-level data is needed (see M<strong>in</strong>ot et al. (2003) <strong>and</strong> Simler <strong>and</strong> Nhate (2003) formeasurements <strong>and</strong> tests of <strong>in</strong>equality us<strong>in</strong>g household-level data)5. Conclusions, limitations <strong>and</strong> future workThis study produces a f<strong>in</strong>ely detailed <strong>poverty</strong> map for Egypt, which goes substantially further<strong>in</strong> terms of <strong>geographic</strong> disaggregation than previously produced <strong>poverty</strong> estimates. Thepaper comb<strong>in</strong>es the full coverage of the 1996 Population Census <strong>and</strong> the detailed <strong>in</strong>formationon <strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> expenditure provided from the 1999/2000 HIECS to estimate per capitaconsumption for all localities <strong>in</strong> Egypt. Results show that <strong>poverty</strong> is spatially distributed <strong>in</strong>Egypt. Substantial disparities <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>cidence of <strong>poverty</strong> exist between localities. Also, thewith<strong>in</strong>-governorate distribution of poor <strong>and</strong> rich localities varies markedly. The poorestlocalities <strong>in</strong> Egypt are predom<strong>in</strong>antly rural <strong>and</strong> are mostly located <strong>in</strong> Upper Egypt. Suhag isthe poorest governorate <strong>in</strong> Egypt, <strong>and</strong> it also comprises the poorest localities nationwide.7


These results suggest that the <strong>geographic</strong>al dimension of <strong>poverty</strong> should be carefullyconsidered when design<strong>in</strong>g public policies <strong>and</strong> <strong>poverty</strong> alleviation programs <strong>in</strong> Egypt.However, the analysis of this paper suffers from two ma<strong>in</strong> problems that often face anyregression model of spatial relation. One common problem is the existence of spatialautocorrelation, which is present when the dependent variable or the error term is correlatedacross clusters. Another problem is the heteroskedasticity (different variance across clusters)of the dependent variable (see M<strong>in</strong>ot et al. (2003) for details on how each of these problemsmanifests itself). The existence of these problems needs to be carefully <strong>in</strong>vestigated, <strong>and</strong>proper regression procedures that account for stratification <strong>and</strong> cluster<strong>in</strong>g should be applied.Hence, further <strong>poverty</strong> analysis research is needed <strong>in</strong> Egypt, particularly as household leveldata gets available, to produce more precise estimates of <strong>poverty</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>equality at the locallevel.6.Policy ImplicationThis study produces a f<strong>in</strong>ely detailed <strong>poverty</strong> map for Egypt, which goes substantially further<strong>in</strong> terms of <strong>geographic</strong> disaggregation than previously produced <strong>poverty</strong> estimates. Thepaper comb<strong>in</strong>es the full coverage of the 1996 Population Census <strong>and</strong> the detailed <strong>in</strong>formationon <strong>in</strong>come <strong>and</strong> expenditure provided from the 1999/2000 HIECS to estimate per capitaconsumption for all localities <strong>in</strong> Egypt. Results show that <strong>poverty</strong> is spatially distributed <strong>in</strong>Egypt. Substantial disparities <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>cidence of <strong>poverty</strong> exist between localities. Also, thewith<strong>in</strong>-governorate distribution of poor <strong>and</strong> rich localities varies markedly. The poorestlocalities <strong>in</strong> Egypt are predom<strong>in</strong>antly rural <strong>and</strong> are mostly located <strong>in</strong> Upper Egypt. Suhag isthe poorest governorate <strong>in</strong> Egypt, <strong>and</strong> it also comprises the poorest localities nationwide.Strategic <strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> of social assistance <strong>and</strong> safety net provisions is currently on the top of thepublic officials <strong>and</strong> policy makers agenda <strong>in</strong> Egypt. Maximiz<strong>in</strong>g the efficiency of <strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong>mechanisms was one of the primarily reasons of recently comb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the M<strong>in</strong>istry of SocialAffairs (MOSA) <strong>and</strong> M<strong>in</strong>istry of Supply (MOS) <strong>in</strong>to the M<strong>in</strong>istry of Social Solidarity (MSS).This merge is expected to more efficiently allow policy makers to pool together resources ofboth m<strong>in</strong>istries when formulat<strong>in</strong>g social assistance strategies for vulnerable groups. For<strong>in</strong>stance, the MOS used to apply a sort of universal non-targeted, or weakly targeted,mechanism to distribute <strong>in</strong>-k<strong>in</strong>d food subsidies through either ration-cards or subsidized<strong>in</strong>puts to bakeries. In contrast, the MOSA had a separate system through which f<strong>in</strong>ancialcash transfers were directly made to poor families. This system was ostensibly targeted to thevery poor by means of <strong>in</strong>formation gathered by locally-based social workers, but was verylimited <strong>in</strong> scope <strong>and</strong> provided very meager social support to the household it reached. Theobjective of the new M<strong>in</strong>istry of Social Solidarity is to more efficiently target the resourcesavailable for subsidies so that a large proportion reaches needy households—provid<strong>in</strong>g themwith a more effective safety net. The MSS is propos<strong>in</strong>g to use a comb<strong>in</strong>ation of <strong>geographic</strong><strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>and</strong> proxy means tests of <strong>in</strong>dividual households.The existence of substantial disparities <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>cidence of <strong>poverty</strong> between localities <strong>in</strong> Egyptmotivates the use of a <strong>geographic</strong> <strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> mechanism when design<strong>in</strong>g public policies <strong>and</strong><strong>poverty</strong> alleviation programs. Geographic <strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> of <strong>poverty</strong> alleviation programs has anumber of advantages over universal non-targeted or self-<strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> mechanisms <strong>and</strong> proxymeans<strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> approach. In a universal non-targeted program, resources (e.g. subsidies of<strong>in</strong>ferior goods) are transferred not only to the poor but also to the non-poor. Hence, despitethe low adm<strong>in</strong>istrative cost of a non-targeted program, the total program cost can be quitehigh to achieve the same amount of social protection.On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the proxy-mean approach is based on a set of basic household-level<strong>in</strong>formation (e.g. education levels, household structure, durable goods <strong>and</strong> access to services)8


comb<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong>to some sort of an <strong>in</strong>dex of social need. Though, the leakage rate of the proxymeanapproach is potentially lower than the non-targeted or self-targeted mechanism, itrequires high adm<strong>in</strong>istrative cost <strong>and</strong> expensive regular updates. Additionally, moral hazardaffects the quality of the reported <strong>in</strong>formation by the household. Under this approach,households have <strong>in</strong>centives to either change their behavior to qualify for a program/subsidyor misrepresent <strong>in</strong>formation about themselves <strong>in</strong> order to cont<strong>in</strong>ue be<strong>in</strong>g eligible for aprogram.In comparison to the universal non-targeted <strong>and</strong> the proxy-mean mechanisms, <strong>geographic</strong><strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> offers the potential for more efficient outcomes <strong>in</strong> terms of m<strong>in</strong>imiz<strong>in</strong>g leakagerates, adm<strong>in</strong>istrative costs, <strong>and</strong> under-coverage. Additionally, the moral hazard problem isnot an issue <strong>in</strong> a <strong>geographic</strong> <strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> mechanism, s<strong>in</strong>ce under this mechanism policy makerstarget a whole community—not a household. Thus, there would be no <strong>in</strong>centive for a s<strong>in</strong>glehousehold to change behavior or distort the data <strong>in</strong> order to qualify for a subsidy. However,there might exist an <strong>in</strong>centive to move to a targeted community to reach subsidized goods orservices. Also, <strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> one locality might <strong>in</strong>crease the sense of <strong>in</strong>equality of distribution ofgoods <strong>and</strong> services between neighbor<strong>in</strong>g communities.Therefore, <strong>in</strong> a develop<strong>in</strong>g country like Egypt where resources are limited, both leakage <strong>and</strong>under-coverage rates would be substantially m<strong>in</strong>imized by us<strong>in</strong>g a detailed <strong>geographic</strong>al<strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> mechanism as the one developed <strong>in</strong> this paper. Us<strong>in</strong>g such a <strong>poverty</strong> mapp<strong>in</strong>gmechanism would allow policy makers to easily compare <strong>poverty</strong> rates acrossdistricts/villages, identify localities with a high concentration of the poor, <strong>and</strong> underst<strong>and</strong> the<strong>geographic</strong> characteristics of areas that are fall<strong>in</strong>g beh<strong>in</strong>d. Nevertheless, the efficiency ofsuch <strong>geographic</strong> <strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> may be further improved if comb<strong>in</strong>ed with a mix of a self-<strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong>mechanism <strong>and</strong> proxy-mean approach (such as comb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>geographic</strong> <strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> withobservable characteristics of beneficiaries or poor communities). Such a mix of <strong>poverty</strong><strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> mechanisms would allow policy makers to tailor anti<strong>poverty</strong> programs resourcesmore effectively accord<strong>in</strong>g to local conditions <strong>and</strong> needs of the targeted areas.Thus, the allocation of resources <strong>in</strong> Egypt should be prioritized accord<strong>in</strong>g to the <strong>poverty</strong>mapp<strong>in</strong>g rank<strong>in</strong>gs. For <strong>in</strong>stance, based on the study results, the efficiency of <strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> wouldbe maximized if a largest share of anti-<strong>poverty</strong> programs resources is first allocated to thepoorest localities nationwide, which are <strong>in</strong> Suhag <strong>and</strong> Assiut. These <strong>poverty</strong> alleviationprograms may take many forms. A thorough exam<strong>in</strong>ation of the with<strong>in</strong>-governorate rank<strong>in</strong>gmap of Suhag reveals that the dark spots represent<strong>in</strong>g poor localities <strong>in</strong>crease the further wemove away from the governorate capital or center cities (Mad<strong>in</strong>et Suhag <strong>and</strong> Markaz Suhag),<strong>and</strong> the closer we get to the governorate borders (Dar al-Salam, Tima, Tahta, Guhayna <strong>and</strong>Al-Maragha districts). Thus, a potential <strong>poverty</strong> alleviation program could take the form ofreduc<strong>in</strong>g economic distance between these remote poor communities <strong>and</strong> the city centers; forexample, by allow<strong>in</strong>g a better access to the public services available <strong>in</strong> the city centers.Another <strong>poverty</strong> alleviation strategy could be allocat<strong>in</strong>g more <strong>in</strong>vestments to basic services<strong>and</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure accord<strong>in</strong>g to the needs of each community. The <strong>poverty</strong> map, developed <strong>in</strong>this study, could also be utilized to underst<strong>and</strong> the <strong>geographic</strong> distribution of those needs bymapp<strong>in</strong>g a mix of <strong>in</strong>dicators of locality characteristics. For <strong>in</strong>stance, compar<strong>in</strong>g the with<strong>in</strong>governoraterank<strong>in</strong>g map of Suhag <strong>and</strong> each of the with<strong>in</strong>-governorate rank<strong>in</strong>g of femaleilliteracy rate <strong>and</strong> household access to public water connection maps (Figure 6), it is clear thatthe poor communities tends to have higher rates of female illiteracy <strong>and</strong> lower access topublic water network. More specifically, once aga<strong>in</strong>, darker spots of high illiteracy rates <strong>and</strong>low access to water connection appear more concentrated the further we move away fromMarkaz/Mad<strong>in</strong>et Suhag, particularly <strong>in</strong> Dar al-Salam <strong>and</strong> the North-West border districts.9


Summ<strong>in</strong>g up, this discussion highlights that the efficiency of strategic <strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> may bemaximized if it is based on a detailed <strong>geographic</strong> <strong>target<strong>in</strong>g</strong> mechanism comb<strong>in</strong>ed with amechanism that carefully accounts for the characteristics of poor communities orbeneficiaries. Implement<strong>in</strong>g both mechanisms would be required—either one alone may notbe sufficient—to efficiently target the poor <strong>in</strong> Egypt.10


ReferencesAstrup, C. <strong>and</strong> S. Dessus. 2001. “Target<strong>in</strong>g the Poor Beyond Gaza or the West Bank: TheGeography of Poverty on the Palest<strong>in</strong>ian Territories,” ERF Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 0120.Bigman, D. <strong>and</strong> H. Fofack. 2000. Geographic Target<strong>in</strong>g for Poverty Alleviation:Methodology <strong>and</strong> Application. World Bank Regional <strong>and</strong> Sectoral Studies, Wash<strong>in</strong>gtonDC, USA.Deaton, A. 1997. The Analysis of Household Surveys: A Microeconometric Approach toDevelopment Policy. John Hopk<strong>in</strong>s University Press, Baltimore, MD.Datt, G.; <strong>and</strong> D. Jolliffe. 2005. “Poverty <strong>in</strong> Egypt: Model<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> Policy Simulations,”<strong>Economic</strong> Development <strong>and</strong> Cultural Change, Vol. 53(2): 327–346.Elbers, C., J. Lanjouw <strong>and</strong> P. Lanjouw. 2002. “Micro-Level Estimation of Welfare,” Policy<strong>Research</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g paper 2911. Development <strong>Research</strong> Group, World Bank, Wash<strong>in</strong>gon,DC.El-Leithy, H. <strong>and</strong> M. Osman. 1997. “Profile <strong>and</strong> Trend of Poverty <strong>and</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Growth <strong>in</strong>Egypt,” Egypt Human Development Report 1997. Institute of National Plann<strong>in</strong>g, Egypt.El-Laithy, H. <strong>and</strong> M. Loksh<strong>in</strong>. 2002. "<strong>Economic</strong> Growth <strong>and</strong> Poverty: Egypt 19995-2000,"Mimeo, Background Paper, June 2002.El-Laithy, H., M. Loksh<strong>in</strong> <strong>and</strong> A. Banerji. 2003. “Poverty <strong>and</strong> <strong>Economic</strong> Growth <strong>in</strong> Egypt,1995-2000,” Policy <strong>Research</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper #3068, The World Bank.Haddad, L. <strong>and</strong> A. Ahmed. 2003. “Chronic <strong>and</strong> Transitory Poverty: Evidence from Egypt,”World Development, Vol. 31(1): 71-86.Henn<strong>in</strong>ger, N. <strong>and</strong> M. Snel. 2002. Where are the poor? Experiences with the Development<strong>and</strong> Use of Poverty maps. World <strong>Research</strong> Institute, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton. D.C. <strong>and</strong> UNEP-GRID/Arendal, Arendal, Norway.Hentschel, J., J. Lanjouw, P. Lanjouw <strong>and</strong> J. Poggi. 2000. “Comb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Census <strong>and</strong> SurveyData to Trace the Spatial Dimension of Poverty: A Case Study of Ecuador,” World Bank<strong>Economic</strong> Review, Vol. 14(1): 147-165.M<strong>in</strong>ot, N. 2000. “Generat<strong>in</strong>g Disaggregate Poverty Maps: An Application to Vietnam,”World Development, Vol. 28(2): 319-331.M<strong>in</strong>ot, N. <strong>and</strong> B. Baulch. 2002. “The Spatial Distribution of Poverty <strong>in</strong> Vietnam <strong>and</strong> thePotential for Target<strong>in</strong>g,” Discussion Paper No. 42. Markets <strong>and</strong> Structural StudiesDivision, International Food Policy <strong>Research</strong> Institute, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton D.C.M<strong>in</strong>ot, N. <strong>and</strong> B. Baulch. 2005. “Poverty Mapp<strong>in</strong>g with Aggregate Census Data: What is theLoss <strong>in</strong> Precision?” Review of. Development <strong>Economic</strong>s, Vol. 9 (1), 5–25.M<strong>in</strong>ot, N., B. Baulch, <strong>and</strong> M. Epprecht. 2003. Poverty <strong>and</strong> Inequality <strong>in</strong> Vietnam: SpatialPatters <strong>and</strong> Geographic Determ<strong>in</strong>ants, International Food Policy <strong>Research</strong> Institute,Wash<strong>in</strong>gton D.C. <strong>and</strong> Institute of Development Studies, University of Sussex, UnitedK<strong>in</strong>gdom.11


Simler, K. <strong>and</strong> V. Nhate. 2003. Poverty , Inequality, <strong>and</strong> Geographic Target<strong>in</strong>g: Evidencefrom Small-area Estimations <strong>in</strong> Mozambique. International Food Policy <strong>Research</strong>Institute, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton DC, USA.Van de Walle, D. 1998. “Target<strong>in</strong>g Revisited,” The World bank <strong>Research</strong> Observer, Vol.13(2): 231-248.12


Figure 1 Distribution of village/shiakha predicted PCC <strong>in</strong> Egypt (national-rank<strong>in</strong>g)SharkiaFayoumBeni SuefAssiutSuhagQ<strong>in</strong>a13


Figure 2 Distribution of village/shiakha predicted PCC <strong>in</strong> SuhagNational-Rank<strong>in</strong>gGovernorate-Rank<strong>in</strong>gTimaTahtaGuhaynaMarkazSuhagMad<strong>in</strong>etSuhagAl-MaraghaDar al-Salam14


Figure 3 Distribution of village/shiakha predicted PCC <strong>in</strong> Dar-al-Salam district <strong>in</strong>SuhagNational-Rank<strong>in</strong>g15


Figure 4 Distribution of poorest 1000 <strong>and</strong> richest 1000 villages/shiakhas <strong>in</strong> Egypt bygovernorate, <strong>and</strong> their with<strong>in</strong>-governorate <strong>in</strong>cidenceaverage100%80%60%40%20%0%DumiatSuezCairoPort SaidAlex<strong>and</strong>riaIsmailiaNew ValleyKafr al-SheikhRed SeaKaliobiaAswanSouth S<strong>in</strong>aiGharbiaGizaTop 1000 Middle Bottom 100016


Figure 5 Distribution of predicted RPCC by governorate8000700060005000RPCC40003000200010000N =292Cairo50004000RPCC30002000N =13717978477516213223Alex<strong>and</strong>riaPort SaidSuezDumiatDakahliaSharkiaKaliobiaKafr al-Shaykh1000017


500040003000RPCC200010000N =347326469362132331693642595000GharbiaMenoufiaBehiraIsmailiaGizaBeni SuefFayoumM<strong>in</strong>yaAssiut4000RPCC30002000N =28619695221431427421SuhagQ<strong>in</strong>aAswanLuxorRed SeaNew ValleyMarsa MatrouhNorth S<strong>in</strong>aiSouth S<strong>in</strong>ai1000018


Figure 6 Distribution of village/shiakha female illiteracy rate <strong>and</strong> percent ofhouseholds with public water connection <strong>in</strong> SuhagFemale Female Illiteracy Illiteracy Rate RatePublic Public Water Water Connection Connection19


Table 1 Regression results of PSU-level log per capita consumption, us<strong>in</strong>g HIECS dataVariables Coefficient St<strong>and</strong>ard ErrorlgAvgHsz 0.553 0.922lgAvgHszSq -0.146 0.287pEldrlyMa 1.317 0.818pEldrlyFa 0.391 0.888pChilda 0.235 0.328pYoungsta -0.187 0.344pAdultFa 0.826 * 0.440RlDpRatioa -0.027 0.025UmpRatea -0.109 0.177PrmEnrRoM 0.204 ** 0.096PrmEnrRoF 0.026 0.092PIllt10Ma 0.032 0.218PIllt10Fa -0.109 0.146pUnivH18M -0.379 0.260pUnivH18F -0.196 0.263pWAgrPrM -0.569 *** 0.202pWContPrM -0.728 ** 0.313pLabor6t14M 0.230 0.214pLabor6t14F 0.248 0.340pHHYoung 9.684 7.408pHHPermF -0.016 0.195pEldrAlon 0.196 0.404pHHReadWr -0.043 0.176pHHPrimPr 0.140 0.218pHHSecond -0.083 0.186pHHAbvSec 0.010 0.290pHHUnivH 0.531 * 0.300pHHWAgrPr 0.474 * 0.277pHHWConPr 0.908 ** 0.410urb_rural 0.237 0.223Alex<strong>and</strong>ria 0.067 ** 0.034Port Said 0.235 *** 0.076Suways 0.296 *** 0.063Dumyat 0.416 * 0.239Daqahliyya 0.024 0.233Sharqiyya 0.001 0.229Qalyubiyya 0.232 0.231Kafr al-Shaykh 0.327 0.233Gharbiyya 0.207 0.231M<strong>in</strong>ufiyya 0.063 0.234Buhayra 0.213 0.228Ismailiyya 0.232 0.242Giza 0.112 0.231Bani Suwayf 0.035 0.240Fayyum 0.101 0.236M<strong>in</strong>ya 0.243 0.238Asyut -0.018 0.234Suhag -0.085 0.232Q<strong>in</strong>a 0.075 0.235Aswan 0.125 0.235Luxor 0.056 0.248Red Sea 0.308 0.27220


Table 1 Regression results of PSU-level log per capita consumption, us<strong>in</strong>g HIECS dataContd.Variables Coefficient St<strong>and</strong>ard ErrorWadi al-gadid 0.218 0.275Marsa Matruh 0.166 0.269Shimal S<strong>in</strong>a 0.133 0.284Ganub S<strong>in</strong>a 0.586 *** 0.160urb rural × Dumyat -0.247 0.242urb rural × Daqahliyya -0.077 0.232urb rural × Sharqiyya -0.269 0.228Urb rural × Qalyubiyya -0.258 0.231Urb rural × Kafr al-Shaykh -0.252 0.235Urb rural × Gharbiyya -0.201 0.230Urb rural × M<strong>in</strong>ufiyya -0.166 0.234Urb rural × Buhayra -0.276 0.230Urb rural × Ismailiyya -0.152 0.251Urb rural × Giza -0.258 0.229Urb rural × Bani Suwayf -0.186 0.239Urb rural × Fayyum -0.285 0.240Urb rural × M<strong>in</strong>ya -0.192 0.239Urb rural × Asyut -0.326 0.235Urb rural × Suhag -0.221 0.231Urb rural × Q<strong>in</strong>a -0.197 0.238Urb rural × Aswan -0.288 0.243Urb rural × Luxor -0.176 0.262Urb rural × Red Sea -0.147 0.307Urb rural × Wadi al-gadid -0.131 0.309Urb rural × Marsa Matruh -0.183 0.309Urb rural × Shimal S<strong>in</strong>a -0.173 0.320HHpersroom -0.085 0.060pRuralHH 0.000 0.057pUntradHH 0.321 1.536pRoomsHH 0.026 0.187pWaterPub -0.055 0.058pPrivKit 0.046 0.080pPrivToil 0.005 0.166pPrivBath 0.055 0.073pCar 0.409 ** 0.194pWashmach 0.097 0.131pFridge 0.206 * 0.114pFreeze 0.128 0.151pAC 0.077 0.175pColTV 0.075 0.170pBWTV 0.015 0.148pVCR 0.495 *** 0.119pDish 0.406 ** 0.224pPC 1.099 *** 0.293_cons 6.156 *** 0.86921


Table 2 Average predicted RPCC by governorateGovernoratesAverage predicted RPCCSouth S<strong>in</strong>ai 3224.48Port Said 2714.39Suez 2705.63Dumiat 2426.42Red Sea 2361.66Cairo 2309.63Alex<strong>and</strong>ria 2223.54Ismailia 2139.90New Valley 2058.57Giza 1874.42Kaliobia 1873.15Kafr al-Shaykh 1851.60Gharbia 1829.00North S<strong>in</strong>ai 1691.02Marsa Matrouh 1673.81Aswan 1642.54Luxor 1625.61Dakahlia 1621.66Behira 1621.38M<strong>in</strong>ya 1546.23Menoufia 1507.42Q<strong>in</strong>a 1456.54Sharkia 1437.49Beni Suef 1326.03Fayoum 1295.34Assiut 1185.41Suhag 1164.0722


Table 3 Distribution of the poorest 100, poorest 1000, <strong>and</strong> richest 1000 villages/shiakha<strong>in</strong> Egypt by governorateBottom 100 Bottom 1000 Top 1000Governorate% of% of% ofIncidence Category Incidence CategoryCategory totaltotaltotalSuhag 61% 258 25.8% 3 0.3%Assiut 28% 232 23.2% 1 0.1%Beni Suef 4% 146 14.6% 4 0.4%North S<strong>in</strong>ai 4% 32 3.2% 11 1.1%Marsa Matrouh 3% 9 0.9% 5 0.5%Fayoum 114 11.4% 3 0.3%Q<strong>in</strong>a 37 3.7% 7 0.7%M<strong>in</strong>ya 20 2.0% 17 1.7%Luxor 1 0.1%Sharkia 72 7.2% 8 0.8%Suez 9 0.9%Red Sea 10 1.0%Menoufia 24 2.4% 13 1.3%Port Said 16 1.6%New Valley 1 19 1.9%South S<strong>in</strong>ai 20 2.0%Ismailia 1 0.1% 24 2.4%Dakahlia 22 2.2% 25 2.5%Aswan 2 0.2% 28 2.8%Giza 19 1.9% 39 3.9%Behira 10 1.0% 41 4.1%Kaliobia 1 0.1% 69 6.9%Gharbia 73 7.3%Dumiat 77 7.7%Kafr al-Shaykh 103 10.3%Alex<strong>and</strong>ria 111 11.1%Cairo 263 26.3%% of urbanneighborhoods (shiakhas)3% 26 2.6% 619 61.9%Total 100% 1000 100% 1000 100%23


AppendixTable A1 Description of variables used <strong>in</strong> the regression analysisVariables Correlation Variable Variable DescriptionCoefficient Type1. lgAvgHsz -0.42 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Log of average household size2. lgAvgHszSq Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Log of average household size squared3. pEldrlyMa 0.33 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent Elderly males4. pEldrlyFa 0.17 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent Elderly females5. pChilda -0.61 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent children6. pYoungsta -0.57 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent Youngsters7. pAdultFa Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent adult females8. RlDpRatioa -0.46 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Real Dependency ratio9. UmpRatea 0.00 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Unemployment rate10. PrmEnrRoM 0.24 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Primary enrolment rate of males11. PrmEnrRoF 0.37 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Primary enrolment rate of females12. PIllt10Ma -0.51 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent illiterate males13. PIllt10Fa -0.69 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent illiterate females14. pUnivH18M 0.78 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent males with university education15. pUnivH18F 0.80 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent females with university education16. pWAgrPrM -0.47 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent male wage <strong>and</strong> unpaid family workers <strong>in</strong> agriculture <strong>in</strong> private sector17. pWContPrM -0.01 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent male wage employees <strong>in</strong> construction <strong>in</strong> private sector18. pLabor6t14M Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent male child/adolescent labor (6-14 years)19. pLabor6t14F Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent female child/adolescent labor (6-14 years)20. pHHYoung Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent children headed households (less than 15 years old)21. pHHPermF 0.21 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent permanent female headed households22. pEldrAlon 0.09 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent households with an elderly liv<strong>in</strong>g alone23. pHHReadWr 0.11 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household heads that can read & write24. pHHPrimPr Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household heads with primary education25. pHHSecond Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household heads with secondary education26. pHHAbvSec Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household heads with above secondary education27. pHHUnivH 0.78 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household heads with University or higher education28. pHHWAgrPr -0.38 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent of household heads wage employed <strong>in</strong> agriculture <strong>in</strong> private sector29. pHHWConPr -0.01 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent of household heads wage employed <strong>in</strong> construction <strong>in</strong> private sector30. HHpersroom -0.31 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Number of persons per room (density)31. pRuralHH -0.51 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent of rural type houses32. pUntradHH -0.03 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent of untraditional type houses33. pRoomsHH -0.22 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent of room-type houses34. pWaterPub 0.21 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household connected to public water network35. pPrivKit 0.49 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household with private kitchen36. pPrivToil 0.42 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household with private Toilet37. pPrivBath 0.48 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household with private bath38. pCar 0.76 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household with a car39. pWashmach 0.44 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household with a wash<strong>in</strong>g mach<strong>in</strong>e(Cont<strong>in</strong>ue)40. pFridge 0.64 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household with a refrigerator41. pFreeze 0.76 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household with a Freezer42. pAC 0.67 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household with an airconditioner43. pColTV 0.79 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household with a colored TV44. pBWTV -0.42 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent with a black & white TV45. pVCR 0.85 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household with a VCR46. pDish 0.61 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household with a satellite dish24


Table A1 Description of variables used <strong>in</strong> the regression analysis – Contd.Variables Correlation Variable Variable DescriptionCoefficient Type47. pPC 0.65 Cont<strong>in</strong>uous Percent household with a personal computer48. urb_rural 0.63 B<strong>in</strong>ary PSU <strong>in</strong> an urban area (rural = omitted category)49. GovernoratesB<strong>in</strong>ary 26 governorate dummies (Cairo= omited category)dummies50. urban <strong>and</strong>governoratedummies<strong>in</strong>teractionsB<strong>in</strong>ary Interaction terms of urb_rural <strong>and</strong> governorate dummy variablesTable A2 Estimated per-capita region-specific <strong>poverty</strong> l<strong>in</strong>es for 1999/2000RegionEstimated per-capitaGovernoratesregion-specific <strong>poverty</strong> l<strong>in</strong>esMetropolitan 1,109 Cairo, Alex<strong>and</strong>ria, Port Said, SuezLower Egypt Urban 1,015Lower Egypt Rural 978Upper Egypt Urban 1,031Upper Egypt Rural 964Frontier Urban 1,021Frontier Rural 1,049Dumiat, Dakhalia, Sharkia, Kalyoubia,Kafr El-Shaikh, Gharbia, Menoufia,Behera, IsmailaGiza, Beni-Suef, Fayoum, Menia,Assyout, Suhag, Quena, AswanRed Sea, New Valley, Matrouh, NorthS<strong>in</strong>ai, South S<strong>in</strong>aiSource: El-Laithy <strong>and</strong> Loksh<strong>in</strong> (2002)25

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!