13.07.2015 Views

The Impact of Direct Democracy on Society - Universität St.Gallen

The Impact of Direct Democracy on Society - Universität St.Gallen

The Impact of Direct Democracy on Society - Universität St.Gallen

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> <strong>Society</strong>D ISSERTATION<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>.<strong>Gallen</strong>Graduate School <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Business Administrati<strong>on</strong>,Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, Law and Social Sciences (HSG)to obtain the title <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Doctor <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omicssubmitted byJustina AnastasiaValerie FischerfromDeutschlandApproved <strong>on</strong> the applicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Dr. Gebhard KirchgässnerandPr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Dr. Sim<strong>on</strong> HugDissertati<strong>on</strong> no. 3074DIFO Druck OHG, Bamberg 2005


– 2 –<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>, Graduate School <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> BusinessAdministrati<strong>on</strong>, Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, Law and Social Sciences (HSG) herebyc<strong>on</strong>sents to the printing <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the present dissertati<strong>on</strong>, without herebyexpressing any opini<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the views herein expressed.<strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>, June 30, 2005<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> President:Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Ernst Mohr, PhD


– 3 –DanksagungDie Arbeit an der vorliegenden Dissertati<strong>on</strong> erfolgte v<strong>on</strong> April 2002 bis Mai 2005 alswissenschaftliche Mitarbeiterin und Assistentin am Institut für Aussenwirtschaft und AngewandteWirtschaftsforschung (SIAW) der Universität <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>.Bes<strong>on</strong>derer Dank gebührt meinem Erstbetreuer Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Dr. Gebhard Kirchgässner, der mir diesen<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>menkomplex erschlossen und mich zur wissenschaftlichen Exaktheit geführt hat.Mein Doktorvater lehrte mich die Tugend, durch wissenschaftlich umsichtiges und präzisesVorgehen Dinge und Fakten abzuwägen und durch Geduld und Ausdauer Klärungsprozessezuzulassen. Ferner vermittelte er mir den Wert der Unangreifbarkeit einer wohl durchdachtenArgumentati<strong>on</strong>skette, und er liess mir als wissenschaftlich Suchende grosse Freiheit, w<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ürich ihm sehr dankbar bin. Er war mir auch ein Vorbild in seiner persönlichen Arbeitsdisziplinund für das Einteilen v<strong>on</strong> geistigen und physischen Kräften. Trotz der selbstgewähltenerzieherischen Distanz v<strong>on</strong> Doktorvater zum Doktoranden vertraute Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Kirchgässner derQualität und dem <strong>St</strong>ehvermögen seines wissenschaftlichen Nachwuchses, indem er zuliessund förderte, im In- und Ausland Vorträge zu halten.Auch Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Dr. Sim<strong>on</strong> Hug möchte ich ganz herzlich dafür danken, dass er die Zweitbetreuungdieser Dissertati<strong>on</strong> übernommen hat, und vor allem dafür, dass er die Kreativität meinerGedankengänge schätzte und einzuordnen wusste. Mit Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Dr. Lars P. Feld verbinden micheine Ko-Autorenschaft und zahlreiche Diskussi<strong>on</strong>en über politische Realitäten in der Schweiz.Mein Dank gebührt ebenfalls PD Dr. Sousa-Poza, ohne dessen Initiative das gemeinsame Papierüber den Zusammenhang zwischen Demokratie und Glück nicht zustande gekommenwäre. In den engeren Kreis v<strong>on</strong> Wissenschaftlern, denen ich ebenfalls danke, möchte ich Dr.Alois <strong>St</strong>utzer und Dr. Markus Frölich aufnehmen, die mir in den verschiedenen <strong>St</strong>adien meinerDissertati<strong>on</strong> wertvolle Hinweise gegeben haben.Diese Arbeit hat auch v<strong>on</strong> Diskussi<strong>on</strong>en mit Teilnehmern v<strong>on</strong> zahlreichen K<strong>on</strong>ferenzen undSeminaren pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>itiert, auf denen ich Teile meiner Arbeit präsentieren durfte. Insbes<strong>on</strong>dereerwähnen möchte ich dabei die K<strong>on</strong>ferenzen der European Public Choice <strong>Society</strong> (2005), derAmerican Puiblic Choice <strong>Society</strong> (2005). der European Associati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Law and Ec<strong>on</strong>omics(2004), der American <strong>Society</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Criminology (2004), der European <strong>Society</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Criminology(2004), des Vereins für Sozialpolitik (2004), der Schweizerischen Gesellschaft für Volkswirtschaftund <strong>St</strong>atistik (2003 und 2004), und der Deutschen, Österreichischen und Schweizeri-


– 4 –schen Gesellschaften für Politische Wissenschaften (2003), sowie der beiden informellenAssistententreffen aus dem Frey-Kreis (2003 und 2005).Zu einer erfolgreichen Arbeit gehört auch eine angemessene work-life-balance. In diesemZusammenhang bin ich bes<strong>on</strong>ders dankbar für die moralische Unterstützung einiger Kolleginnenund Kollegen am SIAW sowie der Mitglieder des Frauennetworks 'Publicati<strong>on</strong> Network<strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>'.Ganz bes<strong>on</strong>derer Dank gebührt meinen Eltern und meiner Schwester, die meine Zukunftsplänestets tatkräftig unterstützt haben.<strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>, September 2005Justina A.V. Fischer


– 5 –Hilfsmittel<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> English language <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this dissertati<strong>on</strong>, except chapter IV,has been edited by Dr. Julia Angelica, Managing Editor, AcademicEdit.com.


– 6 –Table <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> C<strong>on</strong>tentsChapter I: Introducti<strong>on</strong>........................................................................................................... 91 Introducti<strong>on</strong>.................................................................................................................. 102 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>oretical and Empirical Background ....................................................................... 113 Switzerland as a Perfect Laboratory for Empirical Analysis ....................................... 174 <strong>St</strong>ructure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Dissertati<strong>on</strong>......................................................................................... 18Chapter II: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1997 – 2003 ......................................................................... 191 Introducti<strong>on</strong>.................................................................................................................. 202 C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al Changes between 1997 and 2003 ......................................................... 243 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Initiative ................................................................................................................ 283.1 C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al Initiative........................................................................................ 283.2 <strong>St</strong>atutory Initiative................................................................................................ 313.3 Comments <strong>on</strong> the Changes in C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al and <strong>St</strong>atutory Initiatives................ 344 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum ........................................................................................... 394.1 Mandatory <strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum........................................................................ 394.2 Comments <strong>on</strong> the Changes in the Mandatory <strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum.................. 444.3 Opti<strong>on</strong>al <strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum ........................................................................... 484.4 Comments <strong>on</strong> the Changes in the Opti<strong>on</strong>al <strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum ..................... 545 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fiscal Referendum ................................................................................................ 585.1 Mandatory Fiscal Referendum............................................................................. 585.2 Comments <strong>on</strong> the Changes in the Mandatory Fiscal Referendum ....................... 625.3. Opti<strong>on</strong>al Fiscal Referendum................................................................................. 655.4 Comments <strong>on</strong> the Changes in the Opti<strong>on</strong>al Fiscal Referendum........................... 706 Rec<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Index between 1997 and 2003 .................................................. 737 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> from 1997 to 2003 ................... 778 Brief Critique <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Index ........................................................................................... 809 Appendix ...................................................................................................................... 82Chapter III: Happiness.......................................................................................................... 831 Introducti<strong>on</strong>.................................................................................................................. 842 Previous Empirical Research for Switzerland.............................................................. 883 New Estimates for Switzerland.................................................................................... 90


– 7 –3.1 Cross secti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1992 and Balanced Panel 2000 – 2002...................................... 903.2 Results for Single Waves, 2000 – 2002 ............................................................. 1004 Summary and C<strong>on</strong>cluding Remarks........................................................................... 1065 Appendix .................................................................................................................... 107Chapter IV: Income Redistributi<strong>on</strong> ................................................................................... 1131 Introducti<strong>on</strong>................................................................................................................ 1142 Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy Models <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Income Redistributi<strong>on</strong>................................................ 1163 Empirical <strong>St</strong>udies <strong>on</strong> Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Income Redistributi<strong>on</strong> .............. 1204 Swiss Data <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Income Distributi<strong>on</strong> ...................................... 1255 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Welfare and Taxati<strong>on</strong>...................................... 1286 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> the Redistributi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> Income.......................... 1327 C<strong>on</strong>cluding Remarks.................................................................................................. 1368 Appendix .................................................................................................................... 139Chapter V: Public Safety..................................................................................................... 1411 Introducti<strong>on</strong>................................................................................................................ 1422 Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy and the Behavioral Ec<strong>on</strong>omic C<strong>on</strong>text:Derivati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Hypotheses........................................................................................ 1442.1. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Median Voter <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>orem............................................................................... 1442.2 Optimism Bias.................................................................................................... 1452.3 Debiasing <strong>St</strong>rategies........................................................................................... 1482.4 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Role <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Mass Media .................................................................................... 1492.4 Derivati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Empirically Testable Hypotheses ................................................ 1503 Model ......................................................................................................................... 1524 Data ............................................................................................................................ 1565 Empirical Results ....................................................................................................... 1585.1. <strong>St</strong>ructural Equati<strong>on</strong> I: Determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Police Expenditure............................... 1585.2 <strong>St</strong>ructural Equati<strong>on</strong> II: Determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Crime Rates ........................................ 1625.3 Reduced Form: Determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Crime ............................................................. 1695.4 Comparis<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Results for the Reduced and <strong>St</strong>ructural Forms .................... 1766 C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>.................................................................................................................. 1787 Appendix .................................................................................................................... 180Questi<strong>on</strong>naires.................................................................................................................... 194


– 8 –Chapter VI: Educati<strong>on</strong> ....................................................................................................... 2031 Introducti<strong>on</strong>................................................................................................................ 2042 Educati<strong>on</strong> Quality and <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> ................................................................. 2052.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> .............................................................................................. 2052.2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>oretical Background ..................................................................................... 2062.3 U.S. Empirical Evidence <strong>on</strong> Public Schooling................................................... 2082.4 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Educati<strong>on</strong>al Spending in Switzerland ........................... 2093 Data and Model .......................................................................................................... 2123.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Model: <strong>St</strong>ructural and Reduced Form......................................................... 2123.2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> .............................................................................................. 2143.3 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Data ............................................................................................................. 2143.4 Methodology ...................................................................................................... 2154 Estimati<strong>on</strong> Results for Reading.................................................................................. 2174.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> and OLS ............................................................................... 2174.2 Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> Results............................................................................... 2205 Estimati<strong>on</strong> Results for Mathematics and Natural Science ......................................... 2235.1 Results for Mathematics..................................................................................... 2245.2 Results for Natural Science ................................................................................ 2286 Comparis<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Results for Reading, Mathematics and Natural Science ............. 2337 C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>.................................................................................................................. 2348 Appendix: Reading..................................................................................................... 2379 Appendix: Mathematics ............................................................................................. 24510 Appendix: Natural Science ........................................................................................ 25311 Appendix: Descriptive <strong>St</strong>atistics ................................................................................ 262Chapter VII: C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> ..................................................................................................... 270References ............................................................................................................................. 274Curriculum Vitae ................................................................................................................. 300


– 9 –Chapter I:Introducti<strong>on</strong>


– 10 –1 Introducti<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> topic <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this dissertati<strong>on</strong>, as its title suggests, is the societal impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy,with a particular focus <strong>on</strong> Switzerland. This introductory chapter intends to shed light <strong>on</strong> thisissue by providing a brief general descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the theoretical and empirical background andthe general scientific approach the author intends to take. More issue-specific detail and indepthinformati<strong>on</strong> will be provided in the following chapters, each <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> which is dedicated to<strong>on</strong>e aspect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this research problem.'<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy', or more precisely, direct legislati<strong>on</strong>, implies the direct influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thepeople <strong>on</strong> the political decisi<strong>on</strong>-making process whose outcomes gain shape in both laws anddecrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the parliament. This influence means that a modern democracy, which takes placesolely through representative instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> political decisi<strong>on</strong>-making, is complemented bydirect-democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> decisive instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> are referenda andinitiatives, which in ec<strong>on</strong>omic theory are thought <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> as influencing the political outcome infavor <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the preferences <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the citizenry (FELD and KIRCHGÄSSNER, 2001, BESLEY and COATE2001).'Societal impact' is a broad term that seemingly allows a huge scope <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> possible issues foranalysis. To investigate this impact, I will use the so-called social indicators that can, <strong>on</strong> the<strong>on</strong>e hand, be objectively measured but that, <strong>on</strong> the other hand, go bey<strong>on</strong>d the meremeasurement <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> financial or m<strong>on</strong>etary aspects. Fortunately, these indicators must andtherefore will be limited to those linked to public goods whose financial base for provisi<strong>on</strong> isdirectly affected by instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> 1 . This approach narrows the field <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>societal impact c<strong>on</strong>siderably, in this case to the following indicators: subjective well-being <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>residents, public safety, income redistributi<strong>on</strong>, and educati<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> approach <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this dissertati<strong>on</strong> is empirical and employs ec<strong>on</strong>ometric methods <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> analysis.Such systematic methods have the advantage that the resultant scientific findings will be validin a general sense, i.e. they will not be driven by single observati<strong>on</strong>s (statistical outliers) asmight occur if a purely verbal-descriptive case study approach were chosen.1 In the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Switzerland, these are typically those public goods provided by Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s in fields that enjoya high degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> political and financial aut<strong>on</strong>omy (see also the discussi<strong>on</strong> in chapter VI <strong>on</strong> educati<strong>on</strong>). Suchfields are especially police, educati<strong>on</strong>, culture, and welfare.


– 11 –2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>oretical and Empirical BackgroundAccording to some strands <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic theory, in a representative system, resources arewasted and allocati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> goods and resources occur that deviate str<strong>on</strong>gly from the medianvoter's positi<strong>on</strong>. On the <strong>on</strong>e hand, overspending is caused by (a) politicians who exploit thebudget (and implicitly the tax base) to satisfy the needs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the electorate in their local districts('pork-barrel legislati<strong>on</strong>') 2 ; (b) the forming <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> broad coaliti<strong>on</strong> governments that leads to aninefficient expansi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> budgets by the spending ministers ('budget as a comm<strong>on</strong> pool') 3 ; or(c) logrolling in the political decisi<strong>on</strong>-making process, which brings about the financing <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>minority projects that would otherwise not have gained support from the parliamentarymajority 4 . Moreover, (d) government administrati<strong>on</strong>s are headed by bureaucrats who aim atmaximizing their budget and extracting rents, which might lead to a preference for thoseexpenditure projects that also cause an increase in administrative spending (e.g. through thefoundati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> new departments, etc.) 5 . If the administrative budget is c<strong>on</strong>strained, bureaucratsare thought to aim at increasing their pers<strong>on</strong>al administrative staff at the expenses <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theresources available for carrying out their duties related to producti<strong>on</strong> as prescribed by law 6 .Whatever the case, according to these theoretical arguments in a purely representative system,expenses are undertaken that are not preferred by the median voter, leading possibly to anunwanted growth in budget, the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public goods that are not the first priority for orare supplied in a way undesirable to the median voter, or a deteriorating quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the publicgood due to fewer means available for its provisi<strong>on</strong>.Nevertheless, direct democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s, many <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their supporters argue, can serve asmeans to discipline the behavior <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> politicians and bureaucrats. Using a model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> politicalec<strong>on</strong>omy, FELD and KIRCHGÄSSNER (2001) show that the mere existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> such instituti<strong>on</strong>s(playing the role <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a 'credible threat') leads to an allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> good and resources that iscloser to the median voter's preferences than otherwise 7 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, three characteristics2 According to WEINGAST, SHEPSLE and JOHNSEN (1981), this leads to a preference <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> projects in districts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thewinning party at the expense <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> those <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the loosing party. See also TULLLOCK (1959).3 See ROUBINI and SACHS (1989), DE HAAN and STURM (1997), KONTOPOULOS and PEROTTI (1999), orVOLKERINK and DE HAAN (2001). See FELD et al., 2003 for an empirical test with Swiss data.4 See also BESLEY and COATE (1997, 1998) <strong>on</strong> inefficiencies in representative democracies, particularly throughallowing the politicians to pursue their own goals between electi<strong>on</strong>s and the activities <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest groups. Inadditi<strong>on</strong>, see BESLEY and COATE (2001) <strong>on</strong> the role <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> initiatives to break up bundling <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> projects.5 See NISKANEN (1975). See also BESLEY and COATE (2003) for representatives aiding bureaucrats to seek rents.6 See WILLIAMSON (1964).7 Deviati<strong>on</strong> from the desired allocati<strong>on</strong> could also be caused by the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> informati<strong>on</strong> asymmetry betweenpoliticians and citizens (KESSLER 2001), which might also be mitigated through the existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>


– 12 –should be expected in direct democracies: first, less m<strong>on</strong>ey is wasted <strong>on</strong> undesired projectsbecause voters veto them through fiscal referenda and initiatives 8 ; sec<strong>on</strong>d, governmentalbudgets should be smaller than in less direct democratic systems because fewer financialprojects and laws triggering new expenses are approved by the electorate if voters are fiscallyc<strong>on</strong>servative 9 ; and third, public goods might be provided more efficiently as bureaucrats'discreti<strong>on</strong>ary power is also limited 10 . Smaller governmental budgets should in turn bringabout lower income and/or property tax rates, thereby relaxing the individual's budgetc<strong>on</strong>straint in c<strong>on</strong>trast to those <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> voters living in a more representative democratic system. Inadditi<strong>on</strong>, because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the resulting increase in individual utility, pers<strong>on</strong>s living in a system withstr<strong>on</strong>g direct democracy should experience a higher level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> well-being than those livingunder a purely representative political regime 11 .In fact, empirical evidence already partly corroborates most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these c<strong>on</strong>jectures. In general,an allocati<strong>on</strong> closer to the median voters' preferences in direct democracies is observed byPOMMEREHNE (1978) for Switzerland 12 and MATSUSAKA (2000) for the U.S.A. 13 . As regardsthe budgetary and cost-reducing impacts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong>, several studies based <strong>on</strong> typicalpublic finance models for expenditure regressi<strong>on</strong>s show a spending and revenue loweringimpact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> combined cant<strong>on</strong>al and subfederal budgets, and anaccumulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> less debt per capita in Swiss municipalities with str<strong>on</strong>ger direct democraticdirect legislati<strong>on</strong>. For a discussi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest groups, as well as why a mitigati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>informati<strong>on</strong> asymmetry might take place in the Swiss political system particularly, see FELD andKIRCHGÄSSNER (2001) and KIRCHGÄSSNER (2000). A c<strong>on</strong>trasting view <strong>on</strong> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> logrolling <strong>on</strong> theproducti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public goods is presented in BRETON (1996). He argues that in direct democracies aninefficiently low level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> provisi<strong>on</strong> might be achieved because referenda <strong>on</strong> single projects prevent gains fromvote trading. A str<strong>on</strong>g counterargument can be found in FELD and KIRCHGÄSSNER (1998).8 For theoretical arguments, see BESLEY and COATE 1998, 2001, 2003; see also particularly chapter IV <strong>on</strong>redistributi<strong>on</strong>.9 For theoretical arguments, see FELD and KIRCHGÄSSNER, 2001, and the discussi<strong>on</strong> in chapters IV and VI.10 See the discussi<strong>on</strong> in chapter VI <strong>on</strong> educati<strong>on</strong> and the references therein.11 See the various papers by FREY and STUTZER discussed in chapter III <strong>on</strong> happiness.12 As method, he compared the performance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an 'average voter' model with a 'median voter' model to explainlevels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public expenditure for various subsamples grouped by the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> higherthe degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong>, the better the explanatory power <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the median voter variables. For additi<strong>on</strong>alsupporting findings, see also GERBER (1996, 1999).13 See also FELD and KIRCHGÄSSNER (1998) for further references. Moreover, SCHALTEGGER and FELD (2001)show that str<strong>on</strong>ger instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy (fiscal referenda) lead to a lower degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> centralizati<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> expenses at the supra-local level. According to TIEBOUT (1956), decentralizati<strong>on</strong> brings about a moreefficient allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> goods and resources and a producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> goods which is closer to the citizens'preferences. Hence, direct democracy might lead to efficiency gains via decentralizati<strong>on</strong> as transmissi<strong>on</strong>channel. This c<strong>on</strong>jecture is supported by findings <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> FREY and STUTZER (2000, p. 928).


– 13 –rights 14 . Similar empirical results have been obtained for the United <strong>St</strong>ates 15 . As regards thecost-reducing impact, POMMEREHNE (1983) reveals that instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracydecrease the costs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> garbage collecti<strong>on</strong> in Swiss municipalities. Further, and possibly as aresult, FELD et al. (2003) show that income tax and property tax rates are lower in more directdemocratic cant<strong>on</strong>s 16 . In additi<strong>on</strong>, FELD and SAVIOZ (1997) observe that GDP per capita isalso greater in such cant<strong>on</strong>s in Switzerland 17 . Given these results, the c<strong>on</strong>jecture <strong>on</strong> thebudgetary impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> can be viewed as supported. A general corroborati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the shift <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> policy outcomes to the median voter positi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> n<strong>on</strong>budgetary issues like parentalc<strong>on</strong>sent laws and capital punishment is observed by GERBER for the U.S. (1996, 1999). Yet,given the spending dampening effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> budgets, how are public goodsaffected by direct legislati<strong>on</strong>? 18 First, FELD and MATSUSAKA (2000), together withMATSUSAKA (1995a), discover that in direct democracies a str<strong>on</strong>ger reliance <strong>on</strong> user chargesexists that should make the quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the public good more independent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the financialresources (tax revenue) <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al government 19 . Sec<strong>on</strong>d, as menti<strong>on</strong>ed above, efficiencygains in the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a particular good are observed by POMMEREHNE (1983). Similarly,the findings presented in KIRCHGÄSSNER and HAUSER (2001) can be viewed as evidence thatcost savings (induced through the fiscal referendum) occur rather in the expenditure foradministrati<strong>on</strong> than in the financial resources available for the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public goods.14 See e.g. FELD and KIRCHGÄSSNER (2001) for the effect <strong>on</strong> cant<strong>on</strong>al and local revenue, expenditures and debt;FELD and KIRCHGÄSSNER (1999) for Swiss municipalities; FELD and MATSUSAKA (2003) <strong>on</strong> expenditure;KIRCHGÄSSNER and HAUSER (2001) <strong>on</strong> expenditure for administrati<strong>on</strong>; SCHALTEGGER (2001) for impact <strong>on</strong>various subfederal budget comp<strong>on</strong>ents; POMMEREHNE (1978) for Swiss municipalities; SCHNEIDER andPOMMEREHNE (1983) <strong>on</strong> expenditure growth in Swiss municipalities, to name the most importantc<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s. An (incomplete but informative) overview can be found in FELD and KIRCHGÄSSNER 2000. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>expenditure dampening impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s can be seen as evidence that "legislatures tendto spend much more than the median voter wants" (see FELD and MATSUSAKA, 2003, p. 2722). For evidence<strong>on</strong> the fiscal c<strong>on</strong>servatism <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> voters in the U.S., see PELTZMAN (1992).15 See e.g. MATSUSAKA (1995a), KIEWIET and SZAKALY (1996), RUEBEN (1997), HOLCOMBE (1980) for U.S.states, and the work by SHADBEGIAN for local districts with TELs (see also the references in chapter VI). Seealso an overview in KIRCHGÄSSNER et al. (1999).16 In additi<strong>on</strong>, the studies by POMMEREHNE and WECK-HANNEMANN (1996, 1989) reveal also a lower level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>tax evasi<strong>on</strong> (see next secti<strong>on</strong> for discussi<strong>on</strong>). A decentralizing impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> tax revenue,income, and property tax revenues in particular, was detected in SCHALTEGGER and FELD (2001), i.e. in directdemocratic cant<strong>on</strong>s tax collecti<strong>on</strong> occurs more at the local level.17 See also FREITAG and VATTER (2000) for similar results, who find rather the use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directlegislati<strong>on</strong> than their mere existence to be an important determinant.18 Lower spending al<strong>on</strong>e is not a valid indicator <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> efficiency gains; it might be caused by inefficiencies throughinsufficient vote trading in the political decisi<strong>on</strong>-making process (see BRETON, 1996).19 See also POMMEREHNE (1978, 1983) and FELD and MATSUSAKA (1999).


– 14 –Given these results, public goods do not appear to be negatively affected by the lowerspending in more direct democratic political systems 20 .As argued earlier, because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> all these detected impacts to the advantage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the citizens, autility increasing effect can be expected. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> works by FREY and STUTZER (2000, 2002) findempirical evidence in line with this c<strong>on</strong>jecture using a cross secti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1992 data (LEU et al.,1997). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se authors show first that direct democracy appears to lead to an increase in socalledoutcome utility, which means happiness achieved through the resulting allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>goods and resources. Moreover, they also reveal that the major part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the increase in lifesatisfacti<strong>on</strong> can be attributed to so-called procedural utility, i.e. satisfacti<strong>on</strong> gained throughmere participati<strong>on</strong> in the political process. A corroborati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the positive utility impact fromanother perspective might be deduced from the literature <strong>on</strong> tax evasi<strong>on</strong>: In more directdemocratic cant<strong>on</strong>s, significantly less tax evasi<strong>on</strong> occurs than in more representativedemocratic cant<strong>on</strong>s, as the studies by POMMEREHNE and WECK-HANNEMANN suggest (1989,1996) 21 . This finding could be viewed as an indicator <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax payers withthe policy-making carried out by their governments and administrati<strong>on</strong>s.So far, literature speaking in favor <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy has been examined.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are, however, also some theoretical and a few empirical studies 22 which shed light <strong>on</strong>its potential negative aspects which should not be neglected. Some <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these arguments whichfollow have already been alluded to in the previous paragraphs. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se counter-arguments canbe grouped under the heading ‘cost aspect’, ‘interest groups’ and ‘political decisi<strong>on</strong>-making’.As regards the costs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> decisi<strong>on</strong>-making in direct democratic political systems, someec<strong>on</strong>omists suggest that a representative political system has an advantage over a directdemocracy because it saves informati<strong>on</strong> costs and pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>its from efficiency gains through thedivisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> labor between specialized politicians and the electorate (FELD and KIRCHGÄSSNER,2003). Furthermore, the negative sides <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> are also shown in a more specifictheoretical model by MATSUSAKA and MCCARTY (2001) with includes a voter, arepresentative, preference uncertainty and costly initiatives. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> authors' model suggests that20 A detrimental impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> health (infant mortality rate) and educati<strong>on</strong> (share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pupils withmaturité/Matura) going bey<strong>on</strong>d a budgetary <strong>on</strong>e is found by BARANKAY (2002). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se results, however,might suffer from misspecificati<strong>on</strong> as important fiscal and political determinants are missing in his model.21 See also more recent analyses by FELD and FREY (2001, 2002).22 Informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> some empirical studies is provided in the footnotes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this secti<strong>on</strong>.


– 15 –under specific circumstances the voter would be better <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>f without an initiative than with sucha means <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong>. Other costs involved with direct democratic decisi<strong>on</strong>-making arethe costs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> signature collecti<strong>on</strong> for initiatives or opti<strong>on</strong>al referenda. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> higher the signaturerequirement is, that is the higher the costs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> using this instituti<strong>on</strong> are, the less str<strong>on</strong>g itscorrecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the political outcome will be. In line with this argument, a too high signaturerequirement will <strong>on</strong>ly induce costs to the voter without the general beneficial correcti<strong>on</strong>alimpact (see FELD and KIRCHGÄSSNER, 2003, and the references therein). Another costargument is provided by GRILLO (1997), who argues that given a substantially large size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the electorate, the decisi<strong>on</strong>-making, informati<strong>on</strong> and organizati<strong>on</strong>al costs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a directdemocratic system would outweigh its benefits. 23In additi<strong>on</strong>, a comm<strong>on</strong> critique is that in direct democracies there is an increased influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>even small, but well-organized interest groups <strong>on</strong> the political decisi<strong>on</strong>-making process and itsoutcome (see KIRCHGÄSSNER et al., 1999, p.20). Already during the parliamentary process <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>law-making the threat <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> taking the opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum - so the argument - is utilized bythese groups to blackmail politicians. 24 In a theoretical model, (MATSUSAKA and MCCARTY,2001) have shown that, when informati<strong>on</strong> is imperfect and asymmetric, it becomes easy forsuch groups to abuse these instituti<strong>on</strong>s. Hence, an allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> goods and resources far awayfrom the median voter's positi<strong>on</strong> is induced. 25Another group <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> arguments relates to the prerequisites <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a participati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the electorate indirect democracies such that an allocati<strong>on</strong> which is beneficial to society can be achieved. Onthe <strong>on</strong>e hand, if voting took place purely for reas<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> expressi<strong>on</strong> (BRENNAN and LOMASKY,1993), the closeness <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the political outcome to the median voter's preferences would bejeopardized (BRENNAN and HAMLIN, 2000). In such model, a representative political system isshown to mitigate these causes for misallocati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> goods and resources. Related to this23 For counter-arguments, see KIRCHGÄSSNER et al., 1999, p. 33, and the references therein. Particularly, moderntechnology should decrease such costs.24 C<strong>on</strong>sequently, BORNER et al. (1994, p. 129) call for a restricti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the referendum. In additi<strong>on</strong>, they alsosuspect that the threat <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> taking the referendum serves as device to facilitate rent-seeking (ibid., p. 26 c<strong>on</strong>t.).25 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is evidence by LASCHER et al. (1996) and CAMOBRECCO (1998) that government policy is not closer tothe median voters' preferences in US states with initiatives. In MATSUSAKA (2001), however, it was shownthat their results could be driven by misspecificati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their empirical model. Evidence for an existing impact<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest groups was found by ZISK (1987, p. 90 c<strong>on</strong>t.) for the US and SCHNEIDER (1985) for Switzerland.Counter-arguments based <strong>on</strong> casual observati<strong>on</strong>s and further empirical literature supporting either side isgiven in KIRCHGÄSSNER et al., 1999, pp. 25 c<strong>on</strong>t. A general counter-argument is that the influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interestgroups exists also in representative political systems, but is more transparent in direct democracies(KIRCHGÄSSNER et al., 1999, p. 30).


– 16 –aspect is the critique that citizens in direct democracies have no incentives to make wellinformeddecisi<strong>on</strong>s because the costs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> informati<strong>on</strong> gathering are higher than the expectedbenefit (cf. DOWNS, 1957), which is particularly crucial for opti<strong>on</strong>al elements <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directlegislati<strong>on</strong> (see KIRCHGÄSSNER et al., 1999, p.20 and p.47 c<strong>on</strong>t.). 26 Moreover, in an ec<strong>on</strong>omicmodel, MARINO and MATSUSAKA (2005) show that politicians have an incentive to supplybiased informati<strong>on</strong> to the citizenry in a world <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> partial delegati<strong>on</strong>, as takes place in directdemocracies, in order to prevent initiative- or referendum- induced budget cuts. 27 Anotherargument against direct democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s, particularly referenda, is that they slow downthe political decisi<strong>on</strong>-making process which makes this political system unable to react fast toec<strong>on</strong>omic or societal changes (see KIRCHGÄSSNER et al., 1999, p.20). This leads to what iscalled a ‘<strong>St</strong>atus Quo bias’. 28 Moreover, BRETON (1996) suggests that instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directlegislati<strong>on</strong> prevent gains from logrolling, which implies vote trading, leading to a level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public goods which is below the societally optimal level 29 . Finally, a relatedaspect is that means <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> prevent binding compromises necessary for reachinginternati<strong>on</strong>al agreements. 30My own c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to these societal aspects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> influences <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy will betw<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>old: first, after updating the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy for the relevant time span, theanalysis will use the new data to reinvestigate the happiness aspect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy; andsec<strong>on</strong>d, the analysis will address some new transmissi<strong>on</strong> channels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy’sinfluence <strong>on</strong> well-being, channels that are different from those menti<strong>on</strong>ed above. Specifically,I will examine the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the public goods <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income redistributi<strong>on</strong>,public safety, and educati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se empirical analyses will be carried out using Swisscant<strong>on</strong>al data. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> next secti<strong>on</strong> briefly summarizes why Switzerland is an appropriate countryfor studying such effects.26 A similar argument is that a direct democracy requires a higher level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> civic engagement than a representativepolitical system, and a rati<strong>on</strong>al individual should not be expected to show such a level. For systematic andcasual empirical counter-evidence against both arguments, see KIRCHGÄSSNER et al., 1999, pp. 53-68.27 See also related empirical evidence for the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public goods in districts with an override opti<strong>on</strong> in theUnited <strong>St</strong>ates, described in chapter VI.28 For counter-arguments and instituti<strong>on</strong>al soluti<strong>on</strong>s to this problem at the Swiss federal level (seeKIRCHGÄSSNER et al., 1999, pp. 21 c<strong>on</strong>t.). Particularly initiatives serve to ‘accelerate’ the political process.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>atus Quo bias might also be positively interpreted as a higher degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>tinuity and countability inpolicy-making (KIRCHGÄSSNER et al., 1999, p. 24).29 See also footnote 7. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> paper by BARANKAY (2002) might serve as supportive empirical evidence.30 For counter-arguments, see KIRCHGÄSSNER et al., 1999, p. 33, and the references therein.


– 17 –3 Switzerland as a Perfect Laboratory for Empirical AnalysisFew countries in the world <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fer direct-legislative opportunities to their people, particularlythe opportunity to influence the daily political decisi<strong>on</strong>-making processes. Basically, <strong>on</strong>ly tw<strong>on</strong>ati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fer an extensive range <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> such direct-democratic means: the United <strong>St</strong>ates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>America and Switzerland 31 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> political system <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Switzerland is shaped by two importantcharacteristics. First, in this federal country, direct legislative instituti<strong>on</strong>s exist <strong>on</strong> all threelevels – i.e. the federal level, the cant<strong>on</strong>al ('state') level, and the communal level. Sec<strong>on</strong>d,Switzerland shows a very str<strong>on</strong>g fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong>, which, in c<strong>on</strong>trast to Austria andGermany, gives each level in the state its own tax sources. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, a direct instituti<strong>on</strong>allink exists between the power to tax and the direct-legislative instituti<strong>on</strong>s that provide localcitizens with the political means to influence both sides <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the budget equally.Thus, Switzerland can be viewed as a perfect laboratory for studying the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy <strong>on</strong> political outcomes (see also e.g. KIRCHGÄSSNER, 2002, 2000): each cant<strong>on</strong> – orat the communal level, each commune – can be viewed as <strong>on</strong>e observati<strong>on</strong> with a varyingdegree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy laid down in its c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>. All the cant<strong>on</strong>s and communes,however, share an identical macroec<strong>on</strong>omic and political framework at a higher level, so thatsome difficulties arising in a cross-nati<strong>on</strong>al comparis<strong>on</strong> can be avoided. This comm<strong>on</strong>framework is shaped by both policy at the federal level, internati<strong>on</strong>al politics, and theec<strong>on</strong>omic situati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the rest <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the world.At the cant<strong>on</strong>al level, there exist two direct-legislative instituti<strong>on</strong>s that are <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> particularinterest because they greatly affect the daily piecemeal works <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> politics: the fiscalreferendum 32 and the statutory initiative (see FREY and STUTZER, 2000; see the review byKIRCHGÄSSNER 2002 for fiscal aspects). Whereas the fiscal referendum is <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a reactive nature,the statutory initiative provides citizens with an agenda-setting power. Another differencebetween these instituti<strong>on</strong>s is their focus: the fiscal referendum deals with expenditure projects<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al government – i.e. it is related more to decrees and by-laws; in c<strong>on</strong>trast, thestatutory initiative directly influences the law-making process – i.e. it is either used for31 In many other countries, however, such as Canada, Austria, Liechtenstein, Italy, Ireland, and France, a popularvote must <strong>on</strong>ly be held <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al amendments.32 An 'opti<strong>on</strong>al' fiscal referendum can be distinguished from a 'mandatory' <strong>on</strong>e. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y differ with respect to theexpenditure threshold and the signature requirement, which must be met in the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the latter. (See alsochapter II).


– 18 –placing new (proposed) laws <strong>on</strong> the political agenda or for revising or eliminating alreadyexisting laws 33 . Other important instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> are the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>alinitiative and the statutory referendum 34 . Chapter II <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this dissertati<strong>on</strong> describes in moredetail the form that these four instituti<strong>on</strong>s take in the 26 cant<strong>on</strong>s, how they have changed overrecent years, and how they can be used to c<strong>on</strong>struct a measure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy for use inthe subsequent analyses.4 <strong>St</strong>ructure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Dissertati<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> rest <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this dissertati<strong>on</strong> is organized as follows. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sec<strong>on</strong>d chapter outlines and discussesin detail the development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> important instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> between 1997 and2003. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> goal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this chapter is to provide a basis for an update <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the composite index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>direct democracy, which became necessary to carry out the empirical analyses presented inthe subsequent chapters. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> third chapter presents an analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy <strong>on</strong> individual well-being using a cross secti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1992 data and Swiss HouseholdPanel data from 2000 to 2002. Chapter IV analyzes the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> theefficiency <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> redistributi<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> fifth chapter is dedicated to the questi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> how directlegislati<strong>on</strong> affects levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> property crime, hate crime, and sexual <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenses. Chapter VIpresents an investigati<strong>on</strong> into the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> educati<strong>on</strong>al quality asmeasured by PISA-like test scores. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se empirical chapters are structured like scientificpapers and have already been presented as separate papers at various c<strong>on</strong>ferences; for thisreas<strong>on</strong> the reader might find some overlapping in the arguments presented. Finally, chapterVII c<strong>on</strong>cludes with a short summary and evaluati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the findings <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this dissertati<strong>on</strong>.33 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative aims at changing, eliminating, or adding a new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al law. Usually, therequirements for this initiative are the same as those for the statutory <strong>on</strong>e, so that in ec<strong>on</strong>ometric analyses theimpact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the two cannot be distinguished. See also chapter II.34 In some cant<strong>on</strong>s, even more specialized forms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> referenda exist, such as those <strong>on</strong> highway expenditure orinternati<strong>on</strong>al treaties. See chapter II and TRECHSEL and SERDÜLT (1999) for more informati<strong>on</strong>.


– 19 –Chapter II:<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1997 – 2003


– 20 –1 Introducti<strong>on</strong>This chapter describes the changes in direct democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s that occurred in the 26Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s between 1997 and 2003. In general, instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy areinitiatives and referenda that are usually regulated in c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al stipulati<strong>on</strong>s. This secti<strong>on</strong>c<strong>on</strong>tains a brief introducti<strong>on</strong> to these instruments <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy and a descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theso-called index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy that measures the strength <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these instituti<strong>on</strong>s at thecant<strong>on</strong>al level in Switzerland.On the <strong>on</strong>e hand, initiatives c<strong>on</strong>stitute an element <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> active electoral participati<strong>on</strong> in thepolitical decisi<strong>on</strong>-making process. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y allow the electorate to place a proposal for a law orc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al change <strong>on</strong> the political agenda. Accordingly, we speak <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a statutory initiativefor altering laws and a c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative for a c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al amendment. InSwitzerland, any revisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> must be approved by the electorate, i.e.it directly brings about a popular vote, as stipulated in the nati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> (art. 51, lSwiss C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> (SC)). In case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an initiative that refers to a cant<strong>on</strong>al law, a popular votemust usually take place if the cant<strong>on</strong>al parliament makes a counterproposal, and <strong>on</strong>ly in somecant<strong>on</strong>s does a popular vote generally follow an initiative (i.e. without a counterproposal).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> requirement for any type <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> initiative is that a specific number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> signatures is to becollected from am<strong>on</strong>g the electorate, and it is not uncomm<strong>on</strong> for the signature requirement toincrease proporti<strong>on</strong>ally to the importance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the legislative act to which the initiative pertains(e.g. law, partial revisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, total revisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>).Referenda, <strong>on</strong> the other hand, c<strong>on</strong>stitute a reactive element <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> because theycan <strong>on</strong>ly take the form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a reacti<strong>on</strong> to preceding activities <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the legislative body. Referendaat the cant<strong>on</strong>al level are, in general, applicable to laws, decrees, internati<strong>on</strong>al andintercant<strong>on</strong>al treaties (c<strong>on</strong>cordats), and fiscal issues such as expenditure projects.Accordingly, we speak <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a so-called statutory referendum for laws, decrees and by-laws(Gesetzesreferendum), an administrative referendum for administrative acts3535 An administrative act is not necessarily a decisi<strong>on</strong> made by an administrati<strong>on</strong>; the distincti<strong>on</strong> between anadministrative and a legislative act lies in the scope <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> applicability. In Switzerland, nomothetic acts aredefined as acts always referring to the regulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> either obligati<strong>on</strong> or rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pers<strong>on</strong>s, organizati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thestate or duties and processes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> administrati<strong>on</strong>s. Furthermore, administrative acts are not directly linked t<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inancial expenses. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> wording in the various cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s related to legislative and administrativeacts is not c<strong>on</strong>sistent between Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s. Administrative referenda are very difficult to identify as in manycant<strong>on</strong>s administrative acts take the form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a legislative act. On the other hand, there is also an almostunmanageable variety <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal forms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> legislative acts (see TRECHSEL and SERDÜLT 1999, pp. 14-15 and p.31).


– 21 –(Verwaltungsreferendum), a referendum for treaties (<strong>St</strong>aatsvertragsreferendum), and thefiscal referendum (Finanzreferendum). In theory, all referenda could exist in both amandatory and opti<strong>on</strong>al form: a mandatory referendum triggers a popular vote automaticallyfollowing a decisi<strong>on</strong> by the representative body, whereas an opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum must be held<strong>on</strong>ly if some specific requirements have been met by the electorate– usually a signaturerequirement 36 . In theory, all referenda can also exist in an ordinary or extraordinary form. If areferendum is ordinary, its (potential) applicati<strong>on</strong> is directly stipulated in the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>; it is,in a sense, part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the daily political process. An extraordinary referendum can be held if aminority <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the representative organ <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong> demands it: in this case, the requirementsfor taking this extraordinary opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum will be stipulated in the legal act to which itrefers. In general, not all types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> referenda exist in <strong>on</strong>e cant<strong>on</strong>, and there is a huge variati<strong>on</strong>in requirements between the Swiss states.To ensure a minimum level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy in each Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>, the federal c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>rules which instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> must exist at the cant<strong>on</strong>al level. Article 51, 1 SCstates that 'each cant<strong>on</strong> shall stipulate a democratic c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>', where 'democratic ' refers tothe organizati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>, particularly the divisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> power, and to the fact that thecant<strong>on</strong>al parliament is elected by the cant<strong>on</strong>al citizenry (EHRENZELLER et al. 2002, p. 624, no.8). As regards instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong>, as already menti<strong>on</strong>ed above, <strong>on</strong>ly thec<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al referendum and the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative (both for a partial and total revisi<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>) are required in additi<strong>on</strong> by art. 51, 1 SC (EHRENZELLER et al., 2002, p.624, no. 9) 37 . Although at the federal level a statutory referendum is stipulated in its opti<strong>on</strong>alform (art. 141 SC), this instituti<strong>on</strong> is not prescribed for the Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s. Nevertheless, allSwiss cant<strong>on</strong>s guarantee their citizens more direct democratic rights than the requiredminimum. In fact, the statutory referendum <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> exists in all 26 Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s,as do most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the other instituti<strong>on</strong>s such as the fiscal referendum and the administrativereferendum 38 . In additi<strong>on</strong>, changes in cant<strong>on</strong>al territory are subject to approval through apopular vote <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the affected populati<strong>on</strong>s and cant<strong>on</strong>s (art. 53, 3 SC), as are secessi<strong>on</strong>s orunificati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>s (art. 53, 2 SC).36 In case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscal referenda, both forms require the meeting <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a financial threshold in first place.37 Changes in the cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s must be in accordance with the federal law that is ensured by theapproval by the federal assembly (art. 51, 2 SC; art. 172, 2 SC). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> federal assembly c<strong>on</strong>sists <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> twochambers: the federal parliament (Nati<strong>on</strong>alrat) and the representatives <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the 26 cant<strong>on</strong>s (<strong>St</strong>änderat) (art. 148,2 SC). In general, any cant<strong>on</strong>al stipulati<strong>on</strong> should not c<strong>on</strong>tradict federal law (federal law breaks cant<strong>on</strong>al law(art. 49, 1 SC)).38For an overview <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the (n<strong>on</strong>)existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the most important instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> in Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s,see LUTZ and STROHMANN (1998).


– 22 –As regards the instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy to be analyzed in this chapter, they arerestricted mainly to those that serve as a basis for c<strong>on</strong>structing the so-called index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy as developed by STUTZER (1999). This index is an unweighted average <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foursubindices that measure the strength <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> four specific instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong>; inparticular, the initiatives for c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al and statutory changes, the fiscal referendum(ordinary opti<strong>on</strong>al and mandatory) <strong>on</strong> expenditure projects, and the referendum for laws (anddecrees) 39 . To follow this chapter’s development more easily, the reader should recall thatthese subindices are based <strong>on</strong> an evaluati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the requirements for each instituti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>on</strong> the<strong>on</strong>e hand, the signature requirements necessary for opti<strong>on</strong>al referenda and initiatives, and <strong>on</strong>the other, the financial threshold for the (opti<strong>on</strong>al and mandatory) fiscal referenda. In order toprovide as complete a picture <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al changes in instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy ascomplete, however, the discussi<strong>on</strong> also lists most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the changes in administrative referendaand any extraordinary statutory referenda. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> administrative referenda are listed in thesecti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> statutory referenda, because with respect to their political intenti<strong>on</strong>, they areclosely related to the statutory referendum.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> original values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy were presented by STUTZER (1999) andSTUTZER and FREY (2000) for the years 1970, 1992, and 1996 and were then updated for themissing years between 1980 and 1998 by FELD and SCHALTEGGER (see their various articlesin the list <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> references). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> data used for c<strong>on</strong>structing this index up until 1996 can be foundin TRECHSEL and SERDÜLT (1999) 40 (hereafter cited as T/S in this chapter), in which theauthors analyze the instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy and describe the changes from 1970<strong>on</strong>wards (T/S 1999, p. 8). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy has since been employed in varioustime-series cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al analyses <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy and is thus essential 41 .For the purposes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this dissertati<strong>on</strong> an update for the years 1997 – 2003 became necessarybecause the data used to investigate the effect <strong>on</strong> educati<strong>on</strong>, crime, and subjective happinessencompass <strong>on</strong>ly these more recent years 42 . It should also be noted that neither TRECHSEL andSERDÜLT (1999) nor STUTZER (1999) analyze the cant<strong>on</strong>al instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the so-called39 In many cant<strong>on</strong>s, the requirements for the statutory and administrative referendum are identical. However, insome cant<strong>on</strong>s they differ, and STUTZER (1999) used either their average or either <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> them to c<strong>on</strong>struct thesubindex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the statutory referendum.40 Sporadically, the descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the changes reaches 1998, particularly in the sec<strong>on</strong>d part in TRECHSEL andSERDÜLT (1999) in which each single cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> is analyzed.41 E.g., see the literature cited in KIRCHGÄSSNER (2002, 2001, 2000).42 Differences between the values c<strong>on</strong>structed by FELD and SCHALTEGGER (for 1997 and 1998) and my own aremainly due to the extrapolati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> old values without taking into account changes in the underlying cant<strong>on</strong>alpopulati<strong>on</strong>. See also secti<strong>on</strong> 7 in this chapter.


– 23 –Landsgemeinde cant<strong>on</strong>s, i.e. those cant<strong>on</strong>s that know no form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> legislative representati<strong>on</strong> ordelegati<strong>on</strong> but vote <strong>on</strong> everything in an open meeting 43 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se Landsgemeinde cant<strong>on</strong>sexcluded from the analysis in T/S (1999) are Appenzell Innerrhoden, Appenzell Ausserrhoden,Nidwalden, Obwalden, and Glarus because in 1996 they were either still a Landsgemeinde orhad been so until recently (see T/S 1999, p. 7) 44 .<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> update <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this index would not have been possible without the actual wording <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thechanges provided by courtesy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> various cant<strong>on</strong>al legal services and administrati<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, at this point I would like to thank all the various civil servants and h<strong>on</strong>orarycollaborators, most particularly, Mr. Jürg Fehner (ZH), Mr. Urs Rüegg (ZH), Ms. ElisabethVetter (LU), Ms. Kathrin Graber (LU), Ms. Judith Lauber, Mr Georg Zemp (LU), Mr. HeinzBachmann (LU), Mr. Peter Huber (UR), Mr. René Zehnder (SZ) and Mr. Peter Gander (SZ),Mr. Notker Dillier (OW), Mr. Josef Baumgartner (NW), Mr. Hansjörg Dürst (GL), Mr. BrunoZimmermann (ZG), Mr André Schoenenweid (FR), Ms. Yolanda <strong>St</strong>uder (SO), Dr. DeniseMangold (BS), Mr. René Bolliger (BL), Mr. Christian Ritzmann (SH), Mr. Joe Müggler (AR),Mr. Köbi Frei (AR), Gabriela Küpfer (SG), Mr. Walter Frizz<strong>on</strong>i (GR), Mr. Urs Meier (AG),Mr. Claudio Franscini (TI), Mr. Alex Depraz (VD), Ms. Séverine Despland (NE), and Mr.Jean-Jacques Tombet (GE). I also thank ALOIS STUTZER, the inventor <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this index, forhelpful comments and clarificati<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> rest <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this chapter is organized as follows. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> next secti<strong>on</strong> provides an overview <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thechanges in the cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s from 1997 to 2003. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> subsequent secti<strong>on</strong>s separatelyexamine the instituti<strong>on</strong>al changes for the relevant direct democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s and describetheir actual provisi<strong>on</strong>s. Addressed by these secti<strong>on</strong>s are the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative, thestatutory initiative, the mandatory and the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum, and, finally, themandatory and the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> outcome <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this research is organized inthe form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> tables intended to serve as a 'manual' for informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the relevant c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>alrequirements and for further c<strong>on</strong>sultati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se tables also allow c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> furtherc<strong>on</strong>trols <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s, such as the signature requirements or the financialthreshold requirements for various time points between 1997 and 2003. Finally, theimplicati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these changes for the index are described and the c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong>al changes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the index are discussed. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> chapter c<strong>on</strong>cludes with a brief critique <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index.43 In various papers by STUTZER and FREY (e.g. 2000) index values for the Landsgemeinde cant<strong>on</strong>s are alsoreported, without, however, a detailed descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their relevant c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al stipulati<strong>on</strong>s.44 Today (2003), 2 cant<strong>on</strong>s (Glarus and Appenzell Innerrhoden) are still Landsgemeinden; Nidwalden ceasedbefore 1996, Appenzell Ausserrhoden in 1997, and Obwalden in 1998.


– 24 –2 C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al Changes between 1997 and 2003<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> time span between 1997 and 2003 appears to have been a period favoring the adopti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s. Table 2.1 displays a list <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> all 26 cant<strong>on</strong>s and their c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al changesthat affect those direct democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> which the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy isbased (state: 18th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> August, 2004). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>s FR, SH, SG, GR, TI, VD, and NE – about<strong>on</strong>e fourth <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> all Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s – all passed new, totally revised c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s between 1997and 2004 (the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> LU is also currently drafting a new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, which should bevoted up<strong>on</strong> in 2007 45 ). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> reas<strong>on</strong> for this 'clustering' could lie both in a "Year 2000" effectcombined with a "200-years jubilee" effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> membership in the Swiss federati<strong>on</strong>, whichemerged from a c<strong>on</strong>federati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> single independent states. However, not all <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s necessarily brought about alterati<strong>on</strong>s in the existing direct democraticinstituti<strong>on</strong>s: some <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s aimed primarily at rewriting the outdatednineteenth-century wording and giving it a more modern structure without altering its legalc<strong>on</strong>tent. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> rest <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this secti<strong>on</strong> is devoted to an assessment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the amendments in thec<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al stipulati<strong>on</strong>s.With respect to the mandatory and opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum, there is a weakening <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thedirect democratic instituti<strong>on</strong> through a shift <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the political power from the electorate towardthe cant<strong>on</strong>al parliament. Quite <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ten, the applicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory statutory referendumhas been restricted by the inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a majority requirement <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al parliament in thec<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> (SO, BL, SH, AG) or by restricti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the issues to be regulated through legalstipulati<strong>on</strong> (GL) 46. Alternatively, the mandatory statutory referendum has been completelyabolished and replaced by an opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum, as happened in four cant<strong>on</strong>s (ZH,OW, AR, GR (2004)). In general, such changes lead to a decline in the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy in these cant<strong>on</strong>s.45See www.neueverfassung.lu.ch (7/10/2004) and pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong> with Mr. ZEMP (20/04/2005).46 In case the majority restricti<strong>on</strong> serves <strong>on</strong>ly as a means for disciplining the cant<strong>on</strong>al parliament, the introducti<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> such a majority restricti<strong>on</strong> has to be regarded as equivalent to a de facto eliminati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatoryreferendum. Only observati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the daily political usage over a l<strong>on</strong>ger period <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> time can provide a basis fora correct evaluati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this instituti<strong>on</strong>.


– 25 –Table 1: Changes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> from 1997 to 2003Cant<strong>on</strong>Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Changesbetween 1997 and 2003(dates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> effectiveness)CommentsIndex(1996) 47(STUTZER, 1999)Index(2003)ZH GRR*: 1 Jan 1999,FRR*: 1 Jan 19994.417 3.500BE 3.020 3.021LU 4.420 4.417UR VIR, GIR, GRR: 1 Oct 1997FRR: 1 Oct 19975.290 5.125SZ 4.990 4.927OW GIR, GRR*: 29 Nov 1998 Abolishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> LandsgemeindeFRR*: 8 June 1997, (29 Nov 1998) 4.62529 Nov 1998NW 4.438GL GRR*: 5 May 2002 LandsgemeindeFRR: 5 May 20025.500ZG 4.420 4.479FR New c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by 1 Jan 2005 2.850 2.792SO GRR*: 11 Dec 1998FRR: 11 Dec 19985.670 5.250BS FRR: 1 Jan 1998 Change in cant<strong>on</strong>al law 4.400 4.396BL GRR*: 1 Jan 2000 5.690 5.479SH GRR*: 1 Jan 2003 New c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by 1 Jan 2003FRR: 1 Jan 20035.210 5.021AR GRR*: 1 June 2000 Abolishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Landsgemeinde(28 Sept 1997)4.917AI FRR: 28 Apr 2002 Landsgemeinde 5.438SG VIR, GIR: 1 Jan 2003 New c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by 1 Jan 2003GRR: 1 Jan 2003Einheitsinitiative 3.580 3.521FRR: 1 Jan 2003GR New c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by 1 Jan 2004 4.750 4.833AG GRR*: 1 Jan 2003FRR: 1 Jan 20035.460 5.438TG 4.330 4.333TI GRR: 1 Jan 1998New c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by 1 Jan 1998FRR: 1 Jan 19982.100 2.250VD VIR, GIR: 1 Sept 2003 New c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by 1 Sept 2003FRR*: 1 Sept 2003,2.420 2.41729 Nov 1998VS 3.580 3.583NE GRR: 1 Jan 2002,New c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by 1 Jan 2002FRR*: 1 Jan 20022.190 2.729GE 1.750 1.750JU 4.020 3.708<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s and the changes tracked for them are based <strong>on</strong> their newest versi<strong>on</strong>s as <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the 18th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> August, 2004.Updated cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s can be obtained from http://www.admin.ch/ch/d/sr/13.html#131. In case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> FR thesource was http://www.fr.ch/c<strong>on</strong>stituante/doc/fichiers/proj_def/proj.pdf. Empty cells indicate that no relevant revisi<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> or cant<strong>on</strong>al law had been observed. FRR: Fiscal Referendum, GIR: <strong>St</strong>atutory Initiative, GRR:<strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum, VIR: C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al Initiative. *indicates abrogati<strong>on</strong> or restricti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a mandatory referendum.47 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ZÜRICH has been corrected. See secti<strong>on</strong> 7 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this chapter.


– 26 –Looking at the development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the statutory initiative and the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative, threeinteresting changes should be noted. First, more and more cant<strong>on</strong>s list these two existing types<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> initiatives under the identical heading in their c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> in order to group them togetherand indicate them as two possible variati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a people's initiative. This integrati<strong>on</strong> isparticularly true for most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s, and is part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a trend to make c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>smore transparent to the average citizen. In the old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s, the descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the people'srights was subject to a strict c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al structure that reflected the organizati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the stateas understood in the nineteenth century. Traditi<strong>on</strong>ally, revisi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> (includingrevisi<strong>on</strong>s initiated by the people) were given a separate chapter in the back part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thec<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, not <strong>on</strong>ly symbolically almost outside the daily law-making process. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> statutoryinitiative, in c<strong>on</strong>trast, was placed in the middle, linked to the legislative process. For thisreas<strong>on</strong>, integrating both initiatives under <strong>on</strong>e heading c<strong>on</strong>stitutes not <strong>on</strong>ly a formal change butindicates a change in the underlying philosophy and understanding <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the purpose <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ac<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>.Linked to this change is a sec<strong>on</strong>d phenomen<strong>on</strong>: the introducti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the unitary initiative(Einheitsinitiative) (e.g. in <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong> art. 43 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>), which also aims to makeit easier for the citizens to influence the legislative process. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> unitary initiative is a bindingmoti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the electorate for which no specific legal form is required. During the readings(Lesungen) for the new cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> in <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>, the introducti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theEinheitsinitiative was under hot debate and the most important aspects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this instituti<strong>on</strong> werenamed (PROTOCOL 2000, PROTOCOL 2000a). According to the various speakers, theadvantages <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this new type <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> initiative are that it is relatively easy to carry out and that it isthe legislative organ and not the initiator who decides whether a change in cant<strong>on</strong>al law or incant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> is the appropriate (re)acti<strong>on</strong>. This latter means that unitary initiatives canno l<strong>on</strong>ger be turned down <strong>on</strong> the formal ground that the wr<strong>on</strong>g level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> law-making had beenchosen by the initiators, e.g. the proposal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a change in cant<strong>on</strong>al law when an amendment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> would have been correct and vice versa. Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, the Einheitsinitiativeallows the development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al law and the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> in a juristically c<strong>on</strong>sistent andsystematic way.Nevertheless, the Einheitsinitiative should not be seen as a perfect substitute for the traditi<strong>on</strong>alinitiatives, because it serves purely as a device to induce the cant<strong>on</strong>al parliament to becomeactive. Both statutory and c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiatives are viewed as str<strong>on</strong>ger instruments than theEinheitsinitiative because both the legal level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> applicati<strong>on</strong> and the c<strong>on</strong>tent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the change are


– 27 –precisely specified. Moreover, the Einheitsinitiative serves as a mere suggesti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theelectorate, and the cant<strong>on</strong>al parliament can decide whether to follow it or not. If theparliament decides against, a referendum must be held. If it decides in favor and passes a law,this law is then subject to the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum. If a c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al change ischosen, the cant<strong>on</strong>al people again have the final say in a popular vote. Overall, some speakersin the cant<strong>on</strong>al parliament <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong> pointed out, a hierarchy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> initiatives can bec<strong>on</strong>strued in which the unitary initiative is at the lowest level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> influence. Because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thishierarchy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> initiatives, differences in the signature requirements appear justified. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are,however, cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s in which no differentiati<strong>on</strong> is made between the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>signatures required for the unitary versus the statutory initiative 48 .<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> third phenomen<strong>on</strong> linked to the initiative but also to the fiscal referendum is that moreand more cant<strong>on</strong>s tend to regulate the time period for collecting signatures or the financialthreshold in the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> itself and not in a cant<strong>on</strong>al law <strong>on</strong> political rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its citizenry.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> advantage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this development could be increased transparency because now allrequirements c<strong>on</strong>cerning <strong>on</strong>e instituti<strong>on</strong> are laid down in the same legal act. Anotheradvantage, depending <strong>on</strong> whether a mandatory statutory referendum exists in a cant<strong>on</strong> or not,might be that a change in c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> must be approved by the electorate through amandatory referendum 49 , whereas an alterati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a cant<strong>on</strong>al law might <strong>on</strong>ly be subject to anopti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum. In this latter situati<strong>on</strong>, political ec<strong>on</strong>omic theory predicts thatlarger deviati<strong>on</strong>s from the median voter’s preferences will occur than in the former (FELD andKIRCHGÄSSNER 2001). On the other hand, again depending <strong>on</strong> whether differences existregarding the signature requirements for a statutory or c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative, it might havebecome more difficult for the electorate to change that requirement if regulated in ac<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>. In political practice, however, between 1980 and 1998, time periods forcollecti<strong>on</strong> or financial thresholds, whether regulated by a law or the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, were rarelychanged over time. Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, for all cant<strong>on</strong>s during our investigati<strong>on</strong> period, regulati<strong>on</strong> ata new, higher level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> lawmaking failed to bring about a different (shorter) time period forsignature collecti<strong>on</strong>.48 Because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its potentially low level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> political influence and because it <strong>on</strong>ly complements the existingtraditi<strong>on</strong>al initiatives, the Einheitsinitiative does not (yet) form part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy. Only thefuture will show how important the instituti<strong>on</strong> becomes to the daily political process and whether it should beincluded in the index c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> or not.49 As required by art. 51, 1 SC, see also secti<strong>on</strong> 1.


– 28 –Table 1 provides informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> how the index changed between 1996 (as found in STUTZER,1999) and 2003 (based <strong>on</strong> own calculati<strong>on</strong>s). A more detailed discussi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> such change isprovided in secti<strong>on</strong> 7 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this chapter. It must also be noted that not all instituti<strong>on</strong>al changesautomatically cause a change in the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy: index points are awardedbased <strong>on</strong> ranges <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> signature requirements or financial thresholds so that relatively smallalterati<strong>on</strong>s do not necessarily translate into a change in category. In additi<strong>on</strong>, the readershould keep in mind that each instituti<strong>on</strong> influences the composite index by <strong>on</strong>ly 25%: e.g. thechange in signature requirement in Basel-Land (BL) for the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendumcaused a total change <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> just about 0.21 index points. At this point, I would like to emphasizethat because the index is c<strong>on</strong>structed <strong>on</strong> a yearly basis, revisi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>becoming effective after April 1st are always counted as changes in the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thesubsequent year. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, if a cant<strong>on</strong>al electorate approves a revisi<strong>on</strong> in September 1997,becoming effective the same date, it is the index value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the subsequent year 1998 that willbe adapted accordingly. Moreover, it is also possible that several, c<strong>on</strong>trasting instituti<strong>on</strong>alchanges – either occurring simultaneously or subsequent to each other – might cause acompensating impact <strong>on</strong> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy. Finally, it should be noted thatchanges in the index can occur even if the instituti<strong>on</strong>al requirements do not change: suchchanges happen because some evaluati<strong>on</strong>s use per capita values, meaning that fluctuati<strong>on</strong>s inpopulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ten lead to a change in category.3 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Initiative3.1 C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al InitiativeCant<strong>on</strong>Zürich(30 Mar 2004)Bern(21 Oct 2003)Table 2: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al Initiative between 1997 and 2003Signature Articles in cant.Requirement c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>Effective since10,000 art. 29, 3 num.1 11 June 1969(1 June 1969)30,000 (TR)15,000 (PR)art. 58, 1 lit. aart. 58, 2Time-limit forcollecti<strong>on</strong>6 m<strong>on</strong>thsart. 13, 2Initiativgesetz(art. 126 GPR)1 Jan 1995 6 m<strong>on</strong>thssee also T/S 1999,p. 190


– 29 –Cant<strong>on</strong>Luzern(21 Oct 2003)Uri(1 Apr 2003)Uri(old)Schwyz(18 Aug 2004)Table 2: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al Initiative between 1997 and 2003 (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Signature Articles in cant.Requirement c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>5,000 art. 32, 1art. 35 bis, 2600 art. 27, 1art. 28, 2300 art. 27, 1art. 28, 22,000 art. 102, lit. aart. 103, lit. bEffective since1 Jan 1994(28 Nov 1993)1 Sept 1970(7 June 1970)1 Oct 1997(8 June 1997)(since 1985)21 Dec 1899(23 Oct 1898)Time-limit forcollecti<strong>on</strong>1 yearart. 136 lit. a SRGSee T/S 1999, p. 265.N<strong>on</strong>eN<strong>on</strong>eSee T/S 1999, p. 362N<strong>on</strong>eSee also T/S 1999,p. 307Obwalden(22. Oct 2002)Nidwalden(28 Dec 2001)Glarus(30 Mar 2004)Zug(1 Apr 2003)Freiburg(18 Aug 2004)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2005Freiburg(old)Solothurn(30 Mar 2004)Basel-<strong>St</strong>adt(4 July 2000)Basel-Land(22 Oct 2002)500 art. 61, 1 lit. a(until Nov 1998:art. 63 num. 1)1,000 (TR)500 (PR)art. 54, 4, num. 1art. 54, 4, num. 2(Art 54a Abs.4)1 art. 138, 3 1 May 1988(1 May 1988)2,000 art. 79, 2 2 Dec 1990art. 35, 1 (2 Dec 1990)6,000 art. 41aart. 42, 219 May 1968 N<strong>on</strong>e29 Nov 1998 (29 Nov1998): abolishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the Landsgemeinde)changes in 1998 d<strong>on</strong>ot affect instituti<strong>on</strong>1 Dec 1996 2 m<strong>on</strong>ths(1 Dec 1996)1 Jan 2005(16 May 2004)6,000 art. 78, 2 lit. b 3 Aug 1979(24 Sept 1978)3,000 art. 29, I lit. aart. 30, 31 Jan 1988(8 June 1986)4,000 art. 28, 1 3 June 1991(2 June 1991)1,000 art. 28, 1 1 Jan 1987(4 Nov 1984)N<strong>on</strong>eLandsgemeindeN<strong>on</strong>e(Rules for thestatutory initiativeapply)See T/S 1999, p. 39790 days90 daysart. 115, 2 PRGart. 193, 3 PRG (old)see also T/S 1999,p. 21418 m<strong>on</strong>thsN<strong>on</strong>eSee T/S 1999, p. 166N<strong>on</strong>eSee also T/S 1999,p. 144


– 30 –Cant<strong>on</strong>Schaffhausen(21 Oct 2003)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2003Schaffhausen(old)Appenzell AR(3 Apr 2001)Appenzell IR(30 Mar 2004)<strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>(9 July 2002)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2003<strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>(old)Graubünden(6 July 2004)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2004Graubünden(old)Aargau(30 Mar 2004)Thurgau(22 Oct 2002)Tessin(30 Mar 1999)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 1998Tessin(old)Waadt(21 Oct 2003)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Sept 2003Table 2: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al Initiative between 1997 and 2003 (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Signature Articles in cant.Requirement c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>.Effective since1,000 art. 27, 1 lit. a 1 Jan 2003(22 Sept 2002)1,000 art. 108 (TR)art. 107 (PR)art. 43, 26 Apr 1997(6 Apr 1997)1. June 1876(14 May 1976)20 May 1973(29 Jan 1973)300 art. 51 1 May 1996(30 Apr 1995)1 art. 7 bis 25 Apr 1982art. 48 (25 Apr 1982)8,000 art. 41, 1 lit. a, b 1 Jan 2003art. 45 (10 June 2001)8,000 art. 114 num. 2art. 1151926see T/S 1999,p. 3334,000 art. 12, 1 1 Jan 2004(18 May 2003 /14 Sept 2003)5,000 art. 54, 3 2 Mar 1980(2 Mar 1980)3,000 art. 64, 1 1 Jan 1982(28 Sept 1980)4,000 art. 26 1 Jan 1990(4 Dec 1988)10,000 art. 83 1 Jan 1998(art. 119, 2 (14 Dec 1997)LEDP)10,000 art. 54, 1 lit. cart. 5612,000 (PR)18,000 (TR)art. 78 lit. aart. 79, 21970(31 May 1970)1 Sept 2003(22 Sept 2002)Time-limit forcollecti<strong>on</strong>N<strong>on</strong>eN<strong>on</strong>eChange <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1997c<strong>on</strong>cerns <strong>on</strong>ly TR anddoes not affect theVIR-subindexSee T/S 1999, p. 290N<strong>on</strong>eLandsgemeinde5 m<strong>on</strong>ths6 m<strong>on</strong>ths1 yearart. 53c, 1 GPR1 yearart. 53c, 1 GPR1 yearart. 54, 1 GPR6 m<strong>on</strong>ths60 daysart. 119, 1 LEDP60 daysart. 3 LIRRsee T/S 1999, p. 3424 m<strong>on</strong>ths(c<strong>on</strong>tradicts LEDP,art. 92, 1)


– 31 –Waadt(old)Cant<strong>on</strong>Wallis(21 Oct 2003)Neuenburg(16 Oct 2001)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2002Neuenburg(old)Genf(21 Oct 2003)Jura(4 July 2000)Table 2: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al Initiative between 1997 and 2003 (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Signature Articles in cant.Requirement c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>.Effective since12,000 art. 100 1961(11 June 1961)see T/S 1999,p. 3736,000 art. 100, 1 1 June 1994(24 Oct 1993)10,000 (TR) art. 101, 1 1 Jan 20026,000 (PR) art. 102, 1 (24 Sept 2000)10,000 (TR)6,000 (PR)art. 83, 1art. 84, 1 and 21959see T/S 1999,p. 27510,000 art. 64art. 65A (7 Mar 1993)2,000 art. 75, 1 1 Jan 1979(20 Mar 1977)Time-limit forcollecti<strong>on</strong>3 m<strong>on</strong>thsart. 92, 1 LEDPN<strong>on</strong>e6 m<strong>on</strong>thsart.105, 1 LDP6 m<strong>on</strong>thsart. 105, 1 LDP4 m<strong>on</strong>thsart. 89, 1 lit. c LEDP12 m<strong>on</strong>thsArt 89, 1 LDPSee also table 1. In the column ‘Cant<strong>on</strong>’, the date <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the versi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> (or the date <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thedownload, the 18th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Aug, 2004) is displayed in brackets. TR denotes total revisi<strong>on</strong> and PR partial revisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>; if not otherwise indicated, the signature requirement applies to both initiativesequally. Signature requirements relate to the corresp<strong>on</strong>ding cant<strong>on</strong>al electorate. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Einheitsinitiative, whichdoes not enter the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy, is not c<strong>on</strong>sidered. In the column ‘Effective since’ the date <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thepopular vote is given in brackets. For an explanati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the abbreviati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al laws <strong>on</strong> political rightsand their dates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> enactment, see table A.1 in the Appendix.3.2 <strong>St</strong>atutory InitiativeCant<strong>on</strong>Zürich(30 Mar 2004)Bern(21 Oct 2003)Bern(21 Oct 2003)Table 3: Requirements for a <strong>St</strong>atutory Initiative between 1997 and 2003Signature Articles in cant.Effective sinceRequirement c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>10,000 art. 29, 3 num. 1 11 June 1969(1 June 1969)15,000 art. 58, 1 lit. bart. 58, 24,000 art. 41 bis, 1 1 Sept 1970(7 June 1970)Time-limit forcollecti<strong>on</strong>6 m<strong>on</strong>thssee c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>alinitiative1 Jan 1995 6 m<strong>on</strong>thssee also T/S 1999,p. 1911 yearart. 136 lit. a SRGUri(1 Apr 2003)600 art. 27, 1art. 28, 21 Oct 1997(8 June 1997)N<strong>on</strong>e


– 32 –Table 3: Requirements for a <strong>St</strong>atutory Initiative between 1997 and 2003 (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Cant<strong>on</strong>Uri(old)Schwyz(18 Aug 2004)Signature Articles in cant.Requirement c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>Effective since300 art. 27, 1 (since 1985)art. 28, 22,000 art. 31, 2 21 Dec 1899(23 Oct 1898)Time-limit forcollecti<strong>on</strong>N<strong>on</strong>eSee T/S 1999, p. 362N<strong>on</strong>eSee T/S 1999, p. 308Obwalden(22 Oct 2002)Obwalden(8 June 1997)Nidwalden(28 Dec 2001)500 art. 61, 1, lit. b 29 Nov 1998(29 Nov 1998)1 art. 63, num. 2 19 May 1968 N<strong>on</strong>e250 art. 54, 4, num. 3art. 54, 51 Dec 1996(1 Dec 1996)N<strong>on</strong>eNov 1998:abolishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theLandsgemeinde2 m<strong>on</strong>thsGlarus 1 art. 69, 1art. 58, 1Glarus(old)Zug(1 Apr 2003)Freiburg(18 Aug 2004)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2005Freiburg(old)Solothurn(30 Mar 2004)Basel-<strong>St</strong>adt(4 July 2000)Basel-Land(22 Oct 2002)Schaffhausen(21 Oct 2003)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2003Schaffhausen(old)5 May 2002(5 May 2002)1 art. 69, 1 lit. bart. 58, 11 May 1988(1 May 1988)2,000 art. 35, 2 2 Dec 1990(2 Dec 1990)6,000 art. 41 lit. b 1 Jan 2005art. 42, 2 (16 May 2004)6,000 art. 28 ter,art. 28 quarter11 Mar 1921(30 Jan 1921)3,000 art. 29, 1 lit. bart. 30, 31 Jan 1988(8 June 1986)4,000 art. 28, 1 3 June 1991(2 June 1991)1,000 art. 28, 1 1 Jan 1987(4 Nov 1984)1,000 art. 27, lit. b 1 Jan 2003(22 Sept 2002)1,000 art. 43, 2 20 May 1973(29 Jan 1973)N<strong>on</strong>eLandsgemeindeOnly importantregulati<strong>on</strong> in form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>lawN<strong>on</strong>eLandsgemeindeN<strong>on</strong>eSee T/S 1999, p. 39790 days90 daysart 115, 2 PRGart. 193, 3 PRG (old)see also T/S 1999,p. 21518 m<strong>on</strong>thsN<strong>on</strong>eN<strong>on</strong>eSee also T/S 1999,p. 145N<strong>on</strong>eN<strong>on</strong>e


– 33 –Table 3: Requirements for a <strong>St</strong>atutory Initiative between 1997 and 2003 (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Cant<strong>on</strong>Appenzell AR(1 Apr 2001)Appenzell IR(30 Mar 2004)<strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>(9 July 2002)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2003<strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>(old)Graubünden(6 July 2004)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2004Signature Articles in cant.Requirement c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>Effective since300 art. 51 1. May 1996(30 Apr 1995)1 art. 7 bis 25 Apr 1982(25 Apr 1982)6,000 art. 42 1 Jan 2003art. 45 (10 June 2001)4,000 art. 49 1926see T/S 1999,p. 33411 Apr 1996(RIG)3,000 art. 12, 2 1 Jan 2004(18 May 2004,14 Sept 2003)Time-limit forcollecti<strong>on</strong>N<strong>on</strong>eLandsgemeinde5 m<strong>on</strong>ths3 m<strong>on</strong>thsart. 41, 1 RIG1 yearart. 53c, 1 GPRGraubünden(old)Aargau(30 Mar 2004)Thurgau(22 Oct 2002)Tessin(30 Mar 1999)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 1998Tessin(old)Waadt(21 Oct 2003)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Sept 2003Waadt(old)Wallis(21 Oct 2003)3,000 art. 3, 1 2 Mar 1980(2 Mar 1980)3,000 art. 64, 1 1 Jan 1982(28 Sept 1980)4,000 art. 26 1 Jan 1990(4 Dec 1988)7,000 art. 37 1 Jan 1998art. 119, 3 LEDP (14 Dec 1997)7,000 art. 59, 4art. 5612,000 art. 78 lit. bart. 79, 21970(31 May 1970)1 Sept 2003(22 Sept 2002)12,000 art. 27, 1 1978(4 Dec 1977)see T/S 1999,p. 3734,000 art. 33, 1 1 June 1994(24 Oct 1993)1 yearart. 53c, 1 GPR1 yearart. 54, 1 GPR6 m<strong>on</strong>ths60 daysart. 119, 1 LEDP60 daysart. 3, 3 LIRRsee T/S 1999, p. 3434 m<strong>on</strong>ths(c<strong>on</strong>tradicts LEDP,art. 92, 1)3 m<strong>on</strong>thsart. 92, 1 LEDPsee also T/S 1999,p. 373N<strong>on</strong>e


– 34 –Table 3: Requirements for a <strong>St</strong>atutory Initiative between 1997 and 2003 (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Cant<strong>on</strong>Neuenburg(16 Oct 2001)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2002Neuenburg(alt)Genf(21 Oct 2003)Signature Articles inRequirement cant. c<strong>on</strong>st.6,000 art. 40, 1art. 40, 26,000 art. 38, 2art. 38. 3Effective since1 Jan 2002(24 Sept 2000)1960see T/S 1999,p. 27610,000 art. 64art. 65B (7 Mar 1993)Time-limit forcollecti<strong>on</strong>6 m<strong>on</strong>thsart. 105, 1 LDP6 m<strong>on</strong>thsart. 105, 1 LDP4 m<strong>on</strong>thsart. 89, 1 c LEDPJura(4 July 2000)2,000 art. 75,1 1 Jan 1979(20 Mar 1977)12 m<strong>on</strong>thsart. 89, 1 LDPSee table 2.3.3 Comments <strong>on</strong> the Changes in C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al and <strong>St</strong>atutory InitiativesTables 2 and 3 provide an overview <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the 26 Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s and their c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>alstipulati<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>cerning the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al and the statutory initiative between 1997 and 2003.In several cant<strong>on</strong>s, alterati<strong>on</strong>s in these instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> have occurred since1997. In the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Zürich, the time period available for c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al and statutoryinitiatives is not fixed (art. 29, 4 CC) 50 ; instead, it is stipulated that a cant<strong>on</strong>al law shoulddetermine this limit. As <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> June, 1969, the time period for signature collecti<strong>on</strong> wasset at 6 m<strong>on</strong>ths for people's initiatives (art. 13, 2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Initiativgesetz). On the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>September, 2003, a new cant<strong>on</strong>al law <strong>on</strong> political rights (Gesetz über die politischen Rechte,GPR) was passed in the Kant<strong>on</strong>srat that fixed an identical time period (art. 126, 1 GPR) andbecame effective the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2005. In other words, in terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the requirements forstatutory and c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiatives, no changes that affect the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracyhave been undertaken in Zürich since 1969, despite the enactment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a new cant<strong>on</strong>al law <strong>on</strong>political rights.Uri is <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>s in which important changes in the requirements for the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>aland statutory initiatives occurred after 1997. In this cant<strong>on</strong>, the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> required signaturesdoubled from 300 to 600 as <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the 1st October, 1997 (art. 28, 2 CC; art. 27, 1 CC), which50 CC stands for cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>.


– 35 –caused a duplicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the relative signature requirement from 1.18 per voter to 2.36 pervoter and, finally, lowered the subindex for either initiative from 1998 <strong>on</strong>wards. Since theidentical stipulati<strong>on</strong>s are valid for both initiatives, an identical drop is noted for the subindex<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> both types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> initiatives. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> time period for collecti<strong>on</strong>, however, was not altered by thisc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al revisi<strong>on</strong>.In the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Obwalden, <strong>on</strong> the 29th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> November, 1998, the electorate decided againstmaintaining the status <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Landsgemeinde. This choice meant that (a) the open vote in a yearlycitizens' meeting was replaced by a secret vote at the ballot box and (b) the role <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> therepresentative organ <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> legislati<strong>on</strong> was strengthened. As regards the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative,however, no change in instituti<strong>on</strong>al requirements occurred after 1968 except for a formalrenumbering <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> articles in the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>. In c<strong>on</strong>trast, as regards the statutory initiative, theabolishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Landsgemeinde in November 1998 brought about a substantially highersignature requirement than before. As a result, the stipulated number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> supporters rose from1 in June 1997 to 500 in November 1998, which caused a jump in the relative signature hurdlefrom about 0.005 to 2.27. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> time period available for collecti<strong>on</strong>, however, remained thesame. In effect, this change led to a substantial decline in the subindex for the statutoryinitiative.For the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Nidwalden, there have been no apparent changes in the instituti<strong>on</strong>alrequirements for either initiative since 1996. It might be interesting to point out, however, thatin additi<strong>on</strong> to the usual initiatives, the citizens can also make a counterproposal to an existingdecisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>srat either to revise the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> or to make a new/change incant<strong>on</strong>al law. This instituti<strong>on</strong> is very similar to the initiative – in a way it can be viewed as areactive initiative. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> requirements for the counterproposals are identical for the statutoryinitiative and the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative, respectively (see art. 54a, 4 CC).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Glarus is <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the two cant<strong>on</strong>s in which direct democracy in the form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theLandsgemeinde still exists. In this cant<strong>on</strong> every citizen has the right to make a moti<strong>on</strong> to theLandsgemeinde, the assembly <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its citizens, <strong>on</strong> issues that c<strong>on</strong>cern the Landsgemeinde (art.58, 1 CC). Hence, according to art. 58, 1 CC and art. 138, 3 CC, it takes <strong>on</strong>e vote to launch ac<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al or statutory initiative. Art. 69 CC then specifies the fields <strong>on</strong> which theLandsgemeinde can exert its decisi<strong>on</strong>-making power, which is comprised <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>and cant<strong>on</strong>al laws. This stipulati<strong>on</strong>, however, was amended in May 2002, leading to a


– 36 –seemingly indirect restricti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the statutory initiative 51 , because <strong>on</strong>ly fundamentalregulati<strong>on</strong>s should be determined in the form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> laws, whereas before 2002 any issue couldhave been in a statutory form. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> intenti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this new regulati<strong>on</strong> was to give the cant<strong>on</strong>alparliament the power to regulate organizati<strong>on</strong>al issues, particularly the executi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thefederal law, which in Switzerland is carried out by cant<strong>on</strong>al administrati<strong>on</strong>s, in the form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>parliamentary decrees that, as administrative acts, cannot be challenged by direct democraticrights 52 . This change in the scope <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the statutory initiative, however, does not affect the value<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy because no distincti<strong>on</strong> is made between a statutory initiativewith a wide or a narrow scope <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> applicati<strong>on</strong>. In the same period, the requirements <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thec<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative remained unchanged.In the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Freiburg, a new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> took effect <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2005.Regarding the instituti<strong>on</strong>al setup <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> either the statutory or the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative,however, no change was introduced. Thus, the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy remains unaffected.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sole difference to the old legal system is that for both types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> initiatives the signaturerequirements are now explicitly stated in the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> instead <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> being regulatedexclusively by a cant<strong>on</strong>al law. This complete regulati<strong>on</strong> at the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al level does not,however, diminish the power <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the electorate to change these requirements through aninitiative because in Freiburg it is (and was) as easy to launch a statutory initiative as tolaunch a c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al <strong>on</strong>e.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> people <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Schaffhausen adopted a new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> that came into force <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>January, 2003. This new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> is <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> those total revisi<strong>on</strong>s that aimed to modernizethe structure and wording without changing the legal c<strong>on</strong>tent – at least as far as the initiativesare c<strong>on</strong>cerned. In the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, both types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> initiatives are now regulated in <strong>on</strong>earticle (art. 27 CC) rather than being dispersed within the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> (art. 108, 107 old CCand art. 43 old CC). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, no change is observed in the values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the subindices <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> eitherthe c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al or the statutory initiative.51 As well as <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory statutory referendum – see secti<strong>on</strong> 4.52 According to Mr. DÜRST, Ratsschreiber in the Regierungskanzlei <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Glarus, in practice this restricti<strong>on</strong> was<strong>on</strong>ly carried out to solve an academic battle over whether all executi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> federal laws needed to be based <strong>on</strong>a so-called cant<strong>on</strong>al introductory law ('Einführungsgesetz') that would, under the old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, have beensubject to a mandatory referendum. In political practice, he claims, no restricti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democratic rightswas caused by this amendment in May 2002.


– 37 –During the time period under investigati<strong>on</strong>, the people <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong> also adopted a newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> in 2002, which took effect <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2003. This new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>brought about decisive changes for the statutory and c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiatives. Overall,launching an initiative seems to have become more difficult under the new regulati<strong>on</strong>.Specifically, in the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, the time for collecting signatures was fixed at 5 m<strong>on</strong>thsfor either initiative (for reas<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 'harm<strong>on</strong>izati<strong>on</strong>' 53 ) and the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> signatures was raisedsubstantially (from 4,000 to 6,000) for the statutory and maintained at 8,000 for thec<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative, respectively. Hence, the time requirement has become stricter for thec<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative but more relaxed for the statutory <strong>on</strong>e. As a c<strong>on</strong>sequence, thesubindex for the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative stayed the same 54 , but the subindex for the statutoryinitiative declined from 4 points down to 3.66 points. One new feature in this c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> isthe introducti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the so-called Einheitsinitiative (unitary initiative), which is easier to launchin comparis<strong>on</strong> to a traditi<strong>on</strong>al statutory or c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative (4,000 signatures in 5m<strong>on</strong>ths, art. 43, 1 CC and art. 45 CC). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> advantages and disadvantages <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this kind <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>initiative have already been described in the previous secti<strong>on</strong>. As a final change, the minimumtime gap between passing a new law and starting a new initiative appears to have been erasedin the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>. Neither the unitary initiative nor the change in minimum time gap isreflected in the subindex for the statutory initiative.Like many other cant<strong>on</strong>al people, the citizens <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Graubünden also opted for a newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, which became effective <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2004, but which is outside thescope <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this investigati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> new stipulati<strong>on</strong>s brought about a rise in the people'sempowerment through a decrease in the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> signatures necessary for a c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>alinitiative (from 5,000 signatures down to 4,000). This development should be well reflected ina higher value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the subindex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative (from 4.333 up to 4.666).Regarding the statutory initiative, however, the old requirements remained unchanged at3,000 signatures. For both initiatives, the time for collecting signatures is set at <strong>on</strong>e year in acant<strong>on</strong>al law (art. 53c, 1 GPR), which has remained unaltered since 1962.Also counted am<strong>on</strong>g the new cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s has to be that <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Italian-speakingcant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Tessin, which was adopted in December 1997 and became effective <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>January, 1998. Regarding both c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al and statutory initiatives, no changes areobservable in the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al stipulati<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sole observed change is that the time period53 See PROTOCOL 1 and PROTOCOL 2.54 As the index is c<strong>on</strong>structed, both 180 and 150 days <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> time for collecti<strong>on</strong> fall in the same category.


– 38 –available for collecti<strong>on</strong> is now regulated at the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al level and not (exclusively)through a cant<strong>on</strong>al law (art. 3, 3 LIRR for the old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>; art. 137, 1 LEDP since 1 Jan,1999). Hence, the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy is unaffected. As the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> signatures forlaunching a c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative is significantly higher than the number necessary for astatutory <strong>on</strong>e (10,000 vs. 7,000), it is now more difficult for the people to induce a change inthe requirement <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the time period for collecti<strong>on</strong> than prior to the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>. At thispoint, it should be noted that the informati<strong>on</strong> in T/S 1999, p. 343, <strong>on</strong> the signaturerequirement for the statutory initiative in the proposed c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> does not reflect thenumber actually set in the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong> Waadt also experienced the introducti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, which entered int<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>orce <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> September, 2003. As in many other cases, however, <strong>on</strong>ly small instituti<strong>on</strong>alchanges were introduced through this process. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> time period for collecting signatures foreither initiative was increased from 3 m<strong>on</strong>ths to 4 m<strong>on</strong>ths (art. 79, 2 CC) 55 ; however, thenumber <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> signatures was augmented to 18,000 for a total revisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> butstayed the same for the partial revisi<strong>on</strong> and the statutory initiative. Since the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy does not take into account a total revisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> (which occurs lessthan <strong>on</strong>ce in a human lifetime <strong>on</strong> average), it is not affected by that latter change.Nevertheless, the subindices for either initiative should increase from 2004 <strong>on</strong>wards. Inadditi<strong>on</strong>, as in many other cant<strong>on</strong>s and in c<strong>on</strong>trast to the old legal setup, the time period forcollecting signatures is now regulated at the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al level. As, however, therequirements for changing a cant<strong>on</strong>al law and amending the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> are identical inWaadt, regulating such an issue in the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> does not weaken the instituti<strong>on</strong>-settingpower <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the people. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> old regulatory setup facilitated, in theory, changes by the parliamentto their advantage because cant<strong>on</strong>al laws were then subject <strong>on</strong>ly to an opti<strong>on</strong>al statutoryreferendum. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al parliament, however, has never abused its power in the pastbecause, in political practice, the stipulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 3 m<strong>on</strong>ths has remained unchanged, at leastsince 1978 56 .Finally, the people <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Neuenburg also totally revised their old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> and voted <strong>on</strong> a new<strong>on</strong>e <strong>on</strong> the 16th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> October, 2001, which took effect <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2002. In the new55 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al stipulati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tradicts the time limit laid down in the cant<strong>on</strong>al law <strong>on</strong> political rights(art. 92, 1 LEDP). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Grand C<strong>on</strong>seil <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Waadt, however, amended this law <strong>on</strong> the 5th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> April, 2005. Thisrevisi<strong>on</strong> will come into force after a delay <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 40 days if the electorate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Waadt does not carry out a statutoryreferendum to overrule this change.56 See T/S 1999, p. 375 c<strong>on</strong>t. for an account <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the instituti<strong>on</strong>al development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the initiative.


– 39 –c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, the stipulati<strong>on</strong>s are more transparently and logically structured, but this did notcause a change in the instituti<strong>on</strong>al setup for either initiative. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, the two subindices <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the statutory and the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiatives remain unchanged. Additi<strong>on</strong>ally in this case, therequirement <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the time period, originally solely regulated in the cant<strong>on</strong>al law <strong>on</strong> politicalrights (LDP), became part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al provisi<strong>on</strong>s.4 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum4.1 Mandatory <strong>St</strong>atutory ReferendumCant<strong>on</strong>Zürich(30 Mar 2004)Table 4: Mandatory <strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum Between 1997 and 2003Article in cant.c<strong>on</strong>st.art. 30, num. 1Effective since1 Jan 1999(27 Sept 1998)RemarksN<strong>on</strong>-existing for lawsart. 30 bis, 1art. 30 bis, 31 Jan 1999(27 Sept 1998)Extraordinary mand. stat. ref. forlaws and decreesZürich(old)Bern(21 Oct 2003)Luzern(21 Oct 2003)Uri(1 Apr 2003)Schwyz(18 Aug 2004)art. 30, num. 1 1869 All formal laws, including treatieswhich have an impact <strong>on</strong> thecant<strong>on</strong>al legislati<strong>on</strong> (see T/S 1999,p. 405)art. 61, 2 22 Sept 2002 Extraordinary stat. mand.referendum <strong>on</strong> issues which aresubject to the opti<strong>on</strong>al referendumart. 39, 1 1 Jan 1977 Extraordinary mand. stat. ref. forart. 24 lit. bart. 25, 4art. 30, 1art. 32Obwalden(22 Oct 2002) art. 58 lit. c(5 Dec 1976)1 Jan 1985(28 Oct 1984)laws and c<strong>on</strong>cordatsAll formal lawsExtraordinary mand. stat. ref. fordecrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Landrat1969 / 1970 All Laws29 Nov 1998(29 Nov 1998)Extraordinary mand. stat. ref. fordecrees and by-laws enacted by theKant<strong>on</strong>sratOnly initiatives which are notaccepted by the Kant<strong>on</strong>sratart. 59, 2 lit. aExtraordinary mand. stat. ref. forlaws


– 40 –Table 4: Mandatory <strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum Between 1997 and 2003 (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Cant<strong>on</strong>Obwalden(old)Nidwalden(28 Dec 2001)Glarus(30 Mar 2004)Article in cant.c<strong>on</strong>st.Effective sinceRemarksart. 65 19 May 1968 All laws were passed in a popularvote at the ballot box,(Landsgemeinde) 57 . For opti<strong>on</strong>alreferendum, see table 5N<strong>on</strong>-existingart. 69, 1 5 May 2002(5 May 2002)Landsgemeinde: <strong>on</strong>ly importantregulati<strong>on</strong>s and provisi<strong>on</strong>s arepassed in the form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> lawsGlarus(old)Zug(1 Apr 2003)Freiburg(18 Aug 2004)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2005Freiburg(old)art. 69, 1 lit. b, c 1 May 1988(1 May 1988)art. 34, 4art. 34, 12 Dec 1990(2 Dec 1990)1 Jan 2005(16 May 2004)11 Mar 1921(30 Jan1921)Landsgemeinde: All laws andtreaties, including those forexecuti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> federal lawsExtraordinary mand. stat. ref. forlaws and decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>sratN<strong>on</strong>-existingN<strong>on</strong> existing(see also T/S 1999, p. 210)Solothurn(30 Mar 2004)art. 35 1, lit. c11 Dec 1998(29 Nov1998)Laws which have been passed byless than 2/3 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the present members<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>sratSolothurn(old)Basel-<strong>St</strong>adt(4 July 2000)Basel-Land(22 Oct 2002)art. 35, 2;art. 35, 1 lit. kart. 35, 1 lit. dart. 35, 2;art. 35, 1 lit. k(art. 28, 3)art. 29, 1art. 30 lit. a1 Jan 1988(1 Jan 1988)1 Jan 1988, andbefore 1887(1 Jan 1988 /(8 Jun 1986))1890 / 1991(1978 / 1979)1 Jan 2000(7 June 1998)Extraordinary mand, stat. ref. fordecrees (no change)All lawsSee T/S 1999, p. 313.Extraordinary mand. stat ref. fordecrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>srat(all laws stemming fromunformulated initiatives)Extraordinary mand. stat ref. forLaws passed with less than 4/5 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the present members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Landratart. 30 lit. b1 Jan 2000(7 June 1998)Extraordinary mand. stat. ref. forlaws and nomothetic internati<strong>on</strong>altreaties57 Pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong> with Mr. DILLIER <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Rechstdienst <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Obwalden (24/08/2004).


– 41 –Table 4: Mandatory <strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum Between 1997 and 2003 (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Cant<strong>on</strong>Basel-Land(old)Schaffhausen(21 Oct 2003)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2003Article in cant.Effective sincec<strong>on</strong>st.art. 30 lit. b 1 Jan 1987(4 Nov 1984)art. 32 lit. c 1 Jan 2003(22 Sept 2002)art. 32 lit. eRemarksAll laws and important decreesAll Laws which are not subject to anopti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum; i.e.those to which less than 4/5 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thepresent members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>srathave agreedDecrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>srat,stipulated in a cant<strong>on</strong>al lawSchaffhausen(old)Appenzell AR(3 Apr 2001)art. 32 lit. iart. 42, 1art. 42, 1 num. 6art. 60, 1 lit. d8 June 1980(1895, 1960,1977, 1978)1 June 2000(21 May 2000)Extraordinary mandatory statutoryreferendum for any decree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theKant<strong>on</strong>sratAll laws which are not subject to theopti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum(see T/S 1999, p. 18, p. 283)Decrees based <strong>on</strong> art. 23extraordinary mand. stat. ref. forlaws and decrees and possibletreaties(see T/S. 1999, p. 283-284)Fundamental decrees(Grundsatzbeschluss)Appenzell AR(28 Sept 1997)Appenzell IR(30 Mar 2004)<strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>(9 July 2002)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2003<strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>(old)art. 60, 1 lit. h1 June 2000(21 May 2000)art. 60, lit. b, c 1 May 1996(30 Apr 1995)art. 1, 2art. 19, 1art. 20, 127 Apr 1873(24 Nov 1872)art. 49, 1 1 Jan 2003(10 June 2001)Extraordinary mandatory stat. ref.for issues subject to the opti<strong>on</strong>alstat. ref.Mandatory statutory referendum forlaws and treaties with law-creatingcharacter; voting at the ballot boxLandsgemeinde(i.e. mand. stat. ref. is existing)Extraordinary mandatory stat. ref.for laws and nomotheticinternati<strong>on</strong>al treatiesart. 47, 1 (16 Nov 1890) Extraordinary mand. stat. ref <strong>on</strong>issues subject to the opti<strong>on</strong>al stat.ref.(T/S 1999; p. 327 c<strong>on</strong>t.)


– 42 –Table 4: Mandatory <strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum Between 1997 and 2003 (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Cant<strong>on</strong>Graubünden(6 July 2004)New c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2004Graubünden(old)Graubünden(old)(c<strong>on</strong>t.)Aargau(30 Mar 2004)Aargau(old)Article in cant.c<strong>on</strong>st.art. 16, num. 2art. 16, num. 5,art. 16, num. 6art. 2, 2, num. 3art. 2, 2 num. 4art. 2, 2 num. 5Effective since1 Jan 2004(18 May 2003,14 Sept 2003)1 Jan 1894(2 Oct 1892)Art. 2, 2 num. 7 1 Jan 1894(2 Oct 1892)art. 62, 1B,lit. e1 Jan 2003(2 June 2002)1 Jan 2003(2 June 2002)RemarksTreaties which affect thec<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>extraordinary mand. stat. ref. for allissues regulated in art. 16Organic Laws, Laws regarding theadministrati<strong>on</strong>, cant<strong>on</strong>al laws andregulati<strong>on</strong>s regarding the executi<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> federal laws; decrees whichestablish new branches <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>aladministrati<strong>on</strong>de facto no exclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> any law,see T/S 1999, p. 237Extraordinary mand. stat. ref. forany other decrees not regulated inart. 2, 2see also T/S 1999, p. 237 c<strong>on</strong>t.Laws and decrees subject to anopti<strong>on</strong>al referendum but not passedwith absolute majority <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theGrosser Ratart. 62, 1B,lit. eart. 62, b 1 Jan 1982 All Laws(as in T/S 1999, p. 124)Extraordinary mand. stat. ref. for thesame laws and decreesThurgau(22 Oct 2002)Tessin(30 Mar 1999)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by the 1 Jan 1998Tessin(old)Waadt(21 Oct 2003)New c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Sept 2003Waadt(18 Jan 2000)art. 22art. 24, 21.Jan 1990(4 Dec 1988)art. 39 1 Jan 1998(14 Dec 1997)Extraordinary mand. stat. ref. forlaws and decreessee also T/S 1999, p. 347Art 135, 137 LEDPart. 21, 2 29 Oct 1967 Only unformulated statutoryinitiatives(see T/S 1999, p. 339)1 Sept 2003 N<strong>on</strong>-existing29 Nov 1998 N<strong>on</strong>-existing


– 43 –Table 4: Mandatory <strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum Between 1997 and 2003 (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Cant<strong>on</strong>Waadt(old)Wallis(21 Oct 2003)Neuenburg(16 Oct 2001)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2002Neuenburg(old)Genf(21 Oct 2003)Jura(4 July 2000)Article in cant.c<strong>on</strong>st.Art. 31, 2Art. 32, 2Effective sinceArt. 79 1 Jan 1979(20 Mar 1977)Remarks1981 (1885) N<strong>on</strong>-existing(see T/S 1999, p. 369 c<strong>on</strong>t.)1 June 1994 Extraordinary mand. stat. ref for(24 Oct 1993) laws, decrees, and nomothetictreatiessee also T/S 1999, p. 3841 Jan 2002 N<strong>on</strong>-existing21 Nov 1858 N<strong>on</strong>-existing(see also T/S 1999, p. 271)1993 N<strong>on</strong>-existing(see also T/S 1999, p. 230)Extraordinary mand. stat. ref for alldecisi<strong>on</strong>s (decrees, laws, etc.) <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theparliamentSee table 2. In some cases the dates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> effectiveness were obtained from T/S 1999, particularly for ZH, FR,BS, SG, SO, TG, TI, VD and GE. For some selected cant<strong>on</strong>s informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> popular votes <strong>on</strong> internati<strong>on</strong>altreaties have also been included.Table 4 describes the existence and scope <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory statutory referendum. In manycant<strong>on</strong>s, a mandatory statutory referendum exists that is applicable solely to very specificlaws and c<strong>on</strong>tracts but not to all cant<strong>on</strong>al laws in general. For example, since 1999 inNidwalden, the new mandatory referendum is applicable solely to administrative permissi<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong> subterraneous exploitati<strong>on</strong> or storage (art.52, 6. CC) and in Bern exclusively tointercant<strong>on</strong>al treaties and alterati<strong>on</strong>s in the cant<strong>on</strong>al demarcati<strong>on</strong>s (art. 61, 1 lit. c, d). In suchcases, the mandatory referendum is treated and regarded as n<strong>on</strong>existent for the c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy because these special cases do not form part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the dailypolitical decisi<strong>on</strong>-making process. For this reas<strong>on</strong>, I have usually excluded these mandatoryreferenda <strong>on</strong> treaties and special issues. Included however are the extraordinary statutoryreferenda because they might shed light <strong>on</strong> the entire range <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> statutory referenda (jointly withthe opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum) that exists in a cant<strong>on</strong>. In general, however, the analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the mandatory statutory referendum addresses all those applicable to all cant<strong>on</strong>al laws,decrees and by-laws.


– 44 –4.2 Comments <strong>on</strong> the Changes in the Mandatory <strong>St</strong>atutory ReferendumBetween 1997 and 2003, a c<strong>on</strong>siderable c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al change regarding the mandatorystatutory referendum could be observed in Zürich: the mandatory statutory referendum wasabolished and a opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum was introduced instead. This change becameeffective <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 1999. To evaluate how this change affects the index for thestatutory referendum, the interplay with the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum must be taken intoc<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> (see secti<strong>on</strong> 4.3), which caused a drop in the subindex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the statutoryreferendum (from 6 to 3.33). On the other hand, in 1999, an additi<strong>on</strong>al extraordinarymandatory referendum was introduced for laws and decrees (art. 30 bis, 1 and 3 CC).In cant<strong>on</strong> Bern, a restricti<strong>on</strong> with respect to extraordinary mandatory referendum wasintroduced in September 2002. Before this change any law could be subject to such anextraordinary referendum if 120 members (out <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 200) <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grosser Rat so decided (see T/S1999, p. 177). Now, however, it is stipulated that 100 members (out <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 160, art. 72 CC) canput a law or decree <strong>on</strong> the ballot if it is subject to an opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum anyway according toart. 62. CC, to which all laws, internati<strong>on</strong>al treaties, and most decrees are subject. Exceptedare specific expenditure projects that are below the threshold for an opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscalreferendum. This change, however, did not affect the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy because theextraordinary mandatory statutory referendum does not form part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> it.In the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Obwalden, the abolishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Landsgemeinde in 1998 led to a dramaticchange regarding the mandatory statutory referendum. Traditi<strong>on</strong>ally, before the popular vote<strong>on</strong> the 29th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> November, 1998, the assembly <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al electorate voted <strong>on</strong> all laws atthe ballot box (art. 65 old CC) and by open ballot in case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referenda <strong>on</strong>decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>srat (art. 61 old CC). In the new partial revisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>1998, this mandatory statutory referendum was eliminated and replaced by an opti<strong>on</strong>alstatutory referendum for laws (art. 59, 1 CC), and the old opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum <strong>on</strong> decrees wascompletely abolished 58 . According to the revised c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, a statutory initiative must bevoted up<strong>on</strong> if the Kant<strong>on</strong>srat does not agree or if it makes a counterproposal (art. 58 lit. cCC). According to art. 59, 2 lit. a, an extraordinary mandatory statutory referendum can beheld if a third <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>srat agree. This development led to a decline <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the subindex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the statutory referendum in Obwalden from 6 in 1998 to 4.33 in 1999.58 Pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong> with Mr. DILLIER <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Rechtsdienst <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Obwalden (24/08/2004).


– 45 –A similar but less drastic revisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> took place in cant<strong>on</strong> Glarus,<strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the still existing Landsgemeinden, which, <strong>on</strong> the surface, appears to have shifted powerfrom the direct democratic town meeting to the representative legislative organ Landrat <strong>on</strong> the5th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> May, 2002. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> mandatory statutory referendum was restricted to <strong>on</strong>ly 'fundamentaland important regulati<strong>on</strong>s and provisi<strong>on</strong>s' (art. 69 CC), whereas, as implicitly expressed, theremaining legal acts can be determined in the form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> decrees and by-laws by the Landrat(see also art. 82, 4 CC and 89, lit. b - d CC). In c<strong>on</strong>trast, in the old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, theLandsgemeinde was resp<strong>on</strong>sible for the legislati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> all types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> laws (art. 69, 1 lit. b oldCC), which also encompassed acts aimed at regulating the executi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> federal laws.Accordingly, in the new versi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> article 89 CC, the Landrat is given the power to legislatefor the executi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> both federal and intercant<strong>on</strong>al law (art. 89, d). Further, it can enactdecrees if empowered either by the Landsgemeinde or by the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> (art. 89, lit. b and cCC). In practice, however, according to my source, this partial revisi<strong>on</strong> does not play arelevant role in the daily political decisi<strong>on</strong>-making in Glarus and thus, as already discussed inthe secti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> initiatives, does not c<strong>on</strong>stitute a real restricti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislative power <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theelectorate 59 .<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> people <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong> Freiburg have passed a new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> that will come into force <strong>on</strong>the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2005. However, as regards the mandatory statutory referendum, nosignificant change between the old and new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s can be observed: in both, it isbasically n<strong>on</strong>existent.In Solothurn, laws are subject to the mandatory statutory referendum when they have beenpassed by less than a two-thirds majority in parliament. This majority c<strong>on</strong>straint was added inthe c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al referendum <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the 29th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> November, 1998, which became effective <strong>on</strong> the11th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> December, 1998 (see also T/S 1999, p. 312). Hence, since then, a mandatory statutoryreferendum has been taken place more rarely, in c<strong>on</strong>trast to when the unrestricted versi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>this referendum was in force before November 1998. A similar case applies to Basel-Land,where the mandatory statutory referendum is applied to cant<strong>on</strong>al laws passed by less thenfour-fifths <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the votes in the cant<strong>on</strong>al parliament (see also T/S 1999, p. 137). This c<strong>on</strong>straintwas added through a decisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Landrat <strong>on</strong> the 12th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> March, 1998, which becameeffective <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2000. In the course <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this revisi<strong>on</strong>, the extraordinarymandatory statutory referendum was also introduced (art. 30 b CC). In the two cases <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>59 See also footnote 52.


– 46 –Solothurn and Basel-Land, the revisi<strong>on</strong>s in the cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s in 1998 lead to a declinein the subindex value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the statutory referendum for both cant<strong>on</strong>s (from 6 to 5.33 and from 6to 5.17, respectively).On the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2003, the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong> Schaffhausen came into force,which imposes fewer restricti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> the mandatory statutory referendum than the oldc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>. As with the old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, all laws not subject to an opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum (art.32 lit. c CC) must be passed by the cant<strong>on</strong>al electorate. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se include those laws not passedby more than four-fifths <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the present members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al parliament (old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>:‘Grosser Rat‘; new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>: ‘Kant<strong>on</strong>srat’). In c<strong>on</strong>trast to the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, however,the old regulati<strong>on</strong>s also exempted laws referring to cant<strong>on</strong>al administrati<strong>on</strong> and executi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>federal laws from the mandatory referendum, as those laws did not bring about new expensesor new taxes (art. 42 old CC, T/S 1999, p. 283). Moreover, in the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, bothextraordinary mandatory and statutory referenda are applicable (art 32, 1 lit. h CC; art 33, 1lit. f CC). This widening <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the scope <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory statutory referendum in the newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, however, does not affect its valuati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the index.Decisive changes can also be observed after 1997 in the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Appenzell Ausserrhoden. Onthe 28th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> September, 1997 (effective as <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the same date), the annual open Landsgemeindemeeting was replaced by secret voting at the ballot box. At that time, however, the principlecharacter <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the direct democratic instituti<strong>on</strong> remained unchanged (and thus did not affect thevalue <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy) 60 . On the 21st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> May, 2000, however, a distincti<strong>on</strong>between the opti<strong>on</strong>al and the mandatory referendum was introduced that includes theabolishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the statutory mandatory referendum for both laws and internati<strong>on</strong>al treatiesand its replacement by an opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum (art. 60 lit. b, c old CC, art. 60 bisCC, see also table 5, effective: 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> June, 2000). Only fundamental decrees remained subjectto a mandatory statutory referendum (art. 60, 1 lit. d CC). According to Mr. SIGRIST 61 , thisnew mandatory referendum <strong>on</strong> fundamental decrees has been applicable <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>ce since itsintroducti<strong>on</strong> in June 2000 and plays a negligible role. He further stated that the laws referringto the executi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> such a fundamental decree would again be subject to the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutoryreferendum. Through the same c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al revisi<strong>on</strong>, an extraordinary mandatoryreferendum was introduced that can be applied to decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>srat if a third <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its60 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy does not take into account the type <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> voting (e.g. at the ballot box vs. by openballot).61 Chief <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Rechtsdienst Appenzell Ausserrhoden, pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong> (15/10/2004).


– 47 –present members so demand (art. 60, 1 h CC). This change can be regarded as animprovement in the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy (although not <strong>on</strong>e affecting the index) becauseprior to this last revisi<strong>on</strong> in 2000, decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>srat were not subject to anyreferendum whatsoever (see 74, 2 old CC). At this point, it should also be noted that lawstriggering a new expense are still subject to the mandatory fiscal referendum. Through theabolishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory statutory referendum, however, a decline <strong>on</strong> the subindex forthe statutory referendum was recorded (from 6 to 4.67).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> people <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong> adopted a new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the 10th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> June, 2001, which cameinto force <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2003. Regarding the mandatory statutory referendum, itsextraordinary versi<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tinues to exist in the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> with identical requirements (ademand <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>e-third <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al parliament) but couched in revised andmore modern wording (‘Kant<strong>on</strong>srat’ (2003) vs. ‘Grosser Rat’). In both c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s, theissues that are potentially subject to this type <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> referendum are identical to those potentiallysubject to an opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum (art. 49, 1 CC; art. 47 old CC, see also T/S 1999,p. 327 c<strong>on</strong>t.). It is readily apparent that these minor changes do not affect the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy for the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> abolishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory statutory referendum can also be observed in cant<strong>on</strong>Graubünden, becoming effective <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2004. Before this c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>alrevisi<strong>on</strong>, basically all laws, even those <strong>on</strong>ly regulating the executi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> federal laws, as wellas decrees that established new branches <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> administrati<strong>on</strong>, were subject to the mandatorystatutory referendum. In the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, the new opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum applies<strong>on</strong>ly for laws. In both the old and the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, however, an extraordinary statutoryreferendum exists. As observed earlier, the abolishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory statutoryreferendum for cant<strong>on</strong>al laws can be expected to cause a decline in the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy from 2004 <strong>on</strong>wards.In the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Aargau, both the diminishing power <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory statutory referendumfor laws and its strengthening for decrees can be noted simultaneously. Through a popularvote in June 2002, which became effective <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2003, the applicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> themandatory referendum for laws was restricted by the new requirement that it affect <strong>on</strong>ly thoselaws not passed by an absolute majority <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> all members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grosser Rat (art. 62, 1 b CC).Probably to ease this change, the possibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an extraordinary mandatory referendum was


– 48 –also introduced in the case that a quarter <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> all members <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al parliament demandedit (art. 62, 1 lit. b CC). In the course <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this revisi<strong>on</strong>, article 62 was appended a letter ‘e’ (art.62, 1 e CC), which extends the mandatory statutory referendum to decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grosser Rat(according to art. 63, 1 lit. b - d and f CC). This extensi<strong>on</strong> means that this referendum is nowapplicable to decrees to which, prior to its revisi<strong>on</strong>, <strong>on</strong>ly the opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum applied. Itsc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al requirement is, again, that decrees have been passed with a majority below theabsolute majority <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grosser Rat. Analogously to art. 62, 1 lit. b CC, the extraordinarymandatory referendum was also applicable to such decrees. Given that the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy assigns a higher value to a mandatory statutory referendum than to an opti<strong>on</strong>alstatutory referendum, a decline in the index will be induced by the new majority requirement.Am<strong>on</strong>g the remaining cant<strong>on</strong>s, Tessin, Waadt and Neuenburg adopted new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s in1998, 2003, and 2002, respectively. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se, however, did not bring about any changes withrespect to the n<strong>on</strong>existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory statutory referendum for cant<strong>on</strong>al laws. Hence,the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy as measured by the index was not affected.4.3 Opti<strong>on</strong>al <strong>St</strong>atutory ReferendumCant<strong>on</strong>Zürich(30 Mar 2004)Table 5: Opti<strong>on</strong>al <strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum Between 1997 and 2003Signature Time-limit for Articles in cant.requirement collecti<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>st.Effective since5,000 60 days art. 30 bis, 1 1 Jan 1999(27 Sept 1998)Zürich(old)Bern(21 Oct 2003)Luzern(21 Oct 2003)Uri(1 Apr 2003)Uri(old)Mandatory statutoryreferendumSee table 410,000 3 m<strong>on</strong>ths art. 62, 2 1 Jan 1995(6 June 1993)3,000 60 days art. 39, 1 1 Nov 1969 (art. 40, 1)art. 40, 1450 90 days art. 25, 1art. 25, 2 lit. b1 Jan 1977 (art. 39, 1)1 Oct 1997(8 Jun 1997)For by-laws;mandatory stat. ref. forlaws see table 4300 90 days art. 25, 1 Only for by-laws(see T/S 1999, p. 359)(1985)mandatory stat. ref. forlaws see table 4


– 49 –Table 5: Opti<strong>on</strong>al <strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum Between 1997 and 2003 (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Cant<strong>on</strong>Schwyz(18 Aug 2004)Signature Time-limit for Articles in cant.requirement collecti<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>st.Effective since2,000 30 days art. 31, 1 21 Dec 1899(23 Oct 1898)Decrees and by-lawsmandatory stat. ref.see table 4Obwalden(22 Oct 2002)Obwalden(old)100 30 days art. 59, 1 lit. aart. 59, 2 lit. b100 30 days art. 61, no. 1art. 73, 129. Nov 1998(29.Nov 1998)LawsLandsgemeinde:opti<strong>on</strong>al statutoryreferendum fordecrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theKant<strong>on</strong>srat;mandatory stat. ref.see table 4Nidwalden(28 Dec 2001)Glarus(30 Mar 2004)Zug(1 Apr 2003)Freiburg(18 Aug 2004)new c<strong>on</strong>st. by1 Jan 2005)Freiburg(old)Solothurn(30 Mar 2004)250 2 m<strong>on</strong>ths art. 52a, .1 1 Dec 1996(1 Dec 1996)Laws1 n<strong>on</strong>e art. 57, 1 lit. bart. 58, 11,000 60 days art. 34, 1art. 34, 21 May 1988(1 May 1988)Landsgemeindemandatory stat. ref.see table 42 Dec 1990(2 Dec 1990)laws and decrees6,000 90 days art. 46 1 Jan 2005(16 May 2004)Laws6,000 90 dayssee also art.130, 2 PRGart. 28 bis, 1art. 28 quarter11 Mar 1921(30 Jan1921)Laws and decrees1,000 90 days art. 36 1, lit. b 11 Dec 1998(29 Nov 1998)Laws and decrees,which are not subjectto the mand. <strong>St</strong>at. ref.


– 50 –Table 5: Opti<strong>on</strong>al <strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum Between 1997 and 2003 (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Cant<strong>on</strong>Solothurn(old)Basel-<strong>St</strong>adt(4 July 2000)Basel-Land(22 Oct 2002)Basel-Land(old)Schaffhausen(21 Oct 2003)newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by1 Jan 2003Schaffhausen(old)Signature Time-limit for Articles in cant.requirement collecti<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>st.Effective since1,000 90 days art. 36, 1 and 2 1988 – 1998By-Laws, decreesmandatory stat. ref.see table 4see T/S 1999, p. 3142,000 6 weeks art. 29, 1 and 2 21 June 1979(24 Sept 1978)laws and decrees1,000 8 weeks art. 31, 1 lit. a Decrees by theLandrat(Planungsbeschluss)art. 31, 1 lit. c 1 Jan 1987(4 Nov 1984)Laws not beingsubject to the mand.<strong>St</strong>at. ref.1 Jan 2000(7. Jun 1998)1,000 8 weeks art. 31, 1 lit. a Decrees by theLandrat; 1 Jan 1987,(4 Nov 1984)art. 31, 1 lit. c <strong>St</strong>at. mand. ref. seetable 4 (see T/S 1999,p. 137 c<strong>on</strong>t.)1,000 90 days art. 33, 1 lit. a All laws to which atleast 4/5 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Rathave agreed<strong>St</strong>at. mand. ref. seetable 4art. 33, 1 lit. b Internati<strong>on</strong>al treaties1,000 90 days art. 42 bis, 1 8 Jun 1980laws c<strong>on</strong>cerningorganizati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>administrati<strong>on</strong> orexecuti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> laws; allremaining laws towhich at least 4/5 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the Rat have agreedAppenzell AR(3 Apr 2001)300 60 days art. 60 bis 1 June 2000(21 May 2000)Laws, treaties withlaw-like character


– 51 –Table 5: Opti<strong>on</strong>al <strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum Between 1997 and 2003 (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Cant<strong>on</strong>Appenzell AR(old)Appenzell IR(30 Mar 2004)<strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>(9 July 2002)newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by1 Jan 2003SignaturerequirementTime-limit forcollecti<strong>on</strong>Articles in cant.c<strong>on</strong>st.4,000 40 days art. 49, 1 lit. a, bart. 50, 1Effective since1 May 1996(30 Apr 1995)mandatory statutoryreferendum, see table427. Apr 1873(24 Nov 1872)<strong>St</strong>atutory MandatoryReferendum, see table41 Jan 2003(10 Jun 2001)Laws and internati<strong>on</strong>altreaties with law-likec<strong>on</strong>tent<strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>(old)4,000 30 days art. 47 Laws, general decreesnot subject to art. 55or not <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an urgentnatureGraubünden(6 July 2004)newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by1 Jan 2004Graubünden(old)Aargau(30 Mar 2004)1,000 90 days art. 17, 1 num. 1art. 17, 1 num. 23,000 90 daysart. 63, lit. aart. 63, lit. fart. 63, 1 lit. b(art. 62, 1 lit. b,lit. e)T/S 1999; p. 327 c<strong>on</strong>t.Laws; Internati<strong>on</strong>altreaties with lawaffectingc<strong>on</strong>tent1 Jan 2004 (18 May2003, 14 Sept 2004)N<strong>on</strong>-existing1 Jan 1894(2 Oct 1892)<strong>St</strong>at. mand. ref. seetable 41 Jan 2003(2 Jun 2002)-Laws-Specific decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the Grosser Rat whichare determined by law-Fundamental plans <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>state activitywhich are all not s.t. amandatory referendum(see table 4)art. 40 GPR


– 52 –Aargau(old)Table 5: Opti<strong>on</strong>al <strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum Between 1997 and 2003 (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Cant<strong>on</strong>Thurgau(22 Oct 2002)Tessin(30 Mar 1999)newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by1 Jan 1998Tessin(old)Waadt(21 Oct 2003)newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by1 Sept 2003Waadt(old)Signature Time-limit for Articles in cant.requirement collecti<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>st.3,000 90 days art. 63, 1 lit. fart. 63, 1 lit. bart. 63, 1 lit. aEffective since1 Jan 1982Specific decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theGrosser Rat which aredetermined by lawTreatiesFundamental plans <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>state activityart. 40 GPRsee also T/S 1999,p. 124 c<strong>on</strong>t.2,000 3 m<strong>on</strong>ths art. 22 1 Jan 1990(4 Dec 1988)laws,decrees <strong>on</strong> treatiessee also T/S 1999,p. 3467,000 45 daysart. 42 lit. aart. 42 lit. c1 Jan 1998(14 Dec 1997)laws and decreestreaties withnomothetic character7,000 30 days art. 60, I (31 May 1970)laws and decreesSee T/S 1999, p. 339for further applicati<strong>on</strong>12,000 40 days art. 84 1, lit. aart. 84 1, lit. bLaws and decreesTreaties withnomothetic c<strong>on</strong>tent12,000 40 days art. 27, 2 1978 /(29. Nov 1998)*laws and decreessee also T/S 1999,p. 369Wallis(21 Oct 2003)3,000 90 days art. 31, 1art. 31, 2*change c<strong>on</strong>cernsfiscal referendum, seetables 6 and 71 June 1994(24 Oct 1993)laws and decrees,treaties withnomothetic c<strong>on</strong>tentsee also T/S 1999,p. 380 c<strong>on</strong>t.


– 53 –Table 5: Opti<strong>on</strong>al <strong>St</strong>atutory Referendum Between 1997 and 2003 (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Cant<strong>on</strong>Neuenburg(16 Oct 2001)newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by1 Jan 2002Neuenburg(old)Genf(21 Oct 2003)Jura(4 July 2000)See table 2.Signature Time-limit for Articles in cant.requirement collecti<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>st.4,000 40 days art. 42, 1art. 42 2 lit. aart. 42, 2 lit. eart. 42, 2 lit. gart. 42, 2 lit. c6,000 40 days art. 39, 2art. 120 LDPEffective since1 Jan 2002(24 Sept 2001)lawstreatiesextraordinary opti<strong>on</strong>alstatutory referendumdecrees based <strong>on</strong>people's initiatives1879, 1959(see T/S 1999, p. 271)Laws and specificdecrees7,000 40 days art. 53 1983(7 Mar 1982)LawsSee also T/S 1999,p. 221-2222,000 60 daysart. 94 LDPart. 78art. 78 lit. aart. 78 lit. c(1 Jan 1979)20 Mar 1977LawsTreaties withnomothetic characterSee also T/S 1999,p. 250 c<strong>on</strong>t.Table 5 describes the legal <strong>St</strong>atus Quo and recent amendments c<strong>on</strong>cerning opti<strong>on</strong>al statutoryreferenda referring to laws, decrees, or by-laws as they influence the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy in a cant<strong>on</strong> as measured by the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy. For reas<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>completeness, I have also included informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the extraordinary opti<strong>on</strong>al statutoryreferendum. Usually, not reported are opti<strong>on</strong>al referenda referring to internati<strong>on</strong>al orintercant<strong>on</strong>al treaties or <strong>on</strong> special issues. To understand the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these changes <strong>on</strong> thecomposite index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy, it must be recalled that in most cases, the subindex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the statutory referendum is c<strong>on</strong>structed as an average <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the opti<strong>on</strong>al and the mandatorystatutory referendum, if both exist. Again, I will <strong>on</strong>ly include in the verbal descripti<strong>on</strong> thosecases in which alterati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum have occurred since 1997.


– 54 –4.4 Comments <strong>on</strong> the Changes in the Opti<strong>on</strong>al <strong>St</strong>atutory ReferendumAfter 1997, many cant<strong>on</strong>s introduced some alterati<strong>on</strong>s regarding the opti<strong>on</strong>al mandatorystatutory referendum. To begin with, Zürich introduced such a referendum as a new instituti<strong>on</strong>replacing the abolished mandatory statutory referendum. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum is fitted outwith the requirement <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 5,000 signatures to be collected within 60 days. As discussed before,in the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Zürich, this change in the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> led to a decline <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index for thestatutory referendum.In Uri, the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum applies <strong>on</strong>ly to by-laws, not to laws. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> signaturerequirement for this referendum was raised from 300 to 450 votes in June 1997. In this specialcase, the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the statutory referendum is negatively affected by this development. For thetreatment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Uri c<strong>on</strong>cerning the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy, see the secti<strong>on</strong> 6.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> next cant<strong>on</strong> in which a c<strong>on</strong>siderable development could be observed is Obwalden. In thecourse <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the introducti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a (partly) representative system that became effective in 1998,Obwalden introduced an opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum for laws as a new instituti<strong>on</strong> with asignature requirement <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 100 and a collecti<strong>on</strong> time <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 30 days but abolished the old opti<strong>on</strong>alreferendum for decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>srat (with the identical requirements). According to mysource, as a result, decrees can no l<strong>on</strong>ger be challenged by a referendum 62 . This abolishment<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory statutory referendum has led to a lower index value for the both the opti<strong>on</strong>aland the overall statutory referendum compared to the previous maximum value.On the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2005, a new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> entered into force in the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Freiburg.This new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> did not, however, bring about any new stipulati<strong>on</strong>s regarding theopti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum (6,000 signatures within 90 days). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>ly difference lies inthe fact that the time period for collecti<strong>on</strong> is now regulated at the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al not thestatutory level.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> people <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong> Solothurn partially revised their c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> in November 1998.Before 1998, the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum was <strong>on</strong>ly applicable to decrees not to laws, towhich the mandatory referendum applied (T/S 1999, p. 313 c<strong>on</strong>t.). Now all laws and decrees<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al parliament can be subject to an opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> signature62 Pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong> with Mr. DILLIER, Rechtsdienst <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Obwalden (24/08/2004).


– 55 –requirement <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1,500 votes and a time limit for collecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 90 days were kept in theamended article. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index for the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum reaches 4.67 for1999 <strong>on</strong>, and the final value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the subindex for the statutory referendum was brought downfrom the maximum value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 6 in and prior to 1998.In Basel-Land, the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum for laws was also introduced as a newinstituti<strong>on</strong> because the use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory statutory referendum was restricted. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> number<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> signatures required was set to 1,500 in a popular vote in 1998, and the time available forcollecti<strong>on</strong> was stipulated as 60 days, identical to the requirements for the old opti<strong>on</strong>alstatutory referendum for decrees, which still exists (see T/S 1999, p. 137, for the oldc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se changes caused the index for the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum to declinebecause <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the former restricti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the old mandatory statutory referendum before 2000.In Schaffhausen, the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2003, brought about a restricti<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum in comparis<strong>on</strong> to the old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>: <strong>on</strong>ly all those laws,including laws c<strong>on</strong>cerning administrative issues, to which more than four-fifths <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Rathave agreed are subject to this instituti<strong>on</strong>. In the old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, however, all laws related toadministrati<strong>on</strong> and organizati<strong>on</strong> were subject to the opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum (because theremaining laws were subject to the mandatory referendum). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ‘administrative’laws in the scope <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory referendum led to no change in the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy.In the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Appenzell Ausserrhoden, the electorate decided to introduce an opti<strong>on</strong>almandatory referendum for laws in 2000, which was not known prior to this date. This opti<strong>on</strong>alreferendum applies to laws and internati<strong>on</strong>al treaties with a nomothetic impact and can becarried out if 300 signatures have been collected within 60 days after the publicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thatlaw or treaty. Since this new opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum replaces an old mandatory referendum, adecline in the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the overall index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the statutory referendum occurred (see also table 9).On January 1st, 2003, a new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> became effective in the cant<strong>on</strong> <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>. One <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theprominent differences between the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the old and <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> is the time available for the collecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the necessary signatures, which has beenincreased from 30 days to 40 days while the required number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> signatures has been leftunaltered. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> scope <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this referendum has been narrowed because, general decrees(allgemeinverbindlicher Beschluss) <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grosser Rat (now: Kant<strong>on</strong>srat) are no l<strong>on</strong>ger


– 56 –subject to this referendum (and hence not subject to any referendum at all), whereas cant<strong>on</strong>allaws can still be challenged through a referendum (art 49, 1 lit. a CC; art. 47 old CC). In thenew c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, however, regulati<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>cerning the wages <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> civil servants and teachers areexplicitly exempted from the referendum (art. 49, 2 CC). On the other hand, the scope <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theopti<strong>on</strong>al referendum has been widened as internati<strong>on</strong>al and intercant<strong>on</strong>al treaties are nowsubject to it if their c<strong>on</strong>tent is nomothetic (art. 49, 1 lit. b). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> increase in the time availablefor collecti<strong>on</strong> has caused an increase in the subindex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the statutory referendum, which isalso reflected in the total index (see table 9).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> electorate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Graubünden also voted <strong>on</strong> a new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> both <strong>on</strong> the 18th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> May andthe 14th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> September, 2003 63 , which took effect <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2004. Similar to thedevelopment observable in other cant<strong>on</strong>s, the mandatory statutory referendum was replacedby an opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum in the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>. This new opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum is bothapplicable to cant<strong>on</strong>al laws and to treaties whose stipulati<strong>on</strong>s are nomothetic. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> requirement<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1,500 signing supporters out <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the electorate must be met within 90 days after publicati<strong>on</strong>.This c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al change will cause the subindex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the overall statutory referendum to fallfrom its old level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 6 points from 2004 <strong>on</strong>.Observable in the cant<strong>on</strong> Aargau is <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cases in which the scope <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the opti<strong>on</strong>almandatory referendum was broadened at the expense <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory statutory referendum.On the 2nd <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> June, 2002, the electorate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Aargau opted for a revisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> art. 63, 1 lit. a CC.This amendment led to an abolishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the old unc<strong>on</strong>strained mandatory referendum byincluding an absolute majority c<strong>on</strong>straint and by adding 'laws' as a new field <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> applicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum. Additi<strong>on</strong>al potential applicati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum are laiddown in art. 63, 1 CC (except for lit. e), which also include (am<strong>on</strong>g others) decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theGrosser Rat, already known in the old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al requirements for takingthe opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum remained unchanged (3,000 signatures in 90 days). As theindex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy takes into account the statutory referendum for laws rather than fordecrees, a decline in the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the overall index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> statutory referendum occurred due to thischange, which also transmits to the total index (see table 9).63 Because the <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ficial result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the first popular vote <strong>on</strong> the vote system for electing the Grosser Rat appeared tobe scanty and changed after a recount in May 2003, it was decided to hold a sec<strong>on</strong>d popular vote inSeptember 2003 for reas<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> clarificati<strong>on</strong> (pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong> with Mr. FRIZZONI (10/09/2004)).


– 57 –<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al electorate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Tessin passed a new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> effective <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January,1998, that raised the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> days available for collecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 7,000 signatures from 30 to 45(art. 42 CC). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum is applicable to both laws and decrees. This changecaused an increase in the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum, which equals the(overall) index for the statutory referendum because no mandatory referendum is known inthis cant<strong>on</strong> (see also table 9 for the overall change).In the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Waadt, a partial revisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> took place in 1998 that, however,did not affect the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum for laws (and decrees), <strong>on</strong>ly the fiscalreferendum (see tables 6 and 7). In 2003, the electorate passed a completely new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>(effective the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> September, 2003) 64 that extended the applicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the opti<strong>on</strong>alreferendum <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> laws and decrees to internati<strong>on</strong>al treaties and c<strong>on</strong>cordats in case theirstipulati<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>tradicted cant<strong>on</strong>al law or were <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a law-giving character in general (art. 84 1,lit. b CC). In the old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, it was not possible for the people to challenge these treaties(see T/S 1999, p. 368 c<strong>on</strong>t.). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> requirements for taking an opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum, 12,000signatures and 40 days, have remained unchanged since 1997, leaving the index unaffected.Finally, in Neuenburg, a new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> was also adopted in 2001 that entered into force as<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2002. This new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> brought first, a change in the scope <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>applicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the opti<strong>on</strong>al (statutory) referendum and sec<strong>on</strong>d, a facilitati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> carrying it out.On the <strong>on</strong>e hand, both in the old and new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s, the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum isapplicable to laws, but the specific (general) decrees (art. 39, 2 old CC) are exempted fromapplicati<strong>on</strong> in the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>. On the other hand, as regards requirements, the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>signatures was lowered from 6,000 down to 4,500, whereas the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> days for collectingthem remains the same (LDP art. 120: for the old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>; art. 42, 1 CC: for the newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>); this new requirement is now entirely regulated in the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> itself. New tothe opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum, however, is its applicati<strong>on</strong> to internati<strong>on</strong>al and intercant<strong>on</strong>al treaties(art. 42, 2 e CC) that are either nomothetic or equivalent to a decree leading to expenses 65 .Finally, an extraordinary opti<strong>on</strong>al (statutory) referendum was also introduced <strong>on</strong> ”other acts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the Grand C<strong>on</strong>seil“ in the case that 35 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its members so decide (art. 42, 2 g CC). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> declinein signatures in the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> has caused the subindex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the statutory referendum torise for Neuenburg (see also table 9).64 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> date <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> effectiveness given in the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> (art. 175 CC) was altered through a decree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theGrand C<strong>on</strong>seil <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Waadt (2nd <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> July, 2003).65 For a discussi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the n<strong>on</strong>applicability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum to treaties in the old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, see T/S1999, p. 272.


– 58 –5 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fiscal Referendum<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> next two tables are devoted to the descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> both the mandatory(table 6) and opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum (table 7) <strong>on</strong> expenditure projects in the Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>sbetween 1997 and 2003.Ec<strong>on</strong>omically, fiscal referenda refer to resoluti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al parliament that triggerexpenses; these can be both administrative and legislative acts (from a legal perspective). Insome cant<strong>on</strong>s, the fiscal referendum refers explicitly to cant<strong>on</strong>al laws. In any case, thesedecrees and laws involve a substantial expense that must be borne by the cant<strong>on</strong>al budget andthus by the cant<strong>on</strong>al taxpayer. In some cases in which the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum referssolely to decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the parliament, it is the statutory referendum that serves as a c<strong>on</strong>troldevice over expenses triggered by cant<strong>on</strong>al law. In this sense, the fiscal and the statutoryreferendum do c<strong>on</strong>stitute two instituti<strong>on</strong>s whose scope <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> applicati<strong>on</strong> might partly overlap.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> following tables describe <strong>on</strong>ly fiscal referenda <strong>on</strong> expenditure projects (the mostimportant type) and do not take into account the existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> either extraordinary fiscalreferenda or fiscal referenda not related to expenditure projects, such as referenda <strong>on</strong> tax rates,acquisiti<strong>on</strong> or dispositi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> real estate, b<strong>on</strong>d loans, and so <strong>on</strong>, because these latter do notform part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy. For c<strong>on</strong>structing the subindex, in the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thefiscal referendum, usually the greater value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the points awarded to either the opti<strong>on</strong>al or themandatory referendum is chosen.5.1 Mandatory Fiscal ReferendumTable 6: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fiscal Referendum – Mandatory (Ordinary) between 1997 and 2003Cant<strong>on</strong>Zürich(30 Mar 2004)Zürich(old)Financialthreshold> 20 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 2 milli<strong>on</strong>)Article in cant.c<strong>on</strong>st.effective since Remarks1 Jan 1999 N<strong>on</strong>-existing(27 Sept 1998)art. 30 num. 2 6 June 1971 Decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theKant<strong>on</strong>sratBern(21 Oct 2003)1 Jan 1995(6 June 1993)N<strong>on</strong>-existingSee T/S 1999, p. 183


– 59 –Cant<strong>on</strong>Obwalden(22 Oct 2002)Table 6: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fiscal Referendum – Mandatory (Ordinary) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)FinancialthresholdArticle in cant.c<strong>on</strong>st.effective since29 Nov 1998(29 Nov 1998)RemarksN<strong>on</strong>-existingObwalden(8 June1997 -29 Nov 1998)Obwalden(old)> 1 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 200,000)> 300,000(> 50,000)art. 61, num. 3 8 June 1997(8 June 1997)art. 61, num. 3 8 June 1986(8 June 1986)(Landsgemeinde)Laws and decrees(Landsgemeinde)Laws and decreesNidwalden(28 Dec 2001)Luzern(21 Oct 2003)> 5 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 500,000)>25 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 25 milli<strong>on</strong>s =10 times annualexpense)art. 52 num.4 1 Dec 1996(1 Dec1996)art. 39 bis, 1 1 Jan 1977lit. c (5 Dec 1976)art. 39, 2art. 39 bis, 3Decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the LandratDecrees and laws <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theGrosser RatUri(1 Apr 2003)> 1 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 100,000 atleast 10 years)art. 24, lit. cart. 24, lit. d1 Jan 1994(28 Nov 1993)Expenditure projects,i.e. decrees;Laws see table 4Schwyz(18 Aug 2004)> 250,000(> 50,000 )art. 30, 2 31 Dec 1958 Decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theKant<strong>on</strong>sratSee T/S 1999, p. 305Glarus(30 Mar 2004)> 1 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 200,000)art. 69, 2 lit. b 5 May 2002(5 May 2002)(Landsgemeinde)DecreesGlarus(old)> 500,000(> 100,000)art. 69, 1 lit. d 1 May 1988(1 May 1988)(Landsgemeinde)DecreesZug(1 Apr 2003)Freiburg(18 Aug 2004)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2005Freiburg(old)Solothurn(30 Mar 2004)> 1% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theoverall spending<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the lastcant<strong>on</strong>al budget> 1% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theoverall spending<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the lastcant<strong>on</strong>al budget> 5 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 500,000)At least since1970art. 45 lit. b 1 Jan 2005(16 May 2004)art. 28 bis 7 Oct 1986(8 June 1986)art. 35, 1 lit. e 11 Dec 1998(29 Nov 1998)N<strong>on</strong>-existingSee also T/S 1999, p.401Decrees and laws <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theGrand C<strong>on</strong>seil /Grosser RatLaws and decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the Grosser Rat /Grand C<strong>on</strong>seilDecrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theKant<strong>on</strong>srat


– 60 –Cant<strong>on</strong>Solothurn(old)Basel-<strong>St</strong>adt(4 July 2000)Basel-Land(22 Oct 2002)Schaffhausen(21 Oct 2003)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2003Schaffhausen(old)Table 6: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fiscal Referendum – Mandatory (Ordinary) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Financialthreshold> 2 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 200,000)> 3 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 500,000)> 1 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 100,000)Article in cant.effective sincec<strong>on</strong>st.art. 35, 1 lit. e 1 Jan 1988(8 June 1986)(new c<strong>on</strong>st.)Since 1954 orearlier1 Jan 1987 andbeforeart. 32 lit. e 1 Jan 2003(22 Sept 2002)art. 42 ter(23 Apr 1989)RemarksDecrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theKant<strong>on</strong>sratSee T/S 1999, p. 317N<strong>on</strong>-existingSee also T/S 1999,p. 161N<strong>on</strong>-existingSee T/S 1999, p. 139Decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theKant<strong>on</strong>sratDecrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the GrosserRat> 300,000 50,000 5% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ataxing unit(> 1% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ataxing unit)art. 60, 1 lit. eart. 76, 2 lit a, b1 May 1996(30 Apr 1995)(28 Sept 1997:abolishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Landsgemeinde); viavoting at the ballot boxAppenzell AR(old)> 5% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ataxing unit(> 1% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ataxing unit)art. 60, 1 lit. eart. 76, 2 lit. a, b1 May 1996(30 Apr 1995)(Landsgemeinde)Decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theKant<strong>on</strong>sratAppenzell IR(30 Mar 2004)> 1 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 200,000 for atleast 5 years)art. 7 ter, 1 28 Apr 2002(28 Apr 2002)(Landsgemeinde)Decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the GrosserRatAppenzell IR(old)> 500,000(> 100,000 for atleast 5 years)art. 7 ter, 1 25 Apr 1982 (Landsgemeinde)Decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the GrosserRat<strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>(9 July 2002)new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>by 1 Jan 2003> 15 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 1,500,000 forat least 10 years)art. 48 lit. dart.6 RIG1 Jan 2003(10 June 2001);RIG: IV. NG1 Apr 1997(11 Apr 1996)Laws and decrees;threshold specified incant<strong>on</strong>al law RIG


– 61 –Cant<strong>on</strong><strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>(old)Graubünden(6 July 2004)newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by1 Jan 2004Graubünden(old)Table 6: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fiscal Referendum – Mandatory (Ordinary) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Financialthreshold> 15 milli<strong>on</strong>s(> 1,000,000 forat least 10 years)> 10 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 1 milli<strong>on</strong>)> 5 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 500,000 )Article in cant.c<strong>on</strong>st.GS 14, 27;nGS 6, 38*effective since20 Jan 1924(17 Nov 1923)art. 6 RIG RIG: IV NG1 Apr 1997(11 Apr 1996)art. 16, num. 4 1 Jan 2004(18 May 2003,14 Sept 2003)art. 2, 2 num. 6 a (28 Jan 1973)RemarksLaws and decrees,threshold specified incant<strong>on</strong>al law RIGthrough last amendmentIV NGsee T/S 1999, p. 330Decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the GrosserRatDecrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the GrosserRatAargau(30 Mar 2004)Aargau(old)Thurgau(22 Oct 2002)Tessin(30 Mar 1999)newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> bythe 1 Jan 1998> 5 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 500,000)> 3 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 600,000 )art. 62, 1 lit. e 1 Jan 2003(2 Jun 2002)1 Jan 1982(28 Sept 1980)art. 23, 1 1 Jan 1990(4 Dec1988)1 Jan 1998(14 Dec 1997)Decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the GrosserRat if not passed withabsolute majorityN<strong>on</strong>-existingSee also T/S 1999,p. 127Decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the GrosserRatN<strong>on</strong>-existingAlso n<strong>on</strong>-existing in1997See also T/S 1999,p. 341Waadt(21 Oct 2003)newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by1 Sept 2003Waadt(18 Jan 2000)Waadt(old)Wallis(21 Oct 2003)> 20 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 2 milli<strong>on</strong> atleast for 10years)1 Sept 2003(14 Apr 2003)art. 27, 2 bis 29 Nov 1998(29 Nov 1998)N<strong>on</strong>-existingDecrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the GrandC<strong>on</strong>seil is subject to theassembly <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thecommunal electorate(assemblées decommune)1885 N<strong>on</strong>-existingSee T/S 1999, p. 3711 June 1994 N<strong>on</strong>-existing(24 Oct 1993) See T/S 1999, p. 382


– 62 –Cant<strong>on</strong>Neuenburg(16 Oct 2001)newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by1 Jan 2002Neuenburg(old)Genf(21 Oct 2003)Jura(4 July 2000)Table 6: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fiscal Referendum – Mandatory (Ordinary) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Financialthreshold> 1.5 %(> 1.5 per mill)<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> total cant<strong>on</strong>alrevenues> 5%(> 5 per mill)<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the revenues<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the last budgetArticle in cant.c<strong>on</strong>st.effective since1 Jan 2002(24 Sept 2000)art. 39, 3 1992(8 Dec 1991)art. 77, lit. dart. 77, lit. e1 Jan 1979(20 Mar 1977)RemarksN<strong>on</strong>-existingLaws and decreesSee also T/S 1999,p. 273N<strong>on</strong>-existingSee also T/S 1999,p. 223laws and decrees, allexpenses notdetermined by a lawsee also T/S 1999,p. 253See table 2. In the column 'Financial threshold', the threshold for recurring expenses is displayed in brackets, whilethe expenditure threshold for n<strong>on</strong>recurring expenses is displayed above. All numbers are in Swiss Francs.* Grossratsbeschluss (decree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grosser Rat <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>) <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the 17th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> November, 1923.5.2 Comments <strong>on</strong> the Changes in the Mandatory Fiscal ReferendumSince 1997, <strong>on</strong>ly a few developments regarding the mandatory fiscal referendum (<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theordinary type) could be observed. In most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>s, either the mandatory fiscalreferendum was abolished and replaced by an opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum or the threshold wasincreased substantially. Certainly, such a development might cause a decline in the subindexfor the fiscal referendum.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> most prominent change is probably that which occurred in Zürich. After years <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theexistence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a mandatory fiscal referendum (from at least 1970 <strong>on</strong>; see T/S 1999, p. 406), theelectorate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Zürich decided to abolish it and keep <strong>on</strong>ly the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum. Thisnew c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al amendment became effective <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 1999. An eliminati<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory fiscal referendum and its replacement by the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum alsooccurred in Obwalden (effective: the 29th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> November, 1998) after the threshold for themandatory fiscal referendum for laws and decrees had already been increased substantially <strong>on</strong>the 8th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> June, 1997, from 300,000 to 1 milli<strong>on</strong> Swiss Francs. A similar development could


– 63 –also be observed in the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Neuenburg, where <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2002, the newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> brought about the n<strong>on</strong>existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory fiscal referendum. Before thattotal revisi<strong>on</strong>, such an instituti<strong>on</strong> was present for n<strong>on</strong>recurring expenses <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> more than 1.5% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the last total cant<strong>on</strong>al revenues (art. 39, 3 old CC). Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, in the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Waadt, aneliminati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a previously existing mandatory fiscal referendum took place in April 2003.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this instituti<strong>on</strong> in this particular cant<strong>on</strong> is described in more detail below.An obvious decline is noticeable in the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy for these cant<strong>on</strong>s.An increase in the threshold for the mandatory fiscal referendum could be observed in variouscant<strong>on</strong>s. One <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> them is Glarus, in which the threshold for decrees was raised from 500,000 to1 milli<strong>on</strong> Swiss Francs <strong>on</strong> the 5th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> May, 2002. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong> Solothurn also partially revisedits requirements for a mandatory fiscal referendum for decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>srat and raisedthe old financial threshold from 2,000,000 to 5,000,000 Swiss Francs in 1998, which is morethan a doubling <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the old threshold valid since 1988. Similarly, the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thecant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Schaffhausen brought about a tripling <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the old threshold for decrees from 1milli<strong>on</strong> to 3 milli<strong>on</strong> Swiss Francs for n<strong>on</strong>recurring expenses from the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2003,<strong>on</strong>ward. At this point, it is also worth pointing out that the special mandatory fiscalreferendum with a substantially lower hurdle <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 300,000 Swiss Francs for decrees passed withless than a four-fifths majority in the Grosser Rat was not kept in the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Schaffhausen. In the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Appenzell Innerrhoden, <strong>on</strong> the 28th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> April, 2002, the oldthreshold for decrees was doubled and is now fixed at 1 milli<strong>on</strong> Swiss Francs. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> people <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Graubünden approved new and higher expenditure thresholds for the mandatoryfiscal referendum for the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> (effective as <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2004): the figureis now 10 milli<strong>on</strong> Swiss Francs for n<strong>on</strong>recurring expenses triggered by decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the GrosserRat – twice as high as before the change. In general, increases in thresholds led the subindex<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory fiscal referendum decline.C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al amendments that did not lead to an alterati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the legal stipulati<strong>on</strong>s withrespect to the mandatory fiscal referendum also occurred in some cant<strong>on</strong>s during this period.One is Freiburg, in which a new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> entered into force <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2005,which, other than a renumbering <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> articles, did not affect the fiscal referendum. Anotherexample is Appenzell Ausserrhoden in which, in 1997, the Landsgemeinde was abolishedwithout touching the requirements for the mandatory fiscal referendum. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> last changec<strong>on</strong>cerning the financial hurdle in this cant<strong>on</strong> occurred previously <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> May, 1996,


– 64 –when it was set at 5% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a taxing unit (which equaled 1,650,500 Swiss Francs in 2003) 66 . Inthe cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>, a new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> also came into force (1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January, 2003) thatdid not affect the requirements for the mandatory fiscal referendum. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> financial hurdles forlaws and decrees are stipulated in a cant<strong>on</strong>al law (art. 6 RIG) and since 1996 the figure hasbeen 15 milli<strong>on</strong> Swiss Francs for n<strong>on</strong>recurring expenses. From a political ec<strong>on</strong>omyperspective, the regulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> hurdles at the statutory and not at the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al level is veryinteresting, as already discussed in the introductory secti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this chapter <strong>on</strong> the statutoryreferendum. A new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> that became effective in the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Tessin <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>January, 1998, also led to no alterati<strong>on</strong> with regards to the n<strong>on</strong>existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatoryfiscal referendum. Since legal stipulati<strong>on</strong>s do not change, the subindex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fiscalreferendum is unaffected.In a few cant<strong>on</strong>s, there has been an empowerment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the people through the introducti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> amandatory fiscal referendum. One <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these cases is the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Aargau, in which, after years<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> n<strong>on</strong>existence since 1982 (see T/S 1999, p. 341), a mandatory fiscal referendum wasintroduced – although its power is mitigated by the inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a majority restricti<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>evaluati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this restricti<strong>on</strong> was discussed in the introductory secti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this chapter. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>new expenditure hurdles are fixed at 5 milli<strong>on</strong> Swiss Francs for n<strong>on</strong>recurring expenses and at600,000 Swiss Francs for recurring expenses. On the 29th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> November, 1998, the people <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Waadt also passed a partial revisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, introducing a new fiscal mandatoryreferendum with a financial threshold <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 20,000,000 Swiss Francs for n<strong>on</strong>recurring expenses(art. 27, 2 bis old CC), which had never before been known in the history <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Waadt (see T/S1999, p. 368 c<strong>on</strong>t.). It must be noted, however, that this mandatory fiscal referendum did notlead to a vote <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the people <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong> but <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the assembly <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the local communes. In thenew c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> (effective: the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> September, 2003), however, this mandatory fiscalreferendum was again abolished. Only law-changing financial measures by the government toaid a budgetary disequilibrium are now subject to a mandatory referendum (art. 83, 2 CC).This regulati<strong>on</strong> seems to aim at restricting raises in income tax rates in order to equilibrateexpenses and revenue (cf. art. 165, 2 CC). Through this stipulati<strong>on</strong>, the electorate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Waadtcan influence, at least indirectly, the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income tax rates in times <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> overall ec<strong>on</strong>omichardship.66 For recurring expenses, the threshold equals 331,000 Swiss Francs in 2003.


– 65 –5.3. Opti<strong>on</strong>al Fiscal ReferendumTable 7: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fiscal Referendum – Opti<strong>on</strong>al (Ordinary) between 1997 and 2003Cant<strong>on</strong>Zürich(3 Mar 2004)Zürich(old)Bern(21 Oct 2003)Luzern(21 Oct 2003)Uri(1 Apr 2003)Uri(old)Sign.Requ.Time-limitfor coll.Financialthreshold5,000 60 days > 3 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 300,000)5,000 45 days > 2 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 200,000)10,000 3 m<strong>on</strong>ths 2 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 400,000)3,000 60 days laws:> 10 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 1 milli<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>average for 10 years)decrees:> 3 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 300,000 <strong>on</strong>average for 10 years)450 90 days > 500,000(> 50,000 for at least10 years)300 90 days > 500,000(> 50,000 for at least10 years)Article in cant. c<strong>on</strong>st./ effectivesince (date <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> vote)art. 28 bis, 1 num. 1art. 30 bis 1, 21 Jan 1999 (27 Sept1998)decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>sratart. 30 num. 21 Jan 1996 (25 Sept 1994)art. 62, 1 lit. c1 Jan 1995 / (6 Jun 1993)decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grosser Ratart. 39, 21 Jan 1977 (5 Dec 1976)art. 39 bis, 1 lit. a(25 Jun 1995)art. 39 bis, 1 lit. b(27 Sept 1998)(revisi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly w.r.t.extraordinary fisc. ref.)art. 401 Nov 1969 (14 Sept 1969)art. 39 bis, 31 Nov 1969 (14 Sept 1969)Laws and decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theGrosser Ratart. 25, 2 lit. c, d1 Jan 1994 (28 Nov1993)art. 25, 11 Oct 1997 (8 June 1997)art. 25, 31 Jan 1995 (28 Oct 1984)" new expenses": laws anddecreessee also T/S 1999, p. 359art. 25, 2 lit. c, d1 Jan 1994 (28 Nov1993)art. 25, 11955art. 25, 31 Jan 1995 (28 Oct 1984)" new expenses": laws anddecreessee also T/S 1999, p. 359


– 66 –Cant<strong>on</strong>Schwyz(18 Aug 2004)Obwalden(22 Oct 2002)Obwalden(8 June 1997 -29 Nov 1998)Obwalden(old)Nidwalden(28 Dec 2001)Glarus(30 Mar 2004)Zug(1 Apr 2003)Freiburg(18 Aug 2004)newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by1 Jan 2005Freiburg(old)Table 7: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fiscal Referendum – Opti<strong>on</strong>al (Ordinary) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Sign.Requ.Time-limitfor coll.Financialthreshold100 30 days > 1 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 200,000)100 30 days ( > 500,000)(> 100,000)100 30 days > 100,000(> 20,000)250 2 m<strong>on</strong>ths > 250,000(> 50,000 )1,000 60 days > 500,000(> 50,000)6,000 90 days > 0.25% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thetotal expenditures<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the last budget(approved account)6,000 90 days > 0.25% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thetotal expenditures<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the last budget(approved account)Article in cant. c<strong>on</strong>st./ effectivesince (date <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> vote)N<strong>on</strong>-existing<strong>St</strong>at. ref not applicable to decrees<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>srat, but applicableto laws and by-laws 67See also tables 4 and 5(vote at the ballot box)art. 59 1, lit. bart. 59 2, lit. b29 Nov 1998 (29. Nov 1998)decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>srat(Landsgemeinde)art. 61 num. 48 June 1997 (8 June 1997)art. 71, 18 June 1997 (8 June 1997)decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>srat(Landsgemeinde)art. 61 num. 48 June 1986 (8 June 1986)decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>sratart. 71, 18 June 1986 (8 June 1986)decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>sratart. 52 lit. a, 11 Dec 1996 / (1 Dec 1996)No opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendumMandatory referendum see table 6art. 34, 1art. 34, 22 Dec 1990 (2 Dec1990)laws and general decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theKant<strong>on</strong>srat1 Jan 2005(16 May 2004)art. 46, 1 lit. bart. 46, 2All acts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grand C<strong>on</strong>seilart. 28 bis, 37 Oct 1986 (8 June 1986)art. 130, 2 PRGall laws and decreesalso applicable: art. 28 tersee also T/S 1999, p. 211 c<strong>on</strong>t.67 Pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong> with Mr. GANDER, <strong>St</strong>aatsschreiber <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Schwyz.


– 67 –Cant<strong>on</strong>Solothurn(30 Mar 2004)Basel-<strong>St</strong>adt(4 July 2000)(new)Table 7: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fiscal Referendum – Opti<strong>on</strong>al (Ordinary) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Sign.Requ.Time-limitfor coll.Financialthreshold1,000 90 days > 1 milli<strong>on</strong>(>100,000)2,000 6 weeks > 1,5 milli<strong>on</strong>(or = sum <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> allannual expensesover all years)Article in cant. c<strong>on</strong>st./ effectivesince (date <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> vote)art. 36 1, lit. aart. 36, 21 Jan 1988 (8 June 1986)art. 29, 3 lit. c21 Jun 1979 (24 Sept 1978)see T/S 1999, p. 163art. 22 Finanzhaushaltsgesetz(1 Jan 1998)Basel-<strong>St</strong>adt(old)Basel-Land(22 Oct 2002)Schaffhausen( 21 Oct 2003)newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by1st Jan 2003Schaffhausen(old)Appenzell AR(3 Apr 2001)Appenzell IR(30 Mar 2004)<strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>(9 July 2002)newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by1 Jan 20032,000 6 weeks > 1 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 200,000)1,000 8 weeks > 500,000(> 50,000)1,000 90 days > 1 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 100,000)600 60 days > 300,000(> 50,000)1 May 1996(30 Apr 1995)200 30 days > 250,000> 50,0004,000 40 days > 3 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 300,000 for atleast 10 years)art. 29, 3 lit. c21 Jun 1979 (24 Sept 1978)see T/S 1999, p. 163art 1, 1 ArefGDecrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Landratart. 31, 1 lit. bart. 31, 1art. 31, 31 Jan 1987(4 Nov 1984)Decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Kant<strong>on</strong>sratart. 33, 1 lit. dart. 33 , 21 Jan 2003(17 Jun 2002)Decree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grosser Rat if 4/5<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> present members have agreedart. 42 ter, 1art. 42 ter, 2(23 Apr 1989)N<strong>on</strong>-existing (Landsgemeinde)(28 Sept 1997: abolishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theLandsgemeinde and replacement<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> open vote by voting at theballot box)art. 7 ter, 2art. 7 ter, 3(26 Apr 1992)(Landsgemeinde)Decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grosser Ratart. 49, 1 lit. c; art. 50, 11 Jan 2003(21 Jun 2001)art. 7, 1 RIG: IV NG(11 Apr 1996)Decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grosser Rat


– 68 –Cant<strong>on</strong><strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>(old)Table 7: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fiscal Referendum – Opti<strong>on</strong>al (Ordinary) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Sign.Requ.Time-limitfor coll.Financialthreshold4000 30 days > 3 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 300,000 for atleast 10 years)Article in cant. c<strong>on</strong>st./ effectivesince (date <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> vote)art. 47art. 7, 1 RIG: IV NG1 Apr 1997(11 Apr 1996)higher upper limits throughmandatory fiscal referendumdecrees and lawsGraubünden(6 July 2004)newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by1 Jan 2004Graubünden(old)Aargau(30 Mar 2004)Aargau(old)Thurgau(22 Oct 2002)Tessin(30 Mar 1999)newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> bythe 1 Jan 1998Tessin(old)1,000 90 days > 1 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 300,000)3,000 90 days > 1 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 300,000)3,000 90 days > 5 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 500,000)3,000 90 days > 3 Mio(> 300,000)2,000 3 m<strong>on</strong>ths > 1 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 200,000)7,000 45 days > 1 milli<strong>on</strong>(> 250,000 for atleast four years)7,000 1 m<strong>on</strong>th > 200,000(> 50,000 for atleast 4 years)art. 17, 1art. 17, 1 num. 3art. 17, 31 Jan 2004(18 May 2003 / 14 Sept 2003)decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grosser Ratchange in upper limits throughmandatory fiscal referendumart. 2, 2 num. 6 lit. b(28 Jan 1973)Decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grosser Ratart. 63, 1 lit. dart. 63, 11 Jan 2003 (2 Jun 2002 )decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grosser Ratart. 40 GPR(10 Mar 1992)art. 63, 1 lit. cart. 63, 1Decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grosser Rat1 Jan 1982 (28 Sept 1980)art. 40 GPRart. 23, 21 Jan 1990 (4 Dec1988)decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grosser Ratart. 42 lit. b1 Jan 1998 (14 Dec 1997 )decrees and laws (“gli atti”)art. 60, 2(31 May 1970)See also T/S 1999, p. 338 c<strong>on</strong>t.


– 69 –Cant<strong>on</strong>Waadt(21 Oct 2003)newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by1 Sept 2003Waadt(18 Jan 2000)Table 7: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fiscal Referendum – Opti<strong>on</strong>al (Ordinary) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Sign.Requ.Time-limitfor coll.FinancialthresholdArticle in cant. c<strong>on</strong>st./ effectivesince (date <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> vote)12,000 40 days No threshold art. 84, 1 lit. aart. 84, 2 lit bart. 84, 31 Sept 2003 (14 Apr 2003)opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendumapplies to decrees(see also table 5)excepti<strong>on</strong>s: art. 84, 2 lit. b12,000 40 days > 2 milli<strong>on</strong> art. 27, num. 2(> 200,000 for 10 29 Nov 1998 (29 Nov 1998)years )all decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grand C<strong>on</strong>seilWaadt(old)Wallis(21 Oct 2003)Neuenburg(16 Oct 2001)newc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> by1 Jan 2002Neuenburg(old)(12,000) (40 days) No threshold opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendumapplies (see table 5)see also T/S 1999, p. 369art. 27, num. 219783,000 90 days > 0.75%(> 0.25 %)<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the total grossexpenditure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thelast administrati<strong>on</strong>and investmentaccount4,000 40 days > 400,000(acts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the GrandC<strong>on</strong>seil)6,000 40 days art 39, 2art. 120 LDP> 3 per mill <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theapproved budget(decrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theGrand C<strong>on</strong>seil)decrees, but <strong>on</strong>ly forextraordinary expensesart. 31, 3, num. 2art. 31 1, num. 31 June 1994 (24 Oct 1993)decrees which trigger expenses,laws triggering n<strong>on</strong>-budgetaryexpensesart. 42, abs. 2 lit. bart. 42, 1art. 42, 31 Jan 2002 (24 Sept 2000)Laws: opt stat. ref. applies(identical requirements)Simple decrees which trigger anew expenseLaws: opt. stat. ref. applies(identical requirements)


– 70 –Cant<strong>on</strong>Genf(21 Oct 2003)Jura(4 July 2000)See tables 2 and 6.Table 7: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fiscal Referendum – Opti<strong>on</strong>al (Ordinary) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Sign.Requ.Timelimitforcoll.Financialthreshold7,000 40 days > 125,000(> 60,000)2,000 60 days > 5 per mil(> 0,5 per mil)<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the revenue <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thelast budgetArticle in cant. c<strong>on</strong>st./ effectivesince (date <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> vote)Laws triggering n<strong>on</strong>-budgetaryexpensesart. 56 (2 Febr 1986)art. 53 (7 Mar 1982)art. 57 19 Feb 1960 (7 Feb 1960)art. 54, 119 Dec 1958 (7 Dec 1958)See also T/S 1999, p. 223-226art.78 lit. bAll expenses not determined by alaw1 Jan 1979(20 Mar 1977)art. 94 LDP5.4 Comments <strong>on</strong> the Changes in the Opti<strong>on</strong>al Fiscal ReferendumMost <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al revisi<strong>on</strong>s regarding the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum after 1997c<strong>on</strong>cern an alterati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the signature requirement or the financial threshold for thisinstituti<strong>on</strong>. Only in a few cant<strong>on</strong>s was an eliminati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory fiscal referendum (seesecti<strong>on</strong> 5.2) accompanied by an adaptati<strong>on</strong>/extensi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum.After 1997, a major change regarding the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum occurred in the cant<strong>on</strong>Zürich when the mandatory fiscal referendum was abolished at the end <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1998 and <strong>on</strong>ly arevised versi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum remained. In the same partial revisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thecant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, the period allotted to the collecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the signatures was increased from45 to 60 days. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> financial threshold was augmented to 3,000,000 Swiss Francs in c<strong>on</strong>trastto 2,000,000 Swiss Francs, which prevailed until the end <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1998 (see T/S 1999, p. 408 c<strong>on</strong>t.).Despite this c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al change, from 1999 <strong>on</strong>, the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscalreferendum for ZH reached 4, which it had already achieved in 1998 and 1997.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong> Luzern also introduced a change with respect to opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum, but asthis did not relate to any <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the requirements that form the basis for the derivati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theindex, it had no impact <strong>on</strong> the index value for the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum. Only with


– 71 –respect to the extraordinary fiscal referendum did a change occur c<strong>on</strong>cerning the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>members necessary to call in such an instituti<strong>on</strong> (art. 39 bis, 1 lit. b CC). This amendmentbecame necessary because the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al parliament had been reduced from 170 to120 seats 68 .<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong> Uri is <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the rare cases in which the index value for the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscalreferendum remained the same for the period between 1997 and 2001, although a partialrevisi<strong>on</strong> with respect to the requirements did take place. From 1997 to 1998, the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>signatures requested was raised from 300 to 450 (see T/S 1999, p. 359), applicable to allopti<strong>on</strong>al referenda. This revisi<strong>on</strong>, however, neither changed the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> evaluati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theabsolute quantity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> signatures nor that <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the relative number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> signatures, because bothnumbers (still) fall into the identical categories before and after the change.In the cant<strong>on</strong> Obwalden the electorate voted successfully for a supersessi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theLandsgemeinde status <strong>on</strong> the 8th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> June, 1997. An opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum was introducedwith a signature requirement <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 100 voters to be collected within 30 days, and a financialthreshold <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 500,000 Swiss Francs for n<strong>on</strong>recurring expenses was set. In 1998, this thresholdwas then again doubled to 1,000,000 Swiss Francs; the identical development occurred forrecurring expenses. Hence, the index for the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum was negativelyaffected in both 1998 and 1999. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> overall index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscal referendum therefore reflects the(lower) value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum as no mandatory referendum has existed since1998.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum was also revised in the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Tessin <strong>on</strong> the 14th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>December, 1997, which became effective with the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January,1998. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> signatures necessary for such a referendum was kept at 7,000, but thetime allotted for their collecti<strong>on</strong> increased from 30 to 45 days (see also T/S 1999, p. 340). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>financial threshold was also augmented to 1,000,000 Swiss Francs from the original 200,000Swiss Francs (see also T/S 1999, p. 341). This development meant an increase in the value forthe fiscal referendum from 1997 <strong>on</strong>wards.68 Pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong> with Mr. H. BACHMANN, Rechtsdienst <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Luzern (21/01/2004).


– 72 –Changes also occurred in Waadt starting in 1999. This cant<strong>on</strong> (re)introduced the opti<strong>on</strong>alfiscal referendum as a new instituti<strong>on</strong> in its cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> 69 , with a signaturerequirement <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 12,000, 40 days allowed for their collecti<strong>on</strong>, and a financial threshold set at2,000,000 Swiss Francs. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se new characteristics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum allowedcant<strong>on</strong> Waadt to achieve an index value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 3 between 1999 and 2001 for the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscalreferendum. At this point, it should be noted that in cant<strong>on</strong> Waadt before 1999, financialexpenditure projects were (theoretically) covered by the statutory referendum (see T/S 1999,p. 371). However, according to my source 70 , because the statutory referendum was neverapplied to financial issues, its potential scope was never fully exploited by the electorate (seealso the descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fiscal referendum in chapter III). Interestingly, the requirements forthis new opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum were copied from those for the already existing opti<strong>on</strong>alstatutory referendum, which shows the closeness <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these two instituti<strong>on</strong>s. When STUTZER(1999) calculated the index values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy, however, he counted the de iureapplicability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum toward the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fiscal referendum.However, in c<strong>on</strong>trast to the new stipulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1999, the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutory referendum <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theold c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> fixed no financial threshold. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, a higher index value is observed forthe opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum before 1999.In October 2003, the people <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Waadt adopted a new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> that became effective <strong>on</strong> the1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> September, 2003. Besides the abolishment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory fiscal referendum forexpenditure projects, it introduced a ‘réferendum facultatif’ that serves both as a statutoryreferendum (art. 84, 1 lit. a CC) and as fiscal referendum. Exempted from this referendum arethe cant<strong>on</strong>al budget, supplementary credits, b<strong>on</strong>ds, bound expenses, and accounting (art. 84, 1lit. b CC) 71 . This stipulati<strong>on</strong> means, then, that unbound (n<strong>on</strong>-budgeted) expenses – i.e.expenditure projects and also tax-related issues – can be subject to an opti<strong>on</strong>al (fiscal)referendum. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> advantage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this stipulati<strong>on</strong>, from a direct democratic perspective, is that, asin the old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> before its November 1998 revisi<strong>on</strong>, no expenditure threshold exists.According to the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> in Neuenburg, which became effective <strong>on</strong> the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>January, 2002, 4,500 voters can demand a réferendum populaire <strong>on</strong> a decree that triggersexpenses within 40 days after its publicati<strong>on</strong> (art. 42, 2 lit. b CC); the same applies to any lawwhich does not relate to the budget or the account (art. 42, 2 lit. a CC; art. 42, 3 CC). This69 An opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum also existed in the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1961 until 1978 (see T/S 1999, p. 371).70 Pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong> with Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>. G. KIRCHGÄSSNER, March 2004.71 This article resembles the regulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> art. 27, num. 2 ter, old CC for the mandatory referendum.


– 73 –new opti<strong>on</strong>al (fiscal) referendum applies to acts (actes) <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grand C<strong>on</strong>seil, the cant<strong>on</strong>alparliament (as in the old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, see T/S 1999, p. 273). On the surface, there appears tobe no financial threshold for this referendum; however, the state organ resp<strong>on</strong>sible for makingfinancial decrees or laws <strong>on</strong> expenses above 400,000 Swiss Francs is the Grand C<strong>on</strong>seil (theparliament), whereas for those below this threshold the resp<strong>on</strong>sibility falls to the C<strong>on</strong>seild'Etat (the executive organ). Thus, the opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum appears <strong>on</strong>ly to apply to decreeswith expenses above 400,000 Swiss Francs 72 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are, however, some differences withrespect to the stipulati<strong>on</strong>s in the old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>: first, a reducti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the signaturerequirement has occurred (6,000 to 4,500); sec<strong>on</strong>d, in the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, the referendum isapplicable to all acts that meet the threshold requirement, not <strong>on</strong>ly to decrees that trigger a'new' expense as in the old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> (art. 39, 2 old CC). It must also be noted, however,that there existed in the old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> a mandatory referendum <strong>on</strong> expenditure projects forboth laws and decrees that did not survive the recent total revisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> ( seetable 6). For more details <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> how the system <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> financial referenda worked under the ancientrule, see T/S 1999, p. 272 c<strong>on</strong>t.6 Rec<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Index between 1997 and 2003<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy is an unweighted average <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> four different subindices thatreflect different c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al settings regarding four instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong>: thec<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative, the statutory initiative, the fiscal referendum, and the statutoryreferendum. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se four subindices are based <strong>on</strong> an assessment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the following requirements:the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> signatures (both absolute and relative), the time period for collecti<strong>on</strong>, and, inthe case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fiscal referendum, the financial threshold. Both STUTZER (1999) and STUTZERand FREY (2000) describe the c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this index. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> reader should note, however,that each article presents a different versi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> difference lies in the questi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>whether the expenditure threshold per electorate or per residential populati<strong>on</strong> is used inc<strong>on</strong>structing the subindex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fiscal referendum. Whereas the last paper uses the thresholdper vote, STUTZER (1999) uses the threshold per capita, which includes not <strong>on</strong>ly the cant<strong>on</strong>alelectorate but also foreign residents holding a permit <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a year or l<strong>on</strong>ger 73 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first versi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the relative threshold seems to take into account the decisi<strong>on</strong>-making power <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the single72 Pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong> with Ms. DESPLAND, Chancellerie d'Etat <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Neuenburg (12/10/2004).73 In some cant<strong>on</strong>s, foreign permanent residents account for up to 20% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the populati<strong>on</strong>. It takes 13 years <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>residence to gain Swiss citizenship.


– 74 –citizen with respect to financial matters <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>, while the sec<strong>on</strong>d versi<strong>on</strong>s is based <strong>on</strong>the view <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the threshold as a financial burden shared am<strong>on</strong>g all residents <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>. Asthe studies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> FREY and STUTZER also focus <strong>on</strong> the procedural utility gained by Swiss citizensin c<strong>on</strong>trast to foreign residents, the use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the first versi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this index makes sense in theirresearch c<strong>on</strong>text. However, as regards the signature requirement, both versi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the indexare c<strong>on</strong>structed using the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> signature divided by the electorate. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> correlati<strong>on</strong>between these two index versi<strong>on</strong>s exceeds the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 0.9. In the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this study, thenumber <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> signatures per voter and the financial threshold per resident is used to reflect thefinancial burden. According to L.P. FELD, this latter setup was also chosen for thec<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index between 1980 and 1997 carried out by his colleague CH.A.SCHALTEGGER.Regarding the updating <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this index, a few general comments need to be made. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative that forms part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index refers exclusively to the partial revisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> (see STUTZER 1999). In many cant<strong>on</strong>s, it is easier to launch a partial revisi<strong>on</strong>than a total revisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>cerning the mandatory and the opti<strong>on</strong>al statutoryreferendum, in general, this study <strong>on</strong>ly takes into account those referenda referring to all types<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> legislative acts, not those referring to administrative acts. Hence, the loss or gain in citizenpower with respect to the latter should not affect the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy for a cant<strong>on</strong>.Distincti<strong>on</strong> between the two, however, is almost unmanageable (see secti<strong>on</strong> 1), but,fortunately, in most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>s the referendum <strong>on</strong> laws, <strong>on</strong> decrees and <strong>on</strong> by-laws isequivalent in their requirements. C<strong>on</strong>cerning the fiscal referendum, <strong>on</strong>ly the threshold <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>n<strong>on</strong>recurring expenses is taken into account, and changes in thresholds for recurring expensesare not reflected in the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy (see STUTZER 1999). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> index does notdistinguish whether the expense is a c<strong>on</strong>sequence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a law or <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a decree; however, in dailypolitical practice, expenditure projects induced by a decree are more <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ten the object <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> afiscal referendum. Changes that occur after April 1st in any given year are accounted for inthe following year; for example, the changes in the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Obwalden in June 1997and <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Glarus in May 2002 influence the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong>ly from 1998 and 2003<strong>on</strong>wards, respectively. As regards the signature requirement, a m<strong>on</strong>th is counted ascorresp<strong>on</strong>ding to 30 days, 6 weeks to 45 days, and so <strong>on</strong>.Regarding the statutory referendum, 6 index points are awarded to those cant<strong>on</strong>s in which amandatory statutory referendum exists. In the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum, index points are


– 75 –awarded based <strong>on</strong> its requirements (absolute and relative signature requirement, time periodfor collecti<strong>on</strong>). Usually there exists in Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the two types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> statutoryreferenda referring to cant<strong>on</strong>al laws (and decrees), and hence the final subindex value for thestatutory referendum is out <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the questi<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> difficulty with this index lies in the questi<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> whether decrees and by-laws <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al parliament are regarded as 'laws' or asadministrative acts, and whether they should be included in this index or not. This distincti<strong>on</strong>differs from cant<strong>on</strong> to cant<strong>on</strong>, and a decisi<strong>on</strong> can <strong>on</strong>ly be made according to the legal andpolitical practice. For example, in the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Uri, both the mandatory and the opti<strong>on</strong>alreferendum exist, although the opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum c<strong>on</strong>cerns <strong>on</strong>ly parliamentary by-laws notformal laws. In this case, STUTZER (1999), taking into account that both types exist in parallel,decided to calculate the average <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> both referenda (p. 5). For c<strong>on</strong>sistency, I have maintainedthe averaging <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> both instituti<strong>on</strong>s for the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Uri. In additi<strong>on</strong>, for the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Schwyz, themandatory referendum applies to laws and the opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum to by-laws, so here againthe average <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the two referenda is used because some by-laws in particular areas aim atsubstituting for formal laws (STUTZER, 1999, p. 5). Again to maintain c<strong>on</strong>sistency, I will als<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ollow this approach. In a few cant<strong>on</strong>s (SO, BL, SH, AG), a majority restricti<strong>on</strong> wasintroduced for the applicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory statutory referendum during the period from1997 to 2003; if this requirement is not met, the opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum applies. In these cases, Ireplicate the approach chosen by STUTZER (1999) and calculate the average <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> both types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>statutory referenda. As the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al change in Glarus led de facto to no restricti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theuse and scope <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory statutory referendum for cant<strong>on</strong>al laws, <strong>on</strong>ly this instituti<strong>on</strong>will be taken into account for the index c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong>.As regards the fiscal referendum, both the opti<strong>on</strong>al and the mandatory referenda are awardedindex points separately and an index value is calculated for each. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> higher value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the twois then chosen, which c<strong>on</strong>stitutes the subindex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fiscal referendum. In general, nodistincti<strong>on</strong> is made as to whether the fiscal referendum applies to a law or to a decree. Formost <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>s, the threshold for expenditure projects induced by laws or decrees isidentical. Only the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Luzern makes an excepti<strong>on</strong>: here, the c<strong>on</strong>siderably lowerfinancial threshold for decrees is employed as d<strong>on</strong>e in STUTZER (1999). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se thresholds haveremained unchanged since 1995. In the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Schaffhausen, the fiscal referenda applysolely to decrees, not to laws; hence, the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the subindex is based exclusively up<strong>on</strong> thesec<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al stipulati<strong>on</strong>s. In the old c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> prior to January 2003, a lower threshold forthe mandatory fiscal referendum was fixed when a decree was passed with less than a fourfifthsmajority. STUTZER (1999) did not take this specific regulati<strong>on</strong> into account, probably


– 76 –because it did not apply <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ten in practice. C<strong>on</strong>sequently, in the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Schaffhausen, this particular regulati<strong>on</strong> was dropped, and no majority requirement any l<strong>on</strong>gerapplies to any fiscal referendum.In the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Aargau, a mandatory fiscal referendum was introduced in January 2003 aftera time <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> n<strong>on</strong>existence, but it was accompanied by a majority restricti<strong>on</strong>. This newdevelopment is taken into account by averaging the index points for the opti<strong>on</strong>al and themandatory fiscal referenda, analogously to similar cases for the mandatory statutoryreferendum. Regarding the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Schwyz, in which no ordinary opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendumexists, STUTZER (1999) reported taking into account the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum for statehighways; in this case, the average points <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory and the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum(for state highways) is calculated and used as a fiscal subindex. Pers<strong>on</strong>ally, I find thisapproach inc<strong>on</strong>sistent because other cant<strong>on</strong>s such as <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong> have similar opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscalreferenda <strong>on</strong> special issues, particularly <strong>on</strong> infrastructure projects; for these cant<strong>on</strong>s, however,this type <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum is not taken into c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> during calculati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thefiscal subindex. Nevertheless, to keep the index c<strong>on</strong>sistent over time, I will maintain thespecial treatment for the cant<strong>on</strong> Schwyz. In 1999, a new cant<strong>on</strong>al decree <strong>on</strong> streets(<strong>St</strong>rassenverordnung) was adopted by the Kant<strong>on</strong>srat <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Schwyz (effective: the 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> January,2000), which brought about a higher threshold for this opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum (new: art20, 2 CC) to which an expense <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> more than 20,000,000 Swiss Francs is subject (prior tochange: 2,000,000 Swiss Francs). As regards the signature requirement and the time forcollecti<strong>on</strong>, the regulati<strong>on</strong>s have remained unchanged since 1972.In STUTZER (1999), for the cant<strong>on</strong>s Wallis and Genf, the requirements for the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscalreferendum were not taken into account during calculati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the subindex value for the fiscalreferendum because “<strong>on</strong>ly n<strong>on</strong>-budgetary or extraordinary” expenses are subject to thisreferendum (p.7). In STUTZER’s opini<strong>on</strong>, this omissi<strong>on</strong> weakens this political instituti<strong>on</strong> soc<strong>on</strong>siderably that it leads to a de facto n<strong>on</strong>existence. Since the publicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> his calculati<strong>on</strong>sin 1999, the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al requirements in Wallis and in Genf have not changed (see tables 6and 7). In the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Wallis, in art. 31, 1 num. 2, it is explicitly stated that ordinaryexpenses are not subject to an opti<strong>on</strong>al (fiscal) referendum. A mandatory referendum exists<strong>on</strong>ly in its extraordinary form (since 1994) and hence does not influence the subindex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscalreferendum. In the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Genf, a popular vote <strong>on</strong> any expenditure can be avoided by thelegislature through the inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this expenditure in the budget law (art. 54, 1 CC), so thatthe reas<strong>on</strong>s for a c<strong>on</strong>siderable restricti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its use stated in STUTZER (1999) still apply (p.7).


– 77 –Hence, in these cant<strong>on</strong>s, the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum has been awarded an index value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1as if this referendum were n<strong>on</strong>existent.Interesting also is the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Waadt. As a very innovative step, this cant<strong>on</strong> introduced amandatory fiscal referendum in 1998. In c<strong>on</strong>trast to the stipulati<strong>on</strong>s in the other c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s,this mandatory fiscal referendum could <strong>on</strong>ly be used by the assembly <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the communes, notby its cant<strong>on</strong>al electorate. I have, however, decided to regard this mandatory referendum as afully valid mandatory referendum as if the electorate had been given the right to vote 74 . Sincethere are about 380 communes in the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Waadt, the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> each <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> them will be sosmall that a single citizen can be assumed to have quite a decisive (indirect) influence <strong>on</strong> theoutcome <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory fiscal referendum. In the new c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1 Sept 2003, however,this mandatory fiscal referendum was again abolished.Finally, and most importantly, I must point to the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Zürich. Until the end <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1998, amandatory fiscal referendum existed that was then replaced by an opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this important instituti<strong>on</strong> was overlooked by TRECHSEL and SERDÜLT in afirst unpublished versi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a table summarizing the mandatory fiscal referenda inSwitzerland, <strong>on</strong> which STUTZER (1999) then based the calculati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index for 1996 75 . Asa c<strong>on</strong>secutive fault, the subindex for the fiscal referendum in Zürich in STUTZER (1999) isbased <strong>on</strong> incorrect informati<strong>on</strong> and is significantly lower then it should be (4.00 instead <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>5.00). In STUTZER and FREY (2000), however, this mistake has been corrected and the indexvalues reported for Zürich for 1992 are correct.7 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> from 1997 to 2003Table 9 displays the values that the index takes <strong>on</strong> for the 26 cant<strong>on</strong>s during the relevantyears. In additi<strong>on</strong>, for reas<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> comparis<strong>on</strong> in table 8, three different versi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the indexare displayed: that published by STUTZER (1999) for 1996, that c<strong>on</strong>structed by FELD andSCHALTEGGER for a synthetic panel running from 1980 to 1998, and, finally, my owncalculati<strong>on</strong>s for the years 1997 and 1998. I note that in T/S 1999, and c<strong>on</strong>sequently STUTZER’s74 Since in this case both mandatory and opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referenda are awarded identical points for the period inquesti<strong>on</strong>, an averaging over the two instituti<strong>on</strong>s as an alternative would have brought about the identicalsubindex value. Also taking into account <strong>on</strong>ly the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum would not have changed thevalue <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the total index.75 In a pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong> with A. STUTZER, his mistake in STUTZER (1999) was admitted.


– 78 –analysis, the so-called Landsgemeinden (OW, NW, GL, AR, AI) – i.e. those cant<strong>on</strong>s thatknew no representative power <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> legislati<strong>on</strong> in or until shortly prior to 1996 – were excludedfrom the descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> instituti<strong>on</strong>s.Cant<strong>on</strong>Table 8: Comparis<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Index Values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>(1996)<strong>St</strong>utzer(1996)Feld(1997)Feld(1997)Fischer(1998)Feld(1998)FischerZH 4.17 4.167 4.167 4.417 4.167 4.417BE 3.02 3.021 3.021 3.021 3.021 3.021LU 4.42 4.000 4.000 4.417 4.000 4.417UR 5.29 5.125 5.125 5.292 5.125 5.125SZ 4.99 4.656 4.656 4.990 4.656 4.990OW 5.833 5.833 5.833 5.833 5.333NW 5.000 5.000 4.438 5.000 4.438GL 5.500 5.500 5.750 5.500 5.333ZG 4.42 4.417 4.417 4.417 4.417 4.417FR 2.85 2.854 2.917 2.854 2.917 2.854SO 5.67 5.667 5.667 5.667 5.667 5.667BS 4.4 4.396 4.396 4.396 4.396 4.396BL 5.69 5.688 5.688 5.688 5.688 5.688SH 5.21 5.000 5.000 5.208 5.000 5.208AR 5.500 5.500 5.500 5.500 5.500AI 5.250 5.250 5.375 5.250 5.375SG 3.58 3.167 3.167 3.458 3.167 3.458GR 4.75 4.500 4.500 4.833 4.500 4.833AG 5.46 5.458 5.458 5.458 5.458 5.458TG 4.33 4.333 4.333 4.333 4.333 4.333TI 2.10 1.854 1.854 2.104 1.854 2.250VD 2.42 2.417 2.417 2.417 2.417 2.417VS 3.58 3.250 3.250 3.583 3.250 3.583NE 2.19 2.188 2.250 2.188 2.250 2.188GE 1.75 1.750 1.750 1.750 1.750 1.750JU 4.02 3.708 3.708 3.708 3.708 3.708A comparis<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> STUTZER’s versi<strong>on</strong> with that <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> FELD for 1996 reveals that the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Zürich, which was correct for 1992 (see e.g. STUTZER and FREY 2000) was perpetuated byFELD and maintained until 1998, when at least since 1996, it should have been substantially


– 79 –higher (4.417 instead <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 4.17). Minor differences can also be observed for the cant<strong>on</strong>s LU,UR, SZ, SH, SG, GR, TI, VS, and JU. Unfortunately, I was not given access to thecalculati<strong>on</strong>s by which FELD and SCHALTEGGER c<strong>on</strong>structed their versi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index, so thecauses for these differences cannot be traced. However, the main reas<strong>on</strong> for the differencesbetween their index and mine may lie in the fact that, according to a pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong>with CH.A. SCHALTEGGER, they also took into account the so-called recurring expenses in theindex for the fiscal referendum. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> original index developed by STUTZER (1999) was,however, c<strong>on</strong>structed solely <strong>on</strong> the basis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>e-time (i.e. n<strong>on</strong>-recurring) expenditures andneglects the thresholds for recurring expenses. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> reader should note, however, that in most<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>s, the n<strong>on</strong>recurring threshold equals the recurring threshold times the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>years in which it reoccurs, so the differences in the index resulting from different evaluati<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> financial thresholds are influential <strong>on</strong>ly in a few cant<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> correlati<strong>on</strong> between the threeversi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy, however, exceeds the 90% level so thatec<strong>on</strong>ometric analyses using either versi<strong>on</strong> should not produce substantially different results.Table 9: Overview <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1997 - 2003Cant<strong>on</strong> 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003ZH 4.417 4.417 3.500 3.500 3.500 3.500 3.500BE 3.021 3.021 3.021 3.021 3.021 3.021 3.021LU 4.417 4.417 4.417 4.417 4.417 4.417 4.417UR 5.292 5.125 5.125 5.125 5.125 5.125 5.125SZ 4.990 4.990 4.990 4.927 4.927 4.927 4.927OW 5.833 5.333 4.625 4.625 4.625 4.625 4.625NW 4.438 4.438 4.438 4.438 4.438 4.438 4.438GL 5.750 5.750 5.750 5.750 5.750 5.750 5.500ZG 4.417 4.417 4.417 4.417 4.479 4.479 4.479FR 2.854 2.854 2.792 2.792 2.792 2.792 2.792SO 5.667 5.667 5.250 5.250 5.250 5.250 5.250BS 4.396 4.396 4.396 4.396 4.396 4.396 4.396BL 5.688 5.688 5.688 5.479 5.479 5.479 5.479SH 5.208 5.208 5.208 5.208 5.208 5.208 5.021AR 5.500 5.500 5.500 5.500 5.167 4.917 4.917AI 5.375 5.375 5.375 5.438 5.375 5.438 5.438SG 3.458 3.458 3.458 3.458 3.458 3.458 3.521GR 4.833 4.833 4.833 4.833 4.833 4.833 4.833AG 5.458 5.458 5.458 5.458 5.458 5.458 5.438TG 4.333 4.333 4.333 4.333 4.333 4.333 4.333TI 2.104 2.250 2.250 2.250 2.250 2.250 2.250VD 2.500 2.500 2.500 2.500 2.500 2.500 2.500VS 3.583 3.583 3.583 3.583 3.583 3.583 3.583NE 2.188 2.188 2.188 2.188 2.188 2.729 2.729GE 1.750 1.750 1.750 1.750 1.750 1.750 1.750JU 3.708 3.708 3.708 3.708 3.708 3.708 3.708Source: Own calculati<strong>on</strong>s


– 80 –Comparing my own calculated values for 1997 with the values presented by STUTZER for1996, <strong>on</strong>ly a few differences can be observed. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>s in questi<strong>on</strong> (besides Zürich) areFreiburg (FR), Graubünden (GR), and Jura (JU). First, it should be noted that no new oraltered c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al stipulati<strong>on</strong>s were observed in these cant<strong>on</strong>s between 1997 and 2003,which could affect the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy. However, small variati<strong>on</strong>s in the index canoccur even if c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al revisi<strong>on</strong>s are absent: that is, since relative numbers also play asignificant role, a change either in size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> residential populati<strong>on</strong> or cant<strong>on</strong>al electorate canlead to different values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> instituti<strong>on</strong>al subindices. In additi<strong>on</strong>, changes are also possible whenthe expenditure thresholds are defined as a percentage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> some types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al budget,revenues, or investments known to vary over the years. In the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> FR, for example, thevariati<strong>on</strong> in the index is induced by the expenditure threshold for the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscalreferendum, whereas in the cases <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> GR and JU, it is mainly the change in the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theelectorate that makes the relative signature requirement tighter (JU: VIR, GIR, GRR, FRR) orlooser (GR: VIR) 76 . (Since the index points vary with brackets, however, not all minorchanges in a relative requirement are automatically reflected by an index change.)8 Brief Critique <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the IndexThis chapter will c<strong>on</strong>clude with a brief critique <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the composite index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy asc<strong>on</strong>structed by STUTZER (1999). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy has many advantages: itcombines the necessary requirements for utilizing a particular right and makes cant<strong>on</strong>s withc<strong>on</strong>trasting instituti<strong>on</strong>al equipments comparable. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sole prominent disadvantage is the lack<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an inflati<strong>on</strong> adjustment: that is, a threshold introduced decades ago loses its strictness overtime, whereas in other cant<strong>on</strong>s a threshold defined based <strong>on</strong> an annual (approved) budget orsome <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its comp<strong>on</strong>ents not <strong>on</strong>ly tends to grow with inflati<strong>on</strong> but also varies with businesscycles. In practice, however, as can be seen in the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Freiburg, such a change in thethreshold based <strong>on</strong> cant<strong>on</strong>al budget size affects the final index <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong> a very small scale. Inadditi<strong>on</strong>, the missing adjustment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thresholds for inflati<strong>on</strong> has no major influence <strong>on</strong> thevalue <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy: such an adjustment would <strong>on</strong>ly be decisive if it led toa switch in the category for evaluati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the relative financial hurdle <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fiscal referendum.Independent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the mandatory or the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum is affected, a switch inbrackets causes an alterati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the final index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 0.25 index pointsbecause <strong>on</strong>ly the higher subindex value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the two enters the final composite index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct76All other requirements remained unaffected.


– 81 –democracy. Hence, the majority <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>s would not be str<strong>on</strong>gly affected by anadjustment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> threshold for inflati<strong>on</strong>. In a synthetic panel, the missing adjustment for inflati<strong>on</strong>will not lead to biased coefficients because the inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> year dummies filters out the‘inflati<strong>on</strong> effect’ for the affected cant<strong>on</strong>s. A comparis<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy overtime, however, is <strong>on</strong>ly useful for a descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> leaps in direct democracy, not smallchanges.


– 82 –9 AppendixZHZHTable A.1: Cant<strong>on</strong>al Laws Related to Instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>Cant<strong>on</strong> Law Abbreviati<strong>on</strong> Date <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> EnactmentGesetz über die politischenRechteGesetz über dasVorschlagsrecht des VolkesGPRInitiativgesetz(outdated)1 Sep 2003effective: 1 Jan 20051 Jun 1969effective until 1 Jan 2005BELU <strong>St</strong>immrechtsgesetz SRG 21 Oct 1988URSZOWNWGLZGFRSOBSBSBLSHARAISGGesetz über die Ausübungder politischen RechteGesetz übe die Ausübungder politischen RechteFinanzhaushaltsgesetzGesetz über dasAusgabenreferendumPRGPRG(outdated)FinanzhaushaltsgesetzArefG(outdated)6 Apr 2001effective: 1 Aug 200118 Feb 1876effective until 1 Aug 2001(16 Apr 1997)effective: 1 Jan 1998(29. June 1978)effective until 1 Jan 1998Gesetz über Referendumund InitiativeRIGGRGesetz über die Ausübungder politischen RechtePRG 7 Oct 1962AGGesetz über die politischenRechteGPR 10 Mar 1992TGTILegge sull’esercizio deidiritti politiciLEDPLegge sull'iniziativapopolare, sul referendum e LIRRsulla revoca del C<strong>on</strong>siglio di (outdated)22 Jan 1954<strong>St</strong>atoVDLois sur l'exercice des droitspolitiquesLEDPVSNE Lois sur les droits politiques LDP 17 Oct 1984GELois sur l'exercice des droitspolitiquesLEDP 15 Oct 1982JU Lois sur les droits politiques LDP 26 Oct 197827 Nov 1967effective: 1 Jan 19687 Oct 1998effective: 1 Jan 199916 May 1989effective: 1 Jan 1990


– 83 –Chapter III:Happiness


1 Introducti<strong>on</strong> 77A more democratic system, especially a system with direct popular rights, is likely to producepolitical outcomes that are closer to the preferences <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the median voter than a less democraticsystem. 78 C<strong>on</strong>sequently, ceteris paribus, a greater exposure to democracy can be expected toraise individuals’ well-being. Not <strong>on</strong>ly does such exposure lead to political results that areacceptable to a large part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a populati<strong>on</strong>, but citizens' well-being may also arise from theirparticipati<strong>on</strong> in the political decisi<strong>on</strong>-making process and from the perceived extent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theprocedural fairness <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this process. In fact, the utility gained from procedural fairness is foundto be quantitatively much larger than the utility gained from a (democratic) politicaloutcome. 79<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, we expect empirical research to show that a higher level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democratizati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> acountry or state leads to a higher level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> self-reported happiness. However, the limitedempirical evidence from previous cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al studies <strong>on</strong>ly partly supports this propositi<strong>on</strong>.Based <strong>on</strong> a sample <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> about 40 nati<strong>on</strong>s drawn from the World Values Survey, SCHYNS (1998)and VEENHOVEN (2000) find a positive and significant correlati<strong>on</strong> between the FreedomHouse <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> Index and self-reported happiness. However, this correlati<strong>on</strong> becomesinsignificant <strong>on</strong>ce the different nati<strong>on</strong>al income levels are c<strong>on</strong>trolled for. 80 In another studybased <strong>on</strong> the World Values Survey, INGLEHART and KLINGEMAN (2000) note that “[our]findings undermine any simplistic assumpti<strong>on</strong> that democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s are the maindeterminant <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> human happiness” (p. 180).Simplistic relati<strong>on</strong>s between income and happiness are, however, also questi<strong>on</strong>able. As earlierpapers by ABRAMOVITZ (1959) and EASTERLIN (1974) already indicate, income growth mayhave a positive effect <strong>on</strong> pers<strong>on</strong>al happiness in the short run but not in the l<strong>on</strong>g run. As so<strong>on</strong>as individuals adjust to their new situati<strong>on</strong>, the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> happiness may settle down to the old77 This chapter is based <strong>on</strong> the joint paper "Is It Culture or <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>? <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>, Income, andCulture <strong>on</strong> Happiness" by D. DORN, G: KIRCHGÄSSNER, A. SOUSA-POZA, and myself, discussi<strong>on</strong> paper No.2005-12, University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>. D. DORN and A. SOUSA-POZA c<strong>on</strong>tributed particularly to the sec<strong>on</strong>dinternati<strong>on</strong>al analysis, which does not form part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this dissertati<strong>on</strong> chapter. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> paper was presented at theworkshop <strong>on</strong> Happiness, Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Interpers<strong>on</strong>al Relati<strong>on</strong>ships, (4/12/2004), the Swiss Household PanelC<strong>on</strong>ference (26/02/2005), the American Public Choice <strong>Society</strong> C<strong>on</strong>ference (10/03/2005), the AnnualC<strong>on</strong>ference <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Swiss <strong>Society</strong> for <strong>St</strong>atistics and Ec<strong>on</strong>omics (17/03/2005), and the European Public Choice<strong>Society</strong> C<strong>on</strong>ference (3/04/2005).78 See, e.g., POMMEREHNE (1978) or, for a theoretical model, FELD and KIRCHGÄSSNER (2001).79 See STUTZER and FREY (2003).80 See also BJØRNSKOV (2003) for a similar result.


– 85 –equilibrium. 81 C<strong>on</strong>sequently, during recent decades, the average level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> life satisfacti<strong>on</strong> hasremained c<strong>on</strong>stant in many countries despite c<strong>on</strong>siderable ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. Several studiesprovide evidence for this observati<strong>on</strong>. 82 Moreover, EASTERLIN (1974) shows that countrieswith rather different GNP per capita – for example, West Germany and Nigeria, to menti<strong>on</strong>the two most extreme examples – had nearly the same average pers<strong>on</strong>al happiness rating (p.106). 83 Further, JUNGEILGES and KIRCHGÄSSNER’s (2002) internati<strong>on</strong>al study finds that higherincome per capita and especially higher income growth lead to higher suicide rates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> bothsexes and in nearly all age groups. If suicide is interpreted as a measure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ill-being, thisfinding clearly c<strong>on</strong>tradicts the idea <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a positive relati<strong>on</strong> between pers<strong>on</strong>al income andhappiness. 84 On the other hand, differences in ec<strong>on</strong>omic status within a country have a clearand c<strong>on</strong>sistent impact <strong>on</strong> pers<strong>on</strong>al happiness. 85 Thus, to correctly capture the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>income <strong>on</strong> happiness, it is necessary to distinguish between the general income level (oraverage income) within a society (and its development), and the relative ec<strong>on</strong>omic positi<strong>on</strong>that an individual or family occupies in this society. 86Besides political freedom and ec<strong>on</strong>omic well-being, the culture in which a pers<strong>on</strong> residescould also influence subjective well-being. For example, people in different cultures mayvalue certain aspects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> life differently and could, therefore, have different percepti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theirown individual well-being under the same objective circumstances. 87 This possibility is als<strong>on</strong>oted by EASTERLIN (1974, p. 108). Several more recent papers examine this relati<strong>on</strong>ship. 88STUTZER and FREY (2000, 2003), for example, use language as a proxy for culture, and theresulting coefficients are typically highly significant. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> language variables to reflectculture can be justified because in society, language serves as an important transmissi<strong>on</strong>81 See, e.g., EASTERLIN (2001).82 See, e.g., the papers cited in FREY and STUTZER (2002, p. 413), and also FRANK (1997), OSWALD (1997),MCBRIDE (2001), and EASTERLIN (2003). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> l<strong>on</strong>g-term impact may even go in the reverse directi<strong>on</strong>, fromhappiness to ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. See KENNY (1999).83 See also the graph in FREY and STUTZER (2002, p. 417), which appears to indicate that poorer countries havelower happiness ratings but that above a level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> about 5,000 US dollars per capita (in 1995 PPP), there existsno obvious relati<strong>on</strong> between GNP per capita and pers<strong>on</strong>al happiness.84 On the c<strong>on</strong>trary, they found that – <strong>on</strong>ce income effects are c<strong>on</strong>trolled for – higher civil liberty c<strong>on</strong>sistentlyleads to lower suicide rates.85 For the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> relative income <strong>on</strong> happiness see, e.g., D’AMBROSIO and FRICK (2004). That absoluteincome might, nevertheless, also have an impact <strong>on</strong> happiness is shown, e.g., by SCHYNS (2002).86 Another questi<strong>on</strong> is whether it is really income and not wealth together with income that matters. For this, seeHEADY and WOODEN (2004) or HEADEY, MUFFELS and WOODEN (2004).87 For this, see, e.g., LIJPHART (1979) or the difference between Europeans and Americans with respect to(ec<strong>on</strong>omic) inequality shown in ALESINA, DI TELLA and MACCULLOCH (2004).88 See, e.g., the c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s in DIENER and SUH (2000).


– 86 –channel <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> culture and its embedded view <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the world, the social system, and customs. At theindividual level, the language spoken shapes human patterns <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thought. 89 Moreover, asshown in other studies, cultural differences, represented by languages, have str<strong>on</strong>g impacts <strong>on</strong>political behavior. 90 C<strong>on</strong>sequently, such cultural variati<strong>on</strong>s may not <strong>on</strong>ly be reflected ininstituti<strong>on</strong>al differences but also in how the individuals value the c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> politicalinstituti<strong>on</strong>s to their individual welfare. Am<strong>on</strong>g other factors, that are closely related to cultureand that might have an impact <strong>on</strong> people’s happiness are religi<strong>on</strong> and the amount <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> socialcapital available in a society (see, e.g., FERRISS 2002 or BJØRNSKOV 2003).Analyzing these relati<strong>on</strong>ships requires a valid measure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individual happiness; two suchmeasures are comm<strong>on</strong>ly used. While nearly all authors speak <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> happiness, <strong>on</strong>ly some surveystruly questi<strong>on</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>dents about their pers<strong>on</strong>al happiness; the others ask about pers<strong>on</strong>alsatisfacti<strong>on</strong> or well-being. This latter holds true for all Swiss surveys. However, pers<strong>on</strong>alsatisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the <strong>on</strong>e hand and happiness <strong>on</strong> the other are quite different aspects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pers<strong>on</strong>allife, 91 particularly (but not exclusively) for speakers <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the German language. Nevertheless,the literature usually assumes that these two pers<strong>on</strong>al emoti<strong>on</strong>s are comparable ins<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ar as theyare both highly correlated with themselves and with other explanatory variables. 92 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore,as is comm<strong>on</strong>, the two terms are here used interchangeably.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>ly scholars who, after c<strong>on</strong>trolling for income (and sometimes also for language), find apositive influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy <strong>on</strong> subjective life satisfacti<strong>on</strong> are FREY and STUTZER in theiranalyses for Switzerland. 93 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Swiss federal structure allows for wide variati<strong>on</strong>s in politicalinstituti<strong>on</strong>s, especially in direct popular rights, between the 26 different cant<strong>on</strong>s. Further,major cultural differences are reflected in the four different <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ficial languages 94 . Thus,Switzerland can be (and has been) perceived as a laboratory in which to study the effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>various degrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> political instituti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> political and social outcomes. 95 Other factors that89 See, e.g., ALLIOT (1999) or LAZEAR (1999).90 See, e.g. LIJPHART (1979), who in a study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the structure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> party affiliati<strong>on</strong>s in four multilingual countries(including Switzerland) c<strong>on</strong>cluded that “because language is a crucial differentiator am<strong>on</strong>g nati<strong>on</strong>s, it isbound to be a major cleavage and a main source <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> partisan differences in ‘nati<strong>on</strong>s’ that are not linguisticallyhomogeneous” (p .453).91For the difference between satisfacti<strong>on</strong> and happiness see, e.g., LANE (1991, chapter 22) or VEENHOVEN(2000a).92 See, e.g. VEENHOVEN (2000).93 See, e.g., FREY and STUTZER (2000, 2000a, 2000b), as well as STUTZER and FREY (2003).94 Also the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> federalism (between the cant<strong>on</strong>al and the local level) exhibits c<strong>on</strong>siderable variati<strong>on</strong>.95See, e.g., FELD and SAVIOZ (1997) for the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic welfare, FELD andKIRCHGÄSSNER (2001, 2004) for its effect <strong>on</strong> public finances, or FELD et. al. (2004) for the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct


– 87 –are difficult to measure and make comparis<strong>on</strong>s am<strong>on</strong>g countries difficult are irrelevant for ananalysis within <strong>on</strong>e country. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, Switzerland seems very well suited for testing theimpact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> instituti<strong>on</strong>al differences and cultural background <strong>on</strong> perceived happiness. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>lydisadvantage in this respect is that the variati<strong>on</strong> in level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy (and in other politicalinstituti<strong>on</strong>s) is much smaller between Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s 96 than between units in an internati<strong>on</strong>alsample that might include, for example, established democracies like the United Kingdom orthe United <strong>St</strong>ates, as well as relatively weak democracies like that <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Russia. Nevertheless,measured <strong>on</strong> an internati<strong>on</strong>al scale, the extent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democratic rights (as well as the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>federalism) is extremely high for all Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s. Thus, the fact that a significant impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy is observed within Switzerland but not in a cross-nati<strong>on</strong>al setting is verysurprising. Rather, a str<strong>on</strong>ger influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy <strong>on</strong> happiness might be expected in across-nati<strong>on</strong>al study than in a study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the single democratic country <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Switzerland.It might be argued that a cross-nati<strong>on</strong>al analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> subjective well-being is difficult becausecountries vary with regard to a variety <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> determinants, especially (as menti<strong>on</strong>ed above)culture, that might influence individual happiness. As already stated, however, Switzerland isalso divided into four different language regi<strong>on</strong>s with rather different cultures, with theborderline being mainly between the German- and n<strong>on</strong>-German-speaking (‘Latin’) partscomprised <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the French- and Italian-speaking Swiss. 97 Thus, cultural aspects, which arealready shown to be a main source <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> differences in the political behavior in differentcountries, also play a major role within Switzerland. In fact, voting patterns in recent publicelecti<strong>on</strong>s reveal substantial differences am<strong>on</strong>g the different language regi<strong>on</strong>s withinSwitzerland.This chapter takes a closer look at the relati<strong>on</strong> between democracy and perceived subjectivewell-being, while also taking into account the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income and culture. First, I brieflyreview the empirical results for Switzerland obtained by FREY and STUTZER in their variousc<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, using a similar model to that <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> FREY and STUTZER (2000), in thedemocracy <strong>on</strong> income (re)distributi<strong>on</strong>. While possible cultural impacts are not at the centre <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these studies,all use a dummy for the French- and Italian-speaking cant<strong>on</strong>s to take possible cultural differences intoaccount.96 In additi<strong>on</strong>, political rights <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Swiss citizens vary <strong>on</strong>ly with respect to the cant<strong>on</strong>al and local levels. At thefederal level, citizens from all cant<strong>on</strong>s have the same political rights, i.e. with regard to such important policyfields as foreign policy, trade, defense, etc. Am<strong>on</strong>g the important fields <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> politics at the cant<strong>on</strong>al level areeducati<strong>on</strong>, welfare, and police.97 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> those speaking the fourth language, Rhaeto-Romanic, is about 1% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Swiss populati<strong>on</strong> and,therefore, in our c<strong>on</strong>text negligible. Moreover, practically all <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these people speak fluent German, the mainlanguage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Graubünden, the <strong>on</strong>ly cant<strong>on</strong> in which Rhaeto-Romanic is spoken.


– 88 –subsequent secti<strong>on</strong> I reestimate this relati<strong>on</strong>ship allowing for the relative income positi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the individuals and also using new, more recent data from the Swiss Household Panel (SHP).Using this dataset and panel techniques that c<strong>on</strong>trol for individual heterogeneity, no robustrelati<strong>on</strong>ship is observed between democracy and happiness in Switzerland. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> chapterc<strong>on</strong>cludes with some remarks about the differences between the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the two datasets.2 Previous Empirical Research for SwitzerlandAll empirical studies by STUTZER and FREY are based <strong>on</strong> a cross-secti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> approximately6,000 households from a 1992 dataset collected by LEU et al. (1997) that is a representativesample <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Swiss populati<strong>on</strong>. 98 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> dependent variable in these studies measures generallife satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> a scale from 1 to 10. 99 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> explanatory variables, which is verysimilar across their various c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s, includes ec<strong>on</strong>omic, sociodemographic, andinstituti<strong>on</strong>al variables. In most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their studies, cultural determinants and/or macroec<strong>on</strong>omicvariables are included for robustness checks. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se cultural variables are either the language<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the residential commune, as in STUTZER and FREY (2000), or the main language <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> therespective cant<strong>on</strong>, as, e.g., in FREY and STUTZER (2000, 2000a, 2003). However, as in FREYand STUTZER (2000b) or FREY et al. (2001), cultural variables are sometimes missing.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> main variable <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest is an instituti<strong>on</strong>al variable that refers to the situati<strong>on</strong> in 1992:direct democracy, which is measured by an index ranging from 1 to 6 100 . In accordance withthe literature menti<strong>on</strong>ed above, the authors assume that increased exposure to directdemocracy leads to policy outcomes that are closer to citizens' preferences 101 . This proximityshould, in turn, make them happier. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> estimati<strong>on</strong> method used in their analysis is primarily98Actually, there is oversampling <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> two groups, the elderly and the poor. However, a representative sample canbe obtained by either weighting the different groups, as FREY and STUTZER do in all their papers, or byeliminating the oversampled observati<strong>on</strong>s (which is possible due to the c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the dataset). As will beshown below, these two methods can lead to quite different results.99 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first three categories are aggregated to increase the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> observati<strong>on</strong>s for the lowest category.100 This n<strong>on</strong>weighted composite index is comprised <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> four separate indices for (i) the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative,(ii) the statutory initiative, (iii) the statutory referendum, and (iv) the fiscal referendum (See STUTZER (1999)or STUTZER and FREY (2000) for a detailed explanati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong>). FREY and STUTZER (2000, p.937), as well as STUTZER and FREY (2000b, pp. 32 c<strong>on</strong>t.), present tables that show the distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thisindex over all Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s.101 In additi<strong>on</strong>, in some <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their papers (e.g. FREY and STUTZER 2000a), they tested the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscalfederalism which is also predicted to be utility increasing. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y found the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> federalism to serve as a“transmissi<strong>on</strong> mechanism <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy’s beneficial effects” (p. 157) (i.e. the variable turned out not tobe significant in combinati<strong>on</strong> with direct democracy). See also FREY and STUTZER (2000, p. 928).


– 89 –a weighted ordered probit model with robust standard errors obtained through clustering at thecant<strong>on</strong>al level. 102In several c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s the authors show that the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy appears to berobust to different estimati<strong>on</strong> methods and to the inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> additi<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>trol variables; thepositive coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy stays significant at least at the 5% significancelevel. 103 In FREY and STUTZER (2000b), it is shown that the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy is alsorobust to c<strong>on</strong>trolling for those five cant<strong>on</strong>s in which direct democratic rights are exertedthrough an open vote (Landsgemeinden). Measured by the index employed, these cant<strong>on</strong>s areidentical to those that enjoy the highest level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy. In a variati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thisapproach, a regressi<strong>on</strong> excluding these cant<strong>on</strong>s is carried out that also results in the samepositive finding for direct legislative rights. 104 As STUTZER and FREY (2000) show, the impact<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy is also robust to c<strong>on</strong>trolling for measures <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the actualuse <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these instituti<strong>on</strong>s, proxied by the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al referenda. Moreover, theinclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interacti<strong>on</strong> variables between dummies for pers<strong>on</strong>al characteristics and the index<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy reveals that the gains in happiness are quite evenly distributed am<strong>on</strong>gdifferent socioec<strong>on</strong>omic groups 105 . In FREY and STUTZER (2000, p. 927), the problem <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>causality c<strong>on</strong>cerning direct democracy is addressed through ec<strong>on</strong>omic historical reas<strong>on</strong>ing.In their most recent c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to the analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> happiness forSwitzerland, STUTZER and FREY (2003) focus <strong>on</strong> procedural utility. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y test the existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>procedural utility in the political process, which <strong>on</strong>ly Swiss citizens should be able to enjoy.Again, the happiness enhancing impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy is observed. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y also separatethe gain in outcome utility from the gain in procedural utility by estimating separate butidentical models for both Swiss citizens and foreign residents. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y find that the increase inhappiness attributed to procedural utility is more than three times greater than the experiencedincrease in outcome utility. 106102 In some papers, they also present weighted OLS estimati<strong>on</strong>s.103 See, e.g. FREY and STUTZER (2000a). In this paper, they report the estimates when all possible cant<strong>on</strong>aldeterminants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> happiness taken into c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> are simultaneously included in the model, i.e. besidesothers nati<strong>on</strong>al income per capita or the main language <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> (positive) coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy remains significant.104See STUTZER and FREY (2000b, footnote 18).105See FREY and STUTZER (2000) and FREY and STUTZER (2000c) regarding the poor.106 In the sec<strong>on</strong>d part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this chapter, they use the first wave <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the SHP (1999) to test the hypothesis that greaterdirect democratic power <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> citizens in a cant<strong>on</strong> leads to the belief that they have greater political influence.Thus foreigners, who do not have these political participati<strong>on</strong> rights, should believe less in their political


– 90 –3 New Estimates for Switzerland3.1 Cross secti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1992 and Balanced Panel 2000 – 2002We reestimate the FREY and STUTZER (2000) model but deviate from their approach in tworespects. First, following the literature menti<strong>on</strong>ed in the introducti<strong>on</strong>, we do not look <strong>on</strong>ly atthe effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> (absolute) pers<strong>on</strong>al income but rather distinguish between the income levelwithin a cant<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the <strong>on</strong>e hand and the relative income positi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the individual <strong>on</strong> theother. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, we do not use <strong>on</strong>ly the LEU (1997) dataset but also new data from the SwissHousehold Panel (SHP), a l<strong>on</strong>gitudinal panel survey whose data are gathered annually usingcomputer-assisted teleph<strong>on</strong>e interviewing (CATI). In this survey <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> selected households, theprimary household representative must answer all questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> the pers<strong>on</strong>al questi<strong>on</strong>naire,while the remaining household members are <strong>on</strong>ly asked a particular selecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> questi<strong>on</strong>s.For the first wave, a representative sample <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 5,074 households from the Swiss populati<strong>on</strong>was recruited, meaning that a total <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 12,937 individuals were pers<strong>on</strong>ally interviewed in theautumn <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1999. For 2002, the sample size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the panel was equal to 3,690 households,comprised <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 9,544 individuals. A total <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 5,705 individuals were pers<strong>on</strong>ally interviewed. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>resp<strong>on</strong>se rate was between 84 and 89% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> all individuals c<strong>on</strong>tacted, a total <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 9,544individuals in these households. As the informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> life satisfacti<strong>on</strong> is <strong>on</strong>ly available forthe last three waves, i.e. for the years 2000 to 2002, our analysis is restricted to these threewaves.To make this analysis compatible with the FREY and STUTZER (2000) study, we restrict thesample to individuals older than 20. For the balanced panel, we also eliminate observati<strong>on</strong>swith missing values in the c<strong>on</strong>trol variables; e.g. occupati<strong>on</strong>al status, age, or family type, aswell as disabled status. Once missing income variables in <strong>on</strong>e wave are replaced by values inthe previous or subsequent wave(s), and negative income values are set to zero, the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>remaining observati<strong>on</strong>s in the panel declines from 5,362 pers<strong>on</strong>s in 2000 to 4,534interviewees in 2002.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> dependent variable is derived from a questi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> general satisfacti<strong>on</strong> with whose exactwording is as follows:influence. To test this hypothesis, they included an interacti<strong>on</strong> term between the variables ‘politicalparticipati<strong>on</strong> possibilities’ and ‘foreigner’. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> authors find this hypothesis supported by their results.


– 91 –In general, how satisfied are you with your life if 0 means 'not at all satisfied' and 10means 'completely satisfied'?To be able to compare the results with those <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> FREY and STUTZER (2000) and to avoidinference problems caused by too few observati<strong>on</strong>s, we aggregate the four lowest categories(0, 1, 2, 3) into a single category. 107 To make the coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the income variablescomparable to those in FREY and STUTZER (2000), which uses data <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1992, we deflate theincome data <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the SHP using the same year as base year. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se steps reduce the sample to3,301 individuals, i.e. 9,903 observati<strong>on</strong>s. To estimate the model, we first use an unweightedrandom-effects ordered probit model, thereby allowing for individual heterogeneity. 108 As arobustness test, we also carry out the identical estimati<strong>on</strong> for the unbalanced panel, whichleaves approximately 4,000 more observati<strong>on</strong>s. A fixed effects approach was not deemedappropriate because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the time invariance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the dependent variable for many individuals, aswell as the de facto time invariance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the instituti<strong>on</strong>al variables <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest. 109 To c<strong>on</strong>trol forother factors besides the income variables, we use the same explanatory variables as FREYund STUTZER (2000) and also include year dummies. In additi<strong>on</strong>, however, we also employdichotomous variables for various religious denominati<strong>on</strong>s and a dichotomous variable for abad health state.To test the relative income hypothesis and to allow for the likely n<strong>on</strong>linearity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the incomeeffect, we include subsistence income, measured as 40% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> average income in the respectivecant<strong>on</strong>; the difference between actual and subsistence income; and the squares <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thesedifferences calculated separately for positive and negative differences. Assuming a positivebut decreasing marginal utility <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income, we expect a positive sign for the relative income107 As the scale ranges from 0 to 10, it includes <strong>on</strong>e more category than the <strong>on</strong>es in the LEU-dataset used by FREYand STUTZER (2000). As the results in table A.2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendix show, the distributi<strong>on</strong>s over the remaininggroups are quite similar for the three waves <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the panel, the panel altogether, and the LEU data set. (Incalculating these statistics, the data are assumed to be cardinal and not ordinal, as they actually are. However,FERRER-I-CARBONELL and FRIJTERS (2004) have shown that assuming cardinality or ordinality makes littledifference.) – Descripti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the variables, the distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the observati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the life satisfacti<strong>on</strong>variable, and descriptive statistics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy are given in tables A.2, A.3 and A.4 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the Appendix.108 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> calculati<strong>on</strong>s have been performed by using the reoprob command in <strong>St</strong>ata, Versi<strong>on</strong> 8.1. (See for thisFRECHETTE (2001, 2001a).) Points for the Gaussian-Hermite quadrature approximati<strong>on</strong> are set at 30. – Sincethe three waves are each representative for Switzerland, estimati<strong>on</strong> without weights seemed appropriate. Forestimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the three single cross secti<strong>on</strong>s separately, see secti<strong>on</strong> 3.2. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> reoprob command does not allowclustering <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> aggregate level variables.109Furthermore, with <strong>on</strong>ly three time periods, the coefficients in a fixed effects ordered probit would have beensubject to a very severe bias. See for this, e.g., GREENE (2004).


– 92 –and a negative sign for the (positive) difference between actual and subsistence income. 110 If<strong>on</strong>ly relative income matters, the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> subsistence income should be zero. If absoluteincome matters, the coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> subsistence and relative income should be both positiveand identical.As is comm<strong>on</strong> in such studies, language – which can play an important role at different levels,instituti<strong>on</strong>al as well as individual – proxies for culture. Culture at the cant<strong>on</strong>al level can berepresented by the dominant language, which may be a decisive covariate because it can, to arather large degree, ‘explain’ the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy, 111 meaning that cant<strong>on</strong>al culturemight shape the very political instituti<strong>on</strong>s at the centre <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this analysis. Because there are threedominant languages in Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s, three dummy variables are used. Similar argumentshold for local culture, but corresp<strong>on</strong>ding data are <strong>on</strong>ly available in the LEU dataset.C<strong>on</strong>trolling for culture (i.e. language) at the individual level may also be important becausethe percepti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the benefits <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s may vary with individual culturalbackground. Moreover, the percepti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> happiness and what c<strong>on</strong>tributes to pers<strong>on</strong>alsatisfacti<strong>on</strong> may differ am<strong>on</strong>g individuals with different cultural backgrounds. Because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thehigh percentage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreigners (about 20% nati<strong>on</strong>wide), increasing mobility across languageregi<strong>on</strong>s, and a rising number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> bilingual couples, the pers<strong>on</strong>al cultural background isfrequently different from the dominant culture within a cant<strong>on</strong> or local community. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore,we use the language <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the family as the main variables representing the pers<strong>on</strong>al culturalbackground for the analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the SHP data. As the corresp<strong>on</strong>ding data are not available inthe LEU data set, we use the culture <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the local community as the sec<strong>on</strong>d cultural variable foranalysis 112 .Another possible variable to represent culture (that differs from language) is religi<strong>on</strong>. InSwitzerland, this holds because in the German- and French-speaking parts there are regi<strong>on</strong>swith large majorities <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> either Catholic or Protestant populati<strong>on</strong>s. Thus, religi<strong>on</strong> and languageare not highly correlated. To account for religious denominati<strong>on</strong>s, in the LEU data we use a110 Taking subsistence income and the difference between actual and subsistence income is under the null <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theabsolute income hypothesis observati<strong>on</strong>ally equivalent to using average income and the difference betweenactual and average income. Differences occur, however, with respect to the squared terms.111An OLS regressi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy for the year 2000 <strong>on</strong> the three cant<strong>on</strong>al languagevariables yields the following resultDEMO = 4.716 German + 2.753 French + 2.250 Italian + û,(4.72) (2.75) (2.25)with R 2 = 0.612 and 23 degrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> freedom. (<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> numbers in parentheses are the estimated t-statistics.)112 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> definiti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> all variables used in the following models are listed in table A.4 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendix


– 93 –dichotomous variable indicating whether an individual pays church taxes or not. Fortunately,the SHP data are richer and allow c<strong>on</strong>trolling for several individual religious pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>essi<strong>on</strong>s.Following the HENDRY approach, we start with the comprehensive model, for both <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> whosedatasets ordered probit estimates are given in table A.2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendix. 113 For the SHP data,we show the results for both the balanced and unbalanced panel. 114 For the LEU dataset, wepresent the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> weighted estimates that take into account the oversampling, as well asestimates for the reduced representative sample. In all four cases, the squared income variablefor those below the poverty line does not prove significant. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, this variable is deletedfrom further estimati<strong>on</strong>s. In all four estimati<strong>on</strong>s the variables c<strong>on</strong>trolling for religiousdenominati<strong>on</strong>s are either not significant at all or <strong>on</strong>ly very weakly at the 10% level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>significance 115 . For this reas<strong>on</strong>, these cultural factors are excluded from the discussi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theestimati<strong>on</strong> results. Moreover, the discussi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> results is also restricted to the balanced paneland the full LEU dataset.Table 1a shows the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the models with the SHP data. 116 If no cultural variables areincluded, the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct popular rights has a significant positive impact as in the models<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> FREY and STUTZER. However, as so<strong>on</strong> as any cultural variables are taken into account, thesignificance vanishes completely: the corresp<strong>on</strong>ding t-statistics are very far from anyc<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al significance level. Thus, the significance in model (1) seems to be <strong>on</strong>ly a result<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the omitted cultural variables.It is hardly surprising that the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct popular rights is str<strong>on</strong>gly reduced asso<strong>on</strong> as culture is included in the regressi<strong>on</strong> equati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> descriptive statistics in table A.3 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the Appendix and a corresp<strong>on</strong>ding analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> variance show that the main variance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thisindex is between and not within the three language groups. 117 Taking into account that thelanguage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a cant<strong>on</strong> is truly independent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its extent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct popular rights, it becomes113 For reference categories and chosen weights, see there.114 Similar results are obtained when the model is estimated for the three waves <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the SHP separately (see alsosecti<strong>on</strong> 3.2). Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, testing for various functi<strong>on</strong>al forms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy does notreveal a c<strong>on</strong>siderably significant effect when culture is c<strong>on</strong>trolled for.115 In both datasets the religious variables are also not jointly significant at the 5% level.116 We <strong>on</strong>ly present the results for the relevant variables. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> complete results can be received from the authors<strong>on</strong> request.117 61.3 % <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the variance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy is between and <strong>on</strong>ly 38.7 % is within the threelanguage groups. If we add the French and Italian part as <strong>on</strong>e, we still get 60.6 % between and <strong>on</strong>ly 39.4 % <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the variance between the groups.


– 94 –Table 1a: Pers<strong>on</strong>al Subjective Well-Being in Switzerland, 2000 – 2002SHP Data, Balanced Panel, 9903 Observati<strong>on</strong>sBasic Model (1)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy 0.049*(2.55)Subsistence IncomeRelative IncomeIncome above poverty linesquared0.094(0.82)0.052***(5.15)-0.001**(2.76)Model includingcant<strong>on</strong>alculture (2)0.019(0.69)0.054(0.44)0.052***(5.17)-0.001**(2.77)Model includinghouseholdculture (3)-0.009(0.35)0.014(0.12)0.052***(5.13)-0.001**(2.74)French-speaking cant<strong>on</strong> -0.112(1.61)Italian-speaking cant<strong>on</strong> -0.117(0.91)French-speaking family -0.212***(3.28)Italian-speaking family -0.336**(2.93)Model includingcant<strong>on</strong>al andhouseholdculture (4)0.008(0.29)0.062(0.51)0.052***(5.10)-0.001**(2.73)0.104(0.94)0.325(*)(1.66)-0.273**(2.61)-0.547**(3.12)Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> likelihood -14'375.227 -14'373.905 -14'368.221 -14'366.660Subsistence Income =Relative IncomeJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>cant<strong>on</strong>al languagevariablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>family language variablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy and cant<strong>on</strong>allanguage variablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy and familylanguage variablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy and alllanguage variablesWald Tests0.13 0.00 0.10 0.012.65 3.1214.04*** 14.50***9.16* 3.2420.57*** 14.97**23.69***<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> number in parentheses are the absolute values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the z-statistics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the estimated parameters. ‘***’, ‘**’, ‘*’or ‘(*)’ show that the corresp<strong>on</strong>ding null hypothesis can be rejected at the 0.1, 1, 5, or 10% level, respectively.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Wald tests are χ 2 with 1, 2, 3, or 5 degrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> freedom, respectively.


– 95 –obvious that omitting the language variables from the estimated equati<strong>on</strong> results in a seriousspecificati<strong>on</strong> error that inflates the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy, as well as itsestimated significance level.Relative income is always highly significant, but subsistence income is not. This finding isevidence in favor <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the relative income hypothesis. However, when testing for the equality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> subsistence and relative income, the null hypothesis can never be rejected.Thus, the results do not allow discriminati<strong>on</strong> between the absolute and the relative incomehypotheses. On the other hand, the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the squared relative income term is always –as expected – negative and statistically significant. This result is clear evidence for adecreasing marginal utility <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> signs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cultural variables indicate that people in French- and Italian-speaking cant<strong>on</strong>sand/or families are less satisfied with their overall situati<strong>on</strong> than people living in Germanspeakingcant<strong>on</strong>s and/or families (models (2) and (3)). However, if the different indicators aredifferentiated, it becomes clear that it is the language <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the family and not the language <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thecant<strong>on</strong> that matters (model (4)). Once the language <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the family is included, neither thecant<strong>on</strong>al language nor the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy proves c<strong>on</strong>siderably significant. Thisobservati<strong>on</strong> does not <strong>on</strong>ly hold for the single variables, as can be seen in the z-statistics, butalso for the combined hypotheses, as the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Wald tests show. French- and Italianspeakingpeople seem more critical <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their situati<strong>on</strong> than German-speaking people.Table 1b shows the corresp<strong>on</strong>ding results from the LEU dataset, 118 which are quite differentfrom those obtained using the SHP data. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy is more robust in thisdataset. When cultural variables are omitted, the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracyis significantly different from zero even at the 1% level. If <strong>on</strong>ly local culture is included, thesignificance vanishes (model (7)); however, if both sets <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cultural variables are included, it issignificant at the 10% level (model (8)); and if <strong>on</strong>ly the cant<strong>on</strong>al variables are included, it isstill significant at the 5% level (model (6)). 119 As the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Wald tests show, c<strong>on</strong>trary118 Model (5) corresp<strong>on</strong>ds to the sec<strong>on</strong>d equati<strong>on</strong> in FREY and STUTZER (2000, table 2, p. 927); however, thehealth status and denominati<strong>on</strong> variables have been added. (<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y include the health status, e.g., in STUTZERand FREY (2000, 2003)). Using the same specificati<strong>on</strong>, we were able to exactly replicate their results. Thus,differences between their results and model (5) are due to the different specificati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the income variablesand the inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the health status variable.119 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> significance is approximately the same if the fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> variable is included in the model, butit increases if the individual health status is deleted, giving z-values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 3.19, 2.37, 1.60, and 2.17 in models(5) to (8), respectively. On the other hand, the significance vanishes if the smaller, representative dataset is


– 96 –Table 1b: Pers<strong>on</strong>al Subjective Well-Being in Switzerland, 1992LEU Data, Full Cross Secti<strong>on</strong>, 6127 observati<strong>on</strong>s(5)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy 0.080**(2.91)-0.133Subsistence Income(1.35)Relative IncomeIncome above poverty linesquared0.024**(2.83)-0.001***(3.45)Model includingcant<strong>on</strong>al culture(6)0.050*(1.98)-0.210*(2.13)0.025**(2.95)-0.001***(3.74)Model includinglocal culture (7)0.042(1.58)-0.211*(2.05)0.024**(2.91)-0.001***(3.64)-0.194**French-speaking cant<strong>on</strong>(3.09)Italian-speaking cant<strong>on</strong> 0.190*(2.55)French-speaking family -0.224***(4.47)Italian-speaking family 0.157*(1.99)Model includingcant<strong>on</strong>al andlocal culture (8)0.041(*)(1.77)-0.219*(2.21)0.025**(2.95)-0.001***(3.75)-0.047(0.30)0.436***(3.34)-0.185(1.33)-0.274**(3.02)Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> likelihood -10'032.007 -10'014.004 -10'011.961 -10'011.223Wald TestsSubsistence Income =Relative IncomeJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>cant<strong>on</strong>al languagevariablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>family language variablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy and cant<strong>on</strong>allanguage variablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy and familylanguage variablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy and alllanguage variables2.61 5.89* 5.35* 6.29*86.22*** 14.00***158.60*** 9.49**87.22*** 14.01**160.87*** 11.17*261.84***<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> number in parentheses are the absolute values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the z-statistics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the estimated parameters. ‘***’, ‘**’, ‘*’or ‘(*)’ show that the corresp<strong>on</strong>ding null hypothesis can be rejected at the 0.1, 1, 5, or 10% level, respectively.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Wald tests are χ2 with 1, 2, 3, or 5 degrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> freedom, respectively. Full LEU sample has been estimatedwith individual weights. Robust standard errors obtained through clustering <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>s.used. This gives the following z-values: 2.50, 1.67, 1.18, and 1.44. Thus, <strong>on</strong>ce individual culture is included,the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct popular rights never proves significant at any c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al level.


– 97 –Table 2: Results for Different Populati<strong>on</strong> GroupsGermanspeakingcant<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy -0.004(0.14)Subsistence IncomeRelative Income0.117(0.89)0.046***(3.86)Frenchspeakingcant<strong>on</strong>sGermanspeakingfamiliesSHP Data 2000 – 2002, balanced panel0.256**(2.66)0.040(0.10)0.074**(3.17)-0.006(0.22)0.144(1.11)0.044***(3.72)Frenchspeakingfamilies0.050(0.68)-0.235(0.66)0.078***(3.34)Income above poverty linesquared-0.001*(2.48)-0.000(0.20)-0.001*(2.42)-0.000(0.20)Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> likelihood -9'600.8689 -4'038.6533 -9'495.1812 -4'052.0114Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> observati<strong>on</strong>s 6716 2748 6670 2755Subsistence Income =Relative IncomeWald Tests0.29 0.01 0.58 0.76Germanspeakingcant<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy 0.029(1.10)-0.191(*)Subsistence Income(1.82)Relative Income0.024*(2.46)Frenchspeakingcant<strong>on</strong>sLEU Data, 19920.054(0.95)-1.000*(2.28)0.061(*)(1.77)Germanspeakingfamilies0.039(1.32)-0.186(*)(1.73)0.025*(2.50)Frenchspeakingfamilies0.039(0.73)-0.729*(2.18)0.060(*)(1.81)Income above poverty line -0.001*** -0.003*** -0.001*** -0.003***squared(3.73) (3.35) (3.71) (3.20)Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> likelihood -7'108.1302 -2'397.8161 -7'201.1989 -2'293.8294Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> observati<strong>on</strong>s 4466 1378 4531 1308Wald TestsSubsistence Income =Relative Income4.43* 5.50* 4.02* 5.40*<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> number in parentheses are the absolute values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the z-<strong>St</strong>atistics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the estimated parameters. ‘***’,‘**’, ‘*’ or ‘(*)’ show that the estimated parameter is significantly different from zero at the 0.1, 1, 5, or10% level, respectively. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Wald tests are χ 2 with 1 degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> freedom. See also tables 1a and 1b.


– 98 –to the results for the SHP dataset, both sets <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cultural variables should be included. Thus, <strong>on</strong>einteresting result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this analysis is that the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct popular rights is (at leastmarginally) significant if the full LEU dataset is used but not significant at all when morerecent SHP dataset is used.In additi<strong>on</strong>, in model (1), subsistence income has an insignificant coefficient, but the test forequality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coefficients between the subsistence income and the relative income cannot berejected. If culture is included in the following models (2), (3) and (4), however, thecoefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> subsistence income always has a negative sign and is significant at the 5% level.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> equality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> subsistence and relative income, however, can always berejected at the 5% level. This result, again, does not allow discriminati<strong>on</strong> between the absoluteand the relative income hypothesis. On the other hand, we also find decreasing marginalutility <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income as in the SHP dataset.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are also some differences between the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the two datasets with respect to thecultural impact. First, whereas cant<strong>on</strong>al culture is insignificant in the SHP data, in the LEUdata, both group indicators prove significant. This outcome might, however, be due to the factthat local culture is not a sufficiently appropriate substitute for pers<strong>on</strong>al culture. Moresurprising is the sec<strong>on</strong>d difference. Taking the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the SHP data, both French and Italiancant<strong>on</strong>al, as well as pers<strong>on</strong>al, cultures lead, ceteris paribus, to a lower degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> subjectivewell-being, if included separately in the model. In the LEU data, the result is identical for theFrench cant<strong>on</strong>s and local communities but not for the Italian-speaking individuals, who seemhappier than their French- and German-speaking counterparts.Finally, we split the datasets and estimate the model for various cultural subgroups: i.e. forGerman- and French-speaking cant<strong>on</strong>s and families. 120 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se results for the SHP panel, asshown in table 2, seem to c<strong>on</strong>firm that direct democracy has a life satisfacti<strong>on</strong> increasingimpact in cant<strong>on</strong>s whose majority language is French but an insignificant <strong>on</strong>e in Germanspeakingcant<strong>on</strong>s. Splitting the SHP data according to languages <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the householdquesti<strong>on</strong>naire, however, shows no significant impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> anycultural subpopulati<strong>on</strong>. Once again, this result is different with respect to the LEU dataset. InGerman- as well as French-speaking local communities, direct democracy seems to have no120 Estimating separate equati<strong>on</strong>s for Italian culture is not possible as there is <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>e cant<strong>on</strong>, Tessin (Ticino), inwhich the main language is Italian. Moreover, because most Italian-speaking Swiss live in this cant<strong>on</strong>, theequati<strong>on</strong> for the subsample with Italian family culture is also dropped.


– 99 –significant impact <strong>on</strong> pers<strong>on</strong>al well-being, even if the coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the estimated parametersare positive in all four regressi<strong>on</strong>s.Combining the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the two datasets reveals that the findings <strong>on</strong> the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income <strong>on</strong>subjective well-being are c<strong>on</strong>sistent: Both are neither fully compatible with the relativeincome hypothesis, nor with the absolute income hypothesis. However, with respect to(direct) democracy and culture, major differences exist. While both show that culture has astr<strong>on</strong>g impact <strong>on</strong> subjective well-being, according to the SHP data, Italian culture seems tohave a negative impact <strong>on</strong> happiness, but according to the LEU data, it has a positive <strong>on</strong>e.Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, while the SHP results str<strong>on</strong>gly suggest that democracy itself has no statisticallysignificant effect <strong>on</strong> happiness in Switzerland 121 , results for the LEU data indicate a possibleindependent impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> pers<strong>on</strong>al well-being, even if the significances arefragile and str<strong>on</strong>gly dependent <strong>on</strong> the respective specificati<strong>on</strong>s.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> questi<strong>on</strong> remains <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> why these differences exist. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are at least two possible reas<strong>on</strong>s.One is that the weighting procedure does not really produce a representative sample. Thispresumpti<strong>on</strong> is supported by the fact that the results with the reduced sample do not – at leastwith respect to the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy – indicate significance and are thus compatiblewith the SHP data results. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sec<strong>on</strong>d possible reas<strong>on</strong> is that the percepti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Swisspopulati<strong>on</strong> with respect to their valuati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the benefits <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy might havechanged between 1992, when the LEU data were collected, and the beginning <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this century,as represented by the SHP data. In any case, as earlier menti<strong>on</strong>ed, a finding <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> no significantimpact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct popular rights <strong>on</strong> pers<strong>on</strong>al well-being in these individual datasets inSwitzerland does not indicate that there is no impact at all. First, the most important elements<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Swiss direct democracy exist at the federal level, and they are identical for all Swisspeople. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, as menti<strong>on</strong>ed previously, measured <strong>on</strong> an internati<strong>on</strong>al scale, the extent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democratic rights in all Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s is extremely high. Thus, it may well be the case thatdemocracy, and especially direct democracy, has a positive impact <strong>on</strong> the pers<strong>on</strong>al subjectivewell-being <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the whole Swiss populati<strong>on</strong>, even though no statistical significance is found atthe subfederal level.121 In the unbalanced SHP panel a statistical significance at the 10% level is reached (see table A.2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theAppendix). Since in this estimati<strong>on</strong> standard errors are not corrected according to the MOULTON-critique(1990), however, significance levels appear inflated.


– 100 –3.2 Results for Single Waves, 2000 – 2002One interesting extensi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these Swiss results is to look at the single crosssecti<strong>on</strong>s rather than the whole panel. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> advantage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> single waves is that they c<strong>on</strong>tain moreobservati<strong>on</strong>s than the balanced panel al<strong>on</strong>e. In this case, the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> observati<strong>on</strong>s rangesfrom 5,341 to 4,523, in c<strong>on</strong>trast to the 3,301 individuals per wave in the balanced panel. Thisexercise also serves to reveal whether the results obtained in the balanced and unbalancedpanels are driven by <strong>on</strong>e single wave <strong>on</strong>ly; it also serves to account for sample attriti<strong>on</strong> in the(balanced) panel. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> process <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> variable creati<strong>on</strong> and deleti<strong>on</strong> is approximately the same asfor the balanced panel 122 . Again, the model specificati<strong>on</strong> includes religious denominati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the individual. An ordered probit model is estimated with transversal individual weights andadjustment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> standard errors through clustering <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>s. Results for the single waves aredisplayed in tables 3a, 3b, and 3c for the years 2000, 2001, and 2002, respectively.A comparis<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the results for all three waves reveals that direct democracy does not alwaysexert the expected impacts and its influence varies over the three cross secti<strong>on</strong>s. Based <strong>on</strong> thebalanced panel results in table 1a, it should affect happiness positively in the first model, andits coefficient should be positive in models (2) and (4), when measures <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al culture areincluded. In fact, such a significant happiness increasing influence is found in model (1) foreach wave. Yet the estimati<strong>on</strong> results reveal a negative coefficient in models (2) and (4) in theyear 2001 wave 123 , even though the predicted happiness raising influence is observed in the2000 and 2002 waves. On the other hand, as previously observed in the balanced panel,c<strong>on</strong>trolling for (cant<strong>on</strong>al and/or pers<strong>on</strong>al) culture (see models (2), (3), and (4)) leads always toa breakdown in the link between direct popular rights and well-being in all waves.122 In c<strong>on</strong>trast to the balanced panel, observati<strong>on</strong>s with missing income variables have been deleted. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> resultsfor the single SHP waves are similar to the <strong>on</strong>es for single waves in the balanced panel.123 A positive coefficient is observed in model (3) in the year 2002 wave which also c<strong>on</strong>tradicts the results in thebalanced panel.


– 101 –Table 3a: Pers<strong>on</strong>al Subjective Well-Being in Switzerland, 2000SHP Data, Cross Secti<strong>on</strong>, 5341 Observati<strong>on</strong>sBasic Model (1)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy 0.061**(3.15)Subsistence IncomeRelative IncomeIncome above poverty linesquared-0.163(1.20)0.057***(4.64)-0.002*(2.49)Model includingcant<strong>on</strong>alculture (2)0.016(0.72)-0.258(*)(1.90)0.057***(4.70)-0.002**(2.59)Model includinghouseholdculture (3)-0.000(0.02)0.296*(2.25)0.056***(4.64)-0.002**(2.60)French-speaking cant<strong>on</strong> -0.163***(3.72)Italian-speaking cant<strong>on</strong> -0.162**(2.92)French-speaking family -0.241***(6.94)Italian-speaking family -0.322***(3.67)Model includingcant<strong>on</strong>al andhouseholdculture (4)0.009(0.41)-0.252(*)(1.81)0.056***(4.62)-0.002**(2.58)0.001(0.01)0.169(1.20)-0.223*(1.96)-0.411**(2.98)Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> likelihood -8'388.0864 -8'382.5347 -8'369.9752 -8'368.9366Subsistence Income =Relative IncomeJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>cant<strong>on</strong>al languagevariablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>family language variablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy and cant<strong>on</strong>allanguage variablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy and familylanguage variablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy and alllanguage variablesWald Tests2.51 5.32* 7.19** 4.85*14.21*** 1.4748.19*** 13.93***25.54*** 1.6681.43*** 15.55**72.87***<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> number in parentheses are the absolute values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the z-statistics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the estimated parameters. ‘***’, ‘**’, ‘*’or ‘(*)’ show that the corresp<strong>on</strong>ding null hypothesis can be rejected at the 0.1, 1, 5, or 10% level, respectively.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Wald tests are χ 2 with 1, 2, 3, or 5 degrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> freedom, respectively. Estimati<strong>on</strong> with transversal individualweights keeping sample size and with robust standard errors by clustering o cant<strong>on</strong>s.


– 102 –Table 3b: Pers<strong>on</strong>al Subjective Well-Being in Switzerland, 2001SHP Data, Cross Secti<strong>on</strong>, 5004 Observati<strong>on</strong>sBasic Model (1)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy 0.055***(3.37)Subsistence IncomeRelative IncomeIncome above poverty linesquared0.029(0.29)0.036**(3.06)-0.000*(2.07)Model includingcant<strong>on</strong>alculture (2)-0.002(0.09)-0.007(0.08)0.035**(2.94)-0.000(*)(1.92)Model includinghouseholdculture (3)-0.005(0.21)0.007(0.09)0.035**(2.87)-0.000(*)(1.86)French-speaking cant<strong>on</strong> -0.195***(5.16)Italian-speaking cant<strong>on</strong> -0.165**(3.08)French-speaking family -0.226***(5.10)Italian-speaking family -0.207*(2.15)Model includingcant<strong>on</strong>al andhouseholdculture (4)-0.007(0.34)0.007(0.08)0.035**(2.87)-0.000(*)(1.86)-0.053(0.91)0.018(0.12)-0.181***(3.24)-0.224(1.33)Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> likelihood -7'973.7579 -7'965.9563 -7'960.9757 -7'960.7507Subsistence Income =Relative IncomeJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>cant<strong>on</strong>al languagevariablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>family language variablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy and cant<strong>on</strong>allanguage variablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy and familylanguage variablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy and alllanguage variablesWald Tests0.01 0.27 0.12 0.1127.33*** 0.8934.01*** 10.68**43.24*** 1.0939.97*** 12.43**46.11***<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> number in parentheses are the absolute values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the z-statistics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the estimated parameters. ‘***’, ‘**’, ‘*’or ‘(*)’ show that the corresp<strong>on</strong>ding null hypothesis can be rejected at the 0.1, 1, 5, or 10 % level, respectively.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Wald tests are χ 2 with 1, 2, 3, or 5 degrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> freedom, respectively. Estimati<strong>on</strong> with transversal individualweights keeping sample size and robust standard errors by clustering <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>s.


– 103 –Table3c: Pers<strong>on</strong>al Subjective Well-Being in Switzerland, 2002SHP Data, Cross Secti<strong>on</strong>, 4523 Observati<strong>on</strong>sBasic Model (1)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy 0.051***(4.20)Subsistence IncomeRelative IncomeIncome above poverty linesquared-0.015(0.18)0.068***(8.61)-0.001***(7.34)Model includingcant<strong>on</strong>alculture (2)0.034(1.49)-0.054(0.52)0.068***(8.52)-0.001***(7.24)Model includinghouseholdculture (3)0.021(0.98)-0.082(0.80)0.067***(8.19)-0.001***(7.02)French-speaking cant<strong>on</strong> -0.046(0.73)Italian-speaking cant<strong>on</strong> -0.107(1.43)French-speaking family -0.089(1.53)Italian-speaking family -0.292***(4.20)Model includingcant<strong>on</strong>al andhouseholdculture (4)0.035(1.54)-0.032(0.30)0.067***(8.07)-0.001***(7.04)-0.015(0.24)0.248*(2.31)-0.051(0.63)-0.424***(4.13)Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> likelihood -7'195.3371 -7'194.5900 -7'186.9392 -7'184.6366Subsistence Income =Relative IncomeJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>cant<strong>on</strong>al languagevariablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>family language variablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy and cant<strong>on</strong>allanguage variablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy and familylanguage variablesJoint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy and alllanguage variablesWald Tests1.00 1.39 2.08 0.862.67 5.73(*)17.73*** 17.10***28.33*** 6.83(*)47.95*** 28.81***72.34***<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> number in parentheses are the absolute values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the z-statistics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the estimated parameters. ‘***’, ‘**’, ‘*’or ‘(*)’ show that the corresp<strong>on</strong>ding null hypothesis can be rejected at the 0.1, 1, 5, or 10 % level, respectively.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Wald tests are χ 2 with 1, 2, 3, or 5 degrees <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> freedom, respectively. Estimati<strong>on</strong> with transversal individualweights keeping sample size and robust standard errors by clustering <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>s.


– 104 –In additi<strong>on</strong>, also c<strong>on</strong>siderable differences are observed with respect to the income variable.First, if culture is included, the subsistence income is significant in the year 2000 wave, whichsupports the absolute income hypothesis, but with the wr<strong>on</strong>g sign. In c<strong>on</strong>trast, it isinsignificant in the subsequent two waves, which is in line with the relative incomehypothesis. In additi<strong>on</strong>, for the year 2000, the hypothesis that the coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> subsistenceincome and relative income are equal is rejected if culture is included (see models (2) to (4)in table 3a), which is in line with the relative income hypothesis; however, this is not the casefor the years 2001 and 2002, which, again, supports the absolute income hypothesis. Overall,neither the absolute nor the relative income hypothesis can be fully supported or rejected inany <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the three waves. On the other hand, in all three waves, relative income appears alwaysto increase happiness. Decreasing marginal returns to income can also be unambiguouslyobserved in all three waves, although in the year 2001 wave the corresp<strong>on</strong>ding coefficient is<strong>on</strong>ly weakly significant (at the 10% level).As expected, culture measured by language always appears to be an important determinant 124 .In the first two <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the three waves, cant<strong>on</strong>al French or Italian culture is a decisive determinant<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> happiness if pers<strong>on</strong>al culture is not c<strong>on</strong>trolled for (see model (2)); however, in the year2002 wave, the cant<strong>on</strong>al cultural variables are not even jointly significant. Nevertheless, thesigns <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cultural factors point in the same directi<strong>on</strong> in all three waves, corroborating theresult obtained for the balanced panel and indicating a happiness decreasing influence. In allthree waves, the speaking <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> French or Italian in the household exerts an almost alwayssignificantly negative influence <strong>on</strong> a pers<strong>on</strong>'s happiness level, in c<strong>on</strong>trast to households inwhich German is spoken (see model (3)). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> observed signs equal those obtained in thebalanced panel. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se individual cultural determinants at the household level are in all threewaves jointly significant. In model (4), the inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> both cant<strong>on</strong>al and pers<strong>on</strong>al measures<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> culture reveals changing signs and significance levels, particularly for the cant<strong>on</strong>alvariables. In model (4), also jointly significant in all three waves are the measures <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> familyculture, whereas the test results for cant<strong>on</strong>al culture are different in the year 2002 from the<strong>on</strong>es in the year 2000 and 2001 waves.A brief look at the remaining individual determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> happiness may give some indicati<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> whether some <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the changing results for the instituti<strong>on</strong>al, cultural, and income variables124 In the year 2000 and 2001 waves, religi<strong>on</strong> never played a significant role. Only in the year 2002 waveparticularly Protestants appear to be c<strong>on</strong>siderable happier (at the 5% level) in all specificati<strong>on</strong>s, and alsoChrist-Catholic and other Christian denominati<strong>on</strong>s in model (4).


– 105 –result from the creati<strong>on</strong> by the different sample sizes in the three waves <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a sample selecti<strong>on</strong>bias 125 . In all three waves and all specificati<strong>on</strong>s, health status negatively influences theperceived level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> well-being. For all three years, the positive coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the three oldestage groups appear significant; however, results for 2000 and 2001 show that pers<strong>on</strong>s aged 40or younger experience a c<strong>on</strong>siderably lower happiness level than the reference group <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>pers<strong>on</strong>s younger than 30. In additi<strong>on</strong>, females are significantly happier in all three waves andalso foreigners always seem less happy. In <strong>on</strong>ly two <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the three waves does educati<strong>on</strong> matterfor individual well-being. However, in all estimati<strong>on</strong>s, family status and household type showan identical pattern <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> influence. Unemployed pers<strong>on</strong>s do not appear unhappier in 2000 but insubsequent years, possibly as a result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the recessi<strong>on</strong> that began in and c<strong>on</strong>tinued during thatperiod. Housewives, however, are more satisfied with their lives in 2002 and 2000, but not in2001. Finally, the employment status <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 'other’ and 'self-employed' again show identical signsand similar significance levels in all three single cross secti<strong>on</strong>s. In sum, the similarity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theremaining individual determinants between the three waves does not support the likelihood <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>a sample selecti<strong>on</strong> problem 126 .Overall, the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the wave 2000 seem most to resemble the balanced panel results.Despite the differences between the estimati<strong>on</strong> results for the single waves, <strong>on</strong>e comm<strong>on</strong>lyobserved trait is a more fragile and less decisive influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al culture compared topers<strong>on</strong>al culture. Furthermore, from a statistical viewpoint, the cultural factor clearlydominates the instituti<strong>on</strong>al impact in all three single waves: a statistical insignificance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theinstituti<strong>on</strong>al variable could be observed in all three waves when either measure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> culture wasincluded in the specificati<strong>on</strong>. In this respect, the findings for the balanced panel can be seen tobe corroborated. To c<strong>on</strong>clude, the fragility <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> some <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the estimati<strong>on</strong> results am<strong>on</strong>g thevarious waves, however, emphasizes the advantage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a panel estimati<strong>on</strong> over a single crosssecti<strong>on</strong> that might – as a whole – be a statistical outlier.125 FRIJTERS et al. (2004, p. 651 c<strong>on</strong>t.) present an overview <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the findings <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> previous empirical life satisfacti<strong>on</strong>studies with respect to the sociodemographic determinants age, gender, health, marriage/divorce, educati<strong>on</strong>,unemployment and ethnicity.126 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> complete results can be received from the authors <strong>on</strong> request.


– 106 –4 Summary and C<strong>on</strong>cluding RemarksIn this chapter, we analyze the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy <strong>on</strong> subjective well-being both inSwitzerland and in an internati<strong>on</strong>al comparis<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 28 countries. Whereas FREY and STUTZER(2000, 2000b, 2003) show a positive influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy <strong>on</strong> happiness in Switzerland, noother analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this problem exists that uses a microdata-based internati<strong>on</strong>al regressi<strong>on</strong>analysis. In additi<strong>on</strong>, by including language and religi<strong>on</strong> variables, we c<strong>on</strong>trol not <strong>on</strong>ly forvarious sociodemographic and ec<strong>on</strong>omic determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> life satisfacti<strong>on</strong> but also for culturalinfluences.Results for the two different datasets for the 26 Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s revealed that intercant<strong>on</strong>aldifferences in the levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy no l<strong>on</strong>ger show a significant impact <strong>on</strong> pers<strong>on</strong>alhappiness <strong>on</strong>ce cultural differences am<strong>on</strong>g the different Swiss regi<strong>on</strong>s are c<strong>on</strong>trolled for. mostThis is most probably because differences in democracy levels are small am<strong>on</strong>g Swisscant<strong>on</strong>s; thus, levels in the latter may not be sufficiently large to generate a statisticalsignificance at any c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al level when the inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cultural determinants diminishesvariati<strong>on</strong> in the democracy variable. However, this result varies am<strong>on</strong>g the regi<strong>on</strong>s: when <strong>on</strong>lythe French-speaking part is c<strong>on</strong>sidered, the SHP data reveal a significant positive impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy <strong>on</strong> happiness. This observati<strong>on</strong> does not apply, however, to the German-speakingpart.In both investigati<strong>on</strong>s, culture also has a c<strong>on</strong>siderable impact <strong>on</strong> subjective well-being, <strong>on</strong>ethat in most cases is highly significant. With regard to cultural background, it appears thatindividuals speaking French or Italian seem less happy than those speaking a Germaniclanguage. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> questi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> why this apparent difference exists and why people speakingcertain other languages appear less happy remain open. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, it is imperative that,studies <strong>on</strong> subjective well-being, even <strong>on</strong> a nati<strong>on</strong>al level, c<strong>on</strong>trol for individual culture.Finally, relative income has a positive impact <strong>on</strong> happiness, but with diminishing returns. Thisfinding is c<strong>on</strong>sistent with the usual assumpti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> decreasing marginal utility. Whether theabsolute income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a pers<strong>on</strong> also has an impact <strong>on</strong> happiness cannot be unambiguouslydetermined by this study. However, even if absolute income has an additi<strong>on</strong>al impact <strong>on</strong>happiness, the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> relative income clearly dominates.


– 107 –5 AppendixTable A.1: Distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Life Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> in the Balanced Panel,Extent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Fiscal Federalism in 2000Cant<strong>on</strong>Categories10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3Aargau 18.1 20.7 37.8 14.4 3.1 4.0 1.0 0.9 8.9 5.46Appenzell Innerrhoden 0.0 0.0 20.0 40.0 20.0 20.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 5.44Appenzell Ausserrhoden 25.3 13.8 40.2 13.8 4.6 2.3 0.0 0.0 0.9 5.50Bern 19.1 19.2 40.7 14.5 2.1 3.3 0.7 0.4 11.2 3.02Basel-<strong>St</strong>adt 18.9 21.5 40.7 10.4 3.0 4.7 0.3 0.3 3.0 5.48Basel-Landschaft 23.8 18.8 35.8 13.3 3.4 4.3 0.6 0.0 3.3 4.40Freiburg 14.3 16.0 39.3 15.5 6.8 5.8 1.5 0.8 4.0 2.79Genf 16.6 12.6 38.4 17.9 6.7 5.7 0.4 1.7 4.8 1.75Glarus 31.1 11.5 36.1 14.8 0.0 6.6 0.0 0.0 0.6 5.75Graubünden 25.6 23.2 36.3 12.5 1.2 1.2 0.0 0.0 1.7 4.83Jura 1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 3.71Luzern 17.1 21.5 37.7 13.0 4.2 4.8 0.5 1.2 5.7 4.42Neuenburg 18.0 16.1 38.7 14.6 5.9 5.0 1.0 0.6 6.3 2.19Nidwalden 10.7 0.0 57.1 21.4 7.1 3.6 0.0 0.0 0.3 4.44Obwalden 29.8 15.8 35.1 14.0 5.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.6 4.63<strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong> 22.2 21.1 35.2 13.5 3.9 3.3 0.6 0.2 4.9 3.46Schaffhausen 9.8 20.6 44.1 18.6 1.0 3.9 1.0 1.0 1.0 5.21Solothurn 16.2 20.1 38.3 16.6 3.5 3.0 1.6 0.7 4.4 5.25Schwyz 19.4 20.0 40.6 13.3 1.1 5.0 0.0 0.6 1.8 4.93Thurgau 14.4 19.5 40.1 18.3 3.1 3.9 0.4 0.4 2.6 4.33Tessin 17.2 19.0 34.8 14.5 5.4 6.1 0.9 2.0 4.4 2.25Uri 33.3 23.8 28.6 4.8 4.8 4.8 0.0 0.0 0.2 5.13Waadt 14.5 20.5 40.4 13.5 4.6 4.2 1.0 1.3 9.5 2.50Wallis 22.0 18.9 39.3 12.9 3.8 2.5 0.0 0.6 3.2 3.58Zug 13.4 16.8 40.3 20.2 3.4 5.9 0.0 0.0 1.2 4.42Zürich 17.6 19.7 37.6 15.4 4.3 3.6 0.6 1.0 15.5 3.50Total Share 18.0 19.1 38.5 14.7 4.0 4.1 0.7 0.8CS is the cant<strong>on</strong>al share in observati<strong>on</strong>s in the balanced panel, DD the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy for the year 2000.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re are no observati<strong>on</strong>s from the cant<strong>on</strong> Jura in the balanced panel.CSDD


– 108 –Table A2: Results for Switzerland, Full ModelSHP DataLEU DataBalanced PanelUnbalancedPanelFull SampleRepresentativeSample<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy0.008(0.29)0.039(*)(1.67)0.042(*)(1.80)0.025(1.16)Good or average healthReference categoryBad health-0.536***(12.79)-0.562***(15.22)-0.703***(16.93)-0.713***(18.89)Age 20-29Reference categoryAge 30-39Age 40-49Age 50-59Age 60-69Age 70-79Age 80 and older0.045(0.74)0.018(0.27)-0.028(0.41)-0.046(0.59)-0.031(0.34)-0.186(1.29)-0.027(0.51)0.023(0.42)0.002(0.03)-0.060(0.92)-0.136(*)(1.77)-0.272*(2.22)-0.033(0.38)0.069(0.90)0.044(0.73)0.299***(3.91)0.413***(4.69)0.422***(4.60)-0.095(*)(1.68)0.048(0.76)-0.024(0.45)0.255***(5.80)0.398***(5.01)0.492***(6.00)MaleReference CategoryFemale-0.082(*)(1.73)-0.008(0.19)0.062(*)(1.65)0.070*(2.12)SwissReference CategoryForeigner-0.302***(3.90)-0.317***(5.08)-0.233***(4.02)-0.186**(3.16)Low educati<strong>on</strong>Reference CategoryMiddle educati<strong>on</strong>High educati<strong>on</strong>Single womanSingle man0.095(*)(1.71)0.029(0.42)-0.355***(4.51)-0.446***(5.25)0.029(0.63)0.016(0.27)-0.426***(6.24)-0.365***(5.01)0.051(1.23)0.044(0.79)-0.272***(5.45)-0.211***(3.54)0.080***(3.18)0.106**(2.57)-0.177***(3.80)-0.269***(6.44)


– 109 –Table A2: Results for Switzerland, Full Model (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Balanced PanelSHP DataUnbalancedPanelFull SampleLEU DataRepresentativeSampleCouple without childrenReference CategoryCouple with childrenSingle parentOther private householdCollective household-0.140**(2.82)-0.704***(7.53)-0.311(*)(1.96)-0.136(0.74)-0.142***(3.38)-0.603***(7.86)-0.276 *(2.16)-0.262(*)(1.89)-0.142***(3.47)-0.378***(3.68)-0.168 *(2.33)-0.382***(3.25)-0.078**(2.68)-0.350***(3.52)-0.171***(3.53)-0.267**(3.01)EmployedReference CategorySelf-employedHousewifeOther employment statusUnemployedSubsistence IncomeRelative Income0.126(*)(1.77)0.332***(5.18)0.429***(8.27)-0.504***(3.21)0.061(0.51)0.052***(5.07)0.114(*)(1.82)0.313***(5.46)0.375***(8.64)-0.572***(4.24)-0.033(0.42)-0.043***(5.03)0.054(1.22)0.130**(2.57)-0.037(0.55)-0.778***(4.99)-0.223*(2.27)0.030**(2.88)0.064(*)(1.67)0.056(1.11)-0.053(0.83)-0.681***(6.24)-0.399***(3.79)0.029***(3.26)Income above poverty linesquared-0.001**(2.74)-0.001***(3.21)-0.001***(3.46)-0.001**(3.17)Income below poverty linesquared0.033(0.23)0.003(0.02)0.127(1.33)0.031(0.38)German-speaking cant<strong>on</strong>Reference CategoryFrench-speaking cant<strong>on</strong>Italian-speaking cant<strong>on</strong>0.105(0.95)0.325(*)(1.66)0.033(0.35)0.065(0.42)-0.040(0.25)0.434***(3.28)-0.126(0.73)0.270***(3.67)German-speaking household/German-speaking localcommunityReference Category


– 110 –Table A2: Results for Switzerland, Full Model (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Balanced PanelSHP DataUnbalancedPanelFull SampleLEU DataRepresentativeSampleFrench-speaking household/French-speaking local community-0.274**(2.62)-0.233**(2.59)-0.189(1.36)-0.112(0.63)Italian-speaking household/Italian-speaking local community-0.547**(3.12)-0.342**(2.59)-0.268**(2.93)-0.127(*)(1.90)Protestant (SHP)/dummy for paying church taxes0.101(0.92)0.074(0.81)0.047(0.85)0.086(*)(1.94)Catholic (SHP)0.072(0.65)0.059(0.65)Christ-catholic (SHP)0.117(0.81)0.078(0.64)Other Christian religi<strong>on</strong> (SHP)0.241(*)(1.93)0.206(*)(1.90)Other denominati<strong>on</strong>/ Jewish /Muslim (SHP) / dummy for notpaying church taxesReference categoryNo religi<strong>on</strong> (SHP)Dummy for the year 2000-0.000(0.00)0.218***(7.88)-0.045(0.46)0.219***(8.70)Dummy for the year 20010.114***(4.22)0.121***(4.85)Dummy for the year 2002Reference yearNumber <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> observati<strong>on</strong>s 9903 12967 6'127 5'107Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> likelihood -14'366.633 -19'335.282 -10'009.338 -8'531.3623Rho 0.533*** 0.545***Adjusted Mac Fadden's R2 0.015 0.016 0.040 0.036<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> numbers in parentheses are the absolute values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the z-values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the estimated parameters. ‘***’, ‘**’, ‘*’or ‘(*)’ show that the estimated parameter is significantly different from zero at the 0.1, 1, 5, or 10 percentlevel, respectively. C<strong>on</strong>trols for the type (and size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>) <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> commune are included but not reported. Full LEUsample has been estimated with individual weights. Both LEU samples also with robust standard errorsobtained through clustering <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>s.


– 111 –Table A.3: Descriptive <strong>St</strong>atistics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>Mean<strong>St</strong>andardDeviati<strong>on</strong>Median Minimum MaximumAll cant<strong>on</strong>s 4.168 1.182 4.420 1.750 5.750German-speaking cant<strong>on</strong>s 4.716 0.765 4.830 3.020 5.750French-speaking cant<strong>on</strong>s 2.753 0.773 2.645 1.750 3.710Italian-speaking cant<strong>on</strong> 2.250 0.000 0.250 2.250 2.250French- or Italian-speaking cant<strong>on</strong>s 2.681 0.731 2.500 1.750 3.710Table A.4: Descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Variables from the Swiss Household PanelVariable Definiti<strong>on</strong> Based <strong>on</strong> / SourceLife satisfacti<strong>on</strong> 8 categories, with the original categories 0, 1,2, and 3 p0Xc44forming the lowestBad health 1 if subjective state <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> health is not good, 0 otherwise 1 if P0Xc01 >=3Age Year <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interview - birth year <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interviewee 200X – birth yearAge 30 – 39 1 if age is between 30 and 39, 0 otherwiseAge 40 – 49 1 if age is between 40 and 49, 0 otherwiseAge 50 – 59 1 if age is between 50 and 59, 0 otherwiseAge 60 – 69 1 if age is between 60 and 69, 0 otherwiseAge 70 – 79 1 if age is between 70 and 79, 0 otherwiseAge 80 and older 1 if age is older than 80, 0 otherwiseFemale 1 if pers<strong>on</strong> is female, 0 otherwise sex = 2Foreigner1 if pers<strong>on</strong> is foreigner, 0 otherwise (single, double or nat_1_X, nat_2_X,triple citizenship)and nat_3_XMiddle educati<strong>on</strong> 1 if pers<strong>on</strong> completed sec<strong>on</strong>dary II educati<strong>on</strong>, 0otherwiseHigh educati<strong>on</strong> 1 if pers<strong>on</strong> completed a tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> (university,university <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> applied science, Higher MasterCraftsman’s Diploma)educat0X = 4, 5, 6, or8educat0X = 7, 9, 10Single woman 1 if a single is female, 0 otherwise Single = 1 & Sex = 2Single man 1 if a single is male, 0 otherwise Single = 1 & Sex = 1Single 1 if a pers<strong>on</strong> lives al<strong>on</strong>e without children, 0 otherwise hldtyp0X = 1, 2 or 3Couple with children 1 if an unmarried couple with children lives in thesame household, 0 otherwisehldtyp0X = 8, 9, 10 or11Single parent 1 if a single parent with child(ren) lives in thishousehold, 0 otherwisehldtyp0X = 4 or 5


– 112 –Table A.4: Descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Variables from the Swiss Household Panel (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Variable Definiti<strong>on</strong> Based <strong>on</strong> / SourceCollective household 1 if household is a collective household, 0 otherwise hldtyp0X = 13Self-employed1 if a pers<strong>on</strong> is self-employed or employed in owncompany, 0 otherwisep0Xw29 =3 or 4 & ┐(unemployed = 1,housewife = 1, oroccupa0X = 3, 7, 8, or10)Housewife 1 if pers<strong>on</strong> is a housewife or a houseman, 0 otherwise occupa0X = 6Other employmentstatusUnemployedIncome<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democraticrightsFrench, Italian orGerman householdlanguage1 if pers<strong>on</strong> works in the family, is an apprentice or astudent, does military service, is retired or other1 if pers<strong>on</strong> is unemployed and either <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ficiallyrecorded or not, 0 otherwiseM<strong>on</strong>thly net income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the household, deflated to thereference year 1993 with the GDP deflator, dividedby the equivalence scale <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Swiss C<strong>on</strong>ference forPublic Assistance.Index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the year <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interviewInterview language <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> household questi<strong>on</strong>naire1 if (self-employed =0 & housewife = 0 &unemployed = 0 &employed = 0)occupa0X = 9i0Xeqsn /12*inflati<strong>on</strong>indexOwn calculati<strong>on</strong>s,based <strong>on</strong> STUTZER(1999)hlingu0X (1 = French,2 = German, 3 =Italian)Protestant 1 if pers<strong>on</strong> is a housewife or a houseman, 0 otherwise p0Xr01= 1Catholic 1 if pers<strong>on</strong> is a Catholic, 0 otherwise p0Xr01= 2Christian Catholic 1 if pers<strong>on</strong> is a Protestant, 0 otherwise p0Xr01= 3Other Christiandenominati<strong>on</strong>1 if pers<strong>on</strong> is a Christian Catholic, 0 otherwise p0Xr01= 4No denominati<strong>on</strong> 1 if pers<strong>on</strong> has no <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ficial denominati<strong>on</strong>, 0 otherwise p0Xr01= 8X stands for the year in which the pers<strong>on</strong> or household was interviewed (X = 0, 1, or 2, i.e. 2000, 2001 or2002), p for pers<strong>on</strong>al and h for household questi<strong>on</strong>naire. Detailed informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the nomenclature used inthe SHP surveys can be found at www.swisspanel.ch/shpdata/var_nom.php?lang=en&pid=25 (18.02.2005).


– 113 –Chapter IV:Income Redistributi<strong>on</strong>


– 114 –1 Introducti<strong>on</strong> 127<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is an intensive dispute in ec<strong>on</strong>omics about the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between income distributi<strong>on</strong>and ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth (see BÉNABOU 1996 for a survey and BARRO 2000 for a differentiatedanalysis). Several authors particularly argue that an unequal income distributi<strong>on</strong> induces themedian voter to demand higher income taxes that adversely affect labor supply, privateinvestment, risk-taking and hence ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth (ALESINA and RODRIK 1992, 1994,PERSSON and TABELLINI 1994, PEROTTI 1993, 1996, SAINT-PAUL and VERDIER 1996,ALESINA and PEROTTI 1996, LEE and ROEMER 1998). According to theoretical arguments andempirical results (POMMEREHNE 1978, STEUNENBERG 1992, GERBER 1996, 1999), publicpolicies are more in line with median voter preferences in direct than in representativedemocracies. As BESLEY and COATE (1997) show, candidates elected in a representativedemocracy have sufficient leeway to follow their individual goals <strong>on</strong>ce they are in <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fice. Thisin turn opens possibilities for specific influences by interest groups and bureaucracies(BESLEY and COATE 1998, 2003). Referenda and initiatives provide instruments to selectivelyc<strong>on</strong>trol representative and bind policy outcomes to citizens' preferences (FELD andKIRCHGÄSSNER 2001, BESLEY and COATE 2001). It could thus be expected that incomedistributi<strong>on</strong> and redistributi<strong>on</strong> in direct democracies differ from those in representativedemocracies.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> most recent literature dealing with impacts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> fiscal policies has,however, mainly focused <strong>on</strong> expenditure, revenue and debt, which are substantially loweredby referenda or initiatives. This holds for the U.S. states and local jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s for whichMATSUSAKA (2004) and KIEWIET and SZAKALY (1996) provide the most c<strong>on</strong>vincing evidenceas well as for Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s and local jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s for which comparable evidence isprovided by FELD and KIRCHGÄSSNER (1999, 2001, 2001a) and by FELD and MATSUSAKA(2003). With respect to the structure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public spending, SCHALTEGGER (2001) and VATTERand FREITAG (2002) find that mainly cant<strong>on</strong>al and local welfare and cant<strong>on</strong>al administrativespending are reduced by fiscal referenda. FELD and MATSUSAKA (2000) report that cant<strong>on</strong>swith str<strong>on</strong>ger direct democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> fiscal issues relatively more str<strong>on</strong>gly rely <strong>on</strong>user charges than <strong>on</strong> broad-based taxes to finance spending.127 This chapter is based <strong>on</strong> the joint paper "<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Income Redistributi<strong>on</strong>: Evidencefor Switzerland" by L.P. FELD, G. KIRCHGÄSSNER, and myself. This paper was presented at variousc<strong>on</strong>ferences, e.g. the the American Public Choice <strong>Society</strong> C<strong>on</strong>ference (11 – 14/03/2004), European PublicChoice C<strong>on</strong>ference (15 – 18/04/2004), and the Annual C<strong>on</strong>ference <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the German Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Associati<strong>on</strong>(28/09 – 1/10/2004).


– 115 –<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> latter results are explained by the argument that direct democracy enforces the benefitprinciple <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxati<strong>on</strong> according to which public services provided by the government and taxprices charged to citizens should be equivalent. If spending c<strong>on</strong>trol by the voter is str<strong>on</strong>g, usercharges can be more easily justified than broad-based taxes that also affect n<strong>on</strong>-users <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> aparticular public good. Hence, in cant<strong>on</strong>s with str<strong>on</strong>g direct democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s, whichrely less <strong>on</strong> taxes but more <strong>on</strong> fees and user charges as a source <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> revenue, less redistributi<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income should occur. Similarly, welfare spending does not necessarily follow from thebenefit principle: because its main purpose is to use tax revenue received from progressiveincome taxati<strong>on</strong> to provide transfer income to the poor such that those paying for welfare d<strong>on</strong>ot receive a direct benefit from their payments.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se studies imply that direct democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s reduce income redistributi<strong>on</strong> throughthe public sector because less public funds are available and allocated for redistributi<strong>on</strong>purposes. However, reducing the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these funds used does not necessarily lead to adecrease in distributive gaps between the affluent and the needy if redistributi<strong>on</strong> programs arebetter targeted in direct than in representative democratic systems. It may well be thattransfers undertaken in representative democratic systems are much more determined by therent-seeking activities <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest groups than by the normative goal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> providing financial aidto the poor. In direct democratic systems, the str<strong>on</strong>ger c<strong>on</strong>trol <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> representatives may simplyreduce the transfers provided to special interests and lead to a more effective and moretargeted income redistributi<strong>on</strong> from the rich to the poor.In this chapter, a first attempt is made to study the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> incomeredistributi<strong>on</strong>, using data <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s. In a first step, the findings c<strong>on</strong>cerning theimpact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> broad-based taxes and welfare spending are established <strong>on</strong> thebasis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an extended data set. In a sec<strong>on</strong>d step, we estimate a model to explain the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>direct democracy <strong>on</strong> income redistributi<strong>on</strong> using panel data from the Swiss Federal TaxOffice. We start with a brief review <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> political ec<strong>on</strong>omy models <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income redistributi<strong>on</strong> insecti<strong>on</strong> 2 where we critically assess the simple benefit principle argument from above. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>empirical studies <strong>on</strong> instituti<strong>on</strong>al determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income redistributi<strong>on</strong> are summarized insecti<strong>on</strong> 3. In secti<strong>on</strong> 4, the Swiss instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy are introduced. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> impact<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> welfare and taxati<strong>on</strong> is ec<strong>on</strong>ometrically analyzed in secti<strong>on</strong> 5. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>estimati<strong>on</strong> results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> income redistributi<strong>on</strong> are presented insecti<strong>on</strong> 6. C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s follow in secti<strong>on</strong> 7.


– 116 –2 Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy Models <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Income Redistributi<strong>on</strong>What affects income distributi<strong>on</strong> is a l<strong>on</strong>g lasting c<strong>on</strong>troversy in ec<strong>on</strong>omics. Following thetheory <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> factor rewards (CHAMPERNOWNE and COWELL 1998), factor supplies and demandsdrive the compensati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> labor and capital (abstracting from land) such that each factor ispaid its marginal productivity while the exact share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> each factor depends <strong>on</strong> the elasticity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>substituti<strong>on</strong> between factors. How the factor distributi<strong>on</strong> translates into the pers<strong>on</strong>al incomedistributi<strong>on</strong> is a matter <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> how much each pers<strong>on</strong> owns <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the different producti<strong>on</strong> factors and<strong>on</strong> the ability to increase their marginal productivities, e.g., by educati<strong>on</strong>. Hence, propertyrights and the initial endowment with property play an important role. In additi<strong>on</strong>, KEYNES(1936) emphasizes the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> macroec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s for income distributi<strong>on</strong>s, i.e. therole <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> unemployment, inflati<strong>on</strong>, business expectati<strong>on</strong>s, fiscal or m<strong>on</strong>etary policies.<strong>St</strong>arting from the distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> primary pers<strong>on</strong>al income, income redistributi<strong>on</strong> is undertakeneither voluntarily by more affluent individuals or coercively by the state (see KIRCHGÄSSNERand POMMEREHNE 1992, BOADWAY and KEEN 2000 and HARMS and ZINK 2003 for surveys<strong>on</strong> income redistributi<strong>on</strong> in democracies). Aside voluntary income redistributi<strong>on</strong>, the modelsdescribing the determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> coercive income redistributi<strong>on</strong> in a democracy have incomm<strong>on</strong> that they mainly built up<strong>on</strong> the median voter theorem. According to ROMER (1975),ROBERTS (1977) and MELTZER and RICHARD (1981), income redistributi<strong>on</strong> through taxes andtransfers is the higher the more skewed the income distributi<strong>on</strong>. Skewness <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the incomedistributi<strong>on</strong> could be measured by the ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> mean to median income which provides a goodintuiti<strong>on</strong> for the political mechanism underlying redistributi<strong>on</strong>: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> higher the mean ascompared to median income the more the median income taxpayer (supposed to be equivalentto the median voter) can gain from taxing the rich. 128 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> directi<strong>on</strong> in which income isredistributed is, however, not determined. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> median voter might form a coaliti<strong>on</strong> with thepoor in order to exploit the rich (DOWNS 1957) or a coaliti<strong>on</strong> with the rich in order to exploitthe poor (POMMEREHNE 1974) such that income redistributi<strong>on</strong> occurs toward the medianincome positi<strong>on</strong> (STIGLER 1970, TULLOCK 1971). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> rich might, however, also form acoaliti<strong>on</strong> with the poor against the middle income class which has the advantage for the rich<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> acquiring votes in the cheapest possible fashi<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor have an incentive to join this128 Skewness <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the income distributi<strong>on</strong> is however not syn<strong>on</strong>ymous to income inequality. See LEE and ROEMER(1998) and BOADWAY and KEEN (2000). For example, two near symmetric income distributi<strong>on</strong>s having thesame mean but different variances may have the same skewness (close to zero). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> less dispersed incomedistributi<strong>on</strong> could easily be more equal than the other.


– 117 –coaliti<strong>on</strong> because they can expect higher transfers than in a coaliti<strong>on</strong> with the middle incomeclass. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> prec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong> for that coaliti<strong>on</strong> to emerge is that the poor realize that they gainrelative to a coaliti<strong>on</strong> with the middle class. Given the possibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these different coaliti<strong>on</strong>s,no clear-cut predicti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> voting outcomes over income redistributi<strong>on</strong> can be made(BOADWAY and KEEN 2000).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se arguments presume a voter turnout <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 100% which is highly unrealistic. If individualswere rati<strong>on</strong>al, they would realize that their individual vote decisively influences votingoutcomes <strong>on</strong>ly with a very small probability such that costs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> voting usually exceed itsexpected benefits for each individual. It is the ‘Paradox <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Not Voting’ that voter turnout isregularly high, in some countries even above 70%. If some people do not show up at the polls,it is the median pers<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> those who actually do vote who determines the amount <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> incomeredistributi<strong>on</strong>. Because high income people have a higher voter turnout than the poor, themedian <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the actual voting populati<strong>on</strong> is richer than that <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the whole populati<strong>on</strong> (FREY 1971;LEE and ROEMER 1998). However, lower voter turnout does not fundamentally alter thecycling argument outlined above.Moreover, this argument is not satisfactory because it abstracts from the obvious lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>explanatory power <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the rati<strong>on</strong>al voter hypothesis in the predicti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> voter turnout.BRENNAN and LOMASKY (1993) explain voting behavior by expressive motives. Like peoplecheer at a football match they go to the polling booth to express their opini<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> a politicalquesti<strong>on</strong> or <strong>on</strong> candidates. As income redistributi<strong>on</strong> is c<strong>on</strong>cerned, this might either lead topro-poor voting outcomes when voters express their fairness c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s, or to pro-richvoting outcomes when voters express their prejudice that being poor is a matter <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> laziness orvoluntary choice. KIRCHGÄSSNER (1992, 1996; see also KLIEMT 1986) explains votingbehavior by a theory <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> low cost decisi<strong>on</strong>s. In that case, the individual decisi<strong>on</strong> is more or lessirrelevant for the <strong>on</strong>e who makes that decisi<strong>on</strong>, while the collective decisi<strong>on</strong> has c<strong>on</strong>siderablec<strong>on</strong>sequences. With respect to income distributi<strong>on</strong>, the theory <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> low cost decisi<strong>on</strong>s impliesthat voting for redistributi<strong>on</strong> is cheap as the single vote has no influence <strong>on</strong> his own wealthpositi<strong>on</strong> while giving direct payments to the poor is costly. Rati<strong>on</strong>al individuals may thus wellvote for redistributi<strong>on</strong> rather than give direct payments (KIRCHGÄSSNER and POMMEREHNE1992).


– 118 –<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se arguments do not provide any str<strong>on</strong>g predicti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> the extent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income redistributi<strong>on</strong>in direct democracies. A general reluctance to redistribute excessively and enter voting cyclesmay stem from two sources. First, citizens in direct democracies are repeatedly involved inincome redistributi<strong>on</strong> exercises. This repeated interacti<strong>on</strong> may lead to co-operative behavioras EPPLE and RIORDAN (1987) and ARTALE and GRÜNER (2000) show. Citizens may simplyrealize over time that voting cycles <strong>on</strong> income redistributi<strong>on</strong> lead nowhere such that ac<strong>on</strong>sensus emerges am<strong>on</strong>g them according to which <strong>on</strong>ly a moderate redistributi<strong>on</strong> takesplace. This c<strong>on</strong>sensus may be sustained by credible threats to punish those groups in societythat deviate from such an implicit ‘understanding’ (EPPLE and RIORDAN 1987, p. 43, HARMSand ZINK, 2003, p. 657). Sec<strong>on</strong>d, tax base effects may restrict excessive incomeredistributi<strong>on</strong>. As already MELTZER and RICHARD (1981) argue, an egalitarian incomedistributi<strong>on</strong> does not result from tax-transfer-systems decided by the median voter becauselabor supply incentives are c<strong>on</strong>sidered. It is not possible to redistribute income throughmarginal income tax rates close to (or sometimes even above) 100% without, abolishing workincentives. Tax base effects become even more important in open ec<strong>on</strong>omies when the richcan migrate to jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s with lower redistributi<strong>on</strong> and the poor to those with higher incomeredistributi<strong>on</strong> (for labor see EPPLE and ROMER 1991, for capital PERSSON and TABELLINI1992). 129 Tax base effects hence provide for the credibility <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> threats in repeated interacti<strong>on</strong>s<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> citizens in direct democracies such that a moderate income redistributi<strong>on</strong> can be a stablepolitical outcome.Since most countries in the world are not c<strong>on</strong>stituted as direct democracies, the politicalec<strong>on</strong>omy analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income redistributi<strong>on</strong> in representative democracies is more relevant. Ina citizen candidate model, BESLEY and COATE (1997) analyze electoral competiti<strong>on</strong> in arepresentative democracy. Divisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> labor favors the selecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a candidate with highabilities in politics. That candidate whose platform attracts a sufficient number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> votes winsthe race and is able to implement his preferred policy. Although there is an attachment tocitizens' preferences through the selecti<strong>on</strong> process, candidates have sufficient room formaneuver to follow their own interests between electi<strong>on</strong>s. Aside any pers<strong>on</strong>al motives <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fice holders, which might in the extreme involve corrupti<strong>on</strong>, the interests may first stemfrom ideological dispositi<strong>on</strong>s (DIXIT and LONDREGAN 1998, ROEMER 1998) such that leftwing parties impose higher marginal tax rates in progressive income tax schedules than right129 FELD (1997) argues that tax competiti<strong>on</strong> is lower in direct than in representative democratic jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>sbecause the legitimacy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income redistributi<strong>on</strong> is higher in direct democracies. It might be that citizens,therefore, have a str<strong>on</strong>ger attachment to their community, cant<strong>on</strong>, or country.


– 119 –wing parties. If additi<strong>on</strong>al ideological goals are c<strong>on</strong>sidered like, e.g., religi<strong>on</strong>, politicians may,however, refrain from too high marginal tax rates (ROEMER 1998). Sec<strong>on</strong>d, representativesmay follow the interests <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their c<strong>on</strong>stituencies. As WEINGAST, SHEPSLE and JOHNSEN (1981)argue, representatives stem from specific districts and want to obtain benefits that aregeographically c<strong>on</strong>centrated in their district by spreading the costs over the whole populati<strong>on</strong>.Logrolling am<strong>on</strong>g representatives in parliaments ensures that pork barrel politics remainsstable and income redistributi<strong>on</strong> occurs from the districts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the loosing coaliti<strong>on</strong> to those <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the winning coaliti<strong>on</strong>.Third, representatives can be captured by special interest groups that engage in rent seekingactivities. 130 That interest groups are important actors in social policy and incomeredistributi<strong>on</strong> policies has l<strong>on</strong>g been recognized. 131 BESLEY and COATE (1998) more recentlyshow that interest group influence is <strong>on</strong>e source <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> inefficiency in their citizen candidatemodel. Rent seeking as such involves redistributing from those groups in society that are notsuccessfully lobbying the government to those that are successful. One set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> groups obtainsbenefits at the expense <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> another set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> groups. In additi<strong>on</strong>, inefficiencies might occur due torent dissipati<strong>on</strong>. Finally, representatives might follow the interests <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the bureaucracy andredistribute income in their favor (BESLEY and COATE 2003). 132Given that these sources may lead to a potential deviati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> policy outcomes from citizenpreferences, the questi<strong>on</strong> arises whether these deviati<strong>on</strong>s in income redistributi<strong>on</strong> are differentin different c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al envir<strong>on</strong>ments. PERSSON and TABELLINI (2000) argue thatmajoritarian electi<strong>on</strong>s entail more targeted spending (local public c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>) due to porkbarrel politics, less n<strong>on</strong>-targeted spending (broad social spending like unemploymentinsurance) and a larger size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> government (higher taxes) than proporti<strong>on</strong>al electi<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reas<strong>on</strong> is not necessarily that proporti<strong>on</strong>al electi<strong>on</strong>s more str<strong>on</strong>gly reflect the differentpreferences <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> citizens in a society, but that majoritarian electi<strong>on</strong>s involve stiffer competiti<strong>on</strong>for the individual districts. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se results are exacerbated if combined with different politicalregimes. PERSSON and TABELLINI (2000) analyze policy outcomes in presidential and130 Surveys <strong>on</strong> rent seeking by interest groups are provided by TOLLISON (1982, 1996), BROOKS and HEIJDRA(1989), NITZAN (1994), EKELUND and TOLLISON (2001), MCCHESNEY (2001) and MUELLER (2003).131 An early, not well known discussi<strong>on</strong> al<strong>on</strong>g these lines was provided by LIEFMANN-KEIL (1961, p. 101).132 Because the differences in income redistributi<strong>on</strong> between direct and representative democracies is our maininterest, we do not review other sources <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> influence that shape the political ec<strong>on</strong>omy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> incomeredistributi<strong>on</strong> like e.g. social status or capital market imperfecti<strong>on</strong>s. See HARMS and ZINK (2003). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> reas<strong>on</strong>is that we c<strong>on</strong>jecture that the quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their impact <strong>on</strong> income redistributi<strong>on</strong> is not determined by the type <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democratic systems.


– 120 –parliamentary systems and find that presidential systems reinforce the income redistributi<strong>on</strong>targeted to certain districts. A measure against too much redistributi<strong>on</strong> in that sense is asystem <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> checks and balances that prevents centers <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> power from colluding.Instead <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> (or in additi<strong>on</strong> to) enforcing citizens' preferences for income redistributi<strong>on</strong> byelectoral competiti<strong>on</strong> and checks and balances, instruments <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy appear toprovide a valuable alternative. According to these theoretical arguments, but also to empiricalresults (POMMEREHNE 1978, GERBER 1996, 1999), public policies are expected to followmedian voter preferences more in direct than in representative democracies. Referenda andinitiatives provide instruments to selectively c<strong>on</strong>trol representative and bind policy outcomesto citizens' preferences (FELD and KIRCHGÄSSNER 2001). Given the argument that moderateincome redistributi<strong>on</strong> occurs in direct democracies due to tax base effects, and the argumentsfor additi<strong>on</strong>al sources <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> demand for income redistributi<strong>on</strong> in representative democracies, it isexpected that income redistributi<strong>on</strong> is less pr<strong>on</strong>ounced in direct democracies. BESLEY andCOATE (2001) argue that particularly popular initiatives enable citizens to unbundle legislativepackages that combine different issues in log-rolling exercises. Referenda are an additi<strong>on</strong>alpossibility to veto policies that are too far away from citizens' preferences. All in all, thismight well result in direct democracies following the benefit principle <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxati<strong>on</strong> morestr<strong>on</strong>gly than representative democracies. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> benefit principle is, however, not the normativerule that guides decisi<strong>on</strong>s in direct democracy, but the outcome <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> complex political ec<strong>on</strong>omymechanisms.3 Empirical <strong>St</strong>udies <strong>on</strong> Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Income Redistributi<strong>on</strong>From these political ec<strong>on</strong>omy c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s the clear predicti<strong>on</strong> results that politicalinstituti<strong>on</strong>s can matter for income redistributi<strong>on</strong>. Not many empirical studies have, however,been c<strong>on</strong>ducted <strong>on</strong> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> instituti<strong>on</strong>al determinants <strong>on</strong> income redistributi<strong>on</strong> 133 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reare even not that many which analyze the influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> political ec<strong>on</strong>omy mechanisms <strong>on</strong>redistributive outcomes. Most empirical studies focus <strong>on</strong> spending (structure) or revenue(structure), but <strong>on</strong>ly a minority <strong>on</strong> final income distributi<strong>on</strong> measures. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> early studies havebeen c<strong>on</strong>ducted by sociologists and political scientists while ec<strong>on</strong>omists <strong>on</strong>ly recently enteredthe scene. HEWITT (1977) seems to have been the first to include a measure for the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>133 An overview <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the empirical literature <strong>on</strong> political democracy and redistributi<strong>on</strong> with focus <strong>on</strong> franchiseexpansi<strong>on</strong> from an ec<strong>on</strong>omist's perspective can be found in GRADSTEIN and MILANOVIC (2004).


– 121 –democracy as an explanatory variable in his set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> determinants in order to analyze the impact<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> redistributi<strong>on</strong>. He defines democracy by three purely legalisticcharacteristics such as the electi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the executive, universal suffrage, and, finally, thesecrecy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ballot. For a cross-secti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 25 countries in 1965, he finds that democraticexperience had a negative, but insignificant impact <strong>on</strong> redistributi<strong>on</strong>. For the top 5% and thetop 20% income earners, however, the negative impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy <strong>on</strong> their share in totalincome was both str<strong>on</strong>g and significant at least at the 10% level. Thus, the author detects anegative relati<strong>on</strong> between the length <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democratic experience and income inequality; hence,more democratic structures are associated with more income redistributi<strong>on</strong>.In a panel data set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 4 waves between 1960 and 1975 <strong>on</strong> 48 countries across the world,PAMPEL and WILLIAMSON (1985) use a measure for the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy as an explanatoryvariable in order to analyze the extent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pensi<strong>on</strong> expenditures relative to GDP. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>irdemocracy variable reflects political competitiveness and political liberties as originallydeveloped by BOLLEN (1980). Dividing the sample into different groups according to theirlevel <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy, the authors show that for nati<strong>on</strong>s with at least a middle level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>democracy further ec<strong>on</strong>omic development does not have a significant impact <strong>on</strong> pensi<strong>on</strong>spending, but the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> elderly pers<strong>on</strong>s becomes decisive. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y also found that in stateswith a low level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy senior people do not exert political power <strong>on</strong> pensi<strong>on</strong>payments, regardless <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic development. Obviously, the influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>senior residents grows substantially in democracy indicating an increasing political powerchanneled through political instituti<strong>on</strong>s.PAMPEL and WILLIAMSON (1988) almost repeat the previous analysis with an enlarged set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>pooled data (1950 – 1980, <strong>on</strong>e wave every 5th year <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 18 advanced industrial nati<strong>on</strong>s) and anextended set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> explanatory variables which includes also the relative number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> votes as wellas electoral competiti<strong>on</strong>. In c<strong>on</strong>gruence with the interest-groups-politics approach, thesevariables are supposed to measure the political influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the populati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the politicalprocess (voting participati<strong>on</strong>) and the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest groups <strong>on</strong> policy outcomes (the morepolitical competiti<strong>on</strong>, the str<strong>on</strong>ger their influence). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y find that both vote per populati<strong>on</strong>and electoral competiti<strong>on</strong> have a significant positive and robust influence <strong>on</strong> social welfarespending. Interestingly, the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ideology is weak and not robust in this model. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> state structure (e.g. federalism) does not change the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the politicalvariables. Admitting interacti<strong>on</strong>s between percentage aged and voting participati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>on</strong> the


– 122 –<strong>on</strong>e hand, and electoral competiti<strong>on</strong> , <strong>on</strong> the other hand, reveals a significant positive impact<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> both interacti<strong>on</strong> terms which identifies these instituti<strong>on</strong>s as their channels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> influence(while the coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the political instituti<strong>on</strong>s themselves remain insignificant). This mayindicate that the positive effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy measured in their first paper captures theinfluence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the lobbying power <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> senior citizens, which appears to go far bey<strong>on</strong>d their sociodemographicinfluence.Differentiating the dependent variable social welfare in different comp<strong>on</strong>ents, PAMPEL andWILLIAMSON (1988) find am<strong>on</strong>g the political determinants a significant positive effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>voting participati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> social insurance and family allowances, but an insignificant <strong>on</strong>e <strong>on</strong>public assistance. Electoral competiti<strong>on</strong>, the measure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the power <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> lobbies, proves to bepositive and significant <strong>on</strong>ly for social insurance and family allowance. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> reas<strong>on</strong> could bethat social insurance is a c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> based system; hence, people have to be entitled byfinancial c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s whereas public assistance is given <strong>on</strong> the basis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> means-tested needs.In the public assistance regressi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly uni<strong>on</strong>s and unemployment rate have a positive andsignificant coefficient. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the senior populati<strong>on</strong> is observed to exert a positive andsignificant impact <strong>on</strong> social insurance expenses and family allowances, but an insignificant<strong>on</strong>e <strong>on</strong> public assistance. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> authors interpret their results as supporting the interest-grouppoliticstheory based <strong>on</strong> the str<strong>on</strong>g interacti<strong>on</strong> terms between the instituti<strong>on</strong>al variables andthe percentage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> elder residents. Hence, it can be c<strong>on</strong>cluded that democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s helpchanneling the demands <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> particular interest groups.Using data for 21 countries covering an extremely l<strong>on</strong>g time span from 1880 to 1930 in 10-year-distances, LINDERT (1994) investigates the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy, female suffrage, voterturnout and the frequency <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> executive turnover <strong>on</strong> total social transfers and its comp<strong>on</strong>ents,welfare and unemployment, pensi<strong>on</strong>s and health expenditure. He finds a significant positiveinfluence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female suffrage as well as <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> executive turnover <strong>on</strong> total social transfers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>latter is significant and positive for all subcategories <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> social expenditure. Voter participati<strong>on</strong>is positive and highly significant for total social transfers, and particularly for pensi<strong>on</strong>s andhealth payments, but not decisive for welfare and unemployment transfers. According to theauthor, the positive influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> voter participati<strong>on</strong> can be explained either by the legalextensi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> suffrage also to lower income groups, which favor redistributi<strong>on</strong>, or by the actualintegrati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> social groups favoring progressive taxati<strong>on</strong> and transfer payments into the


– 123 –political process. In general, demographic influences (age structure and religi<strong>on</strong>) are str<strong>on</strong>gerdeterminants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> redistributi<strong>on</strong> than political variables.LOTT and KENNY (1999) use panel data <strong>on</strong> 48 American states from 1870 until 1940. As'democratic' variables they c<strong>on</strong>sider the existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a literacy test, a secret ballot, the poll tax(a tax <strong>on</strong> each adult in the community), female suffrage, the additi<strong>on</strong>al turnout due to femalesuffrage and, finally, the additi<strong>on</strong>al turnout due to the poll tax. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> authors believe (a) that theadopti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> secret ballot prevented illiterate people from voting; and also (b) that the poll taxhad a disenfranchising effect <strong>on</strong> blacks and poor whites in the United <strong>St</strong>ates as its paymentwas a perquisite for voting. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> literacy test, however, aimed mainly at preventingimmigrants with poor language skills from voting. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> authors show that giving women theright to vote obviously increased voter turnout, which in turn exerted a positive effect <strong>on</strong>expenditure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> social services. Furthermore, the literacy test had an insignificant coefficient.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> additi<strong>on</strong>al turnout reducti<strong>on</strong> due to the poll tax as well as the secret ballot, <strong>on</strong> the otherhand, exerted significant and negative effects <strong>on</strong> social expenditure. This shows that theseinstituti<strong>on</strong>s do, indeed, prevent lower income groups, or, in general, groups favoringredistributi<strong>on</strong>, from voting. With respect to total expenditures <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the government (includingeducati<strong>on</strong>, social services, highways) the signs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the 'democratic' variables remain the same,although the significance levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coefficients alter. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a poll tax has anegative, significant impact <strong>on</strong> total expenditure, but an insignificant influence <strong>on</strong> socialservices, thus weakly corroborating the hypothesis c<strong>on</strong>cerning its effect. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> important result<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this paper might be that democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s can be realized in such a way that particularsocietal groups are disenfranchised, which does significantly affect redistributive spending.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> most recent c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s in the field <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omics have been undertaken by macroec<strong>on</strong>omistsinvestigating the determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth in the so-called fiscal policyapproach.Using a cross secti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> about 50 democratic and n<strong>on</strong>-democratic countries,PEROTTI (1996) employs a 2SLS approach to simultaneously estimate (a) an ec<strong>on</strong>omic model,which describes the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscal policy <strong>on</strong> growth, and (b) a political model, whichcomprises democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s and income equality as instruments for the fiscal policyvariables. In his political model, he employs alternatively as regressands various tax-relatedand social transfer variables; these are the average pers<strong>on</strong>al income tax, the marginal tax rate,expenditures for social security and welfare and, finally, expenditure for health and housing.His main result is that the interacti<strong>on</strong> term between the democracy variable and the measure


– 124 –<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> (in)equality proved to be significant for social security expenditures showing that anincrease in inequality has a significant and positive effect in democracies <strong>on</strong> welfarespending: He also finds a significantly positive effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> inequality in democracies <strong>on</strong> themarginal income tax rate, but a negative <strong>on</strong>e <strong>on</strong> the average income tax rate, although bothnot significant. With respect to the remaining regressands (e.g. health and housingexpenditure, expenditure for educati<strong>on</strong>), the interacti<strong>on</strong> term appears to be insignificant aswell. Income equality solely exerts a dampening, but insignificant effect <strong>on</strong> publicexpenditure or tax rates. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> populati<strong>on</strong> above 65 proves to have a positive andsignificant influence <strong>on</strong> marginal tax rates, the average tax <strong>on</strong> labor as well as spending forhousing and health. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se results show that particularly in democratic states higher levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inequality lead to more public assistance, which is not the case for n<strong>on</strong>-democracies and othertypes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> redistributive expenditures.PERSSON and TABELLINI (1994) estimate the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the median voter <strong>on</strong> redistributi<strong>on</strong>,predicting a negative relati<strong>on</strong>ship between transfers and the middle quintile, their measure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>income equality. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y find a dampening impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the middle income share <strong>on</strong> redistributi<strong>on</strong>,some ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> redistributive spending to GDP, in a cross secti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> around 1960 (13countries) 134 . BASSET et al. (1999) re-estimate their model and do not find the previous resultto be robust to differences in definiti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> equality, sample size and the inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the share<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> senior residents. Using the average ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> transfers to GDP over the period 1970-1985,however, BASSET et al. (1999) were able to mildly corroborate a negative relati<strong>on</strong> fordemocracies, using a specificati<strong>on</strong> similar to the <strong>on</strong>e in PEROTTI (1996) and by including aninstituti<strong>on</strong>al interacti<strong>on</strong> term. Both the instituti<strong>on</strong>al interacti<strong>on</strong> term with a negative sign andthe coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy with a positive <strong>on</strong>e appear to be significant, whereas the equalitymeasure is never. Again, the result obtained by PEROTTI (1996) is <strong>on</strong>ly mildly corroborated, asit is not robust to different measures <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income equality: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> by itself appears to befavoring redistributi<strong>on</strong>, but in case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> low income inequality less redistributi<strong>on</strong> occurs, whenalso the actual income distributi<strong>on</strong> is included in the regressi<strong>on</strong>.More recently, GRADSTEIN et. al. (2001) have empirically shown how ideology and politicaldemocracy interplay and how political instituti<strong>on</strong>s impact inequality: Political democracyappears to affect income inequality negatively in Judeo-Christian societies if inequality ishigh because the needy outvote the affluent. If, however, there is no need for redistributi<strong>on</strong>,134 Significance was observed by BASSETT et al. (1999) after having corrected a small mistake in the data.


– 125 –democracy does not appear to have a significant distributi<strong>on</strong>al effect. This is the case in n<strong>on</strong>-Judeo-Christian societies which value income equality highly. No influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy <strong>on</strong>income distributi<strong>on</strong> might also be observed because these societies rely <strong>on</strong> informal transfersto a large extent.To sum up, according to these findings, democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s appear to serve as channels fortransporting the interest <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> specific socio-demographic groups bey<strong>on</strong>d their purelydemographic influence. Furthermore, the design <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> instituti<strong>on</strong>s matters for the inclusi<strong>on</strong> orexclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> specific societal groups and thus influences redistributi<strong>on</strong>. In additi<strong>on</strong>, themacroec<strong>on</strong>omic literature suggests that the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> inequality by itself as a comp<strong>on</strong>ent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the preferences <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the median voter cannot be predicted, whereas the negative interacti<strong>on</strong>between democracy and equality seems to be quite robust. N<strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these papers has, however,addressed the differential impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> democratic regimes <strong>on</strong> income redistributi<strong>on</strong>. For a panel<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> OECD countries since the 1960’s, MILESI-FERRETI, PEROTTI and ROSTAGNO (2002) studywhether countries with majoritarian electi<strong>on</strong>s have different levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> transfer payments thancountries with proporti<strong>on</strong>al electi<strong>on</strong>s and find that transfer payments are str<strong>on</strong>gly positivelyrelated to the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> proporti<strong>on</strong>ality. For a panel <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 60 countries from 1960 to 1998,PERSSON and TABELLINI (1999, 2003) support these findings and also report evidence thatwelfare spending is lower in presidential systems. Most interesting, GRADSTEIN et. al. (2001)also showed that parliamentary systems exhibit a higher degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income redistributi<strong>on</strong> thanpurely presidential regimes. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se results support the hypothesis that the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interestgroups and bureaucracies <strong>on</strong> broad based income redistributi<strong>on</strong> is less restricted inpresidential systems.4 Swiss Data <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Income Distributi<strong>on</strong>Our study <strong>on</strong> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> income redistributi<strong>on</strong> adds to this politicalec<strong>on</strong>omics literature. Before proceeding to the empirical study, it is necessary to brieflyintroduce the Swiss political system. Switzerland is an ideal laboratory to study the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>direct democracy <strong>on</strong> policy outcomes. Aside its pr<strong>on</strong>ounced structure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscal federalism,Switzerland is known for its c<strong>on</strong>siderable variati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy. Mostcant<strong>on</strong>s have some form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> semi-direct democracy with a parliamentary system withlegislators elected according to a system <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> proporti<strong>on</strong>al party representati<strong>on</strong>. Only two ruralcant<strong>on</strong>s (Appenzell Innerrhoden and Glarus) take political decisi<strong>on</strong>s in cant<strong>on</strong>al meetings


– 126 –(Landsgemeinde). On the other hand, the cant<strong>on</strong>s are shaped by different instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>political participati<strong>on</strong> rights (TRECHSEL and SERDÜLT 1999; FELD and MATSUSAKA 2003).Proposals can be initiated via the voter initiative, and new laws passed by the legislature are,to different degrees, subject to an opti<strong>on</strong>al or even a mandatory popular referendum. Fiscalreferenda <strong>on</strong> policy decisi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> sub-nati<strong>on</strong>al governments have been <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> particular interest inthe literature. In our empirical analysis, we use an overall index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy asproposed by FREY and STUTZER (2000). Because it c<strong>on</strong>sists <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> many different instruments <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>direct democracy 135 , we refer the reader to that source. In order to c<strong>on</strong>trast the index with <strong>on</strong>e<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its comp<strong>on</strong>ents, we have a closer look at the data for the fiscal referendum and the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the year 1992. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> relevant informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the fiscal referendum is provided in table 1.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re exists no fiscal referendum at the federal level, but with the excepti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Waadt (VD) 136 all cant<strong>on</strong>s know at least some kind <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a fiscal referendum. 13 cant<strong>on</strong>s have amandatory as well as an opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum. In seven other cant<strong>on</strong>s (BE, BS, BL, AG,TI, VS, GE) <strong>on</strong>ly the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum exists , whereas in SZ, GL, ZG, AR, NE newspending projects have to pass the mandatory, but not an opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>fiscal referendum can be differentiated according to five categories: the fiscal referendum forpublic spending, public-sector b<strong>on</strong>ds, taxes, holdings <strong>on</strong> enterprises, and purchases <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> realestate. In principle, there are threshold variati<strong>on</strong>s for n<strong>on</strong>-recurring expenditures and forrecurring expenditures. Five cant<strong>on</strong>s (FR, AR, VS, NE, JU) determine thresholds as apercentage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> last budget’s expenditures. All others determine a specific amount instead. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> signatures required to qualify for ballots and the time span within which thesignatures have to be collected for the opti<strong>on</strong>al fiscal referendum are also very diverse am<strong>on</strong>gcant<strong>on</strong>s. This number varies from 0.49% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> all voters in the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Obwalden (OW) up to4.28% in the cant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Jura (JU), while the time span for collecting the signatures rangesfrom 30 to 90 days.Comparing the existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> different forms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscal referenda and their spending thresholdswith the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy (see table 1), it becomes clear that there is a certaincorresp<strong>on</strong>dence. On the other hand, it becomes obvious that the index c<strong>on</strong>tains additi<strong>on</strong>alinformati<strong>on</strong> based <strong>on</strong> the signature requirements for the two initiatives and the (opti<strong>on</strong>al) sta-135 It is c<strong>on</strong>structed as an unweighted average <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the indexes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the legislative initiative, the legislativereferendum, the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative, and the fiscal referendum.136 Also laws and decrees which trigger public spending are subject to an opti<strong>on</strong>al legislative referendum in thecant<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Waadt, in which, however, this instituti<strong>on</strong> never seemed to have been applied to such cases.


– 127 –Table 1: Fiscal Referenda and <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> in Swiss Cant<strong>on</strong>sCant<strong>on</strong>N<strong>on</strong>-recurring expenditures a Recurring expenditures a Frey-<strong>St</strong>utzer Index bOpti<strong>on</strong>al Mandatory Opti<strong>on</strong>al Mandatory (1992)ZH 2-20 20 0.2-2 2 4.17BE 2 0.4 3.50LU 3-25 25 specific stipulati<strong>on</strong>s 4.48UR 0.5 1 0.05 0.1 5.42SZ 0.25 0.05 4.93OW 0.5 1 0.1 0.2 5.58NW 0.25 5 0.05 0.5 4.92GL 0.5 0.1 5.50ZG 0.5 0.05 4.42FR 0.25 % 1 % 0.25 % 1 % 2.42SO 1-2 2 0.1-0.2 0.2 5.42BS 1 0.2 4.40BL 0.5 0.05 5.69SH 0.3-1 0.3 0.05-0.1 0.05 5.08AR 5% 1% 5.50AI 0.25 0.5 0.05 0.1 5.25SG 3-15 15 0.3-1.5 1.5 3.40GR 1-5 5 0.3-0.5 0.5 4.75AG 3 0.3 5.46TG 1 3 0.2 0.6 4.04TI 0.2 0.05 2.10VD 2.42VS 0.75% 0.25% 3.42NE 1.5% 1.5% 2.13GE 0.125 0.06 1.75JU 0.5 % 5% 0.05% 0.5% 3.71Source: G. LUTZ and D. STROHMANN (1998); B.S. FREY and A. STUTZER (2000).abIn milli<strong>on</strong> Swiss Francs if not indicated otherwise.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> index is c<strong>on</strong>structed by the signature requirement as the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> signatures relative to thenumber <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> voters, by the days within which the signatures have to be collected and by the financialthreshold as the per capita spending limit allowing for referendum (the values corresp<strong>on</strong>d to the year1992).tutory referendum. What is also striking are the differences between French- and Italianspeakingcant<strong>on</strong>s and German-speaking cant<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> average index value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Germanspeakingcant<strong>on</strong>s is with 4.9 c<strong>on</strong>siderable higher than that <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> French- and Italian-speakingcant<strong>on</strong>s with 2.6. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se cultural differences must hence be c<strong>on</strong>sidered carefully in theempirical analysis.


– 128 –5 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Welfare and Taxati<strong>on</strong>In order to test the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> income redistributi<strong>on</strong>, we follow a two stepstrategy. First, we analyze public expenditure and revenue as well as tax revenue and welfarespending as the two most important instruments for income redistributi<strong>on</strong> at the Swisscant<strong>on</strong>al level as a functi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the direct democracy index and c<strong>on</strong>trols. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, we analyzeincome distributi<strong>on</strong> as measured by Gini coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the (approximated) pre- and post-taxpers<strong>on</strong>al income distributi<strong>on</strong> as well as the difference between both distributi<strong>on</strong>s. We thuspropose the following basic model:ID it = β 0 + β 1 DIRDEM it + β 2 V it + u it (1)where ID it stands for the different dependent variables that are <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest in our study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>income redistributi<strong>on</strong>. More precisely, in this secti<strong>on</strong> we take a closer look at the log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> realper capita spending and revenue at the cant<strong>on</strong>al and local levels as well as tax revenue andwelfare and in the next secti<strong>on</strong> at Gini coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the pre- and post-tax incomedistributi<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> model implies that ID it is a functi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy, as measured by the Frey-<strong>St</strong>utzerindex (DIRDEM it ) and a vector <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>trol variables V it . β 0 to β 2 are the parameters <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interestwhile u it denotes the error term. According to previous empirical work by FELD andKIRCHGÄSSNER (1999, 2001, 2001a), FELD and MATSUSAKA (2003, 2000), SCHALTEGGER(2001) and VATTER and FREITAG (2002), we expect a negative impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong>public spending, revenue, tax revenue and welfare spending. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy<strong>on</strong> the after-tax income distributi<strong>on</strong> and redistributi<strong>on</strong> is, however, ambiguous. It may well bethat less funds are available for income redistributi<strong>on</strong>, but that transfers are better targeted tothe needs. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> expected sign <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the direct democracy index <strong>on</strong> the Gini coefficients is henceindeterminate.V it c<strong>on</strong>sists <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> variables capturing the structure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscal federalism such as fiscaldecentralizati<strong>on</strong> measured by the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> local in total subfederal (i.e. cant<strong>on</strong>al and local)spending (revenue, tax revenue), tax competiti<strong>on</strong> measured by the inverse <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the average <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> allother cant<strong>on</strong>s income tax rates in the highest income tax bracket, weighted by the inverse <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>geographical distance between cant<strong>on</strong>al capitals, and unc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al grants which address theimpact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> vertical transfer payments from the federal government to cant<strong>on</strong>al governments.


– 129 –<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> more fiscally decentralized a cant<strong>on</strong> the less leeway exists for income redistributi<strong>on</strong>because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> migrati<strong>on</strong> incentives. Similarly, the intensity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax competiti<strong>on</strong> restricts incomeredistributi<strong>on</strong> at the cant<strong>on</strong>al level. Finally, unc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al grants help to finance additi<strong>on</strong>alspending and relax cant<strong>on</strong>al budget c<strong>on</strong>straints.Moreover, the log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> nati<strong>on</strong>al income disaggregated to the cant<strong>on</strong>al level is includedaccording to the interpretati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> WAGNER'S Law (1892) <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a possible income effect <strong>on</strong> thedemand for public goods, but also the for income redistributi<strong>on</strong> as an insurance against risk.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> urban populati<strong>on</strong> in a cant<strong>on</strong> reflects the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> populati<strong>on</strong> density <strong>on</strong> fiscalpolicy decisi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> governments. In agglomerati<strong>on</strong>s, a c<strong>on</strong>centrati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor people <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>tenoccurs such that additi<strong>on</strong>al income redistributi<strong>on</strong> has to be undertaken. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> populati<strong>on</strong>takes into account ec<strong>on</strong>omies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> scale: Can larger cant<strong>on</strong>s benefit from ec<strong>on</strong>omies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> scale inorder to reach a lower level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public (welfare) expenditures when achieving an identical level<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> supply <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public goods. A negative impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this variable indicates that the larger thepopulati<strong>on</strong> the lower the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the dependent fiscal variables. In additi<strong>on</strong>, a variableincorporating fiscal c<strong>on</strong>straints at the cant<strong>on</strong>al level is included. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y can be seen as asupplementary instrument to limit the taxing power <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> policymakers and hence their ability toredistribute income (SCHALTEGGER, 2002). We also include a coaliti<strong>on</strong> variable in order toempirically evaluate the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> broad based coaliti<strong>on</strong> governments <strong>on</strong> the exploitati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thebudget as a fiscal comm<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> argument that the tax base represents a fiscal comm<strong>on</strong>s thatis exploited by too many spending ministers in the sense <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pork barrel politics is developedby ROUBINI and SACHS (1989), DE HAAN and STURM (1997), KONTOPOULOS and PEROTTI(1999), or VOLKERINK and DE HAAN (2001). Moreover, the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> leftist parties in thegovernment is c<strong>on</strong>sidered in order to c<strong>on</strong>trol for the ideological dispositi<strong>on</strong> to redistributeincome. In line with the literature, we expect this variable to have a positive impact <strong>on</strong> (theinstruments <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>) income redistributi<strong>on</strong>. Finally, the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the young and the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thesenior populati<strong>on</strong> in total populati<strong>on</strong> are c<strong>on</strong>trolled for in order to reveal the influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thetwo groups which (supposedly) most str<strong>on</strong>gly benefit from income redistributi<strong>on</strong> measures bythe state. We finally include the cant<strong>on</strong>al unemployment rate indicating the macroec<strong>on</strong>omicc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s and a French and Italian language dummy as c<strong>on</strong>trols.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> analysis uses annual data from 1980 to 1998 deflated to the year 1980. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> subscript i =1, ..., 26 indicates cant<strong>on</strong>s and t = 1980, ..., 1998 indexes years. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> empirical analysis isperformed using a pooled cross-secti<strong>on</strong> time-series model. We follow FELD and KIRCHGÄSS-


– 130 –Table 2: Expenditure, Revenue, Taxes, and Welfare Expenditure per Capita,1980 – 1998, 494 Observati<strong>on</strong>sPublicExpenditurePublic RevenueTax RevenueWelfareExpenditureC<strong>on</strong>stant 0.621(0.66)0.772(0.97)1.688**(2.79)8.218***(5.81)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy-0.040*(2.25)-0.043**(2.61)-0.045**(3.17)-0.148***(4.73)Fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong>-0.570***(3.91)-0.596***(4.33)-0.060(1.00)0.141(0.82)Tax competiti<strong>on</strong>-0.175*(2.50)-0.177**(4.32)-0.204***(6.74)-0.119(1.17)Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> unc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al grants0.110*(2.27)0.145**(3.19)-0.047(1.42)-0.033(0.51)Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> nati<strong>on</strong>al income0.135(0.99)0.110(0.89)0.322***(3.85)0.224(1.23)Urbanizati<strong>on</strong>0.141(1.33)0.110(*)(1.71)0.460***(7.26)0.391*(2.47)Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> populati<strong>on</strong>-0.001(0.03)-0.001(0.04)-0.044**(2.62)-0.088*(2.28)Fiscal c<strong>on</strong>straints-0.001(0.11)0.004(0.32)0.020**(2.62)-0.034(1.25)Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> parties in thecant<strong>on</strong>al government0.024(1.03)0.022(1.06)-0.003(0.24)0.042(1.59)Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> leftist parties in thegovernment0.019(1.44)0.013(1.22)-0.037**(3.34)-0.010(0.47)Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> youngpopulati<strong>on</strong>-0.005(0.56)-0.011(1.35)-0.029***(5.32)-0.044**(3.20)Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> oldpopulati<strong>on</strong>0.015(*)(1.65)0.010(1.29)-0.006(1.15)0.031*(2.23)Dummy for French andItalian language-0.108(1.44)-0.134*(1.96)-0.031(0.82)-0.155(1.58)Unemployment rate 0.007(0.43)0.003(0.22)-0.000(0.01)-0.003(0.11)2R 0.734 0.744 0.918 0.866SER 0.118 0.108 0.076 0.177J.-B. 7.484* 33.206*** 2.802 1.376<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> numbers in parentheses are the absolute values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the estimated t-statistics, based <strong>on</strong> the Newey-Westautocorrelati<strong>on</strong>-c<strong>on</strong>sistent standard errors. ‘***’, ‘**’, ‘*’ or ‘(*)’ show that the estimated parameter issignificantly different from zero at the 0.1, 1, 5, or 10% level, respectively. SER is the standard error <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theregressi<strong>on</strong>, and J.-B. the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Jarque-Bera test for normality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the residuals.


– 131 –NER (2001), who argue that despite the panel structure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the data the inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fixedeffects in the cross-secti<strong>on</strong> domain is inappropriate because the instituti<strong>on</strong>al variablesreflecting the extent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy vary <strong>on</strong>ly very little or remain c<strong>on</strong>stant over time inmost cant<strong>on</strong>s. Accordingly, cant<strong>on</strong>al intercepts do not make sense as the captured impact <strong>on</strong>fiscal outcomes is either solely driven by the time variati<strong>on</strong> or in case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> time invariantvariables, fixed effects are likely to hide the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> instituti<strong>on</strong>al variables and render theminsignificant. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>sistency <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> OLS-estimates depends <strong>on</strong> the exogeneity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theregressands. In order to tackle the problem <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> possible endogeneity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the decentralizati<strong>on</strong>variable, we use an instrumental variable technique with cant<strong>on</strong>al fixed effects as instrumentswhich are supposed to capture systematic differences in cant<strong>on</strong>al policy-making. 137 Finally,year effects to circumvent time dependency are included in the main regressi<strong>on</strong> and theautocorrelati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sistent standard errors according to the Newey-West method arecalculated.Table 2 c<strong>on</strong>tains the estimati<strong>on</strong> results for the fiscal policy variables. In all equati<strong>on</strong>s, directdemocracy has the expected negative sign and is significant at least at the 5% significancelevel. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> coefficient in the public revenue equati<strong>on</strong> is a little bit greater than the <strong>on</strong>e in thepublic expenditure equati<strong>on</strong>, and the <strong>on</strong>e in the tax revenue equati<strong>on</strong> is <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> similar magnitude.But because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the log-form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the dependent variable no direct c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> with respect to thesize <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy can be drawn. However, direct democracy reduceswelfare spending much more significantly than the other fiscal policy variables. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se resultscorroborate the earlier findings in the literature and are fully in line with the arguments above.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> government obtains less funds in a direct democracy for redistributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>trols exhibit the expected influences in most cases, but also show interesting patterns<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> results. Fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> is associated with significantly less spending and revenue,but does not significantly affect tax revenue and welfare spending. Tax competiti<strong>on</strong> leads to asignificantly smaller public sector in spending, revenue, and also tax revenue terms while itdoes not significantly affect welfare spending. Unc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al grants from the federal levelsignificantly relax the cant<strong>on</strong>al budget c<strong>on</strong>straints in general, but neither significantly affecttax revenue nor welfare spending. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> unemployment rate and the dummy for French andItalian-speaking cant<strong>on</strong>s are largely insignificant. As expected, urbanizati<strong>on</strong> has asignificantly positive impact <strong>on</strong> public revenue, tax revenue as well as welfare expenditure,137 We used the same instruments in all equati<strong>on</strong>s. This also holds for the estimates in table 3.


– 132 –but we do not find a significant impact <strong>on</strong> total expenditure. Nati<strong>on</strong>al income <strong>on</strong>ly has asignificant positive impact <strong>on</strong> tax revenue. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> higher income in a cant<strong>on</strong> the higher is taxrevenue, an unsurprising result with progressive income tax schedules. Interestingly, fiscalc<strong>on</strong>straints do not play a significant role in restricting general expenditure or revenue, or evenwelfare spending. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y, however, appear to trigger higher tax revenue which means that taxcuts are less easily possible in cant<strong>on</strong>s with fiscal restraints. Of the political variables, thenumber <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> parties in the government does not have any significant effect <strong>on</strong> fiscal policy,while the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> leftist parties in government is unexpectedly associated with significantlyless redistributi<strong>on</strong> in terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxes. Ec<strong>on</strong>omies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> scale do not appear to exist in the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>spending and revenue in general because the populati<strong>on</strong> variable is not significant. Morepopulous cant<strong>on</strong>s do have less tax revenue and welfare spending. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> young peopleis associated with significantly lower tax revenue and lower welfare payments while the share<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> senior residents has a significantly positive impact <strong>on</strong> welfare and total public expenditure.Generally speaking, the model explains the variati<strong>on</strong> in fiscal policy quite well. More than73% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the variance is explained. In the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the expenditure and revenue equati<strong>on</strong>, theJarque-Bera test statistic indicates that the null hypothesis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> normality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the residuals can berejected. Analyzing the outliers and eliminating them from the sample does, however, notqualitatively alter the results 138 .6 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> the Redistributi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> IncomeAs c<strong>on</strong>tended above, lower levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax revenue and welfare spending do not necessarilyimply that less income redistributi<strong>on</strong> is achieved in direct democracy. If direct democracy hasa more efficient government, these instruments may be more effectively targeted to the needysuch that less funds are necessary to achieve a specific level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income redistributi<strong>on</strong>. Wetherefore turn to the analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the income distributi<strong>on</strong> as measured by Gini coefficients.Data <strong>on</strong> income distributi<strong>on</strong> are not generally available for Switzerland. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is <strong>on</strong>e microdata set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1992 (LEU et al., 1997) which could <strong>on</strong>ly be used as a single cross secti<strong>on</strong> 139 .Because the focus <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> our interest is <strong>on</strong> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> several cant<strong>on</strong>al variables <strong>on</strong> income138 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> results are presented in table A.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendix.139 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Swiss Household Panel (SHP) provides informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> gross and net household income from 1999 –2003, but does not distinguish federal and sub-federal tax payments.


– 133 –redistributi<strong>on</strong>, the cross secti<strong>on</strong> data are not enormously helpful however. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y leave us with<strong>on</strong>ly 26 observati<strong>on</strong>s with respect to the direct democracy variable even if individual dataprovide the basis. For our analysis we, therefore, use panel data <strong>on</strong> the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxpayinghouseholds and their incomes in different income classes for the period 1980 – 1997 from theSwiss Federal Tax Office. FLÜCKIGER and ZARIN-NEJADAN (1994) use quite similar data fortheir analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> macroec<strong>on</strong>omic policy <strong>on</strong> the income distributi<strong>on</strong> inSwitzerland. Since Swiss tax collecti<strong>on</strong> until recently has taken place <strong>on</strong> a biennial basis, thedata set is a two years panel. Tax liability for periods t and t + 1 (taxati<strong>on</strong> period) have beencalculated <strong>on</strong> the basis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the average income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> periods t – 1 and t – 2 (calculati<strong>on</strong> period),while the payment was made over the periods t + 1 and t + 2 (payment period). Both pre-taxand post-tax distributi<strong>on</strong>s can <strong>on</strong>ly be approximated because the FTA data do not cover thetrue gross or taxable income, but are limited to the 'adjusted gross income'("Reineinkommen") 140 and the actual tax payments. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, we view the 'Reineinkommen'as proxy for gross income and calculate a hypothetical net income by deducing the taxpayment. Whether a pers<strong>on</strong> is entitled to financial support and how big the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the actualtransfer is exhibits significant variati<strong>on</strong> between cant<strong>on</strong>s. Some <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these social transfersalready directly affect the gross income and the adjusted gross income, some impact <strong>on</strong>ly theafter-tax income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the needy households 141 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> estimati<strong>on</strong> method and the basic model to beestimated is the <strong>on</strong>e described in secti<strong>on</strong> 5. However, because income distributi<strong>on</strong> might havean impact <strong>on</strong> voting behavior and, therefore, also <strong>on</strong> the compositi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the government, theideology <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the government is instrumented with the identical set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> variables described inpreviously.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> estimati<strong>on</strong> results are presented in table 3. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first column c<strong>on</strong>tains the results for theapproximated pre-tax Gini coefficient (in percentage points) as a functi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the modeldescribed above. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy index has a negative impact <strong>on</strong> the pre-tax Ginicoefficient which is highly significant at the 0.1% level. In cant<strong>on</strong>s with more directdemocracy income distributi<strong>on</strong> before the federal government begins to redistribute incomevia taxes and further allowances is more equal 142 . Fiscal federalism does not have a c<strong>on</strong>sistentand clear-cut effect. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong>, grants and tax competiti<strong>on</strong> are140 For a more precise definiti<strong>on</strong> and descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the relati<strong>on</strong> between gross income, 'Reineinkommen' andtaxable income according to the Swiss laws <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> taxati<strong>on</strong>, see HÖHN and WALDBURGER, 2001, p. 359.141 We have to thank EMANUEL LAUBER, tax inspector <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the EstV/FTA for clarificati<strong>on</strong> (pers<strong>on</strong>alcommunicati<strong>on</strong>, 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> June 2004).142 This observed impact may be possibly caused by welfare payments at the sub-federal level which alreadyaffect the adjusted gross income <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Swiss households


– 134 –not significantly different from zero. Fiscal c<strong>on</strong>straints do not have a significant impact <strong>on</strong> thepre-tax income distributi<strong>on</strong>; the significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the estimated parameter is somewhat belowthe 10% level. 143 Of the political variables, <strong>on</strong>ly the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> leftist parties in government hasa significant impact <strong>on</strong> pre-tax Gini coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> higher the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> leftistparties in government, the more equal is the income distributi<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> coaliti<strong>on</strong>parties in government is not significantly different from zero. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> young and oldpeople from total populati<strong>on</strong> both have a significant negative impact <strong>on</strong> income distributi<strong>on</strong>meaning that they are both associated with more equal distributi<strong>on</strong>s. Cant<strong>on</strong>s with a largerpopulati<strong>on</strong> as well as French- and Italian-speaking cant<strong>on</strong>s have significantly more equalincome distributi<strong>on</strong>s while urbanizati<strong>on</strong> is associated with significantly higher incomeinequality. Nati<strong>on</strong>al income and unemployment do not have a significant effect.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> income distributi<strong>on</strong> measured by post-tax Gini coefficients shows the same qualitativepattern <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> results. With respect to our variable <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest, this means that cant<strong>on</strong>s with moredirect democracy have also more equal post-tax income distributi<strong>on</strong>s. It is hence veryinteresting to look at the difference between pre- and post-tax income distributi<strong>on</strong>s whichindicate to what extent the closing <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the gap in income distributi<strong>on</strong>s is due to the differentvariables in our model. Note that a positive (negative) sign in the difference equati<strong>on</strong> incolumns (3) and (4) means that a variable has a positive (negative) impact <strong>on</strong> the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>income redistributi<strong>on</strong>, i.e. more (less) income is redistributed. A positive (negative) impactalso implies that redistributi<strong>on</strong> is such that more (less) equalizati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income distributi<strong>on</strong> isachieved because the directi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> redistributi<strong>on</strong> is in all cant<strong>on</strong> inequality decreasing 144 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>estimati<strong>on</strong> results reveal that significantly less income redistributi<strong>on</strong> occurs in directdemocratic cant<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> coefficient is significant at the 0.1% level. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> other variables revealagain the same pattern <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> results as before with the difference that tax competiti<strong>on</strong> nowbecomes marginally significant and has a positive impact. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is significantly less incomeredistributi<strong>on</strong> in cant<strong>on</strong>s with a higher share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> leftist parties in the government, a higher share<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> old and young people, in more populous and in the French- and Italian-speaking cant<strong>on</strong>s.On the other hand, there is significantly more income redistributi<strong>on</strong> in the cant<strong>on</strong>s with moreintense tax competiti<strong>on</strong> (at the 10% level), and with a higher share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the urban populati<strong>on</strong> (atthe 5% level).143 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is, however, a marginally significant negative effect if we exclude the outliers. This would imply thatcant<strong>on</strong>s with fiscal c<strong>on</strong>straints have a more equal income distributi<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> same holds for the equati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the post-tax distributi<strong>on</strong> and <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the difference. See for these results table A.2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendix.144 For all cant<strong>on</strong>s in all years, post-tax income distributi<strong>on</strong> minus pre-tax distributi<strong>on</strong> has a negative sign.


– 135 –Table 3: Inequality and Redistributi<strong>on</strong>, 1981 – 1997, 234 Observati<strong>on</strong>s(Gini-Coefficients in Percentage Points)Pre-Tax Gini-CoefficientPost-Tax Gini-CoefficientDifferenceDifferenceC<strong>on</strong>stant 62.781***(3.91)58.843***(3.98)3.940**(2.96)-1.371**(2.82)Pre-tax Gini-Coefficient0.085***(18.20)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy-1.679***(6.04)-1.562***(6.09)-0.117***(4.97)0.025*(2.12)Fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong>2.756(1.23)2.678(1.31)0.078(0.37)-0.155*(2.21)Tax competiti<strong>on</strong>0.724(1.17)0.635(1.10)0.089(*)(1.95)0.027(1.49)Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> unc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al grants1.027(1.28)1.005(1.37)0.023(0.31)-0.064**(3.02)Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> nati<strong>on</strong>al income2.545(1.12)2.311(1.11)0.234(1.17)0.019(0.29)Urbanizati<strong>on</strong>3.359*(2.40)3.080*(2.39)0.279*(2.36)-0.005(0.11)Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> populati<strong>on</strong>-1.646***(4.57)-1.526***(4.61)-0.120***(3.87)0.020(1.36)Fiscal c<strong>on</strong>straints-0.323(1.61)-0.294(1.60)-0.029(1.60)-0.004(0.81)Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> parties in thecant<strong>on</strong>al government-0.242(0.91)-0.221(0.91)-0.021(0.90)-0.001(0.10)Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> leftist parties in thegovernment-0.634**(2.81)-0.577**(2.77)-0.057**(3.07)-0.004(0.46)Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> youngpopulati<strong>on</strong>-0.298(*)(1.80)-0.273(*)(1.79)-0.026(*)(1.82)-0.001(0.14)Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> oldpopulati<strong>on</strong>-0.506***(3.41)-0.460***(3.36)-0.046***(3.75)-0.003(0.85)Dummy for French andItalian language-3.428**(3.07)-3.180**(3.10)-0.250**(2.61)-0.029(1.32)Unemployment rate 0.100(0.42)0.103(0.47)-0.003(0.17)-0.012*(2.09)R20.673 0.672 0.672 0.958SER 1.449 1.338 0.119 0.043J.-B. 177.544*** 165.945*** 232.692*** 19.369***Comments see table 2.


– 136 –It is most interesting to finally analyze the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the different variables <strong>on</strong> incomeredistributi<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ed <strong>on</strong> the pre-tax income distributi<strong>on</strong> in the fourth column <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> table3. 145 This method allows to identify which variables affect income redistributi<strong>on</strong> when it maybe most needed to close the gap between the rich and the poor. Again, the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy is very instructive: C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>ed <strong>on</strong> the pre-tax income distributi<strong>on</strong>, cant<strong>on</strong>s withdirect democracy exhibit significantly more income redistributi<strong>on</strong> (at the 5% level). If the pretaxincome inequality is relatively high, direct democratic cant<strong>on</strong>s redistribute more income,otherwise they d<strong>on</strong>’t. Taken together, the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy is very intriguing: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reare significantly less funds available for income redistributi<strong>on</strong>, there is significantly lessincome redistributi<strong>on</strong>, but if the pre-tax income inequality is relatively high, incomeredistributi<strong>on</strong> in direct democratic cant<strong>on</strong>s is significantly higher. This supports thehypothesis that welfare payments in direct democratic cant<strong>on</strong>s are better targeted than in morerepresentative democratic cant<strong>on</strong>s: the m<strong>on</strong>ey is more effectively used in direct than inrepresentative democracies.More fiscally decentralized cant<strong>on</strong>s show a significantly lower level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income redistributi<strong>on</strong>if the pre-tax income distributi<strong>on</strong> is relatively higher, an effect that is slightly corrected by the(insignificant) impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax competiti<strong>on</strong>. Cant<strong>on</strong>s which receive higher grants do redistributeless income. Cant<strong>on</strong>s with more unemployment redistribute income significantly less. Overall,the model explains the variati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income distributi<strong>on</strong> and income redistributi<strong>on</strong>quite well. At least 67% <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the variance can be explained. According to the Jarque-Bera teststatistics, the null hypothesis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> normality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the residuals can be rejected at high significancelevels. An analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> outliers and a sensitivity check <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the estimates to outliers reveal again,however, that the results are quite robust. 1467 C<strong>on</strong>cluding RemarksDoes direct democracy lead to less redistributi<strong>on</strong>? Taking into account that – according to theresults presented in this chapter but also to other empirical results – it leads to lower welfareexpenditure per capita, <strong>on</strong>e might draw such a c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>. Such an apprehensi<strong>on</strong> is probablybehind the str<strong>on</strong>g rejecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> introducing additi<strong>on</strong>al direct popular rights in Germany by145 In additi<strong>on</strong> to the instruments menti<strong>on</strong>ed above we employ the two year lagged value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the pre-tax Ginicoefficient as an instrument for this variable.146 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> results are again presented in the Appendix. See table A.2.


– 137 –some political scientists: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y fear the end <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the welfare state. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> possible effects might belargely overestimated by such fears; despite the largely developed direct popular rights theSwiss welfare state has not yet broken down, and a cutback <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public welfare expenditureoccurred in purely representative systems like the German <strong>on</strong>e during recent years as well.Nevertheless, there might be – ceteris paribus – a negative impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong>redistributi<strong>on</strong>.That public welfare expenditure is somewhat lower might, <strong>on</strong> the other hand, not necessarilycompromise redistributi<strong>on</strong>. Because public expenditure might be better tailored to the needs<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the electorate in direct democracies, given the amount <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public welfare expenditure itsredistributive effect might be larger than in purely representative systems. Taking these twocountervailing effects into account, it is theoretically open which <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> them dominates.Our results provide an interesting picture. Looking just at the differences between the incomedistributi<strong>on</strong>s before and after taxati<strong>on</strong>, it is shown that direct democracy has a negative impact<strong>on</strong> redistributi<strong>on</strong>, as it is supposed by many <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its critics. Furthermore, taking into account thatredistributi<strong>on</strong> is needed the more the more unequal the pre-tax distributi<strong>on</strong> is, directdemocracy has a significantly positive effect <strong>on</strong> redistributi<strong>on</strong>. Moreover, analyzing its impact<strong>on</strong> the pre-tax and after-tax income distributi<strong>on</strong>s a str<strong>on</strong>g inequality equalizing effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directlegislati<strong>on</strong> could be revealed. This indicates two things: first, efficiency gains are present indirect democracies when it comes to reducing income inequality. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, the electorate is themore in favor <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> redistributi<strong>on</strong> the more they assess it as being justified by the unequalstarting c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s. Such a behavior will rather strengthen than weaken the welfare state.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> results which are presented in this chapter are, however, <strong>on</strong>ly first estimates. Furtheranalyses have to follow. One obvious shortcoming <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this study is that by using tax data thosewho do not pay taxes (and might be the poorest citizens in the society) are not included in ouranalysis. Another shortcoming <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these tax data are that they are rather based <strong>on</strong> householdthan pers<strong>on</strong>al income and do not take into account the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pers<strong>on</strong>s living in the samehousehold. Such improvements might be made by estimating a similar model using the crosssecti<strong>on</strong> data <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1992 from the study <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> LEU et al. (1997). As menti<strong>on</strong>ed above, due to the verysmall number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> observati<strong>on</strong>s and the cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al nature we then, however, face other andnot less severe problems.


– 138 –Finally, <strong>on</strong>e should take into account that here we <strong>on</strong>ly deal with the cant<strong>on</strong>al and local leveland, there, <strong>on</strong>ly with the tax side. This side is, <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> course, very important for redistributi<strong>on</strong>.Nevertheless, a large part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> redistributi<strong>on</strong> is d<strong>on</strong>e by public expenditure. 147 Moreover, theperhaps most str<strong>on</strong>gly redistributive part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Swiss welfare state is the first column <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theold age pensi<strong>on</strong> system (AHV) which is located at the federal level. It is much moreredistributive as, e.g., the corresp<strong>on</strong>ding German system. Nevertheless, not <strong>on</strong>ly itsintroducti<strong>on</strong> but also all <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its many revisi<strong>on</strong>s have finally been accepted in referenda. Thus,Switzerland with its direct democracy at all governmental levels can hardly be seen as anexample where the welfare state is endangered by the existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct popular rights.147 See for this the corresp<strong>on</strong>ding estimates in KIRCHGÄSSNER and POMMEREHNE (1996) and FELD (2000).


– 139 –8 AppendixTable A.1: Expenditure, Revenue, Taxes, and Welfare Expenditure per Capita,1980 – 1998 (Outliers excluded)Public ExpenditureC<strong>on</strong>stant 0.585(0.63)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracyFiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong>Tax competiti<strong>on</strong>Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> unc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al grantsLog <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> nati<strong>on</strong>al incomeUrbanizati<strong>on</strong>Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> populati<strong>on</strong>Fiscal c<strong>on</strong>straintsNumber <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> parties in the cant<strong>on</strong>al governmentShare <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> leftist parties in the governmentShare <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> young populati<strong>on</strong>Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> old populati<strong>on</strong>Dummy for French and Italian language-0.042*(2.19)-0.556***(3.84)-0.183**(2.67)0.113*(2.35)0.124(0.93)0.153(1.48)-0.001(0.01)-0.001(0.05)0.026(1.15)0.20(1.54)-0.005(0.15)0.015(*)(1.75)-0.107(1.44)Unemployment rate 0.005(0.34)Public Revenue0.626(0.86)-0.038*(2.44)-0.465***(4.12)-0.188**(3.13)0.163***(3.78)0.098(0.86)0.134(1.60)-0.000(0.02)0.006(0.52)0.024(1.26)0.016(*)(1.66)-0.013(*)(1.81)0.012(*)(1.83)-0.113(*)(1.79)0.004(0.36)R20.741 0.744Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> observati<strong>on</strong>s 493 484SER 0.117 0.108J.-B. 4.382 4.981(*)Comments see table 2.


– 140 –Table A.2: Inequality and Redistributi<strong>on</strong>, 1981 – 1997 (Outliers excluded)Pre-Tax Gini-CoefficientPost-Tax Gini-CoefficientDifferenceDifferenceC<strong>on</strong>stant 63.951***(4.35)59.976***(4.42)3.975**(3.33)-1.489**(3.16)Pre-tax Gini-coefficient0.085***(19.20)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy-1.647***(6.18)-1.534***(6.23)-0.113***(5.06)0.025*(2.17)Fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong>4.749*(2.43)4.419*(2.45)0.330*(2.11)-0.181**(2.75)Tax competiti<strong>on</strong>0.832(1.40)0.732(1.32)0.100*(2.34)0.024(1.29)Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> unc<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al grants0.654(0.93)0.680(1.05)-0.027(0.44)-0.56**(2.72)Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> nati<strong>on</strong>al income3.385(*)(1.77)3.039(*)(3.04)0.346*(2.23)0.013(0.21)Urbanizati<strong>on</strong>3.717**(3.06)3.383**(3.00)0.334***(3.48)-0.013(0.11)Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> populati<strong>on</strong>-1.717***(5.07)-1.588***(5.09)-0.129***(4.53)0.022(1.60)Fiscal c<strong>on</strong>straints-0.304(*)(1.71)-0.278(*)(1.71)-0.026(*)(1.78)-0.001(0.15)Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> parties in thecant<strong>on</strong>al government-0.363(1.52)-0.326(1.48)-0.037(*)(1.94)0.001(0.08)Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> leftist parties in thegovernment-0.674***(3.43)-0.608**(3.32)-0.65**(4.35)-0.008(1.09)Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> youngpopulati<strong>on</strong>-0.333*(2.07)-0.306*(2.07)-0.028*(2.01)0.001(0.16)Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> oldpopulati<strong>on</strong>-0.484***(3.74)-0.441***(3.68)-0.043***(4.24)-0.003(0.79)Dummy for French andItalian language-2.726”*(2.92)-2.556**(2.95)-0.170*(2.37)0.031(1.3204Unemployment rate 0.081(0.44)-0.063(0.37)-0.017(1.23)-0.009(*)(1.77)R20.768 0.764 0.797 0.961Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> observati<strong>on</strong>s 200 200 200 207SER 1.175 1.092 0.091 0.041J.-B. 0.428 0.742 1.589 3.194Comments see table 2.


– 141 –Chapter V:Public Safety


– 142 –1 Introducti<strong>on</strong> 148<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy is c<strong>on</strong>jectured to lead to an allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> resources that comes closer to thepreferences <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the median voter than does that in a representative democracy. In c<strong>on</strong>trast totraditi<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omic theory, however, this study assumes that the median voter is subject tobounded rati<strong>on</strong>ality. Based <strong>on</strong> these two assumpti<strong>on</strong>s particularly, it is hypothesized that thevoter (1) prefers that less m<strong>on</strong>ey be spent <strong>on</strong> crime preventi<strong>on</strong> measures and (2) favorsprotecti<strong>on</strong> against property crime over fighting violent crime. In this c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>, thesehypotheses are developed in detail and empirically tested for the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Switzerland, acountry with str<strong>on</strong>g variati<strong>on</strong> in the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy and public safety at thecant<strong>on</strong>al level.Based <strong>on</strong> an extensive review <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the literature, it appears that this investigati<strong>on</strong> is <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thefirst to combine and empirically test the median voter theorem <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public choice with thetheorem <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> bounded rati<strong>on</strong>ality developed by behavioral ec<strong>on</strong>omists and ec<strong>on</strong>omicpsychologists. It is also the first analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an ec<strong>on</strong>omic model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime for Switzerland usingan ec<strong>on</strong>ometric panel method for cant<strong>on</strong>al-level data that employs a rich set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> explanatoryvariables 149 .<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>oretical models <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> political ec<strong>on</strong>omy dem<strong>on</strong>strate that instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracylead to an allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> goods and resources that comes closer to the median voter'spreferences than the allocati<strong>on</strong> achieved in a representative democratic system. Empiricalstudies for both the U.S. and Switzerland provide evidence that the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public goodsis more efficient in direct democracies and government spending is lower. In the theoreticalmodel world <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> political ec<strong>on</strong>omy, the median voter is assumed to be a perfectly rati<strong>on</strong>alhomo ec<strong>on</strong>omicus who, <strong>on</strong> average, makes unerr<strong>on</strong>eous predicti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> event probabilities. Onthe other hand, ec<strong>on</strong>omic psychologists have found that the rati<strong>on</strong>ality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an average humanbeing is bounded: i.e., an individual’s predicted probabilities differ systematically from actual148 A preliminary versi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this paper was presented at the c<strong>on</strong>ferences <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the British <strong>Society</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Criminology,(6-9/07/2004), Portsmouth, GB, the European <strong>Society</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Criminology, (25-29/08/2004), Amsterdam,Netherlands, the European Associati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Law & Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, Zagreb, Croatia, (23-25/09/2004), and the 56 thAnnual Meeting <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the American <strong>Society</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Criminology, Nashville, (17-20/11/2004). I thank ReinerEichenberger, Sim<strong>on</strong> Gächter, Martin Jäggi, Gebhard Kirchgässner, Friedrich Schneider and c<strong>on</strong>ferenceparticipants for helpful comments and suggesti<strong>on</strong>s.149 Using Swiss data, a purely time-series analysis can be found in FUNK and KUGLER (2002, 2003), who used asexplanatory variables <strong>on</strong>ly two deterrents and either the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> unemployed (2003) or lagged crime rates(2002). A partial correlati<strong>on</strong> analysis for two cross secti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1960 and 1970 can be found in ZWICKY (1982)


– 143 –average probabilities. An optimism bias induces the underestimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the subjectiveprobability for a bad event to occur, with, according to the literature <strong>on</strong> the availabilityheuristic, the bias becoming str<strong>on</strong>ger when an event is less frequently observed than otherevents.This study combines ec<strong>on</strong>omic and psychological approaches by applying themsimultaneously to the supply <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the public good, 'public safety', defined by the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crimein a specific regi<strong>on</strong>. Depending <strong>on</strong> the type <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime, some crimes are committed more <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>tenthan others. Based <strong>on</strong> this observati<strong>on</strong> and applying the 'optimism bias' theory and'availability heuristic' <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic psychology, it is c<strong>on</strong>jectured that voters prefer thepreventi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> more frequently occurring property crime relative to less frequently occurringviolent crime. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, it is hypothesized that direct democratic systems will reallocategiven budgetary resources for police issues in favor <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the protecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> property at theexpense <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pers<strong>on</strong>al integrity. Further, since studies in ec<strong>on</strong>omic psychology have shown thatthe true average likelihood for the whole society is also systematically underestimated, it isalso c<strong>on</strong>jectured that fewer financial means will be allocated through instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directlegislati<strong>on</strong> to crime preventi<strong>on</strong> and crime protecti<strong>on</strong> measures.This study also assumes that governmental and administrative decisi<strong>on</strong> makers are better atforecasting than the comm<strong>on</strong> citizen, because empirical investigati<strong>on</strong>s by ec<strong>on</strong>omicpsychologists have detected that debiasing strategies – linked to bureaucratic procedures,c<strong>on</strong>tinuous training, statistical informati<strong>on</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>tinuous feedback – may reduce theunderestimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> true probability. Because these findings seem c<strong>on</strong>sistent with the initialhypotheses, it is further c<strong>on</strong>jectured that in more representative democracies, more resourceswill be devoted to public safety in general and, more specifically, available means allocatedbetween several crimes will reflect the actual probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their occurrence more closelythan in direct democracies.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se hypotheses are tested using a synthetic panel <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Swiss data <strong>on</strong> cant<strong>on</strong>al policeexpenditure and crime rates between 1986 and 2001. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> regressors are selected according tothe ec<strong>on</strong>omic model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime and public choice models <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> government expenditure. Inanticipati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the empirical results, support is found for the boundedly rati<strong>on</strong>al median votertheorem: First, subfederal police expenditure is observed to be dampened by the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>direct democracy, which subsequently translates also into a lower relative number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al


– 144 –policemen. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, if the model takes the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> police expenditureexplicitly into account, property crime rates are shown to be c<strong>on</strong>siderably lower in directdemocratic cant<strong>on</strong>s than in more representative democratic <strong>on</strong>es, and, the assault rate isshown to be significantly higher. Finally, executive efficiency gains are detected in stateprovisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public safety against those crimes that are <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> lower priority to the median voter.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se empirical results are interpreted as supporting this study’s hypothesis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the str<strong>on</strong>glybounded rati<strong>on</strong>ality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the median voter and bureaucratic efforts to partly compensate for itsredistributive effect <strong>on</strong> crime.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> rest <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the chapter is organized as follows. Secti<strong>on</strong> 2 reviews relevant theoretical andempirical literature – particularly that by ec<strong>on</strong>omic psychologists and behavioral ec<strong>on</strong>omists,with which a public choice ec<strong>on</strong>omist might not be too familiar – from which testablehypotheses are derived. Secti<strong>on</strong> 3 outlines the specificati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the ec<strong>on</strong>omic model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime,and secti<strong>on</strong> 4 describes the data. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> estimati<strong>on</strong> results are then presented and discussed insecti<strong>on</strong> 5. Finally, secti<strong>on</strong> 6 c<strong>on</strong>cludes the report.2 Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy and the Behavioral Ec<strong>on</strong>omic C<strong>on</strong>text: Derivati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Hypotheses2.1. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Median Voter <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>oremEc<strong>on</strong>omic theory predicts that in a direct democracy, an allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> resources is achievedthat more closely approximates median voter preferences than such allocati<strong>on</strong> in arepresentative democracy. Using a model with a <strong>on</strong>e-dimensi<strong>on</strong>al ideology space, FELD andKIRCHGÄSSNER (2001) show that instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> force politicians to shifttheir policies toward the median voter's positi<strong>on</strong> 150 . In general, the str<strong>on</strong>ger the instituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>direct legislati<strong>on</strong> (i.e. the easier it is for voters to make use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> it), the str<strong>on</strong>ger its influence <strong>on</strong>the decisi<strong>on</strong>-making process and the greater the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this shift. In other words, bureaucrats<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a Niskanen type (NISKANEN 1975, WILLIAMSON 1964) and politicians interested <strong>on</strong>ly inreelecti<strong>on</strong> are c<strong>on</strong>siderably limited in their budget maximizing or spending behavior.Accordingly, resources should be wasted less in more direct democratic systems than in morerepresentative democratic systems, and the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public good should be more efficientat the societal level. In this c<strong>on</strong>text, it must be noted that the mere existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> such a direct150 This effect is found for both the mandatory and opti<strong>on</strong>al referendum, as well as the (statutory) initiative.


– 145 –legislative instituti<strong>on</strong> itself serves as a sufficiently credible threat to influence the allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>resources.Empirical analyses <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy for the U.S. and Switzerland <strong>on</strong> theprovisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public goods provide evidence c<strong>on</strong>sistent with the median voter theorem.Investigati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a budgetary effect show a revenue and spending restraining influence (FELDand KIRCHGÄSSNER 2001, MATSUSAKA 1995), and POMMEREHNE (1983) provides empiricalevidence for Switzerland that garbage collecti<strong>on</strong> is more efficient in direct democraticmunicipalities than in more representative democratic <strong>on</strong>es. Most recent research <strong>on</strong> welfarepayments also shows them to be more efficiently targeted in direct democracies than in morerepresentative <strong>on</strong>es (FELD et al., 2004). In sum, there exists ample empirical support for themedian voter theorem (for a literature review and overview, see KIRCHGÄSSNER, 2000, 2001,2002a, KIRCHGÄSSNER et al. 1999). Based <strong>on</strong> these findings, it is quite probable that, in moredirect democracies, the allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> goods and resources for the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the public good'public safety' should also be closer to the median voter's preferences.2.2 Optimism BiasA preferred allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> goods and resources may depend not <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong> the present ec<strong>on</strong>omicsituati<strong>on</strong> but also <strong>on</strong> median voter predicti<strong>on</strong>s about the future and opini<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> what is requiredto meet pers<strong>on</strong>al needs. Hence, a mispredicti<strong>on</strong> about future developments will also affect thedemanded state producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public goods: the str<strong>on</strong>ger the influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a boundedly rati<strong>on</strong>almedian voter <strong>on</strong> the political decisi<strong>on</strong>-making process, the more biased away from a(theoretically optimal) fully rati<strong>on</strong>al median voter's positi<strong>on</strong> the actual allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> goods andresources will be. However, the typical model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the median voter assumes perfect rati<strong>on</strong>ality,which also implies perfect foresight. In this paper, in c<strong>on</strong>trast, based <strong>on</strong> recent developmentsin the fields <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> behavioral ec<strong>on</strong>omics and ec<strong>on</strong>omic psychology, this traditi<strong>on</strong>al approach willbe extended to assume <strong>on</strong>ly a partially rati<strong>on</strong>al voter.One type <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> bounded rati<strong>on</strong>ality hypothesized by behavioral ec<strong>on</strong>omists and particularlyec<strong>on</strong>omic psychologists is human judgment error, meaning that actual judgments showsystematic differences from unbiased forecasts (KAHNEMAN et al., 1982). Am<strong>on</strong>g these, therealso exists an optimism bias, which means that individuals underestimate their own


– 146 –probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> experiencing a bad event relative to the predicted risk for the average pers<strong>on</strong> 151 .In other words, the estimated ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the subjective to the societal likelihood is biaseddownwards.Empirical studies c<strong>on</strong>ducted mostly by psychologists show the validity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the optimism biashypothesis. In particular, empirical evidence supports the c<strong>on</strong>jecture that human beings wouldrather systematically underestimate their own likelihood than overestimate the averagepers<strong>on</strong>'s risk. In other words, people assume their own probability to be lower than that <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>their peers (ARNOULD and GRABOWSKI 1981, CAMERER and KUNREUTHER 1989). Such anoptimism bias is observed am<strong>on</strong>g college-age drivers for the estimated likelihood <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> beinginvolved in a car accident (DEJOY 1989) 152 , am<strong>on</strong>g college students for being sued afterhaving committed a fel<strong>on</strong>y (WEINSTEIN 1980), or am<strong>on</strong>g male drivers (aged 17 – 72 years) forbeing caught after having committed fel<strong>on</strong>y drunk driving (GUPPY 1993), and am<strong>on</strong>g smokersfor the health risk <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> smoking (HAMMAR and JOHANSSON-STENMAN 2004, PROKHOROV et al.2003). In all, over 250 empirical studies provide support for the existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the optimismbias (JOLLS 2004). Moreover, this bias can be quite substantial: test subjects' own estimatedlikelihoods are observed to be 20% to 80% lower than the predicted risk in society (JOLLS1998). Based <strong>on</strong> this empirical evidence, the likelihood <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> becoming a crime victim should besystematically underestimated by a typical human being, making it systematically lower thanthe estimated risk for the average pers<strong>on</strong>.In additi<strong>on</strong> to the mispredicti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pers<strong>on</strong>al probability, the general probability in thepopulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> experiencing a negative event is systematically misjudged. An early study byLICHTENSTEIN et al. (1978) asked test subjects to assess annual relative average frequencies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>various causes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> death in the United <strong>St</strong>ates, including diseases, accidents, and naturaldisasters. Most interesting for this present study, the relative risk for an average pers<strong>on</strong>becoming the victim <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> murder or manslaughter was underestimated despite extensivecoverage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this topic in the mass media (see secti<strong>on</strong> 2.4). However, the frequencies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> badevents that affect many people simultaneously (e.g. natural disasters) or are c<strong>on</strong>nected toaccidents evoked by (unc<strong>on</strong>trollable) technology (e.g. nuclear meltdowns) tended to besystematically overestimated. Apparently, test subjects deemed these crime related causes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>151 A possible cause for positive and negative biases can be emoti<strong>on</strong>s such as anger or fear (LERNER et al. 2003).152 See also SVENSON et al. (1985); for motorcyclists see RUTTER et al. (1998).


– 147 –death less probable than other causes (FISCHHOFF 2002) 153 . Following this argument, andassuming a high correlati<strong>on</strong> between the estimated frequencies and predicted societalprobabilities, the average pers<strong>on</strong> should also mispredict the average likelihood <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> any 'normal'property or violent crime occurring in society. C<strong>on</strong>sequently, given the misjudgment aboutboth pers<strong>on</strong>al and peer probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> becoming a crime victim, a boundedly rati<strong>on</strong>al medianvoter can be c<strong>on</strong>jectured to prefer a lower level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime preventi<strong>on</strong> measures than if thedecisi<strong>on</strong>-making process were unbiased.Finally, the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the optimism bias seems to depend <strong>on</strong> the rareness <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the event. JOLLS(2004) and FISCHHOFF (2002) argue in the traditi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the literature <strong>on</strong> the availabilityheuristic 154 that infrequent events, those not <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ten heard <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> or seen, are not easily imagined orkept in mind. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, the likelihood <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their occurrence is underestimated. As a result,there exists a causal relati<strong>on</strong> between the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> mispredicti<strong>on</strong> and the frequency <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> anevent: the less frequently an event occurs, the lower its 'availability' and the higher theunderestimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> occurrence 155 by a boundedly rati<strong>on</strong>al individual. Someempirical evidence supports this hypothesis. For example, availability heuristic helps explainthe fact that people do not insure against natural disasters and car accidents – their subjectiveestimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> likelihood is negatively affected by absence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> such experience in their own lifeor that <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their friends, neighbors, and relatives (KUNREUTHER 1976). On the other hand,people are observed to update their estimated probabilities after experiencing a negative eventeither pers<strong>on</strong>ally or in their immediate envir<strong>on</strong>ment. For example, after being arrested <strong>on</strong>ce,<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenders appear to substantially correct the subjective probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> arrest (LOCHNER2003). 156 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, the probability predicted for the types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> events that occur more <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>tenshould be closer to actuality than predicti<strong>on</strong>s for very rare events. In the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this study, theprobability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> being murdered should be underestimated to a str<strong>on</strong>ger degree than the risk <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>153 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> probabilities <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> nuclear power accidents and other envir<strong>on</strong>mental catastrophes are usually overestimated(see also VISCUSI 1992; KURAN and SUNSTEIN 1999), which might be explainable by mass media coverage(COMBS and SLOVIC 1979). Most particularly, the likelihood <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> disease is str<strong>on</strong>gly underestimated, a littleless than the likelihood <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> accidents.154 See TVERSKY and KAHNEMAN (1973).155 In particular, the accuracy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> subjective estimates depends <strong>on</strong> whether "(1) the exposures are proporti<strong>on</strong>al toactual frequencies; (2) the events are equally memorable; and (3) [the] people have reliable mentaltechniques for c<strong>on</strong>verting the availability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> instances into summary estimates" (FISCHHOFF 2002). Accordingto SCHWARZ and VAUGHN (2002), people usually do not investigate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ficial statistics before answering aquesti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the likelihood <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an event but rather rely <strong>on</strong> their own memory.156 However, this same study finds no impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the experience <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> random individuals or their local surroundings,friends included, which c<strong>on</strong>tradicts the previous empirical finding <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> KUNREUTHER (1976).


– 148 –being burglarized. Hence, the relative subjective probabilities for different crimes would bebiased in favor <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the more frequent crime 157 .2.3 Debiasing <strong>St</strong>rategiesBiases, such as mispredicti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> event probabilities, can be mitigated through debiasingstrategies such as the influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the social envir<strong>on</strong>ment, available factual informati<strong>on</strong>, andbureaucratic decisi<strong>on</strong> making. For example, the use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> protocols that prescribe a step-by-stepprocedure for experts can help alleviate these experts’ judgment bias (MERKHOFER 1987,MORGAN and HENRION 1990, MORGAN and KEITH 1995) as can specific instructi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> howto assess particular informati<strong>on</strong> (that might otherwise give rise to a bias or not lead todebiasing by itself) (CLARKSON et al. 2002). Peer reviews are also suitable for mitigatingjudgment errors: people tend to be more critical <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> other pers<strong>on</strong>’s statements than <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their ownestimates (TAYLOR and BROWN 1988). Most particularly, according to psychological evidence,<strong>on</strong>e potential remedy is to make more objective informati<strong>on</strong> available to test subjects(DASGUPTA and GREENWALD 2001) or provide training in research methods and statistics(LEHMAN et al. 1988). Other debiasing techniques are abundant practice and/or training, taskrestructuring, and feedback <strong>on</strong> performance (FISCHHOFF 1982). Such feedback may bethought <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> as the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> appropriate statistical informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> frequencies <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> rare events:individuals might then use this informati<strong>on</strong> to objectively evaluate their own estimate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>probability 158 . In this specific case, such objective statistical informati<strong>on</strong> might address crimerates, clear-up rates, and c<strong>on</strong>victi<strong>on</strong> rates that could debias criminologists, policeadministrators, and politicians specializing in this issue. According to the empirical evidence,<strong>on</strong>ce given specialized training, daily practice, and bureaucratic procedures for assessing suchinformati<strong>on</strong>, these experts will probably be less subject to an optimism bias and/or availabilityheuristic than the average pers<strong>on</strong>.157 A similar c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> can be drawn from applicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a variati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the availability hypothesis: According tothis theory, <strong>on</strong>ly those probabilities are underestimated that do not exceed a particular critical level (JOLLS,2004). An alternative explanati<strong>on</strong> is given by prospect theory: a certainty effect can lead to an increase in thedifference between the perceived probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an infrequent and very frequent event. This theory leavesopen whether <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the probabilities is underestimated or the other overestimated; what is important is thatthe gap in subjective likelihoods <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> occurrence is greater than the actual gap (KAHNEMAN and TVERSKY1983).158 Experiments do indeed show that overc<strong>on</strong>fidence is decreased if the framing for an assessment is generatedby a random process and is thus not based <strong>on</strong> the subject's own prior beliefs, i.e. when the subject’s ownnaiveté creates the framing for the next evaluati<strong>on</strong> (WINMAN et al. 2004).


– 149 –2.4 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Role <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Mass Media 159It is <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ten argued that the biased reporting <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> particularly severe and spectacular crimes in themass media influences how people assess both the pers<strong>on</strong>al and societal risk <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> becoming avictim (SLOVIC 1986, JOHNSON and COVELLO 1987). Based <strong>on</strong> this argument, we wouldexpect an increase in the availability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> such crimes (KALICHMAN 1994), which might (partly)<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fset the low-frequency effect (see secti<strong>on</strong> 2.2). An assessment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the empiricalpsychological literature <strong>on</strong> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> mass media <strong>on</strong> risk percepti<strong>on</strong>, however, gives arather mixed picture.First, at least in some studies <strong>on</strong> mass media c<strong>on</strong>tent, the reporting was shown to be lessbiased than usually c<strong>on</strong>jectured (e.g., FREUDENBERG, et al. 1996). 160 Sec<strong>on</strong>d, it is likely thatthe correlati<strong>on</strong> between media c<strong>on</strong>tent and risk percepti<strong>on</strong> found in earlier studies 161 wassubject to a reversed causality 162 . Furthermore, even if media coverage increases availability<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> events 163 , this effect might be rather short-term, but studies <strong>on</strong> the durati<strong>on</strong> aspect are stillmissing. In general, influences can <strong>on</strong>ly be permanent if an event is recalled <strong>on</strong> a regularbasis. 164 Third, as already menti<strong>on</strong>ed in secti<strong>on</strong> 2.2, the two main important sources <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>informati<strong>on</strong> for forming an opini<strong>on</strong> are <strong>on</strong>e’s pers<strong>on</strong>al experience and that <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> relatives andfriends (TYLER 1984), whereas third-hand informati<strong>on</strong>, such as media c<strong>on</strong>tent, is suppressedby higher-order informati<strong>on</strong> (WIEGMAN and GUTTELING 1995) 165 . Finally, media coveragetends to influence the percepti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> societal risk more than individual risk, with individualrisk remaining significantly underestimated (TYLER and COOK 1984, COLEMAN 1993) 166 . Thisfinding is in line with the impers<strong>on</strong>al impact hypothesis (TYLER 1980).159 This secti<strong>on</strong> is draws up<strong>on</strong> a survey written by WÅHLBERG and SJÖBERG (2000).160 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> study by COMBS and SLOVIC (1979) is traditi<strong>on</strong>ally cited as evidence for a mass media bias in reporting.161 Particularly studies that are based <strong>on</strong> cultivati<strong>on</strong> theory propose a link between the amount <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> mediac<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> and assessment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> risks. However, more recent studies showed no link (Hirsch 1980).162 More recent research reveals that pers<strong>on</strong>s with higher apprehensi<strong>on</strong> tend to select more frequently programswith a crime-related c<strong>on</strong>tent (WAKSHLAG et al. 1983). For more potential explanati<strong>on</strong>s, see WÅHLBERG andSJÖBERG (2000).163 MILBURN and MCGRAIL (1992) showed that news can be recalled more easily when it c<strong>on</strong>tained somedramatic parts. But both positive and negative coverage can lead to more c<strong>on</strong>cern and thus to higher riskpercepti<strong>on</strong> (MORGAN et al. 1985).164 See the references cited in WÅHLBERG and SJÖBERG (2000). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is also a related literature <strong>on</strong> the relati<strong>on</strong>between media coverage and fear <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime. It is, however, questi<strong>on</strong>able how much fear <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime andestimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> probabilities <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its occurrence are correlated.165 For the marginality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> mass media <strong>on</strong> people's opini<strong>on</strong>, see e.g. VALLONE et al. (1985).166 Some correlati<strong>on</strong> between the two probabilities, however, pertains (SJÖBERG et al. 1996).


– 150 –Overall, the available literature <strong>on</strong> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> mass media <strong>on</strong> people's percepti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> risksuggests that this field <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> research is still under development. Empirical findings areinc<strong>on</strong>sistent and c<strong>on</strong>tradicting. For this reas<strong>on</strong>, no final c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> can be made with respectto the development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> my hypotheses and will furthermore be neglected.Based <strong>on</strong> all <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the above, the following hypotheses can be formulated:Hypothesis 1:Instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy induce an allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> scarce means for crimepreventi<strong>on</strong> which is in accordance with median voter preferences to a higher degree thanin political systems without such instituti<strong>on</strong>s.Hypothesis 2:Assuming the median voter to be <strong>on</strong> average boundedly rati<strong>on</strong>al, she or hesystematically underestimates the probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pers<strong>on</strong>ally becoming a victim <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> acrime. Further, the median voter systematically mispredicts the risk <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a less frequentcrime to a higher degree than the risk <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a more frequent crime.Hypothesis 3:<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> median voter also systematically underestimates the average probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theoccurrence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>e crime in society.Hypothesis 4:Because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the bureaucratic manner <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> informati<strong>on</strong> gathering, processing, and decisi<strong>on</strong>making, trained administrators and experienced politicians tend to suffer less fromoptimism bias and availability heuristic than the electorate.2.4 Derivati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Empirically Testable Hypotheses<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> hypotheses developed above are not directly empirically testable using data <strong>on</strong> crimerates, police expenditure, and political instituti<strong>on</strong>s. However, combining the fundamentalHypothesis 1 with the remaining three leads to the following testable hypotheses:


– 151 –Testable Hypothesis 1:<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> financial means available for the preventi<strong>on</strong> and detecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime is c<strong>on</strong>siderablylower in more direct democracies than in more representative democracies.(Combinati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> hypotheses 1, and 3 or 2)Testable Hypothesis 2:In systems with str<strong>on</strong>g direct democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s, the median voter, because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> his orher bounded rati<strong>on</strong>ality, induces a reallocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> given means towards those crimes thatseem (subjectively) to occur more frequently than other crimes. Debiasing <strong>on</strong> the part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>trained bureaucrats or experienced politicians, however, mitigates this effect in morerepresentative democratic systems.(Combinati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> hypotheses 1, 2, and 4)Available for the empirical testing <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these hypotheses are Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>al data <strong>on</strong> crimesagainst pers<strong>on</strong>, sexual integrity, and property between 1986 and 2001. Table 1 gives anoverview <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their occurrences in Switzerland.Table 1: Summary <strong>St</strong>atistics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Cant<strong>on</strong>al Crime Rates, 1986 – 2001Crime Obs. Mean <strong>St</strong>d. Dev. Min MaxHomicide 416 2.016582 1.918033 0 13.55932Rape 416 4.377733 3.602149 0 26.00049Pickpocketing 416 16.58696 20.19978 0 111.4252Robbery 416 18.32574 20.73591 0 121.2102Other sex 416 33.00213 23.91515 0 139.8345crimesDefalcati<strong>on</strong> 416 33.16078 47.2319 0 734.2105Assault 416 52.52116 36.77527 2.164346 232.4125Fraud 416 111.9786 143.2382 0 2296.57Burglary 416 784.0628 458.3655 80.68312 2577.983Auto theft 416 1214.325 591.9845 54.63459 3243.841A mean crime rate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 100 in a populati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 100,000 equals a probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 0.1% that <strong>on</strong>eparticular individual in this society will be victimized. Setting an (admittedly arbitrary)threshold at this level and defining crimes with probabilities above this level as frequentproduces the following observati<strong>on</strong>s. According to this threshold, most violent and hate


– 152 –crimes, such as killing, assault, rape, and other sex crimes, have a low average frequency.However, pickpocketing does not appear to occur as <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ten as usually presumed, which mightbe caused by a low reporting rate. In additi<strong>on</strong>, the crime rates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> robbery and defalcati<strong>on</strong> arequite low, at a probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 0.018% and 0.033%, respectively.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> most frequent crimes reported are auto theft, with an objective probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1.214%, andburglary, with 0.78%. Fraud also exhibits a 0.11% likelihood <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> occurrence, but with a largestandard deviati<strong>on</strong> that reflects a str<strong>on</strong>g variati<strong>on</strong> over time and/or between cant<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> becoming a victim <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a property crime (e.g. burglary) is 15 times higher thanthe likelihood <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> being assaulted, and the risk <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> having a car stolen or misappropriated 607times greater than the probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> being killed. Nevertheless, these latter pair <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crimes issubject to a very low level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> underreporting 167 , so the data-derived ratio may be close to theactuality. In sum, the frequency ratios <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the most prominent violent crimes to property crimesare c<strong>on</strong>siderably biased towards the latter.Combining these mean levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>al crime rates and their likelihood with thehypotheses developed above allows the formulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the following testable hypothesis:Testable Hypothesis 2a:In political systems with instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong>, the median voter prefers andinduces an allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> relatively more resources for fighting most types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> propertycrime than for fighting crime against pers<strong>on</strong>s.3 ModelTo test these hypotheses, the ec<strong>on</strong>omic model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime is estimated based <strong>on</strong> the work <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>BECKER (1968) and EHRLICH (1973) 168 and subsequent empirical c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s. This modelcan be formulated in a "structural form" but may also be reduced to a single equati<strong>on</strong> (the"reduced form"). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> analysis is carried out for both forms. In the structural form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theec<strong>on</strong>omic model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime, the following two equati<strong>on</strong>s must be estimated:167 See footnote 180.168 Whereas BECKER's original model aimed to identify a socially optimal crime rate by equating the marginalcost <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime preventi<strong>on</strong> and the marginal societal loss through criminal activities, it was EHRLICH (1973)who derived an individual's supply curve <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fences.


– 153 –(1) log O = f (D 1 , D 2 , Y, X 1 , E 1 , cult, inst) + ε.(2) D 1 = f (Y, X 2 , E 2 , F, cult, inst) + ε,where equati<strong>on</strong> (1) represents a typical specificati<strong>on</strong> to estimate the supply <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime andequati<strong>on</strong> (2) an auxiliary regressi<strong>on</strong> to determine the endogenous variable.D 1 denotes the endogenous deterrence variable linked to the probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> punishment; in thiscase, the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> policemen per capita, which is driven by subfederal police expenditure 169 .D 2 represents the sec<strong>on</strong>d deterrent related to the severity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> punishment, measured by theshare <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> suspended sentences am<strong>on</strong>g total sentences, which is treated as exogenous in thissystem 170 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> term inst stands for the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy in the respective cant<strong>on</strong>,the variable <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest, whereas cult represents the cant<strong>on</strong>al main language as a culturalcovariate. Traditi<strong>on</strong>ally, the wealth <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the society, measured by nati<strong>on</strong>al income (Y) isemployed in both equati<strong>on</strong>s. In equati<strong>on</strong> (1), the usual further exogenous sociodemographic(X 1 ) and ec<strong>on</strong>omic determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime (E 1 ) are added: welfare transfers per capita, incomeinequality in society, unemployment rate, closeness to an important border crossing,interacti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> populati<strong>on</strong> between cant<strong>on</strong>s, cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong>, urbanizati<strong>on</strong>, and the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>15 to 24-year-old and 25 to 29-year-old residents. Also included in equati<strong>on</strong> (2) are mostlytypical fiscal and political determinants (F) used in the field <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public finance for governmentexpenditure models. Here, they c<strong>on</strong>sist <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong>, tax competiti<strong>on</strong>, federaltransfers, a c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>straint that aims to balance the state budget, a measure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theideology <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al government, the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coaliti<strong>on</strong> in the cant<strong>on</strong>al executive. Alsoincluded are ec<strong>on</strong>omic and sociodemographic determinants (E 2 , X 2 ) like urbanizati<strong>on</strong>,cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong>, the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> young residents between the age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 0 and 14, the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>169 Clear-up rates are not collected throughout the whole <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Switzerland and are therefore not available. FUNKand KUGLER (2003) employ and proxy a c<strong>on</strong>victi<strong>on</strong> rate for mass crimes theft and robbery by dividing thenumber <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>victi<strong>on</strong>s by the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> reported <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenses. According to the experts in the crime secti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the BFS, using this variable is not advisable since c<strong>on</strong>victi<strong>on</strong>s are measured by sentences and <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenses byeither pers<strong>on</strong>s or cases. Further, heterogeneity in data collecti<strong>on</strong> (pers<strong>on</strong>s or cases) between Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>smakes this 'c<strong>on</strong>victi<strong>on</strong>' rate incomparable. Moreover, this approximati<strong>on</strong> does not work with infrequentlyobserved crimes like homicides (years with 0 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fense rates but positive c<strong>on</strong>victi<strong>on</strong> rates).170 For an alternative specificati<strong>on</strong> as a two-way causati<strong>on</strong> model incorporating two different endogenousdeterrence variables, see EIDE (1994) and CAMERON (1988). Assuming the severity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> punishment asexogenous takes into account that no valid instrument exists in the data; furthermore, this approach followsthe classical traditi<strong>on</strong> applied in most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the criminometric literature.


– 154 –residents between 15 and 24, and the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pers<strong>on</strong>s aged 60 or older 171 . Since D 1 isendogenous in equati<strong>on</strong> (1), it is instrumented with the determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> police force size usedin equati<strong>on</strong> (2) to prevent bias in the whole coefficient vector 172 .In the reduced form, the endogenous variable D 1 is replaced with the exogenous determinants<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> equati<strong>on</strong> (2). Hence, the complex model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime shrinks to <strong>on</strong>e single equati<strong>on</strong>:(3) log O = f (D 2 , Y, X 1 , X 2 , E 1 , E 2 , F, cult, inst) + ε,where the crime supply depends <strong>on</strong> all exogenous determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> both equati<strong>on</strong>s (1) and (2).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> chosen approach <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> estimating both a structural form and a reduced form is usefulbecause direct democracy, the variable <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest, is an exogenous determinant in bothequati<strong>on</strong>s (1) and (2) <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the structural form and also <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the reduced form (3). Analyzing bothforms allows separati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the direct instituti<strong>on</strong>al impact from its indirect impact: Whereas thestructural form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model allows observati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the direct impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong>the endogenous deterrent (2) and also its direct influence <strong>on</strong> the crime rate (1), the reducedform permits an analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its combined direct and indirect instituti<strong>on</strong>al effect (3). Withrespect to the Testable Hypotheses, the first can be assessed with the help <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> equati<strong>on</strong> (2)because it determines the instituti<strong>on</strong>al impact <strong>on</strong> expenditure. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sec<strong>on</strong>d (2 and particularly2a) must be tested using equati<strong>on</strong> (1) since this specificati<strong>on</strong> takes into account the allocati<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> given means for crime preventi<strong>on</strong> and crime detecti<strong>on</strong> (this specificati<strong>on</strong> analyzes <strong>on</strong>ly thereallocati<strong>on</strong> between crimes). Finally, a comparis<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the estimates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> equati<strong>on</strong>s (1) and (3)help reveal the efficiency gains in the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public safety at the cant<strong>on</strong>al police levelthat might hint at the validity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the not directly testable Hypothesis 4 (secti<strong>on</strong> 2.3).According to the traditi<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omic model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime, the potential criminal weighs theexpected costs and expected gains <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> committing a [property] crime (EHRLICH 1973).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, crime preventi<strong>on</strong> policies can influence both sides <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this decisi<strong>on</strong>-making process.171 Splitting up the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> young residents into the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreigners and the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Swiss citizens for bothyounger age groups did not seem appropriate because the shares <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreigners are too highly correlated (rho =0.93). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> main results for the democracy variable, however, are robust to such an alterati<strong>on</strong> in specificati<strong>on</strong>.Estimati<strong>on</strong> results are available from the author.172 In the traditi<strong>on</strong>al model specificati<strong>on</strong>, probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> punishment depends <strong>on</strong> the financial resources available,the crime rate, and some determinant <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> effective usage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these financial means like urbanizati<strong>on</strong> or level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>educati<strong>on</strong>. For a discussi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the endogeneity problem, see WOLPIN (1980) and CAMERON (1988).


– 155 –Higher clear-up and detecti<strong>on</strong> rates, here proxied by the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> police per capita, and astricter severity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> punishment increase the expected costs (BECKER 1986), whereas higherwealth raises the expected illegal income opportunities (EHRLICH 1973). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> incomeinequality appears to be undecided in the criminometric literature (FAJNZYLBER et al. 2002,BOURGUIGNON et al. 2003) 173 , although criminal theory does predict an increasing impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>inequality <strong>on</strong> crime rates (CHIU and MADDEN 1998). Unemployment rate as a measure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>missing legal income opportunities is supposed to raise the expected (net) gains from crime(WITTE and TAUCHEN 1994, DOYLE et al. 1999) 174 ; however, welfare transfers increase thecosts (loss <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> secure legal income) (STEVANS 1988). Agglomerati<strong>on</strong>s provide greateropportunities for committing a crime and ensuring greater an<strong>on</strong>ymity, thus affecting bothsides <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the criminal's cost-benefit analysis equally in favor <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fel<strong>on</strong>y (GLAESER andSACERDOTE 1999). Young people below the age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 24 who are not yet part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the labor marketor who have <strong>on</strong>ly a low (starting) income are found to be particularly pr<strong>on</strong>e to committingproperty and violent fel<strong>on</strong>ies (COHEN and LAND 1987) 175 . For Switzerland, this current studyincludes additi<strong>on</strong>ally the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 25 to 29-year-olds because they c<strong>on</strong>stitute an important agegroup am<strong>on</strong>g c<strong>on</strong>victed pers<strong>on</strong>s in some cant<strong>on</strong>s 176 . This specificati<strong>on</strong> also includes the size<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> each cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> to take into account that smaller cant<strong>on</strong>s might be systematicallysafer. In additi<strong>on</strong>, to account for the geographic proximity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s, the modelemploys an ec<strong>on</strong>ogeographic variable that measures the interacti<strong>on</strong> between centers:interacti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong> i is defined as the sum <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the populati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong> i multiplied with thepopulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong> j weighted with the inverse <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the absolute distance between the twocant<strong>on</strong>s. In accordance with SAH (1991) and KELLY (2000), I assume that a higher degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>interacti<strong>on</strong> between populati<strong>on</strong>s leads to more spillovers <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> criminality across groups andmore potential <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenders in a cant<strong>on</strong>, more opportunities for committing a fel<strong>on</strong>y throughgreater an<strong>on</strong>ymity, and a lower probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> neighborhood watch, thus raising the crime rate.173 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se proxies for legal and illegal income opportunities appear to be interchangeable. Inequality in incomecan both be interpreted in terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> legal and illegal income opportunities (see ENTORF and SPENGLER 2000for further literature). Even in the most recent c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s, the empirical evidence <strong>on</strong>ly partly corroboratesthe positive impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> inequality <strong>on</strong> crime. See BOURGIGNON et al. (2003) and DYOLE et al. (1999) for adescripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the various ambiguous results and differences in interpretati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> authors also emphasizethat the results depend <strong>on</strong> the measure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> inequality used.174 FUNK and KUGLER (2003) employ the absolute number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> unemployed pers<strong>on</strong>s in a Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>, which maybe misspecified.175 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir analysis was carried out for motor vehicle theft and homicide. In additi<strong>on</strong>, DOYLE et al. (1999) found asignificant positive impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> wages in the low-skilled sector <strong>on</strong> various crimes, particularly <strong>on</strong>property crime, which this age group might proxy.176 In additi<strong>on</strong>, COHEN and LAND (1987) found the age group <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 25 – 29 particularly decisive for killings in theU.S. It should be noted that young pers<strong>on</strong>s below 29 are also more pr<strong>on</strong>e to victimizati<strong>on</strong> than higher agegroups and therefore form a substantial part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime demand (COHEN et al. 1981).


– 156 –In additi<strong>on</strong>, since Switzerland is a small country surrounded by several neighboring countries,the relatively greater wealth <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Switzerland might attract an influx <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreign criminals whomight exert a deleterious influence <strong>on</strong> p ublic safety. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, a dichotomous variable isincluded indicating that a cant<strong>on</strong> is closely situated to a border crossing rich in traffic.A different way <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interpreting the traditi<strong>on</strong>al determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime supply is provided bybehavioral ec<strong>on</strong>omics and sociologists who emphasize that ecological factors such asopportunities for illegal activities, the instituti<strong>on</strong>al envir<strong>on</strong>ment in which decisi<strong>on</strong>s are made,and peer group pressure are decisive. For example, it is argued that in segmented (dual) labormarkets, workers in the sec<strong>on</strong>dary labor market face job c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s that are more similar toillegitimate activities than to normal employment (see PIORE 1968, and an empirical test byMYERS 1983). With respect to income inequality, it is believed that relative welfare or incomecomparis<strong>on</strong>s 177 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> those below the mean income with those above occur, creating a feeling <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>‘malevolence’ and causing more crime (EHRLICH 1973). On the other hand, welfare transfers,if correctly targeted, might reduce this envy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the socially deprived (KELLY 2000).According to PUTNAM's (2000) social capital theory, higher social capital such as voluntaryneighborhood watches and mutual c<strong>on</strong>trol and trust brings about lower <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fense rates. In sum,in the behavioral approach, all types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> sociodemographic and ec<strong>on</strong>omic variables such aseducati<strong>on</strong>, urbanizati<strong>on</strong>, age structure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> populati<strong>on</strong>, income, expenditure for police,unemployment rates, wage levels, share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreigners, and racial structure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> populati<strong>on</strong> canbe motivated and interpreted ecologically.4 DataAvailable for this study are Swiss macro data at the cant<strong>on</strong>al level, which can be used toestimate the aggregate supply <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fense functi<strong>on</strong>. Crime rates are calculated <strong>on</strong> the basis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>data provided by the Federal Office <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Police (BAP) <strong>on</strong> cant<strong>on</strong>al occurrences <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> infracti<strong>on</strong>sand attempted infracti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> criminal law from 1986 to 2001 per 100,000 residents 178 .177 Hence, cases <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> utility interdependence are included that are not usually present in a neoclassical framework.178 In Switzerland, centralized collecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> reliable cant<strong>on</strong>al data <strong>on</strong> crime started in 1984, and since 1986 theyhave been available electr<strong>on</strong>ically. Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>al police forces either count the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> victims or thenumber <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cases. For example, a murder with four victims is recorded as a 'four' in some cant<strong>on</strong>s and in therest as '<strong>on</strong>e'. Also definiti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> auto theft differ to a great extent. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, cant<strong>on</strong>al crime levels are notdirectly comparable. Heterogeneity in reporting behavior was identified through a survey <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the 26 cant<strong>on</strong>alpolice forces in cooperati<strong>on</strong> with the Swiss c<strong>on</strong>ference <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> chiefs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al police. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se results are subjectto strict c<strong>on</strong>fidentiality. Based <strong>on</strong> these findings, dichotomous c<strong>on</strong>trol variables are c<strong>on</strong>structed and includedin equati<strong>on</strong>s (1) and (3). Most are highly significant. A replicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the German and French questi<strong>on</strong>nairecan be found in the Appendix <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this chapter.


– 157 –Following the procedure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> CHERRY and LIST (2002) and WEEDE (1981), the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenses is augmented by 1 to avoid the problem <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime rates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> zero. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crimeincluded in the study are crime against pers<strong>on</strong>s, property, morality, and decency, as well aswhite collar property crimes. In order to take into account measurement errors in thedependent variable and huge differences in relative numbers, all crime rates arelogarithmized, as is comm<strong>on</strong> in the criminometric literature 179 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> latest theoretical andsimulati<strong>on</strong>-based findings show that this transformati<strong>on</strong> ensures that the estimates will bereas<strong>on</strong>ably accurate and not overly biased 180 . A detailed descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the crimecategorizati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fel<strong>on</strong>ies (as defined by the articles <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Swiss Criminal Code, <strong>St</strong>GB) isprovided in the Appendix (table A.1).Am<strong>on</strong>g deterrents, the severity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> punishment is measured by the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> unsuspendedsentences in total sentences 181 , which is available from the Swiss Federal <strong>St</strong>atistical Office(BFS) <strong>on</strong>ly for several major crimes (theft, robbery, fraud, murder, bodily assault, sexualabuse, and rape). Swiss criminal law specifies minimum and/or maximum levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>punishment and allows for suspended and unsuspended sentences, hence still leaving room forthe discreti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individual judges. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re is reas<strong>on</strong> to believe that the different cant<strong>on</strong>s havedeveloped distinguishable cultures in the local applicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Swiss Criminal Code, so thatnot <strong>on</strong>ly a variati<strong>on</strong> over time but also between the 26 Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s can be expected 182 . As asec<strong>on</strong>d deterrent, the model uses the cant<strong>on</strong>al police force per capita, based <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>fidentialdata provided by the Federal Office <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Police (BAP) 183 , which proxies the probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> being179 To reduce the detrimental impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> measurement errors, also the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> policemen serving as proxy forclear-up rates was logarithmized. See also footnote 180.180 Regarding underreporting and the resulting measurement error which might bias the coefficients see EHRLICH(1996) and FAJNZYLBER (2002) for a theoretical investigati<strong>on</strong>. For empirical evidence <strong>on</strong> reporting behaviordepending <strong>on</strong> the victim’s characteristics and the nature <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the crime, see MACDONALD (2002). PUDNEY et al.(2000) show through a M<strong>on</strong>te Carlo simulati<strong>on</strong> that simple OLS estimates are not seriously biased due tomeasurement errors in the dependent variable or the clear-up rates (see also LEVITT (1998) for similarresults). In general, the smallest degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> underreporting can be expected for murder and robbery (seeFAJNZYLBER et al. 2002.) and, in the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Switzerland, auto theft and burglary for reas<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> car andhousehold insurance. High underreporting is observed for crimes with a social stigma, such as rape(MACDONALD 2002).181 Severe crimes, which are under c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> here, do not allow for fining the c<strong>on</strong>victed.182 This assumpti<strong>on</strong> can be c<strong>on</strong>cluded from the fact that first, until recently, there was no mutualacknowledgment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> advocate’s licenses between cant<strong>on</strong>s; sec<strong>on</strong>d, criminal procedural law c<strong>on</strong>sists <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>cant<strong>on</strong>al laws that prevent intercant<strong>on</strong>al mobility <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> judicial pers<strong>on</strong>nel (EXPERTENKOMMISSION 1997, p. 25);third, it is mostly local l<strong>on</strong>g-term residents who are elected as judges in cant<strong>on</strong>al and local courts; and finally,there is a c<strong>on</strong>tinuous effort by the Swiss Supreme Court to eliminate systematic differences in the sentencingpractice <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>al courts (GIGER 2002, p. 257 c<strong>on</strong>t., ROTH 2003, 3.3.7).183 Data were obtained with the explicit permissi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> all chiefs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al police forces.


– 158 –detected and arrested 184 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se data allow an identificati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ordinary cant<strong>on</strong>al policemenand criminal detectives in charge <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the detecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the more severe crimes 185 . Since the size<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the police force is determined by cant<strong>on</strong>al policies, a c<strong>on</strong>siderable cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al variati<strong>on</strong>is expected 186 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> instituti<strong>on</strong>al measure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy is c<strong>on</strong>structed based <strong>on</strong> STUTZER(1999). This measure is a composite index that ranges from 1 to 6, with 1 indicating thelowest degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy. It encompasses all direct legislative instituti<strong>on</strong>s, such asthe statutory initiative, the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative, and the fiscal and statutory referendum.All sociodemographic and expenditure informati<strong>on</strong> was obtained from the BFS. All m<strong>on</strong>etaryvariables are deflated to the base year 1980 using the GDP deflator series provided by the<strong>St</strong>ate Secretariat for Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Affairs (SECO). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> remaining ec<strong>on</strong>ogeographic, ec<strong>on</strong>omic,and fiscal determinants are calculated using data from the BFS, the Swiss Federal TaxAdministrati<strong>on</strong> (FTA), the Swiss Household Panel (SHP), the Federal Office <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> SpatialDevelopment, and yearly issues <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> L'Année politique Suisse 187 . A more detailed descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>all variables and their c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> and descriptive statistics can be found in the Appendix(tables A.1, A.4, and A.11).5 Empirical Results5.1. <strong>St</strong>ructural Equati<strong>on</strong> I: Determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Police Expenditure<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first computati<strong>on</strong>al step – using a times-series cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al panel <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 26 cant<strong>on</strong>s from1986 to 2001 – analyzes the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> combined cant<strong>on</strong>al and localspending <strong>on</strong> security issues (per capita), and particularly <strong>on</strong> the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al police forces184 See e.g. CORNWELL and TRUMBULL (1994) for the use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> police per capita as a measure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the county's abilityto detect crime.185 As in the U.S., there exists a communal and a state (i.e. cant<strong>on</strong>al) police force. According to MARTIN JÄGGI,chief commander <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al police <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Solothurn and President <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Swiss C<strong>on</strong>ference <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Cant<strong>on</strong>alChiefs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Police, local police forces deal mainly with traffic issues and their c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to crime detecti<strong>on</strong> isnegligible.186 In Switzerland, not all cant<strong>on</strong>s seem to report clear-up rates in their cant<strong>on</strong>al criminal statistics, and data <strong>on</strong>c<strong>on</strong>victi<strong>on</strong> rates have not been found. Data <strong>on</strong> the length <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> sentence are also unavailable.187 L' Année politique Suisse, HANS HIRTER et al., Institut für Politikwissenschaft an der Universität Bern (ed.),Bern: Institut für Politikwissenschaft, 1986–2001. For the years 1986 to 2001, some <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fiscal and politicalvariables were obtained by courtesy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> my colleagues G. KIRCHGÄSSNER, L.P. FELD, and Ch.A.SCHALTEGGER.


– 159 –(per capita) 188 . In this specificati<strong>on</strong>, the fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> variable is instrumented withcant<strong>on</strong>al fixed effects 189 , and standard errors are robust and also adjusted for serialautocorrelati<strong>on</strong>. Table 2 reports the results for different budgetary comp<strong>on</strong>ents <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> securityexpenditure. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first column represents the police expenditure estimati<strong>on</strong>, while columns (2)to (4) represent more specifically the regressi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al police force andits subcategories 'ordinary policemen' and 'criminal detectives'. Also included for reas<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>comparis<strong>on</strong> are the results for the aggregate total security expenditure and the judicial systemand nati<strong>on</strong>al defense expenditure, which are reported in columns (5) to (8) in the Appendix(table A.2).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> variable <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest, the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al direct democracy, appears to exert anexpenditure-lowering influence <strong>on</strong> police expenditure in the subfederal budgets inSwitzerland (at the 1% level). In additi<strong>on</strong>, with respect to the actual size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al policeforce, a c<strong>on</strong>siderable decreasing impact can be observed for all three police force sizevariables (at the 1% and 5% levels, respectively). Since work <strong>on</strong> crime preventi<strong>on</strong> anddetecti<strong>on</strong> is divided am<strong>on</strong>g the several types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> policemen, which depends <strong>on</strong> the type <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>crime, a deterrence-lowering impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> all the different crime categoriesanalyzed can be c<strong>on</strong>jectured. Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, it is observed that in more direct democraticcant<strong>on</strong>s fewer financial means are available for total security spending and judicial systemexpenditure. As regards nati<strong>on</strong>al defense expenditure <strong>on</strong>ly, no such impact is detected, whichmight be the result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> regulati<strong>on</strong>s at the federal level. A high (centered) R2 indicates a good fit<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model to the time-series cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al data. For corroborating estimati<strong>on</strong> results withoutliers excluded, see table A.5 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendix.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se empirical results are perfectly in line with the c<strong>on</strong>jecture made in Testable Hypothesis1. By systematically underestimating the average pers<strong>on</strong>'s (or their own) probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>becoming victimized, median voters induce a police expenditure budget c<strong>on</strong>straint in cant<strong>on</strong>swhose instituti<strong>on</strong>al setup allows the voter to exert a str<strong>on</strong>ger influence <strong>on</strong> the politicaldecisi<strong>on</strong>-making process. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> fewer means then available for crime preventi<strong>on</strong> and crimedetecti<strong>on</strong> translate directly into a lower number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> police per capita. In more representativedemocracies, however, in which trained bureaucrats and specialized politicians, who make188 This time span is chosen to make it comparable with crime equati<strong>on</strong> (1). Estimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the widest time spanpossible (1984–2001) does not alter the results significantly. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> identical results found here also hold forcant<strong>on</strong>al expenses <strong>on</strong>ly.189 Because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the way this variable is c<strong>on</strong>structed, the dependent variable might influence its size.


– 160 –more accurate predicti<strong>on</strong>s about crime rates, exert more influence <strong>on</strong> budgets, more m<strong>on</strong>ey isspent <strong>on</strong> fighting crime 190 .Table 2: Security Expenditure 1986 – 2001(1) (2) (3) (4)PoliceOrdinary CriminalPolice forceexpenditurepolicemen detectives<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy -0.115** -0.093** -0.068* -0.210**(4.03) (3.64) (2.56) (4.65)Fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> -0.514** -0.23 -0.23 -0.29(2.70) (1.26) (1.39) (0.74)Tax competiti<strong>on</strong> -0.272** -0.059 -0.102 0.113(3.55) (0.88) (1.49) (0.87)Federal transfers 0.145* 0.172** 0.115* 0.397**(2.26) (2.87) (2.03) (3.31)C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>straint -0.024(*) -0.001 0.012 -0.033(1.72) (0.03) (0.66) (1.10)C<strong>on</strong>servative ideology 0.02 0.017 -0.123 0.549*(0.14) (0.13) (0.95) (2.22)Size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> coaliti<strong>on</strong> -0.013 -0.052* -0.054* -0.065(0.42) (2.00) (2.22) (1.12)Romance cant<strong>on</strong> -0.26* -0.086 -0.063 -0.173(2.37) (0.94) (0.71) (0.99)Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> 0.00 -0.002(*) -0.004** 0.004(*)(0.20) (1.69) (2.86) (1.75)Nati<strong>on</strong>al income 0.719** 0.579** 0.518** 0.860**(3.99) (3.87) (3.55) (3.22)Cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> 0.019 0.002 0.009 -0.012(0.57) (0.08) (0.30) (0.28)Residents 0 – 14 -0.044(*) -0.081** -0.102** 0.004(1.96) (4.09) (4.79) (0.14)Residents 15 – 24 0.049* 0.045* 0.024 0.099*(2.07) (2.03) (1.02) (2.54)Residents over 60 0.037** 0.047** 0.040** 0.068**(2.74) (3.77) (2.89) (3.46)C<strong>on</strong>stant -5.185** -8.577** -7.617** -14.474**(3.50) (6.83) (5.63) (7.33)Observati<strong>on</strong>s 416 416 416 416Centered R 2 0.82 0.83 0.82 0.51Jarque-Bera χ-value 40.05*** 1.69 1.57 210.50***02SLS with heteroscedasticity and autocorrelati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sistent standard errors for two lags.Absolute values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> t-statistics are in parentheses. Endogenous variable: fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong>.(*) indicates significance at the 10%, * at the 5%, and ** at the 1% level. Year fixed effects areincluded but not reported.190 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se empirical findings are in line with all the U.S American and Swiss efficiency literature <strong>on</strong> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> budgets (see secti<strong>on</strong> 2.1). Most particularly, SCHALTEGGER (2001), using adifferent specificati<strong>on</strong>, also finds a limiting instituti<strong>on</strong>al impact <strong>on</strong> subfederal total security spending forSwiss data between 1980 and 1989. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> innovative c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this secti<strong>on</strong> lies in the theoreticalargument.


– 161 –Regarding the additi<strong>on</strong>al fiscal, political, and sociodemographic predictors in the model, anexpenditure-lowering impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> and the fiscal break is observed <strong>on</strong>police expenditure but not <strong>on</strong> the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> policemen. Tax competiti<strong>on</strong> causes a decline <strong>on</strong>lyin the expenditure for police but not in the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> policemen. Financial lumpsum transfersfrom the federal government lead to both significantly higher police expenditure and a largercant<strong>on</strong>al police force. Interestingly, a more c<strong>on</strong>servative ideology <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al executives isassociated with more criminal detectives per capita but is insignificant with respect to policeexpenditure and the remaining measures <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al police force. In c<strong>on</strong>trast to the usualexpectati<strong>on</strong>, the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coaliti<strong>on</strong>, which measures government fragmentati<strong>on</strong>, appears tocause a lower number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> policemen, particularly ordinary policemen. In cant<strong>on</strong>s in which themain culture is French or Italian, significantly less m<strong>on</strong>ey is spent <strong>on</strong> police, leaving thenumber <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> policemen seemingly unaffected 191 . On average, a higher degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> urbanizati<strong>on</strong> isassociated (albeit weakly) with a lower number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ordinary policemen and total policemen butalso (weakly) with more criminal detectives. Moreover, wealthier cant<strong>on</strong>s (in terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>nati<strong>on</strong>al income) show a higher spending <strong>on</strong> police that appears to translate into significantlyhigher numbers <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> all types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> policemen. Further, there is no significant linkage between thesize <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> and police-related variables. Regarding the demographicstructure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>, a significant negative relati<strong>on</strong> is observed between almost all policevariables (except criminal detectives) and the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> young residents below the age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 14 192 ,but a positive <strong>on</strong>e (except ordinary policemen) is found for the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> residents between 15and 24 years, criminally the most active period in life (e.g. COHEN and LAND 1987). Finally,in this model, senior residents appear to either demand or require more <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the good 'publicsafety': their share is significantly positively associated with higher levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> spending <strong>on</strong>police issues and also with higher numbers <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> all types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> police.As a robustness test, this same analysis is performed with a specificati<strong>on</strong> that includes thenatural log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the theft and assault crime rate lagged by two periods, because both policeexpenditure and the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the police force might be determined also by cant<strong>on</strong>al crime rates.As expected, both crime rates affect the independent police-related variables str<strong>on</strong>gly andpositively. Most important, the police expenditure and police force lowering impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy remains unchanged (all at the 1% level). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> estimati<strong>on</strong> outcomes for this191 A possible interpretati<strong>on</strong> is that the (unobservable) technical equipment might be negatively affected.192 In Switzerland, the age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> criminal resp<strong>on</strong>sibility is 7, but until the age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 16 no pris<strong>on</strong> terms are applicable,but <strong>on</strong>ly measures according to art 82 – 88 <strong>St</strong>GB.


– 162 –specificati<strong>on</strong> can be found in the Appendix (table A.3). In additi<strong>on</strong>, estimati<strong>on</strong> results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theoriginal model with outliers excluded are displayed in table A.5 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendix.5.2 <strong>St</strong>ructural Equati<strong>on</strong> II: Determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Crime RatesIn the sec<strong>on</strong>d step, structural equati<strong>on</strong> (1) is estimated to determine the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy <strong>on</strong> cant<strong>on</strong>al crime rates based <strong>on</strong> an ec<strong>on</strong>omic model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime but taking intoaccount that it also reduces the means available for cant<strong>on</strong>al police forces. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, the(endogenous) police force variables are explicitly included in the crime regressi<strong>on</strong>, whichmakes the direct impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> various crime rates observable. Since thesedeterrents are subject to a potential simultaneity 193 , they are instrumented with the exogenousvariables in equati<strong>on</strong> (2). This relati<strong>on</strong> is analyzed for various categories <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> property crime,including 'white collar' property crime like fraud and defalcati<strong>on</strong>, and violent crime 194 . Allregressi<strong>on</strong>s include dichotomous determinants that c<strong>on</strong>trol for heterogeneity in recordingbehavior by cant<strong>on</strong>al police forces, and the standard errors are adjusted for serialautocorrelati<strong>on</strong>.Property CrimeTable 3 displays the estimati<strong>on</strong> results for property crime, particularly burglary,pickpocketing, auto theft, robbery, fraud, and defalcati<strong>on</strong>. Regarding the variable <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest,in this model, the direct impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy is observed to significantly decreaseproperty crimes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> burglary and auto theft and robbery (all at the 5% level or above). It doesnot, however, affect pickpocketing, fraud, and defalcati<strong>on</strong> rates.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se important empirical results are perfectly in line with Testable Hypothesis 2. Auto theftand burglary <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fense rates are the two highest in the list <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime rates (see table 1). Based <strong>on</strong>this finding, it can be c<strong>on</strong>cluded that due to the high frequency <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these property crimes, themedian voter overestimates their true probabilities <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> occurrence (in comparis<strong>on</strong> to violentcrimes) and demands that more <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the available resources be allocated to the preventi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>auto theft and burglary. Rather puzzling, however, is the result for robbery because, based <strong>on</strong>its quite rare occurrence, there should be no overestimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its relative probability.193 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> significant impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theft and assault crime rates <strong>on</strong> these deterrents in the empirical analysis in secti<strong>on</strong>5.1 corroborates this c<strong>on</strong>jecture.194 Robbery is counted am<strong>on</strong>g property crimes because its primary goal is to generate illegal income.


– 163 –Table 3: Property Crime 1986 – 2001 <strong>St</strong>ructural Form(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)Burglary Pickpocketing Auto theft Robbery Fraud Defalcati<strong>on</strong>Criminal detectives -0.574* 0.164 -0.840* -0.734* 0.735 1.141*(2.58) (0.45) (2.36) (2.20) (1.34) (2.01)Ordinary policemen 0.429** 1.121** 0.710** 1.219** 1.255** -0.04(2.88) (4.33) (2.83) (4.41) (3.80) (0.11)Severity 139 -0.005 0.006 0.001(1.62) (1.20) (0.17)Severity 140 0.000(0.103)Severity 146 0.000(0.019)Severity 138 -0.005(1.57)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy -0.204** 0.137 -0.214* -0.186* -0.008 -0.001(2.87) (1.30) (2.06) (2.16) (0.05) (0.01)Welfare transfers 0.283** 0.302* 0.304* 0.376** -0.126 -0.349(*)(3.05) (2.03) (1.99) (2.75) (0.70) (1.96)Income inequality 0.14 0.169 0.028 0.004 -0.197 -0.263(1.33) (1.00) (0.20) (0.02) (0.92) (1.08)Nati<strong>on</strong>al income 0.545* -0.857* 0.409 -0.216 -1.628** -0.82(2.48) (2.00) (0.89) (0.59) (3.82) (1.51)Unemployment rate 0.032 0.043 -0.004 0.006 0.006 -0.039(0.97) (0.61) (0.07) (0.11) (0.07) (0.46)Closeness to border -0.255** 0.494** 0.093 0.166(*) 0.019 -0.365*(3.19) (4.72) (0.80) (1.70) (0.11) (2.23)Interacti<strong>on</strong> b. cant<strong>on</strong>s 0.001 0.012(*) 0.011 0.035** -0.009 -0.004(0.11) (1.79) (1.57) (4.92) (0.85) (0.36)Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> 0.010** 0.012** 0.006* 0.012** 0.010* 0.011*(4.41) (3.73) (1.97) (3.99) (2.37) (2.43)Cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> 0.121 0.22 -0.206 -0.401** 0.217 0.128(1.23) (1.61) (1.43) (2.82) (1.02) (0.57)Residents 15 – 24 0.139** 0.178** 0.174** 0.05 0.074 -0.136(*)(3.73) (2.67) (2.92) (0.80) (1.01) (1.72)Residents 25 – 29 0.045 -0.045 0.077 0.138 0.068 0.097(0.67) (0.51) (0.95) (1.52) (0.52) (0.68)Romance cant<strong>on</strong> -0.033 -0.307 -1.050** -0.362* -1.146** 0.102(0.27) (1.44) (5.74) (2.08) (3.75) (0.29)C<strong>on</strong>stant -0.179 7.210** 3.983* 8.456** 19.308** 13.934**(0.11) (3.14) (2.05) (4.05) (4.89) (2.95)Observati<strong>on</strong>s 416 416 416 416 416 416Centered R 2 0.71 0.65 0.30 0.53 0.41 0.05Jarque-Bera χ-value 0.20 48.20*** 800.60*** 9.57** 36.29*** 75.30***2SLS with heteroscedasticity and autocorrelati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sistent standard errors for two lags. Absolute values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> t-statistics are in parentheses. Endogenous variables: Criminal detectives and ordinary policemen. (*) indicatessignificance at the 10%, * at the 5%, and ** at the 1% level. Year fixed effects and measures <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> recording behaviorare included but not reported.


– 164 –Nevertheless, given that, according to availability heuristic frequencies, more severe anddamaging crimes are more persistent in people's memories than simple crimes likepickpocketing, the optimism bias for robbery rates might not be as great as for simple theft,thus leading to higher efforts in more direct democratic cant<strong>on</strong>s to fight this crime.In line with the predicti<strong>on</strong>s, the deterrent 'criminal detectives' exerts a crime-dampeninginfluence <strong>on</strong> burglary, auto theft, and robbery. No such effect, however, is prominent for theremaining property crimes, and for defalcati<strong>on</strong> even a crime enhancing effect is revealed. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ordinary policemen also appears to increase property crime for the first fivecategories, but exerts an insignificant impact <strong>on</strong> defalcati<strong>on</strong>. 195 In all six property crimecategories, the coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the severity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> punishment are always rendered insignificant,which might be caused by the unsolved potential endogeneity 196 . For burglary anddefalcati<strong>on</strong>, however, the coefficients show at least the expected sign.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic determinants, however, reveal a different pattern <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> behavior. Welfare transfersare associated with higher levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> burglary, pickpocketing, auto theft and robbery, but notfraud and defalcati<strong>on</strong>, which it decreases. This <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fense-raising result c<strong>on</strong>tradictsexpectati<strong>on</strong>s 197 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income inequality is always rendered insignificant, butwith the predicted sign in the first four crime categories. Nati<strong>on</strong>al income, the measure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> asociety's wealth, leads – as anticipated – to significantly higher burglary rates but, c<strong>on</strong>trary toexpectati<strong>on</strong>s, to lower pickpocketing and fraud rates. In this specificati<strong>on</strong>, the unemploymentrate appears to be insignificant for all six types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> property crime.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the ec<strong>on</strong>ogeographic determinant <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> proximity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a cant<strong>on</strong> to important bordercrossings, which measures the exposure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a cant<strong>on</strong> to an influx <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreigners, unexpectedlydecreases crimes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> burglary and defalcati<strong>on</strong>, but increases crimes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pickpocketing androbbery. This result indicates that although cases <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> serial burglaries committed by foreigngangs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thieves have occasi<strong>on</strong>ally been prominent in the Swiss media, in the synthetic panel195 It is generally known that a higher frequency <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> patrolling policemen and higher efforts to detect crime lead tohigher reported and recorded crime rates in criminal statistics, even when the true crime rate might not havechanged over time.196 Given that higher crime rates increase the severity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> punishment, which, again, lowers the crime rate, the‘simultaneous’ effect will be zero (insignificant).197 One possible explanati<strong>on</strong> is that this variable serves as a proxy for the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor, uneducated pers<strong>on</strong>s in acant<strong>on</strong> who might be more pr<strong>on</strong>e to commit a crime. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax data (until 1998) <strong>on</strong> which the inequalityvariable is based excludes pers<strong>on</strong>s with n<strong>on</strong>taxable income. Alternatively, welfare transfers might directlyincrease the propensity to commit crimes through the creati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> disincentives for regular work, as shown inan ec<strong>on</strong>omic model by IMROHOROGLU et al. (2000).


– 165 –from 1986 to 2001, it is pickpocketing and robbery rather than burglary that is induced fromabroad. Moreover, a more intense interacti<strong>on</strong> between cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong>s withinSwitzerland is associated with higher cant<strong>on</strong>al pickpocketing and robbery rates, whichsupports the predicti<strong>on</strong> about this determinant.As regards the sociodemographic determinants, as expected, a higher degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> urbanizati<strong>on</strong>is associated with higher levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> property crime for all categories. Robbery rates decrease inthe size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong> measured by cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong>. However, no such effect can bedetected for the remaining property crimes. Also in line with the original BECKER model, ahigher share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> young pers<strong>on</strong>s between 15 and 24 causes higher rates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the 'blue collar'property crimes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> burglary, pickpocketing and auto theft, but weakly lower rates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the 'whitecollar' <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenses <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> defalcati<strong>on</strong> 198 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pers<strong>on</strong>s aged between 25 and29 years appear to be insignificant for all property crimes, which is also in line with thetraditi<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omic theory <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime.Finally, Romance culture, as measured by the main cant<strong>on</strong>al language being Italian or French,leads to significantly less auto theft, robbery, and fraud. As people’s reporting behavior maybe shaped by the dominant cant<strong>on</strong>al culture, it is possible that this variable captures suchdifferences. In general, the centered R 2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> between 0.30 and 0.71 indicates quite a good fit <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the model for all crimes reported in columns (1) through (5). For defalcati<strong>on</strong>, however, nosuch statement can be made (based <strong>on</strong> a centered R 2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 0.052). Table A.6 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendixreports estimati<strong>on</strong> results with outliers excluded 199 .Violent CrimeTable 4 reports the estimati<strong>on</strong> results for crimes against pers<strong>on</strong>s and against morality anddecency. Columns (1) to (3) indicate the hate crimes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> homicide and assault and a combinedcategory for both crimes, while columns (4) and (5) show the results for two types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> sexual<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenses: rape and crimes against sexual integrity. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> combined category (3) is c<strong>on</strong>structedto take into account the fact that in some cant<strong>on</strong>s attempted homicides (category 1) might becounted as completed severe assaults (category 2) 200 .198 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> exclusi<strong>on</strong> from the labor market <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pers<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this age might serve as <strong>on</strong>e explanati<strong>on</strong>.199 As table A.6 shows, a significant crime lowering impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> defalcati<strong>on</strong> rates can beobserved (at the 5% level).200 Because CHERRY and LIST (2002) and WITHERS (1988) show that aggregati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> different crimes can lead toa bias in the coefficients, the estimati<strong>on</strong> results for this artificial category must be interpreted with cauti<strong>on</strong>.


– 166 –<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> variable <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest, direct democracy, appears to have an <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fense-raising impact <strong>on</strong>assault (2) and the combined assault and homicide rate (at the 1% and 5% levels,respectively). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> remaining types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenses are not affected by direct democracy. Only inthe other sex crime regressi<strong>on</strong> is a t-value close to the 10% level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> significance observed,again with a positive sign <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coefficient 201 .This empirical result is also in line with Testable Hypothesis 2. Obviously, in directdemocratic cant<strong>on</strong>s, available means for public safety are allocated in such a way that higherrates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> assault and (possibly) other sex crimes are admitted. Thus, the median voter appearsto particularly disfavor the preventi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> assault, possibly because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its low frequency, whichinduces the systematic underestimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its occurrence (compared to property crime).Unexpectedly, homicide and rape rates do not appear to 'dis-benefit' from reallocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>given means in direct democratic cant<strong>on</strong>s despite their low probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> occurrence. Onepossible explanati<strong>on</strong> is that they are both rather severe crimes always reported by the mediaand therefore the severity might exert an increasing influence <strong>on</strong> the subjective assessment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>their probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> occurrence, somewhat <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fsetting the decrease <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the low-frequency impact(see secti<strong>on</strong> 2.4).Am<strong>on</strong>g the deterrents in general, the police force variables do not appear to influence the<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fense rate in the predicted manner: For all types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> hate and sex crimes, the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ordinary policemen per capita is associated with higher crime levels. In additi<strong>on</strong>, criminaldetectives affect hate and assault crime rates positively, but a weak decreasing tendencyemerges for their impact <strong>on</strong> sex crimes 202 . As with property crime, the coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theseverity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> punishment variables for homicide, assault, rape, and sexual <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenses areinsignificant in all estimati<strong>on</strong>s, which might be the result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its endogeneity.201 Excluding outliers, however, the coefficients for both sex crime categories become positive, but are notsignificant (see table A.7 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendix).202 See also footnote 195.


– 167 –Table 4: Violent Crime and Sex Crime 1986–2001 <strong>St</strong>ructural Form(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Homicide Assault Hate Crime Rape Sex CrimeCriminal detectives -0.037 0.516** 0.518** -0.54 -0.610(*)(0.21) (2.72) (2.70) (1.59) (1.66)Ordinary policemen 0.528** 0.753** 0.745*** 1.581** 1.433**(2.73) (3.96) (3.71) (4.23) (3.51)Severity 111 0.001(0.97)Severity 122 123 0.003(1.41)Severity 0.001(0.70)Severity 187 -0.002 0.001(1.20) (0.33)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy -0.042 0.191** 0.160* -0.014 0.145(0.63) (2.59) (2.31) (0.18) (1.48)Welfare transfers 0.023 0.361** 0.323*** 0.075 0.102(0.21) (3.38) (3.33) (0.75) (0.84)Income inequality 0.088 -0.108 -0.077 0.058 -0.180(0.69) (0.91) (0.69) (0.39) (1.14)Nati<strong>on</strong>al income -0.298 -0.738** -0.772** -0.578(*) -0.559(*)(1.09) (2.66) (2.90) (1.81) (1.87)Unemployment rate -0.016 0.024 0.012 0.027 -0.064(0.40) (0.53) (0.29) (0.58) (1.19)Closeness to border 0.197(*) -0.346** -0.299*** 0.136 -0.006(1.96) (3.68) (3.55) (1.27) (0.06)Interacti<strong>on</strong> between cant<strong>on</strong>s 0.009 -0.002 -0.002 0.030** 0.016*(1.56) (0.48) (0.27) (3.91) (2.07)Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> 0.000 -0.006* -0.005(*) 0.003 0.012**(0.01) (2.12) (1.93) (1.17) (3.82)Cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> -0.195(*) 0.047 0.034 -0.536** 0.006(1.68) (0.47) (0.23) (4.12) (0.04)Residents 15 – 24 -0.021 -0.100* -0.075 0.169* 0.226*(0.45) (1.97) (1.56) (2.15) (2.44)Residents 25 – 29 0.043 0.025 0.005 0.163* -0.034(0.61) (0.24) (0.05) (1.97) (0.35)Romance cant<strong>on</strong> -0.330(*) 0.025 0.001 -0.412* -0.088(1.90) (0.15) (0.01) (2.05) (0.42)C<strong>on</strong>stant 7.243** 16.007** 16.040*** 11.727** 5.371*(4.16) (8.32) (7.81) (5.74) (2.45)Observati<strong>on</strong>s 384 416 416 416 416Centered R2 0.29 0.57 0.57 0.33 0.33Jarque-Bera χ-value 2.41 44.84*** 19.56*** 19.06*** 33.99***See table 3..


– 168 –As regards the ec<strong>on</strong>omic determinants, an <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fense rate enhancing influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> welfarepayments <strong>on</strong> assault and hate crime is observed. Again, this effect is c<strong>on</strong>trary to predicti<strong>on</strong> bythe ec<strong>on</strong>omic model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime 203 . Also c<strong>on</strong>trary to expectati<strong>on</strong>s, the coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> incomeinequality are rendered insignificant, while nati<strong>on</strong>al income exerts a crime decreasing impact<strong>on</strong> assault, hate crime, and all sexual <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenses. Thus, again c<strong>on</strong>trary to BECKER's model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>crime, the unemployment rate does not appear to be <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> any importance for the type <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fensesunder investigati<strong>on</strong>. Proximity to traffic-rich border crossings to neighboring countriesappears to be weakly associated with higher homicide rates (at the 10% level) butsignificantly lower assault and hate crime rates (at the1% level, respectively). Interestingly,more interacti<strong>on</strong> between the cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong>s does not affect any crime against pers<strong>on</strong>,but does exert a str<strong>on</strong>g raising influence <strong>on</strong> both sexual <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fense rates (at the 1% and 5% level,respectively). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se last finding is in line with the predicti<strong>on</strong> that higher mobility increasesthe opportunities for committing a crime, as well as the an<strong>on</strong>ymity that in turn lowersdetecti<strong>on</strong> probability.Regarding the sociodemographic variables, a higher degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> urbanizati<strong>on</strong> is associated withlower assault and hate crime rates 204 but higher sex crime rates, this last being perfectly in linewith the ec<strong>on</strong>omic theory <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime. Cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> exerts a crime-decreasing influence<strong>on</strong> homicide and rape. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> residents 15 to 24-year-olds is associated with fewerassault <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fences but a more frequent occurrence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> sexual <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenses, which latter finding issupported by ec<strong>on</strong>omic theory 205 . As c<strong>on</strong>jectured, the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 25 to 29-year-old residentsappears <strong>on</strong>ly to positively affect rape rates.As regards Romance culture, a negative linkage between Latin language and homicide andrape rates is observed. Again, unobserved reporting or recording behavior could be capturedby this variable. With respect to the goodness <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fit <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model, <strong>on</strong> average lower levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the centered R 2 are observed for these crimes than for property crimes. This finding is notsurprising as the ec<strong>on</strong>omic rati<strong>on</strong>al choice model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime was developed to explain propertycrime rather than violent crimes, whose emoti<strong>on</strong>al aspects it may not capture. Again,estimati<strong>on</strong> results with outliers excluded can be found in table A.7 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendix.203 For an explanati<strong>on</strong>, see footnote 197.204 It is possible that in urbanized areas, reporting rates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> less severe cases <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> assaults are lower.205 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime-dampening impact <strong>on</strong> assault might be explained by a lower propensity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this age group to reportsuch cases to the police.


– 169 –In sum, in the structural model, direct democracy appears to exert a reducing impact <strong>on</strong>property crime and an increasing impact <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenses against pers<strong>on</strong>, particularly assault.Obviously, even taking into account that protecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pers<strong>on</strong> against assaults will beneglected, the median voter prefers that relatively more <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the available means be devoted t<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>ighting the property crimes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> auto theft, burglary, and robbery. This finding corroboratesTestable Hypothesis 2a that postulates a reallocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> available means for fighting morefrequently occurring property crime at the expense <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> less frequent crimes against pers<strong>on</strong>.5.3 Reduced Form: Determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> CrimeIn the reduced form, presented in equati<strong>on</strong> (3), the endogenous variables for police per capitaare replaced with their exogenous determinants; hence, this specificati<strong>on</strong> also includes fiscopoliticalvariables that determine government expenditure. This makes it possible to observethe combined direct and indirect impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> public safety as well as thetotal effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> those variables which form part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> both the auxiliary and the main regressi<strong>on</strong> inthe structural versi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> reduced form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model is, again, estimated for all the types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> property, hate, and sexcrimes under investigati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> replacement <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the endogenous factors with the exogenousdeterminates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> equati<strong>on</strong> (1) seemingly increases the goodness <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fit <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the reduced form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the model: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> centered R 2 s have increased substantially in comparis<strong>on</strong> with the structuralform, particularly for the two sexual <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenses. Again, estimati<strong>on</strong> results with outliers excludedare given in tables A.8 and A.9 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendix.Property CrimeTable 5 reports the estimati<strong>on</strong> results for property crime. <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy exerts a crimereducingimpact <strong>on</strong> burglary, auto theft, and fraud rates. No significant influence can beobserved, however, <strong>on</strong> pickpocketing, robbery, and defalcati<strong>on</strong> rates. Comparing theseestimati<strong>on</strong> results for the total instituti<strong>on</strong>al effect in the reduced from <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model with those<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the structural model reveals that the <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fense rate lowering impact is present in both formsfor burglary and auto theft. With respect to robbery, the significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracyvanishes in the reduced form, probably because its lowering direct effect is <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fset by thereporting rate increasing impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ordinary policemen. As regards fraud rates, the opposite is


– 170 –observed: the direct impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> political instituti<strong>on</strong>s appears to be irrelevant, whereas thecombined influence significantly lowers the <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fense rate 206 .For severity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> punishment, a crime lowering impact <strong>on</strong> defalcati<strong>on</strong> is observed that isperfectly in line with the predicti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the ec<strong>on</strong>omic model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime but that c<strong>on</strong>tradicts theprevious results from the structural form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model; <strong>on</strong> auto theft, even a (weakly) positiveimpact can be observed. As regards the remaining ec<strong>on</strong>omic, sociodemographic, andec<strong>on</strong>ogeographic determinants, the discussi<strong>on</strong> will focus <strong>on</strong> a descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the differences inimpact between the reduced and the structural form. In c<strong>on</strong>trast to the structural form, welfaretransfers lose their (albeit) weak lowering impact <strong>on</strong> defalcati<strong>on</strong> rates, but remain significantfor the first four categories <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> property crime. Interestingly, income inequality becomes astatistically decisive determinant <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pickpocketing, indicating a (weakly) positive relati<strong>on</strong>between higher income inequality and simple theft rates, c<strong>on</strong>trasting the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thestructural form. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> directi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this influence is in line with the ec<strong>on</strong>omic model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime. Inadditi<strong>on</strong>, the coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> nati<strong>on</strong>al income are rendered insignificant forburglary and pickpocketing, but its fraud lowering influence pertains. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> unemployment rateis now str<strong>on</strong>gly positively associated with burglary rates, which supports BECKER's theory.As regards the remaining ec<strong>on</strong>ogeographic and sociodemographic determinants, in thereduced form, the closeness <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a cant<strong>on</strong> to important border crossings is no l<strong>on</strong>ger animportant determinant <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pickpocketing, but for robbery rates a change in directi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> impactis observable, while the crime reducing impact <strong>on</strong> defalcati<strong>on</strong> and burglary stays the same.Further, compared to the structural form results, an interacti<strong>on</strong> between cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong>sappears now to be significantly crime reducing for burglary rates but str<strong>on</strong>gly crimeincreasing for fraud and defalcati<strong>on</strong>, in additi<strong>on</strong> to the already observed crime raisinginfluence <strong>on</strong> pickpocketing and robbery. Moreover, in c<strong>on</strong>trast to the previous resultsobtained from the structural form estimati<strong>on</strong>, the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> urbanizati<strong>on</strong> in a cant<strong>on</strong> no l<strong>on</strong>gerraises burglary and fraud rates, but weakly decreases auto theft rates. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> now become significant for burglary, fraud, and defalcati<strong>on</strong>, butinsignificant for robbery. Most interesting, in this specificati<strong>on</strong>, the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> young pers<strong>on</strong>sbetween 15 and 24 years is now decisive for robbery rates, but has no impact <strong>on</strong> burglary anddefalcati<strong>on</strong>; in c<strong>on</strong>trast, its positive influence <strong>on</strong> pickpocketing and auto theft remains the206 Excluding outliers, also a dampening impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> defalcati<strong>on</strong> rates is detected, whereas the<strong>on</strong>e <strong>on</strong> auto theft rates looses its significance. See also secti<strong>on</strong> 5.4.


– 171 –same. It is for robbery and fraud <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fences that a significant crime increasing effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a highershare <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> residents aged 25 to 29 years is observed, in c<strong>on</strong>trast to the finding for the reducedform. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fense raising impacts are in line with the underlying ec<strong>on</strong>omic theory. In terms<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cultural determinant, the (reported) crime rate lowering influence is now also prominentfor the occurrence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> burglary (besides the already observed effect <strong>on</strong> auto theft and fraud),but this impact has lost its significance for robbery. In general, c<strong>on</strong>tradicti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the ec<strong>on</strong>omicmodel <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime may result from the fact that in the reduced form the combined impact formany covariates is estimated, whereas in the previously estimated structural form <strong>on</strong>ly thedirect crime-related influence is calculated.In the reduced form, the exogenous variables <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the expenditure equati<strong>on</strong> are also included inthe crime equati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se additi<strong>on</strong>al variables are sociodemographic, fiscal or political. Sincethese determinants usually do not form part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the traditi<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omic model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime, nopredicti<strong>on</strong> has been made because their influence occurs indirectly through their impact <strong>on</strong>police expenditure. In this reduced specificati<strong>on</strong>, the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> people over 60 exerts a crimedampening impact <strong>on</strong> burglary and auto theft rates but a crime increasing impact <strong>on</strong>pickpocketing and robbery rates 207 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pers<strong>on</strong>s below the age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 14 appears to leadto less burglary, auto theft, or fraud 208 . Am<strong>on</strong>g the fiscal variables, fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> isassociated with less robbery but is not significant with respect to any other property crime.Further, as shown in columns (1), (2), (5) and (6), tax competiti<strong>on</strong> appears to lead to lowermostly n<strong>on</strong>-violent property crime rates. Finally, a stricter debt break causes a more frequentoccurrence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pickpocketing, fraud, and defalcati<strong>on</strong>. With respect to the political variables,more c<strong>on</strong>servative governments seem to favor the preventi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> burglary and (weakly) <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fraud, whereas a larger coaliti<strong>on</strong> size is weakly associated with higher burglary rates.207 Based <strong>on</strong> the social capital theory (PUTNAM 2000), the retired pers<strong>on</strong>s positively c<strong>on</strong>tribute which shouldlower crime rates (through, e.g. neighborhood watching). On the other hand, they might also form animportant part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime demand.208 In explanati<strong>on</strong>, it should be noted that children in this age group are simply not physically, mentally, orsocially capable <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> committing some types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> property crime.


– 172 –Table 5: Property Crime 1986–2001 Reduced Form(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)Burglary Pickpocketing Auto <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ft Robbery Fraud Defalcati<strong>on</strong>Severity 139, 140, 146, 138 -0.002 0.004 0.005(*) 0.000 0.002 -0.006*(0.94) (0.85) (1.74) (0.46) (0.73) (2.52)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy -0.158** 0.088 -0.142* -0.074 -0.204* -0.167(3.67) (1.04) (2.26) (1.21) (2.06) (1.55)Welfare transfers 0.142* 0.479** 0.176(*) 0.323** 0.141 0.034(2.15) (3.67) (1.80) (3.04) (0.93) (0.20)Income inequality 0.079 0.309(*) 0.043 0.154 -0.276 -0.212(0.93) (1.80) (0.36) (1.21) (1.40) (1.00)Nati<strong>on</strong>al income -0.114 0.116 0.249 0.479 -1.233* -0.146(0.49) (0.25) (0.70) (1.44) (2.27) (0.25)Unemployment rate 0.063* 0.022 0.013 -0.057 0.103 -0.013(1.97) (0.34) (0.30) (1.23) (1.40) (0.16)Closeness to border -0.241** 0.167 0.09 -0.161(*) -0.221 -0.456**(3.75) (1.33) (0.93) (1.79) (1.41) (2.86)Interacti<strong>on</strong> b. cant<strong>on</strong>s -0.006* 0.016** 0.004 0.018** 0.016* 0.024**(1.99) (2.92) (0.86) (4.46) (2.34) (3.39)Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> 0.004 0.015** -0.006(*) 0.015** 0.005 0.015*(1.64) (3.05) (1.68) (4.15) (0.80) (2.31)Cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> 0.200** 0.066 -0.136 -0.065 -0.379* -0.551**(3.21) (0.54) (1.46) (0.74) (2.54) (3.55)Residents 0 – 14 -0.078** -0.026 -0.200** 0.063 -0.222** -0.078(2.73) (0.47) (4.24) (1.55) (3.39) (1.09)Residents 15 – 24 0.048 0.256** 0.112* 0.142* -0.025 -0.089(1.23) (3.31) (2.06) (2.53) (0.27) (0.91)Residents 25 – 29 0.036 0.097 0.054 0.226** 0.247* 0.205(0.70) (0.94) (0.68) (3.03) (2.06) (1.57)Residents over 60 -0.051* 0.125** -0.092* 0.165** -0.010 -0.001(2.24) (2.77) (2.33) (5.10) (0.19) (0.01)Fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> 0.338 -0.382 -0.333 -0.856** 0.755 0.549(1.56) (0.89) (1.03) (2.73) (1.52) (1.01)Tax competiti<strong>on</strong> -0.199(*) -0.565* 0.071 0.004 -1.018** -0.760**(1.71) (2.47) (0.42) (0.03) (3.82) (2.60)Federal transfers 0.045 -0.204 -0.450** -0.405** 0.413(*) 0.02(0.45) (1.04) (3.14) (2.80) (1.76) (0.08)C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>straint 0.02 0.205** 0.02 0.038 0.305** 0.287**(0.61) (3.26) (0.37) (0.84) (4.10) (3.59)C<strong>on</strong>servative ideology -0.656** -0.129 -0.262 -0.049 -0.732(*) 0.232(3.50) (0.35) (0.99) (0.18) (1.70) (0.50)Size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> coaliti<strong>on</strong> 0.069(*) -0.06 -0.096 0.015 -0.125 -0.099(1.68) (0.74) (1.64) (0.25) (1.27) (0.97)Romance cant<strong>on</strong> -0.371* -0.334 -1.043** 0.014 -1.934** -0.172(2.35) (1.07) (4.68) (0.06) (5.34) (0.44)C<strong>on</strong>stant 5.808** -6.225 15.559** -4.642 13.256* 10.499(*)(2.68) (1.46) (4.47) (1.51) (2.55) (1.95)Observati<strong>on</strong>s 416 416 416 416 416 416Centered R2 0.81 0.65 0.59 0.67 0.47 0.35Jarque-Bera χ-value 2.90 50.62*** 1424.00*** 46.71*** 31.38*** 56.78***OLS with heteroscedasticity and autocorrelati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sistent standard errors for two lags. Absolute values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> t-statistics are in parentheses. (*) indicates significance at the 10%, * at the 5%, and ** at the 1% level. Year fixedeffects and measures <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> recording behavior are included but not reported.


– 173 –Violent CrimeTable 6 displays the results for violent crime when the total - i.e. the combined direct andindirect - impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy is analyzed in the reduced form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime.Again, the estimati<strong>on</strong> outcomes for violent and sex crimes are reported in columns (1) to (5).Of highest interest are the estimati<strong>on</strong> results for the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy in Swisscant<strong>on</strong>s. As already observed in the structural equati<strong>on</strong> specificati<strong>on</strong>, a c<strong>on</strong>siderable <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenseincreasing influence can be observed <strong>on</strong> the assault and hate crime rates. However, a str<strong>on</strong>gincreasing effect <strong>on</strong> sex crime stands out that c<strong>on</strong>tradicts the estimati<strong>on</strong> results reported forthe structural form. Apparently, the combined direct and indirect influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy leads to more sex crime, while the direct impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy isinsignificant. Since the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ordinary policemen significantly increases (reported) crimein the structural form 209 , however, the combined crime raising influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> sex crime is an interesting result that might be explained using the findings for the reducedform.As already observed for the reduced form, the severity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the punishment variable is notsignificant for any <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the violent and sexual <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenses. As regards the remaining determinants<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the traditi<strong>on</strong>al model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime, the analysis will again focus <strong>on</strong> the differences between theoutcomes for the reduced and the structural from <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model. Welfare payment exhibits theidentical pattern in both forms, as does income inequality and the unemployment rate. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> nati<strong>on</strong>al income in cant<strong>on</strong>s, however, exerts different influences in each form: in thereduced form, it is found to be positively associated with hate crime and sex crime, whereas inthe structural form it appears to significantly decrease almost all <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fense rates, excepthomicide rates.Am<strong>on</strong>g the ec<strong>on</strong>ogeographic variables, the influence from abroad reveals a significantlylowering impact <strong>on</strong> rates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> sexual <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenses, an outcome not obtained in the structural form,while for the remaining crime types the observed effect stays unchanged. On the other hand,the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interacti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong>s is rendered positive and str<strong>on</strong>glysignificant for all violent crimes, as previously c<strong>on</strong>jectured, and also for the occurrence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>rape. Only the latter impact coincides with the <strong>on</strong>e already observed in the structural model;209 For sex crimes, the positive impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ordinary policemen appears to <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fset the quantitatively smaller crimereducing influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> criminal detectives found in the reduced form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model.


– 174 –for other sex crimes, however, where previously an enhancing effect was revealed, nosignificant influence is found. With respect to the sociodemographic determinantstraditi<strong>on</strong>ally included in an estimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the ec<strong>on</strong>omic model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime, the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>urbanizati<strong>on</strong> is seen to be n<strong>on</strong>decisive for any type <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fense, which c<strong>on</strong>tradicts the resultsobtained for the structural form for assault, hate crime and sex crime. Moreover, in thereduced form, less violent crimes and rape occur in bigger cant<strong>on</strong>s, but more sexual <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fensesbel<strong>on</strong>ging to the category 'other sex crime'. In c<strong>on</strong>trast, the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong>was almost always rendered insignificant in the structural form, except a lowering impact inthe rape and homicide regressi<strong>on</strong>s. Further, in the reduced form, the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>alshare <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> residents 15 – 24 differs <strong>on</strong>ly with respect to other sex crimes, where it no l<strong>on</strong>gerappears important. Again, a higher ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pers<strong>on</strong>s between the age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 25 and 29 arepositively associated with rape. In additi<strong>on</strong> to the crime lowering effect <strong>on</strong> homicide and rapealready observed in the structural form, cant<strong>on</strong>al culture also appears to be an important, but<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fense rate raising determinant for assault, hate crimes, and other sex crimes in the reducedform.Again, estimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a reduced form model reveals the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> otherwise <strong>on</strong>ly indirectlyeffective determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime; i.e. the exogenous factors exclusively employed in structuralequati<strong>on</strong> (1). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> residents below the age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 14 does not appear at all decisive for anycrime, whereas the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pers<strong>on</strong>s over 60 exerts a crime raising influence <strong>on</strong> all <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fensesagainst pers<strong>on</strong> or morality and decency. Am<strong>on</strong>g the fiscal and political variables, the degree<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> and the amount <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> federal transfers are observed to beirrelevant; however, tax competiti<strong>on</strong> is found to be crime lowering for homicide, assault, hatecrimes, and rape but weakly rate increasing for sex crimes. Moreover, the fiscal c<strong>on</strong>straintappears to lead str<strong>on</strong>gly to more assault, hate crimes, and sexual <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenses, but no such effect isdetected for homicide. In additi<strong>on</strong>, a more c<strong>on</strong>servative government has a significantlystr<strong>on</strong>ger propensity to fight the commitment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> homicide and rape in comparis<strong>on</strong> to theremaining crime types <strong>on</strong> which no decisive influence is revealed. Finally, the morefragmented the government, the more it is associated with lower levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> other sex crimes.


– 175 –Table 6: Violent Crime and Sex Crime 1986–2001 Reduced Form(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)Homicide Assault Hate Crime Rape Sex CrimeSeverity 111, 122 - 123.combined severity, 187 0.000 0.001 0.001 -0.001 0.001(0.27) (0.39) (0.72) (1.07) (0.84)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy -0.057 0.237** 0.195*** -0.002 0.212**(0.92) (3.82) (3.44) (0.04) (3.19)Welfare transfers -0.017 0.499** 0.444*** 0.052 0.103(0.17) (5.45) (5.32) (0.61) (1.01)Income inequality 0.155 0.109 0.113 0.159 -0.102(1.23) (0.94) (1.07) (1.35) (0.74)Nati<strong>on</strong>al income 0.104 0.509 0.517(*) 0.066 0.756*(0.33) (1.64) (1.81) (0.22) (2.08)Unemployment rate -0.04 0.034 0.020 -0.021 -0.074(0.89) (0.78) (0.50) (0.49) (1.49)Closeness to border 0.235* -0.535** -0.468*** -0.201* -0.294**(2.27) (5.81) (5.58) (2.40) (2.88)Interacti<strong>on</strong> b. cant<strong>on</strong>s 0.015** 0.013** 0.015*** 0.015** 0.000(2.81) (3.02) (3.73) (3.84) (0.06)Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> 0.000 0.005 0.005 0.005 0.006(0.12) (1.38) (1.55) (1.60) (1.40)Cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> -0.296** -0.437** -0.478*** -0.272** 0.356**(2.60) (4.41) (5.07) (3.39) (3.66)Residents 0 – 14 0.039 -0.003 -0.005 0.035 -0.008(0.80) (0.09) (0.15) (0.91) (0.18)Residents 15 – 24 0.026 -0.094(*) -0.067 0.168** 0.089(0.42) (1.75) (1.35) (2.92) (1.29)Residents 25 – 29 0.125 0.115 0.109 0.255** -0.027(1.57) (1.55) (1.60) (3.60) (0.32)Residents over 60 0.076* 0.086** 0.094*** 0.175** 0.124**(2.05) (2.80) (3.28) (6.09) (3.57)Fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> 0.008 -0.262 -0.200 0.402 0.371(0.03) (0.88) (0.74) (1.40) (1.08)Tax competiti<strong>on</strong> -0.558** -0.513** -0.487** -0.306* 0.319(*)(2.88) (2.95) (3.01) (2.00) (1.73)Federal transfers -0.13 -0.143 -0.123 0.009 -0.103(0.97) (1.04) (1.00) (0.07) (0.66)C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>straint 0.034 0.355** 0.321*** 0.082* 0.110*(0.74) (7.24) (7.18) (1.98) (2.19)C<strong>on</strong>servative ideology -0.625* 0.197 0.182 -0.569* -0.202(2.46) (0.79) (0.80) (2.30) (0.68)Size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> coaliti<strong>on</strong> -0.019 -0.078 0.182 0.028 -0.264**(0.34) (1.38) (1.58) (0.53) (4.13)Romance cant<strong>on</strong> -0.511* 0.410(*) 0.379(*) -0.411(*) 0.504(*)(2.28) (1.90) (1.92) (1.87) (1.91)C<strong>on</strong>stant 0.283 5.700(*) 5.728* -5.156(*) -5.909(*)(0.08) (1.90) (2.11) (1.88) (1.78)Observati<strong>on</strong>s 384 416 416 416 416Centered R 2 0.34 0.65 0.57 0.50 0.49Jarque-Bera χ-value 4.02 40.20*** 17.39*** 13.12** 39.00***See table 5.


– 176 –5.4 Comparis<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Results for the Reduced and <strong>St</strong>ructural FormsWhereas the reduced form reveals the combined direct and indirect effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy<strong>on</strong> crime (B), the structural form explicitly makes the direct impact observable (A). Acomparis<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the results for both forms makes it possible to draw c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s about theunobserved indirect effect (the difference between B and A, B - A) 210 . As shown in secti<strong>on</strong>5.2, the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy significantly dampens police expenditure and reducespolice force size; therefore, a crime increasing unobserved indirect impact would be expected.On the other hand, gains in executive efficiency 211 in the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the public good 'publicsafety' are detectable that could (over)compensate for the fewer resources available. Based <strong>on</strong>the hypotheses <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> bounded rati<strong>on</strong>ality, some debiasing <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> both police administrators andregular policemen can be c<strong>on</strong>jectured that might explain which crimes efficiency gains at thecant<strong>on</strong>al police level might be observed for and which not. Table 7 briefly summarizes thedifferent influences <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> detected for both forms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model:<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>jectured crime increasing indirect influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> is str<strong>on</strong>glycorroborated for robbery, sex crime and weakly corroborated for assault and hate crimes 212 . Inthese cases, fewer available financial means for crime preventi<strong>on</strong> and crime protecti<strong>on</strong> do leadto higher crime rates through the subfederal budgetary channel.In the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fraud – and possibly also for burglary and auto theft 213 – the indirect impactthrough the budget even appears crime reducing, a finding that c<strong>on</strong>tradicts expectati<strong>on</strong>s. Eventhough fewer financial means are made available for police issues at the cant<strong>on</strong>al andcommunal level, these particular crimes are negatively affected. This is possibly a case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>executive super-efficiency in which fewer resources are allocated in such a way that thepublic good gains in quality, at least with respect to these crimes. In other words, even though210 This discussi<strong>on</strong> is based <strong>on</strong> the estimati<strong>on</strong> results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the previous regressi<strong>on</strong>s in tables 3 to 6, not the <strong>on</strong>eslisted in the Appendix. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s, however, do not change c<strong>on</strong>siderably when the regressi<strong>on</strong> resultswith outliers excluded are taken into account. Affected is the instituti<strong>on</strong>al impact <strong>on</strong> defalcati<strong>on</strong> and autotheft, which in turn, changes the c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> efficiency <strong>on</strong>ly in the last case. Furthermore, for any crime thedifferences (B – A) might always be insignificant, which would be interpreted as hinting at efficiency gains.211 Efficiency in the producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public safety at the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the police forces, i.e. executive efficiency, shouldnot be c<strong>on</strong>fused with the questi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an efficient allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> goods and resources at the societal level.212 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> indirect effect might also be insignificant.213 Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, in the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an insignificant indirect impact <strong>on</strong> burglary and auto theft, the result would alsobe interpreted as supporting efficiency gains (see next paragraph).


– 177 –the policemen in direct democratic cant<strong>on</strong>s are fewer, they carry out their work in a moreefficient way than their peers in more representative democratic cant<strong>on</strong>s 214 .Table 7: Influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> in the Reduced and <strong>St</strong>ructural FormsCrime type<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> EffectCombined <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> and IndirectIndirect Effect(<strong>St</strong>ructural Form)Effect(Reduced Form)A B B – ABurglary Negative Negative Negative orinsignificantPickpocketing Insignificant Insignificant InsignificantAuto theft Negative Negative Negative orinsignificantRobbery Negative Insignificant PositiveFraud Insignificant Negative NegativeDefalcati<strong>on</strong> Insignificant Insignificant InsignificantHomicide Insignificant Insignificant InsignificantAssault Positive Positive Positive orinsignificantHate crime Positive Positive Positive orinsignificantRape Insignificant Insignificant InsignificantSex crime Insignificant Positive PositiveAn unambiguously insignificant indirect influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy through the budget isdetected not <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong> the very severe crimes against pers<strong>on</strong>s – i.e. homicide and rape – but also<strong>on</strong> defalcati<strong>on</strong>. It must be c<strong>on</strong>cluded that this indirect impact through reducti<strong>on</strong> in policeexpenditure does not exert a decisive influence, which also runs c<strong>on</strong>trary to expectati<strong>on</strong>s.214 A decrease in reporting rates for these crimes is also possible, probably because there are fewer policemen toreport to. This interpretati<strong>on</strong>, however, is not very trustworthy as, in order to obtain their insurance benefits,victims have a str<strong>on</strong>g incentive to report burglaries and auto thefts particularly.


– 178 –<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, it is again suggested that, in more direct democratic cant<strong>on</strong>s, police forces musthave increased their efficiency in fighting these crime to <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fset their lower number.In sum, comparing the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the reduced form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model with those <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the structuralform reveals efficiency gains at the police level for some crimes in more direct democraticcant<strong>on</strong>s. Obviously, the disguised indirect impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> is not fully reflected bythe estimates obtained for the police force deterrents in the structural form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the ec<strong>on</strong>omicmodel <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime 215 . Efficiency gains in executi<strong>on</strong> can be observed for severe crimes againstpers<strong>on</strong> (rape, homicide) and the either infrequent or not so severe property crimes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fraud,defalcati<strong>on</strong>, and pickpocketing 216 . Most interesting, this group is comprised <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> those types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fenses for which no direct instituti<strong>on</strong>al crime dampening impact can be observed in thestructural form; i.e. those crimes that would potentially suffer from a reallocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> availablemeans as preferred by the median voter. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> interpretati<strong>on</strong> made here is that practiti<strong>on</strong>ers andpolice administrators try to compensate for the potentially crime increasing redistributiveeffect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> some crimes through efficiency gains achieved in theirproducti<strong>on</strong> process. Such unambiguously compensating efficiency gains are, however, notobservable for assault and sex crime. It may be that, since assault and other sex crimes are <strong>on</strong>average much less severe than homicide or rape, not attempting to achieve efficiency gains intheir preventi<strong>on</strong> is rati<strong>on</strong>al. Overall, Hypothesis 4, which proposes that bureaucrats andpractiti<strong>on</strong>ers are less subject to optimism bias and the availability heuristic than the comm<strong>on</strong>voter, appears to be corroborated by the observed executive efficiency gains for less frequentcrimes.6 C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>This chapter has presented an analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the relati<strong>on</strong> between a boundedly rati<strong>on</strong>al medianvoter and the allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> means for crime preventi<strong>on</strong> and crime detecti<strong>on</strong> through estimati<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an ec<strong>on</strong>omic model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime in the traditi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> BECKER (1968) and EHRLICH (1973). Giventhe newest empirical findings in the field <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic psychology, the median voter isc<strong>on</strong>jectured to suffer from an optimism bias when predicting the probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pers<strong>on</strong>ally215 In the structural form, other aspects like the equipment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the police forces are omitted.216 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> frauds is <strong>on</strong>e candidate for being seriously affected by cant<strong>on</strong>al heterogeneity in datacollecti<strong>on</strong>. Recording the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> victims or even sent letters instead <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> reported cases increases thenumber over 100 times. Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, the variati<strong>on</strong> appears quite str<strong>on</strong>g. Finally, fraud rates have risenrecently through the use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Internet. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se facts might explain why no crime rate decreasing impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>direct democracy is found in the structural model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime.


– 179 –becoming a victim <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime. Moreover, a severe mispredicti<strong>on</strong> is also hypothesized regardingthe average probability in society, meaning that fewer financial means should be spent <strong>on</strong>police issues in more direct democratic cant<strong>on</strong>s than otherwise. When such bias is combinedwith availability heuristic, the boundedly rati<strong>on</strong>al median voter should mispredict thelikelihood <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> occurrence to a greater extent for less frequent crimes than for more frequentfel<strong>on</strong>ies. Given the actual crime rates in Switzerland, a preference for fighting property crimescompared to preventing violent crimes is predicted.Using a synthetic panel <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>al crime rates from 1986 to 2001 and a set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>determinants, a structural and a reduced form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model is estimated. In general, theempirical evidence corroborates the hypotheses. First, estimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the structural formreveals an expenditure dampening and police force reducing impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy. Inadditi<strong>on</strong>, <strong>on</strong>ce the availability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> financial means is c<strong>on</strong>trolled for, direct democracy is foundto significantly decrease burglary, auto theft, and robbery rates but also to increase assaultrates. Estimating the reduced form and comparing it with the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the structural formreveals executive efficiency gains in the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public safety for most crimes that do notbenefit from a reallocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> given means induced by the median voter. This finding is in linewith the hypothesis that the optimism bias and availability heuristic are less prominent forpractiti<strong>on</strong>ers and police administrators.In sum, it is again shown that in direct democracies there exists an allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> goods andresources that appears to be c<strong>on</strong>sistent with the median voter's preferences, independent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>whether the median voter preference is objectively and societally the best allocati<strong>on</strong> or not.Hence, this result is in line with the traditi<strong>on</strong>al public choice literature <strong>on</strong> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>instituti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> political decisi<strong>on</strong> making and political outcomes. In this study, it is also shownthat administrators, who in the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime preventi<strong>on</strong> can be c<strong>on</strong>sidered less subject tohuman misjudgments, prefer an allocati<strong>on</strong> closer to the objectively and ec<strong>on</strong>omically bestallocati<strong>on</strong>. In particular, the additi<strong>on</strong>al resources devoted to meet the median voter'spreferences appear to be obtained through executive efficiency gains in fighting those crimesthat are less important to the median voter.For future research, it would appear valuable to combine approaches from the fields <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> publicchoice and ec<strong>on</strong>omic psychology and relax the perfect rati<strong>on</strong>ality assumpti<strong>on</strong> to makeec<strong>on</strong>omic models more suitable for explaining real world events.


– 180 –7 AppendixTable A.1: Crime Categories as Codified in the Swiss Criminal Code (<strong>St</strong>GB)Crime in estimati<strong>on</strong>outputArticles in <strong>St</strong>GBDescripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> articleHomicide 111 – 116111: killing112: murder113: manslaughter114: euthanasia115: assisting suicide116: infanticideAssault 122 – 123122: mayhem123: malicious injuryDefalcati<strong>on</strong> 138 138: defalcati<strong>on</strong>Pickpocketing 139 139: theftBurglary 139 139: theftAuto theft 139 139: theftRobbery 140 140: robberyFraud 146 146: fraudRape 190 190: rape <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a female pers<strong>on</strong>Sex crime187 – 189,191 – 194,198187: sexual abuse <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> children188: sexual abuse <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> minor adultdependants189: sexual assault191: rape <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> defenseless pers<strong>on</strong>s192: sexual abuse <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> dependants ininstituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> correcti<strong>on</strong>193: sexual abuse <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> dependants194: exhibiti<strong>on</strong>ism198: sexual harassment


– 181 –Table A.2: Security Expenditure 1986 – 2001(5) (6) (7)Security Nati<strong>on</strong>al defense Judicial system<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy -0.068** 0.033 -0.061*(3.09) (0.96) (2.30)Fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> -0.407** 0.449* -0.361(*)(2.70) (2.54) (1.82)Tax competiti<strong>on</strong> -0.194** 0.069 -0.207**(3.47) (0.59) (2.90)Federal transfers 0.050 0.042 0.011(1.11) (0.54) (0.19)C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>straint 0.006 0.018 0.039**(0.57) (0.81) (2.65)C<strong>on</strong>servative ideology 0.003 0.139 -0.028(0.03) (1.10) (0.24)Size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> coaliti<strong>on</strong> 0.004 -0.046 0.045(*)(0.18) (1.14) (1.68)Romance cant<strong>on</strong> -0.152* 0.215 -0.193*(2.10) (1.48) (2.19)Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> -0.001 -0.010** 0.004*(0.51) (3.61) (2.16)Nati<strong>on</strong>al income 0.697** 0.539** 0.453**(5.61) (2.63) (2.79)Cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> 0.039(*) -0.034 0.088**(1.69) (1.06) (3.13)Residents 0 – 14 -0.011 -0.016 -0.012(0.72) (0.62) (0.74)Residents 15 – 24 0.010 -0.129** 0.049*(0.49) (3.78) (2.03)Residents over 60 0.034** -0.031(*) 0.045**(3.22) (1.91) (3.96)C<strong>on</strong>stant -4.176** -0.568 -6.192**(3.89) (0.35) (5.34)Observati<strong>on</strong>s 416 416 416Centered R 2 0.77 0.68 0.80Jarque-Bera χ-value 0.80 210.00*** 7.03*2SLS with heteroscedasticity and autocorrelati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sistent standard errors for two lags.Absolute values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> t-statistics are in parentheses. Endogenous variable: fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong>.(*) indicates significance at the 10%, * at the 5%, and ** at the 1% level. Year fixed effects areincluded but not reported.


– 182 –Table A.3: Security Expenditure 1986 – 2001 with Lagged Crime Rates(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)Police Police Ordinary CriminalJudicialSecurity Defenseexpenditure force police detectivessystem<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy -0.125** -0.102** -0.075** -0.228** -0.078** 0.027 -0.075**(5.61) (5.02) (3.34) (5.40) (5.69) (0.81) (4.34)Assault crime rate 0.085** 0.064** 0.038* 0.144** 0.080** 0.064(*) 0.109**(3.77) (3.69) (2.13) (3.22) (5.66) (1.89) (5.40)<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ft crime rate 0.160** 0.215** 0.226** 0.141 0.150** -0.05 0.156**(3.50) (5.58) (4.60) (1.56) (4.04) (0.50) (2.67)Fiscaldecentralizati<strong>on</strong> -0.328(*) -0.056 -0.094 -0.017 -0.232* 0.499** -0.145(1.96) (0.36) (0.65) (0.05) (2.48) (2.61) (1.16)Tax competiti<strong>on</strong> -0.226** -0.004 -0.047 0.163 -0.151** 0.065 -0.159**(3.86) (0.07) (0.80) (1.35) (3.87) (0.54) (2.86)Federal transfers 0.172** 0.199** 0.138** 0.434** 0.073(*) 0.05 0.043(2.79) (3.71) (2.77) (3.67) (1.96) (0.66) (0.84)C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>alc<strong>on</strong>straint -0.025* -0.005 0.006 -0.031 0.004 0.023 0.039**(1.99) (0.34) (0.41) (1.08) (0.62) (1.01) (3.49)C<strong>on</strong>servativeideology 0.028 0.039 -0.093 0.541* 0.011 0.115 -0.026(0.25) (0.37) (0.87) (2.41) (0.16) (0.93) (0.33)Size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> coaliti<strong>on</strong> 0.01 -0.029 -0.035(*) -0.033 0.026(*) -0.038 0.072**(0.42) (1.41) (1.75) (0.60) (1.82) (0.99) (3.63)Romance cant<strong>on</strong> -0.302** -0.127 -0.093 -0.245 -0.196** 0.189 -0.251**(3.22) (1.59) (1.20) (1.43) (3.76) (1.37) (3.70)Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> 0.000 -0.002(*) -0.004** 0.005* 0.000 -0.009** 0.004**(0.06) (1.75) (3.02) (2.29) (0.16) (3.27) (3.05)Nati<strong>on</strong>al income 0.483** 0.339** 0.311* 0.543* 0.474** 0.470* 0.181(3.31) (2.88) (2.56) (2.09) (5.91) (2.24) (1.39)Cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> -0.032 -0.056* -0.046(*) -0.071(*) -0.009 -0.035 0.033(*)(1.24) (2.54) (1.95) (1.77) (0.62) (1.08) (1.66)Residents 0 – 14 -0.033(*) -0.066** -0.084** 0.011 -0.001 -0.022 -0.003(1.71) (3.83) (4.23) (0.42) (0.10) (0.82) (0.20)Residents 15 – 24 0.037(*) 0.029 0.006 0.090** -0.001 -0.124** 0.038(*)(1.96) (1.58) (0.29) (2.71) (0.07) (3.32) (1.93)Residents over 60 0.024(*) 0.035** 0.031* 0.050** 0.022* -0.037* 0.029**(1.96) (2.90) (2.15) (2.87) (2.55) (2.23) (3.12)C<strong>on</strong>stant -5.303** -8.963** -8.156** -14.258** -4.284** -0.139 -6.193**(4.20) (8.20) (6.35) (8.72) (5.61) (0.09) (7.40)Observati<strong>on</strong>s 416 416 416 416 416 416 416Centered R 2 0.82 0.83 0.82 0.51 0.86 0.68 0.872SLS with heteroscedasticity and autocorrelati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sistent standard errors for two lags. Absolute values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> t-statisticsare in parentheses. Endogenous variable: fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong>. (*) indicates significance at the 10%, * at the 5%, and** at the 1% level. Year fixed effects are included but not reported. Crime rates are lagged by two periods.


– 183 –Table A.4: Summary <strong>St</strong>atistics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Explanatory VariablesVariable Obs. Mean <strong>St</strong>d. Dev. Min Max<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy 416 4.261 1.211 1.583 5.833Real welfare transfers(no log) 416 0.255 0.147 0.0488 0.866Income inequality 416 1.214 0.253 0.746 1.898Nati<strong>on</strong>al income(no log) 416 27.009 6.049 18.608 53.997Unemployment rate 416 2.243 1.907 0 7.800Closeness to border 416 0.269 0.444 0 1Interacti<strong>on</strong> b. cant<strong>on</strong>s 416 16.505 17.157 0.901 81.450Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> 416 59.142 24.041 14.063 100Populati<strong>on</strong> (no log) 416 266505.9 276036.3 13137 1228628Residents 0 – 14 416 18.291 2.210 11.268 23.172Residents 15 – 24 416 13.127 1.738 10.073 17.874Residents 25 – 29 416 7.533 0.861 5.161 9.495Residents over 60 416 18.366 2.888 11.584 27.073Fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> 416 0.394 0.176 0.004 0.978Tax competiti<strong>on</strong> (no log) 416 0.233 0.078 0.096 0.419Federal transfers(no log) 416 302.022 115.906 150.452 914.377C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>straint 416 0.339 0.863 0 3C<strong>on</strong>servative ideology 416 -0.098 0.184 -0.6 0.4Size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> coaliti<strong>on</strong> 416 3.310 0.871 1 5Romance cant<strong>on</strong> 416 0.269 0.444 0 1Severity art. 111 384 217 73.309 30.23066 0 100Severity art. 122/123 416 17.444 13.91414 0 100Severity art. 187 416 19.040 18.46005 0 100Severity art. 139 416 25.514 9.470814 0 66.7Severity art. 140 416 42.141 24.84547 0 100Severity art. 146 416 23.711 14.37432 0 100Severity art. 138 416 19.065 17.89831 0 100Criminal detectives percapita (no log) 416 0.0003689 0.0001769 0.0000484 0.0010211Ordinary policemen percapita (no log) 416 0.0015139 0.0005898 0.0005924 0.0039329217 In two cant<strong>on</strong>s, the severity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> punishment variable is missing. For this reas<strong>on</strong>, in the homicide regressi<strong>on</strong>s<strong>on</strong>ly 384 observati<strong>on</strong>s are used.


– 184 –Table A.5: Security Expenditure 1986 – 2001, Outliers Excluded(1) (4) (6) (7)PoliceexpenditureCriminaldetectivesNati<strong>on</strong>alDefenseJudicialsystem<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy -0.117** -0.203** 0.044(*) -0.057*(4.25) (5.53) (1.88) (2.22)Fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> -0.437* -0.512 0.650** -0.445*(2.48) (1.56) (4.65) (2.36)Tax competiti<strong>on</strong> -0.269** 0.122 0.178** -0.218**(3.81) (1.18) (2.79) (3.21)Federal transfers 0.140* 0.332** 0.036 -0.009(2.26) (3.31) (0.73) (0.15)C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>straint -0.022 -0.018 -0.011 0.041**(1.64) (0.79) (0.89) (2.94)C<strong>on</strong>servative ideology 0.042 0.437* 0.082 -0.015(0.31) (2.45) (0.84) (0.14)Size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> coaliti<strong>on</strong> -0.013 -0.152** -0.084** 0.041(0.47) (3.77) (3.10) (1.62)Romance cant<strong>on</strong> -0.244* -0.049 0.374** -0.175*(2.53) (0.38) (4.28) (2.14)Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> 0.000 0.001 -0.015** 0.003(0.21) (0.62) (10.39) (1.50)Nati<strong>on</strong>al income 0.732** 0.939** 0.700** 0.560**(4.46) (4.32) (4.63) (3.52)Cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> 0.014 -0.025 0.003 0.088**(0.44) (0.71) (0.14) (3.29)Residents 0 – 14 -0.046* -0.006 -0.052** -0.009(2.10) (0.22) (3.14) (0.55)Residents 15 – 24 0.047* 0.055 -0.143** 0.035(2.08) (1.46) (6.94) (1.47)Residents over 60 0.037** 0.055** -0.034** 0.046**(2.88) (2.99) (3.10) (4.29)C<strong>on</strong>stant -5.095** -12.740** -0.072 -6.252**(3.53) (7.34) (0.06) (5.61)Observati<strong>on</strong>s 412 396 389 410Centered R 2 0.78 0.60 0.83 0.82Jarque-Bera χ-value 3.72 3.04 3.95 4.172SLS with heteroscedasticity and autocorrelati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sistent standard errors for two lags. Absolutevalues <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> t-statistics are in parentheses. Endogenous variable: fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong>. (*) indicatessignificance at the 10%, * at the 5%, and ** at the 1% level. Year fixed effects are included but notreported.Excluded outliers are: in regressi<strong>on</strong> (1): Uri (1989, 1990), and Glarus (1991) and Tessin (1988) inregressi<strong>on</strong> (4): Zürich (1986 - 1996), Uri (1986 - 1990), Schwyz (2001), Graubünden (1986), Thurgau(2000) and Jura (1998); in regressi<strong>on</strong> (6): Luzern (1999), Uri (2000), Obwalden (1988), Nidwalden(1986 - 1988, 1999, 2000, 2001), Glarus (1994), Freiburg (1989, 1990), Solothurn (1992 - 1995),Appenzell Innerrhoden (1994, 1996, 1997), Tessin (1986), Jura (1986, 1987, 1990, 1998 - 2001), and,finally, in regressi<strong>on</strong> (7): Glarus (1988 - 1992) and Appenzell Innerrhoden (2001).


– 185 –Table A.6: Property Crime, Outliers Excluded, <strong>St</strong>ructural Form(2) (3) (4) (5) (6)Pickpocketing Auto <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ft Robbery Fraud Defalcati<strong>on</strong>Criminal Detectives 0.129 -0.372* -0.898** 0.620 1.521**(0.42) (2.02) (2.67) (1.16) (2.96)Ordinary Policemen 1.052** 0.427** 1.274** 1.322** 0.384(4.78) (3.05) (4.77) (4.09) (1.23)Severity 139 0.01 0.003(1.40) (1.00)Severity 140 0.000(0.02)Severity 146 -.001(0.35)Severity 138 -0.003(1.13)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy 0.053 -0.107(*) -0.218* -0.014 -0.218*(0.57) (1.78) (2.50) (0.10) (2.02)Welfare transfers 0.261* 0.155 0.457** -0.077 -0.279(*)(2.12) (1.50) (3.30) (0.44) (1.89)Income inequality 0.105 0.046 -0.026 -0.16 -0.004(0.64) (0.51) (0.17) (0.76) (0.02)Nati<strong>on</strong>al income -0.455 0.547** -0.051 -1.537** -1.526**(1.11) (2.73) (0.14) (3.67) (3.15)Unemployment rate 0.026 0.033 -0.013 0.02 -0.059(0.44) (0.90) (0.26) (0.27) (0.78)Closeness to border 0.408** 0.053 0.147 0.031 -0.399**(4.49) (0.69) (1.50) (0.18) (3.26)Interacti<strong>on</strong> betweencant<strong>on</strong>s 0.010(*) 0.002 0.038** -0.007 -0.016(1.71) (0.44) (4.98) (0.70) (1.55)Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> 0.013** 0.005* 0.013** 0.009* 0.012**(4.24) (2.40) (4.30) (2.23) (3.25)Cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> 0.218(*) -0.034 -0.482** 0.2 0.088(1.84) (0.42) (3.25) (0.95) (0.46)Residents 15 – 24 0.191** 0.151** 0.087 0.095 -0.096(3.25) (3.93) (1.38) (1.33) (1.40)Residents 25 – 29 -0.021 0.155** 0.171(*) 0.061 -0.016)(0.27) (3.07) (1.88) (0.47) (0.15)Romance cant<strong>on</strong> -0.395* -0.937** -0.360* -1.164** -0.471(*)(2.25) (8.19) (2.02) (3.81) (1.87)C<strong>on</strong>stant 5.269* 2.496* 7.327** 18.601** 23.583**(2.52) (2.26) (3.48) (4.82) (6.61)Observati<strong>on</strong>s 404 400 411 415 394Centered R 2 0.73 0.64 0.53 0.44 0.29Jarque-Bera χ-value 3.75 3.90 3.94 2.85 3.982SLS with heteroscedasticity and autocorrelati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sistent standard errors for two lags. Absolute values<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> t-statistics are in parentheses. Endogenous variables: Criminal detectives and ordinary policemen. (*)indicates significance at the 10%, * at the 5%, and ** at the 1% level. Year fixed effects and measures <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>recording behavior are included but not reported. Excluded outliers are displayed in table A.10.


– 186 –Table A.7: Violent Crime and Sex Crime, Outliers Excluded, <strong>St</strong>ructural Form(2) (3) (4) (5)Assault Hate Crime Rape Sex CrimeCriminal Detectives 0.432* 0.430* -0.487(*) -0.899*(2.58) (2.57) (1.95) (2.31)Ordinary Policemen 0.849** 0.834** 1.275** 1.715**(5.60) (4.96) (4.70) (4.13)Severity 122 123 0.001(0.69)Severity 0.000(0.32)Severity 187 -0.002 0.001(1.40) (0.37)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy 0.137* 0.111(*) 0.052 0.086(2.42) (1.93) (0.78) (0.90)Welfare transfers 0.360** 0.336** 0.102 0.111(3.78) (3.95) (1.15) (0.87)Income inequality -0.129 -0.121 -0.058 -0.122(1.11) (1.12) (0.52) (0.81)Nati<strong>on</strong>al income -0.691** -0.739** -0.111 -0.643*(2.77) (3.14) (0.48) (2.05)Unemployment rate -0.025 -0.022 0.005 -0.071(0.67) (0.63) (0.11) (1.33)Closeness to border -0.353** -0.306** 0.204* 0.053(4.24) (4.00) (2.47) (0.47)Interacti<strong>on</strong> between cant<strong>on</strong>s -0.004 -0.003 0.028** 0.022**(0.96) (0.47) (4.48) (2.67)Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> -0.003 -0.003 0.004* 0.012**(1.45) (1.50) (2.01) (4.07)Cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> 0.081 0.045 -0.480** -0.139(0.89) (0.36) (4.32) (0.93)Residents 15 – 24 -0.06 -0.045 0.157* 0.269**(1.51) (1.16) (2.53) (2.91)Residents 25 – 29 -0.098 -0.088 0.09 0.025(1.37) (1.30) (1.32) (0.27)Romance cant<strong>on</strong> 0.037 -0.013 -0.154 -0.189(0.24) (0.09) (0.97) (0.94)C<strong>on</strong>stant 16.014** 16.281** 8.500** 5.915**(9.60) (8.90) (5.39) (2.72)Observati<strong>on</strong>s 406 406 401 407Centered R 2 0.62 0.63 0.44 0.32Jarque-Bera χ-value 2.21 2.56 2.78 3.87See table A.6.


– 187 –Table A.8: Property Crime, Outliers Excluded, Reduced Form(2) (3) (4) (5) (6)Pickpocketing Auto <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ft Robbery Fraud Defalcati<strong>on</strong>Severity 139, 140, 146 0.004 0.001 0.002(*) 0.001 -0.006**(1.09) (0.45) (1.70) (0.38) (3.40)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy 0.042 -0.017 -0.035 -0.192* -0.300**(0.61) (0.47) (0.66) (1.97) (3.28)Welfare transfers 0.441** 0.130* 0.385** 0.16 0.171(4.01) (2.30) (4.56) (1.07) (1.25)Income inequality 0.275(*) 0.059 0.108 -0.228 -0.023(1.92) (0.89) (0.98) (1.18) (0.13)Nati<strong>on</strong>al income 0.161 0.197 0.174 -1.176* -0.396(0.42) (0.99) (0.60) (2.21) (0.83)Unemployment rate -0.018 0.091** -0.036 0.113 -0.03(0.34) (3.57) (0.92) (1.56) (0.46)Closeness to border 0.088 0.017 -0.127 -0.212 -0.575**(0.84) (0.33) (1.62) (1.38) (4.32)interacti<strong>on</strong> b. cant<strong>on</strong>s 0.012** 0.000 0.015** 0.015* 0.016**(2.70) (0.17) (4.49) (2.31) (2.76)Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> 0.016** -0.005* 0.019** 0.004 0.021**(3.89) (2.36) (5.86) (0.70) (4.08)Cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> 0.141 0.05 -0.024 -0.344* -0.553**(1.38) (0.95) (0.32) (2.34) (4.32)Residents 0 – 14 0.012 -0.118** 0.116** -0.207** -0.033(0.25) (4.52) (3.29) (3.22) (0.56)Residents 15 – 24 0.241** 0.005 0.118* -0.005 -0.017(3.77) (0.17) (2.38) (0.05) (0.21)Residents 25 – 29 0.164(*) 0.111* 0.237** 0.241* 0.238*(1.93) (2.56) (3.67) (2.05) (2.21)Residents over 60 0.141** -0.091** 0.180** 0.002 0.087(*)(3.75) (4.18) (6.51) (0.03) (1.82)Fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> -0.468 -0.562** -0.682* 0.792 0.701(1.32) (3.15) (2.51) (1.62) (1.56)Tax competiti<strong>on</strong> -0.656** -0.219* 0.079 -1.084** -0.617*(3.46) (2.31) (0.55) (4.12) (2.55)Federal transfers -0.200 0.075 -0.175 0.414(*) 0.301(1.23) (0.89) (1.38) (1.81) (1.47)C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>straint 0.169** 0.028 0.033 0.304** 0.347**(3.25) (0.98) (0.84) (4.15) (5.23)C<strong>on</strong>servative ideology -0.387 -0.471** -0.01 -0.843* 0.646(*)(1.26) (3.24) (0.04) (1.99) (1.67)Size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> coaliti<strong>on</strong> -0.027 -0.132** 0.093(*) -0.105 -0.087(0.41) (4.03) (1.79) (1.09) (1.03)Romance cant<strong>on</strong> -0.435(*) -1.077** -0.022 -1.982** -0.326(1.65) (8.80) (0.11) (5.57) (1.00)C<strong>on</strong>stant -8.449* 9.602** -6.770* 11.710* 6.422(2.38) (4.94) (2.56) (2.29) (1.44)Observati<strong>on</strong>s 401 389 404 415 402Centered R 2 0.73 0.79 0.73 0.49 0.49Jarque-Bera χ-value 4.36 3.39 4.05 2.71 0.55OLS with heteroscedasticity and autocorrelati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sistent standard errors for two lags. Absolute values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> t-statisticsare in parentheses. (*) indicates significance at the 10%, * at the 5%, and ** at the 1% level. Year fixed effects andmeasures <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> recording behavior are included but not reported. Excluded outliers are displayed in table A.10.


– 188 –Table A.9: Violent and Hate Crime, Outliers Excluded, Reduced Form(2) (3) (4) (5)Assault Hate Crime Rape Sex CrimeSeverity 122-123,(111, 122, 123 combined), 187 0.001 0.001 -0.001 0.001(0.38) (0.69) (0.91) (0.94)<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy 0.193** 0.169** -0.001 0.193**(3.33) (3.18) (0.02) (3.17)Welfare transfers 0.489** 0.467** 0.049 0.058(5.84) (6.10) (0.61) (0.62)Income inequality 0.086 0.098 0.147 -0.168(0.81) (1.02) (1.33) (1.34)Nati<strong>on</strong>al income 0.444 0.409 0.131 0.886**(1.52) (1.55) (0.46) (2.64)Unemployment rate 0.017 0.005 -0.03 -0.042(0.42) (0.14) (0.77) (0.92)Closeness to border -0.517** -0.465** -0.192* -0.286**(6.11) (6.08) (2.43) (3.03)Interacti<strong>on</strong> between cant<strong>on</strong>s 0.013** 0.013** 0.013** (0.000)(3.12) (3.56) (3.59) (0.00)Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> 0.004 0.004 0.006(*) 0.004(1.25) (1.18) (1.95) (1.03)Cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> -0.439** -0.434** -0.236** 0.323**(4.86) (5.03) (3.14) (3.62)Residents 0 - 14 -0.03 -0.035 0.048 -0.015(0.81) (1.04) (1.31) (0.34)Residents 15 - 24 -0.081 -0.066 0.176** 0.049(1.64) (1.45) (3.26) (0.77)Residents 25 - 29 0.058 0.045 0.224** 0.016(0.82) (0.71) (3.36) (0.20)Residents over 60 0.073* 0.071** 0.174** 0.122**(2.57) (2.68) (6.46) (3.80)Fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> -0.104 -0.164 0.264 0.568(*)(0.38) (0.67) (0.97) (1.80)Tax competiti<strong>on</strong> -0.497** -0.478** -0.282* 0.428*(3.13) (3.23) (1.97) (2.53)Federal transfers (0.156 -0.139 -0.003 -0.132(1.23) (1.21) (0.03) (0.92)C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>straint 0.334** 0.304** 0.062 0.116*(7.44) (7.45) (1.59) (2.51)C<strong>on</strong>servative ideology 0.139 0.096 -0.581* -0.115(0.61) (0.46) (2.50) (0.43)Size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> coaliti<strong>on</strong> -0.088(*) -0.094* 0.044 -0.288**(1.68) (1.99) (0.87) (4.91)Romance cant<strong>on</strong> 0.363(*) 0.322(*) -0.399(*) 0.549*(1.81) (1.77) (1.93) (2.28)C<strong>on</strong>stant 7.349** 7.494** -5.820* -4.951(2.67) (3.01) (2.26) (1.63)Observati<strong>on</strong>s 410 409 413 408Centered R 2 0.68 0.70 0.52 0.54Jarque-Bera χ-value 3.17 0.19 3.49 0.42See table A.8.


– 189 –Table A.10: Deleted Observati<strong>on</strong>s as Outliers in the Crime Regressi<strong>on</strong>s<strong>St</strong>ructural FormAssault Obwalden (1988), Nidwalden (1996),Zug (1993), Freiburg (1993), Basel-Land (1992), Schaffhausen (1990),Tessin (1986, 1987, 1988), Jura(1986).Hate Crime Uri (1990), Obwalden (1988),Nidwalden (1996), Zug (1993),Freiburg (1993), Schaffhausen (1990),Tessin (1986 – 1988), Jura (1986).Rape Nidwalden (2001), Zug (1993, 1995,1998, 1999) Basel-Land (1990, 1993 -1996), Aargau (2001), Thurgau(2001), Waadt (2000), and Jura(1992).Sex Crime Uri (1994), Nidwalden (1994),Appenzell Innerrhoden (1990, 1992,1999), Aargau (1992), Thurgau(2000), Tessin (1989), Jura (1998).Reduced FormSchwyz (1987), Nidwalden (1996),Appenzell Innerrhoden (1999), Tessin(1986, 1988), Jura (1986).Schwyz (1987), Obwalden (1988),Nidwalden (1996), Aargau (2001),Tessin (1986, 1988), Jura (1986).Zug (1999), Basel-Land (1995),Thurgau (2001).Nidwalden (1994), Freiburg (1993),Appenzell Ausserrhoden (1990),Appenzell Innerrhoden (1993, 1996,1999), Aargau (1992, 1997).Pickpocketing Schwyz (1990, 1992, 2000),Obwalden (1996), Zug (1995 – 1998),Solothurn (1995), Basel-Land (2000),Waadt (1989, 1990).Auto <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ftRobberyUri (1988), Obwalden (1998), Zug(1996 – 1999), Wallis (1995 – 2001).Uri (1998), Schwyz (1986), Zug(1995, 1996), Graubünden (1986).Schwyz (1989, 1990, 1992, 2000),Obwalden (1996), Nidwalden (1990),Zug (1997), Solothurn (1995), Basel-Land (2000), Schaffhausen (1989),Aargau (1988), Waadt (1986, 1989,1990, 1998).Schwyz (1986, 1987, 1999 – 2001),Obwalden (1998), Glarus (1986 –1988), Zug (1996, 1997, 1998, 1999),Solothurn (1990, 1991, 1994),Appenzell Ausserrhoden (1993, 1996,1997), Wallis (1995 – 2001).Uri (1992), Schwyz (1986, 1989),Obwalden (1996), Glarus (1987,1997), Zug (1988, 2000), AppenzellAusserrhoden (1989, 1990, 1995,2000).Fraud Nidwalden (1996). Nidwalden (1996).Defalcati<strong>on</strong> Uri (1989 – 1991), Nidwalden (2000),Schaffhausen (1990, 1996), Aargau(1986 – 1999), Thurgau (2000), Genf(1999).Nidwalden (2000), Schaffhausen(1996), Graubünden (2001), Aargau(1989 – 1999).


– 190 –Table A.11: Descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> VariablesVariable Formula Type <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> variable SourceDeterrentsCriminal detectives Log (criminal detectives / populati<strong>on</strong>) c<strong>on</strong>tinuous BAP, full time equivalentsOrdinary policemen Log(ordinary policemen / populati<strong>on</strong>) c<strong>on</strong>tinuous BAP, full time equivalentsSeverity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> punishmentUnsuspended sentences / total sentences c<strong>on</strong>tinuous BFS(art. 111, 122/123, 138, 139, 140, 146,178 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Swiss criminal code)Instituti<strong>on</strong>al determinant<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy Index from 1 (minimum) to 6 (maximum) c<strong>on</strong>tinuous Own calculati<strong>on</strong>s / STUTZER (1999)Ec<strong>on</strong>omic variablesWelfare transfers Log(deflated welfare payments / populati<strong>on</strong>) c<strong>on</strong>tinuous BFS, SECO (deflator)Income inequalityMean household income / median householdc<strong>on</strong>tinuousFTA (1986 - 1998; biannually); SHPincome(1999 - 2001; annually)190


– 191 –Table A.11: Descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Variables (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Variable Formula Type <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> variable SourceNati<strong>on</strong>al incomeLog(deflated nati<strong>on</strong>al income in 1000 Sfr/c<strong>on</strong>tinuousBFS;populati<strong>on</strong>)Unemployment rate Officially recorded unemployed / labor force c<strong>on</strong>tinuous SECO, BFS (labor force)Federal transfers Log (deflated federal transfers / populati<strong>on</strong>) BFS, SECO (deflator)Fiscal variablesFiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong>1-(cant<strong>on</strong>al total expenditure /cant<strong>on</strong>al + localc<strong>on</strong>tinuousOwn calculati<strong>on</strong>s, BFSexpenditure)Tax competiti<strong>on</strong>Tax competiti<strong>on</strong> for cant<strong>on</strong> i = [Sum (tax(j)*c<strong>on</strong>tinuousOwn calculati<strong>on</strong>s, FTAinverse distance (ij)) ]/ 25C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>straint Index from 1 to 3 (strictest) categorical G. KIRCHGÄSSNERC<strong>on</strong>servative ideologyShare <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> rightist parties in executive – sharec<strong>on</strong>tinuousOwn calculati<strong>on</strong>s based <strong>on</strong> issues <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> leftist partiesAnnée Politique SuisseSize <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> coaliti<strong>on</strong>Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> parties / independent members inc<strong>on</strong>tinuousOwn calculati<strong>on</strong>s based <strong>on</strong> issues <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>governmentAnnée Politique Suisse191


– 192 –Table A.11: Descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Variables (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Variable Formula Type <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> variable SourceEc<strong>on</strong>ogeographic variablesCloseness to borderAt least <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the ten most important borderdichotomousFederal Office <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Spatial Development;crossings is closely located to the cant<strong>on</strong>;importance is given if >6,000 cars per day in2001Interacti<strong>on</strong> between cant<strong>on</strong>s I(ij) = (Pop i *Pop j )/absolute distance ij ; c<strong>on</strong>tinuous Own calculati<strong>on</strong>s, BFS (populati<strong>on</strong>),www.michelin.de (distances)Sociodemographic variablesUrbanizati<strong>on</strong> Residents in urbanized areas (>10,000inhabitants)/ populati<strong>on</strong>c<strong>on</strong>tinuousBFSCant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong>Log(permanent residential populati<strong>on</strong> at thec<strong>on</strong>tinuousBFSend <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the year 218 )218 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> BFS defines permanent residents as Swiss people and foreigners holding a C- or B-permit. Seas<strong>on</strong>ally admitted residents are excluded.192


– 194 –Questi<strong>on</strong>naires


– 195 –Fragebogen über die Erstellung der polizeilichen KriminalstatistikKlassifikati<strong>on</strong> der Delikte Nummer 1, 2, 4, 5, 6, 7, 9, 17, 18 der polizeilichenKriminalstatistik, wie sie m<strong>on</strong>atlich dem Bundesamt für Polizei (BAP) gemeldet wird(Delikte gegen die Pers<strong>on</strong>, gegen das Eigentum und gegen die sexuelle Integrität).Bitte beantworten Sie die Fallfragen (ab Seite 2) so, als ob Sie die Delikte für das m<strong>on</strong>atlicheMeldeblatt an das BAP aufnehmen würden. Bitte kreuzen Sie richtige Antworten an bzw.geben Sie die entsprechende Zahl an. Gerne dürfen Sie Kommentare und Bemerkungenhinzufügen (siehe auch die letzte Seite). Alle Angaben werden selbstverständlich vertraulichbehandelt.Allgemeine Fragen:Wenn ein (1) Verbrechen mit mehreren Opfern (x) begangen wurde, wird dies in demm<strong>on</strong>atlichen Meldeblatt für das BAP aufgenommen als:a) ein (1) begangenes Verbrechenb) als (x) begangene Verbrechen (x = Zahl der Opfer)c) dies ist v<strong>on</strong> Delikt zu Delikt unterschiedlichWenn ein schweres und ein leichteres Delikt in Tateinheit begangen worden sind, erscheintauf dem Meldeblatta) lediglich das schwere Verbrechenb) lediglich das leichte Deliktc) beide Delikte ( a) und b) )c) kann man so pauschal nicht sagenIst Ihre Erfassungsmethode für das BAP v<strong>on</strong> heute die selbe wie die des Jahres 1998 ?a) ja / mit hoher Wahrscheinlichkeitb) neinc) Ich weiss es nicht.Ist Ihre Erfassungsmethode v<strong>on</strong> heute die selbe wie die des Jahres 1986 ?a) ja / mit hoher Wahrscheinlichkeitb) neinc) Ich weiss es nicht.Gab es eine wichtige Änderung zwischen 1986 und heute in der polizeilichenErfassungspraxis für das BAP? Dann geben Sie bitte das ungefähre Jahr an (mehrereNennungen möglich):


– 196 –Halten Sie die Erfassungspraxis (in den Gemeinden) in Ihrem Kant<strong>on</strong> für einheitlich?a) ja (relativ homogen)b) nein (relativ heterogen)c) Frage ist nicht anwendbarDelikt 1 / Delikt 2 (Mord / Totschlag / Körperverletzung)Fall 1:2 Kriminelle töten zusammen ein Opfer.Dieses Verbrechen wird dem BAP gemeldet als:a) 1 Tötungsdelikt (Delikt 1)a) 2 Tötungsdelikte (Delikt 1)Fall 2:1 Krimineller tötet eine Familie v<strong>on</strong> 4 Pers<strong>on</strong>en.Dieses Verbrechen wird für das BAP erfasst als:a) 1 Tötungsdelikta) 4 TötungsdelikteFall 3:Ein Amokläufer tötet 1 Pers<strong>on</strong> und verletzt leicht einen Passanten.Dieses Verbrechen wird für das BAP erfasst als:a) 1 (vollendetes) Tötungsdeliktb) 1 Körperverletzungc) 1 (versuchtes) Tötungsdeliktd) als Kombinati<strong>on</strong> aus ______ und _________und ________Delikt 4 / Delikt 5 / Delikt 6 (Diebstahl / Entreissdiebstahl / Einbruchdiebstahl)Fall 4:Eine Pers<strong>on</strong> auf einem fahrenden Moped entreisst einer Passantin ihre Handtasche.Dieses Verbrechen wird dem BAP gemeldet als:a) Entreissdiebstahl (Delikt 5)b) Diebstahl (Delikt 4)c) eine Kombinati<strong>on</strong> aus a) and b)


– 197 –Fall 5:Eine Pers<strong>on</strong> entdeckt, dass Ihre Geldbörse aus ihrer Hosentasche verschwunden ist. Sie istüberzeugt, dass diese gestohlen worden sein muss.Dieses Delikt wird für das BAP erfasst alsa) Diebstahl (Delikt 4)b) Entreissdiebstahl (Delikt 5)c) eine Kombinati<strong>on</strong> aus a) und b)Fall 6:Eine Pers<strong>on</strong> meldet der Polizei, dass das Schloss der Haupteingangstüre ihres Wohnhausesbeschädigt und dass eine Fensterscheibe zerschlagen worden ist. Sie glaubt, dass jemanderfolglos versucht hat, in ihr Haus einzubrechen.Dieses Delikt wird für das BAP aufgenommen alsa) Sachbeschädigungb) (versuchter) Einbruchdiebstahlc) als Kombinati<strong>on</strong> aus a) und b)Fall 7:Eine Verbrecherbande aus 4 Pers<strong>on</strong>en bricht in derselben Nacht in 2 Wohnhäuser ein undstiehlt einige wertvolle Gemälde.Dieses Verbrechen wird dem BAP gemeldet als:a) ______ Einbruchdiebstahl(e) (Delikt 6)b) ______ Sachbeschädigung(en)c) eine Kombinati<strong>on</strong> aus a) und b)d) keines, s<strong>on</strong>dern_______________________________________________Delikt 7 (Autodiebstahl) / Delikt 9 (Betrug)Fall 8:Eine Pers<strong>on</strong> verschickt 500 Briefe, um eine lukrative Geldanlage mittels einesSchneeballsystems vorzutäuschen.Dieses Verbrechen wird dem BAP gemeldet als:a) 500 Betrugsfälle / Betrügereienb) 1 BetrugFall 9:Eine Bande v<strong>on</strong> 3 Kriminellen stiehlt 10 Autos innerhalb der letzten 2 Wochen.Dieses Verbrechen wird für das BAP aufgenommen alsa) ________ Autodiebstahl/ Autodiebstähle (Delikt 7)


– 198 –Frage:Was wird neben dem Diebstahl v<strong>on</strong> Automobilen noch in die Kategorie 7 aufgenommen:a) Diebstahl ganzer Schiffe / Booteb) Diebstahl v<strong>on</strong> Schiffsmotorenc) Schidiebstahld) Entwendung v<strong>on</strong> Fahrzeugen zum blossen Gebrauche) Fahrraddiebstahlf) Diebstahl v<strong>on</strong> Motorrädern, Kleinmotorrädern und Motorfahrräderng) andere, nämlich_________________________________Delikt 17 / Delikt 18 (Vergewaltigung / Unzuchtsdelikte)Fall 9:Eine Frau kommt zur Polizei und behauptet, sie sei vergewaltigt worden. Aufgrund ihrerZeugenaussage ist nicht klar, ob es sich um eine Vergewaltigung (Art. 190) oder ‘lediglich’um eine sexuelle Nötigung (Art. 189) handelt.Dieses Verbrechen wird für das BAP aufgenommen alsa) Vergewaltigung (Delikt 17)b) Unzuchtsdelikt (Delikt 18)c) sowohl a) als auch b)Fall 10:3 Männer vergewaltigen 2 Frauen am selben Ort zur selben Zeit.Dieses Verbrechen wird für das BAP aufgenommen alsa) _____ Vergewaltigung(en)Vielen Dank für Ihre Kooperati<strong>on</strong> !!!__________________________________________________________________________Raum für zusätzliche Kommentare:Datum:................................Name:........................................................Korps:.........................................


– 199 –Questi<strong>on</strong>naire c<strong>on</strong>cernant le relevé des infracti<strong>on</strong>s pour la statistique policièrede la criminalitéClassificati<strong>on</strong>s des infracti<strong>on</strong>s numéro 1, 2, 4, 5, 6, 7, 9, 17, 18 de la statistique policière de lacriminalité comme elle est communiquée mensuellement à l’Office Fédéral de la Police(OFP) (infracti<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>tre la pers<strong>on</strong>ne, c<strong>on</strong>tre la propriété et c<strong>on</strong>tre l'intégrité sexuelle).Veuillez, s.v.p., rép<strong>on</strong>dre aux questi<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>cernant les affaires criminelles modèles (page 2c<strong>on</strong>t.), comme si vous enregistriez ces infracti<strong>on</strong>s dans la statistique policière mensuelle pourl'OFP. Cochez les rép<strong>on</strong>ses correctes et remplissez les chiffres corresp<strong>on</strong>dants. Vous pouvezaussi commenter les questi<strong>on</strong>s / rép<strong>on</strong>ses (voir aussi la dernière page). Toutes les informati<strong>on</strong>sser<strong>on</strong>t traitées c<strong>on</strong>fidentiellement.Questi<strong>on</strong>s générales:S’il y a plusieurs (x) victimes d’une (1) infracti<strong>on</strong>, cette infracti<strong>on</strong> est communiquée à l’OFPcomme:a) une (1) infracti<strong>on</strong> commiseb) (x) infracti<strong>on</strong>s commisesc) ça dépend de la nature du crimeSi une infracti<strong>on</strong> grave et une infracti<strong>on</strong> légère <strong>on</strong>t été commises durant le même crime(Tateinheit), ce cas est retenu dans la statistique policière de la criminalité comme:a) un crime graveb) un crime légerc) un crime grave et un crime léger ( a) et b) )d) une rép<strong>on</strong>se globale n'est pas possibleVotre méthode actuelle pour retenir des infracti<strong>on</strong>s pour l'OFP, est-elle encore la même quecelle de 1998 ?a) oui / plutôt ouib) n<strong>on</strong>c) Je ne sais pas.Votre méthode actuelle pour retenir des infracti<strong>on</strong>s pour l'OFP, est-elle encore la même quecelle de 1986 ?a) oui / plutôt ouib) n<strong>on</strong>c) Je ne sais pas.Est-ce qu'il y a eu un changement important entre 1986 et aujourd'hui c<strong>on</strong>cernant la méthodepour retenir des infracti<strong>on</strong>s pour les envoyer à l'OFP ? S.v.p. indiquez l'année(s)approximative(s) du changement (plusieurs indicati<strong>on</strong>s possibles):


– 200 –Est-ce que vous jugez la pratique de retenir les infracti<strong>on</strong>s (dans les communes) dans votrecant<strong>on</strong> homogène?a) oui (plutôt homogène)b) n<strong>on</strong> (plutôt hétérogène)c) cette questi<strong>on</strong> n'est pas applicableDélit 1 / délit 2 (homicide/lési<strong>on</strong> corporelle)Cas model 1:2 criminels assassinent ensemble une victime.Ce crime serait communiqué à l’OFP comme:a) 1 homicide (délit 1)a) 2 homicides (délit 1)Cas model 2:1 criminel assassine une famille de 4 pers<strong>on</strong>nes.Ce crime serait retenu pour l'OFP comme:a) 1 homicidea) 4 homicidesCas model 3:Un fou furieux tue une (1) pers<strong>on</strong>ne et lèse légèrement un passant.Ce crime serait retenu pour l'OFP comme:a) 1 homicide (c<strong>on</strong>sommé)b) 1 lési<strong>on</strong> corporellec) 1 homicide (tentative)d) la combinais<strong>on</strong> de ______ et _________ et ________Délit 4 / délit 5 / délit 6 (vol/vol a l'arraché/cambriolage)Cas model 4:Une pers<strong>on</strong>ne sur un moto arrache un sac à main d'une passante.Ce crime serait communiqué à l'OFP comme:a) vol à l'arraché (délit 5)b) vol (délit 4)c) la combinais<strong>on</strong> de a) et b)


– 201 –Cas model 5:Une pers<strong>on</strong>ne c<strong>on</strong>state que s<strong>on</strong> porte-m<strong>on</strong>naie a disparu de sa poche. Elle est c<strong>on</strong>vaincue qu' ila du être volé.Ce délit serait retenu pour l'OFP comme:a) vol (délit 4)b) vol à l'arraché (délit 5)c) la combinais<strong>on</strong> de a) et b)Cas model 6:Une pers<strong>on</strong>ne déclare à la police qu' <strong>on</strong> a endommagé la serrure de sa mais<strong>on</strong> et qu' <strong>on</strong> afracassé la vitre d'une fenêtre. Elle croit que quelqu'un a tenté de cambrioler sa mais<strong>on</strong> sanssuccès.Ce délit serait retenu pour l'OFP comme:a) dommage à la propriétéb) cambriolage (tentative)c) la combinais<strong>on</strong> de a) et b)Cas model 7:Un gang de 4 pers<strong>on</strong>nes cambriole 2 immeubles d'habitati<strong>on</strong> dans la même nuit et en dérobentplusieurs peintures de grande valeur.Ce crime serait communiqué à l'OFP comme:a) ______ cambriolage(s) (délit 6)b) ______ dommage(s) à la propriétéc) la combinais<strong>on</strong> de a) et b)d) rien de tout, mais_______________________________________________Délit 7 (vol de véhicules) / délit 8 (escroquerie)Cas model 8:Une pers<strong>on</strong>ne a envoyé 500 lettres pour simuler un placement d'argent lucratif au moyen d'unsystème de la boule de neige.Ce crime serait communiqué à l'OFP comme:a) 500 escroqueriesb) 1 escroquerieCas model 9:Un gang de 3 criminels a volé 10 voitures pendant les deux dernières semaines.Ce crime serait retenu pour l'OFP comme:a) ________ vol(s) de véhicules (délit 7)


– 202 –Questi<strong>on</strong>:Les catégories suivantes de vols, s<strong>on</strong>t-elles comprises dans les vols d'automobiles ?a) vol de bateaux / de barques entiersb) vol de moteurs de bateauxc) vol de skisd) vol d'usage / soustracti<strong>on</strong> de véhicule automobile dans le dessein d'en faire usagee) vol de bicyclettes / cyclesf) vol de motocyclettes (légers) et cyclomoteursg) outres, comme_________________________________Délit 17 / délit 18 (viol / infracti<strong>on</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>tre l'intégrité sexuelle)Cas model 10:Une femme signale à la police qu'elle a été violée. Sur la base de s<strong>on</strong> témoignage c'est n'estpas évident si cet incident c<strong>on</strong>stitue un viol (art. 190) ou ‘seulement’ une c<strong>on</strong>trainte sexuelle(art. 189).Ce crime serait communiqué à l'OFP comme:a) viol (délit 17)b) délit c<strong>on</strong>tre l'intégrité sexuelle (délit 18)c) les deux a) et b)Cas model 11:3 hommes violent 2 femmes dans la même localité en même temps.Ce crime serait retenu pour l' OFP comme:a) _____ viol(s)Nous vous remerci<strong>on</strong>s pour votre coopérati<strong>on</strong>.__________________________________________________________________________Espace pour des commentaires complémentaires:date :...............................................nom :....................................................corps..........................................


– 203 –Chapter VI:Educati<strong>on</strong>


– 204 –1 Introducti<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy is c<strong>on</strong>jectured to lead to lower educati<strong>on</strong>al spending and thus to loweracademic achievement. In this chapter, this assumpti<strong>on</strong> is examined for the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Switzerland, a country with str<strong>on</strong>g variati<strong>on</strong> in the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy at the cant<strong>on</strong>allevel. To provide supportive evidence for the hypothesized negative impact, the analysisfocuses specifically <strong>on</strong> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> educati<strong>on</strong>al budgets and its effects<strong>on</strong> student achievement in reading.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> unexpectedly mediocre performance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Swiss students in the 2000 internati<strong>on</strong>al PISAstudy has rekindled discussi<strong>on</strong> about improving the Swiss educati<strong>on</strong>al system 219 . At the sametime, because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the ec<strong>on</strong>omic recessi<strong>on</strong>, cuts in federal, cant<strong>on</strong>al, and local budgets havebecome necessary that have also affected the funding available for public educati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g><strong>on</strong>going debates about school reforms are further complicated by the fact that Swiss votershave an important influence <strong>on</strong> fiscal and budgetary issues through direct legislati<strong>on</strong>. Ingeneral, direct legislative instituti<strong>on</strong>s restrict the financial means available to the governmentfor the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> schooling (BRADBURY et al. 2001; SCHALTEGGER 2001; FISCHER 2005).Similarly, in the U.S., measures to cut property taxes have been enacted through popularinitiatives at the state level. Because American school budgets rely primarily <strong>on</strong> this local taxas their revenue source, the questi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> how and whether these newly introduced tax capsaffect student performance has arisen to create a new field <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> empirical research in the U.S.Hence, the underlying questi<strong>on</strong> is whether citizens' c<strong>on</strong>trol over the school budget necessarilyleads to a lower quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this public good or not. Since Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s are heterogeneouswith respect to the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy, and quite aut<strong>on</strong>omous in their policies <strong>on</strong>public educati<strong>on</strong>, Switzerland seems especially suitable for such an analysis.This chapter aims at c<strong>on</strong>tributing to these recent discussi<strong>on</strong>s both in Switzerland and the U.S.by analyzing the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> the quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public educati<strong>on</strong> in Switzerlandusing nati<strong>on</strong>al individual data <strong>on</strong> ninth graders acquired simultaneously with data collecti<strong>on</strong>for the 2000 OECD-PISA study. This chapter is also the first to analyze (a) the ways thatpolitical instituti<strong>on</strong>s affect public schooling provisi<strong>on</strong> in Switzerland and (b) the instituti<strong>on</strong>alimpact <strong>on</strong> an entire c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> test scores.219 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> average test score <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 494 for Switzerland was below the internati<strong>on</strong>al mean <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 500 for the PISA study.


– 205 –In anticipati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the empirical results, direct democracy is first shown to c<strong>on</strong>siderably restrictthe financial resources available for public educati<strong>on</strong> in Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s. Since the combinedcant<strong>on</strong>al and local school expenses are the main source for public schooling in Switzerland,this limiting impact <strong>on</strong> the subfederal school budget can be c<strong>on</strong>sidered crucial. Subsequently,it is observed that if an educati<strong>on</strong>al producti<strong>on</strong> functi<strong>on</strong> based <strong>on</strong> pers<strong>on</strong>al and classcharacteristics is estimated, direct democracy leads to a c<strong>on</strong>siderable decline in studentperformance in reading, but not in mathematics or natural science. This result for reading isvery similar to that obtained by researchers for the U.S. However, following the inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>revenue-driven input variables, the link between direct democracy and academic achievementbreaks down for reading, while a performance raising influence is detected for mathematics.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, it can be c<strong>on</strong>cluded that the major (negative) impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> mustoccur solely through the school budgetary channel. Bey<strong>on</strong>d its financial impact, no furtheradditi<strong>on</strong>al effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> student performance can be observed.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> rest <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the chapter is organized as follows. Secti<strong>on</strong> 2 provides a brief overview <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theSwiss political and public educati<strong>on</strong>al system and presents related findings for the United<strong>St</strong>ates. Secti<strong>on</strong> 3 describes the data and model, and outlines the chosen estimati<strong>on</strong> methodsand the measure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy. Secti<strong>on</strong>s 4 and 5 present a discussi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the estimati<strong>on</strong>results. Secti<strong>on</strong>s 6 and 7 c<strong>on</strong>clude. Detailed regressi<strong>on</strong> outcomes are provided in theAppendix.2 Educati<strong>on</strong> Quality and <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>2.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>In modern (semi)direct democracies, a representative democracy is complemented by directdemocratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> most prominent cases are Switzerland and the United <strong>St</strong>ates,which are both also shaped by a very str<strong>on</strong>g fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong>, with each level having itsown sources <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax revenue. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, there exists a direct instituti<strong>on</strong>al link between thepower to tax and the direct legislative instituti<strong>on</strong>s that provide citizens with the politicalmeans to influence both sides <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the budget equally. In Switzerland, popular rights can beexerted at all three levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the state (federal, cant<strong>on</strong>al, and communal). Since cant<strong>on</strong>s (andcommunes) differ with respect to the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy in their c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s, it is


– 206 –possible to analyze the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a change in the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> a particularpolicy outcome (FELD and KIRCHGÄSSNER 2001) like the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> schooling.In Switzerland, cant<strong>on</strong>s are not <strong>on</strong>ly resp<strong>on</strong>sible for public educati<strong>on</strong> but bear the financialburden for its provisi<strong>on</strong>. C<strong>on</strong>cerning the overall costs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> compulsory educati<strong>on</strong>, the federalgovernment c<strong>on</strong>tributes <strong>on</strong>ly 0.2%, whereas the cant<strong>on</strong>s bear 38.8% and the communes61.1% 220 . With respect to the communes, they mostly finance primary schools. In general, inall 26 Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s, two types <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> advanced educati<strong>on</strong> can be distinguished: basic educati<strong>on</strong>and educati<strong>on</strong> to meet advanced requirements (e.g. university preparati<strong>on</strong>). Usually, thesec<strong>on</strong>d type can <strong>on</strong>ly be entered <strong>on</strong> a selective basis. Nowadays, Swiss cant<strong>on</strong> schoolcurricula in primary and sec<strong>on</strong>dary stages <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> educati<strong>on</strong> are harm<strong>on</strong>ized to a great extent 221 .Also included in cant<strong>on</strong>al authority is the general resp<strong>on</strong>sibility for teacher educati<strong>on</strong>,particularly for primary schools, which takes place in specialized teacher seminaries.Compulsory educati<strong>on</strong> finishes with the ninth grade, usually at the age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> about 15. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>fundamental regulati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public educati<strong>on</strong>, particularly school organizati<strong>on</strong> and the financialc<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> each level, are laid down in various cant<strong>on</strong>al laws <strong>on</strong> educati<strong>on</strong>.2.2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>oretical BackgroundInstituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong>, argue their many supporters, serve as a means to disciplinepoliticians and bureaucrats, who are assumed to behave in a Niskanen-like manner rather thanas benevolent dictators. Specifically, these bureaucrats exercise m<strong>on</strong>opoly power and aim atmaximizing their budgets 222 . For example, there is evidence for the U.S. that people in favor<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the introducti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> property tax limits actually believed that these budget cuts would lead toefficiency gains (TEMPLE 1996), hence an allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> goods that is closer to the citizens',particularly the median voter's, preferences (POMMEREHNE 1978) 223 . In practice, a reliance <strong>on</strong>user charges in more direct democratic cant<strong>on</strong>s was observed that makes the quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thepublic good more independent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the financial resources <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al government (FELD220 Appropriate informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> this issue can be found at www.educa.ch, the Federal <strong>St</strong>atistical Office,www.bfs.admin.ch or in the annual issues <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the STATISTISCHES JAHRBUCH DER SCHWEIZ, Bundesamt für<strong>St</strong>atistik (ed.), Neue Zürcher Zeitung.221 Such a curriculum includes the cant<strong>on</strong>al main language, a first foreign language, mathematics, writing,religi<strong>on</strong>, history and civics, natural sciences, applied arts, needlework, music, and sports.222 See ROMER and ROSENTHAL (1978, 1979, 1982, 1983) and ibid. with MUNLEY (1992).223 See FELD and KIRCHGÄSSNER (2001) for a theoretical model that applies to fiscal referenda, KIRCHGÄSSNER(2000, 2001, 2002) for a review <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ample empirical evidence, FELD and SAVIOZ (1997) for perspective <strong>on</strong>growth, and HUG (2004) for a corroborating meta-analysis.


– 207 –and MATSUSAKA 1999) 224 . However, in the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> compulsory public schooling, this soluti<strong>on</strong>is (politically) not an opti<strong>on</strong>.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> limitati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the budget through direct legislati<strong>on</strong> can give rise to bureaucratic adaptivebehavior. Two different strategies are suggested in the theoretical literature. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first,according to Niskanen’s theory <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> bureaucracy (e.g. INMAN 1979), is a substituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> budgetmaximizati<strong>on</strong> with a (relative) increase in administrative staff at the expense <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the resourcesavailable for producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the public good (WILLIAMSON 1964). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> rati<strong>on</strong>ale for thisstrategy is that a large pers<strong>on</strong>al staff gives the bureaucrat a feeling <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> importance and power(DOWNS 1967). When facing the decisi<strong>on</strong> to cut either administrative or instructi<strong>on</strong>alspending, a Leviathan-like administrator can be expected to choose the latter. For example,empirical U.S. studies show that a tax limit that imposes a limit <strong>on</strong> school budget growthleads to a spending shift from instructi<strong>on</strong> to administrati<strong>on</strong> (FIGLIO 1997, 1998) 225 .Alternatively, FIGLIO and O’SULLIVAN (2001) propose a manipulative bureaucratic behaviorin which the administrator deliberately allows student performances to decline by allocatingfewer financial resources to instructi<strong>on</strong> than to administrati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> goal is persuade theelectorate that budget reducti<strong>on</strong> has a deleterious impact <strong>on</strong> the quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> educati<strong>on</strong> so that itoverrules the previous tax limit vote. FIGLIO and O’SULLIVAN (2001), using expense data forpolice, fire protecti<strong>on</strong>, and general administrati<strong>on</strong> from 5,150 U.S. cities, show that in thosecities with a so-called override opti<strong>on</strong>, the deteriorati<strong>on</strong> in public service was larger than incities without this opti<strong>on</strong> 226 . Moreover, they observe the same phenomen<strong>on</strong> with respect toteacher-administrator ratios in school districts with an override opti<strong>on</strong> 227 . Moreover, Bradburyet al. (2001) show that communities with a history <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> passing overrides had the fastest schoolspending growth compared to communities without such an opti<strong>on</strong>.224 For the U.S., see MATSUSAKA (1995).225 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> same authors find this phenomen<strong>on</strong> to be mitigated in some cases by str<strong>on</strong>g competiti<strong>on</strong> betweenjurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s.226 It is, however, questi<strong>on</strong>able whether a change in the ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> administrati<strong>on</strong> to producti<strong>on</strong> costs providessufficient evidence for <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the two theories. If instructi<strong>on</strong> costs are more variable than administrativecosts, in the short term <strong>on</strong>ly a cut in instructi<strong>on</strong> costs might be practical.227 A third, alternative explanati<strong>on</strong> would be that if the school administrati<strong>on</strong> were already working efficientlyprior the decisi<strong>on</strong> to cut its budget, a decline in the quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the public service should be revealed eventhough a benevolent school administrator was in charge.


– 208 –2.3 U.S. Empirical Evidence <strong>on</strong> Public SchoolingIn the last two decades, so-called tax revolts – for example, California's famous Propositi<strong>on</strong>13 in 1978 – have taken place in about 20 U.S. states 228 , pushed through by means <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directlegislati<strong>on</strong>, particularly statutory initiatives at the state level 229 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se revolts aim mostly atreducing the level and growth <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> property taxes 230 that create important revenue at the locallevel (CARD and PAYNE 2002, DOWNES et al. 1998, DYE and MCGUIRE 1997). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore,such a change has a direct negative effect <strong>on</strong> school budgets (BRADBURY et al. 2001,SHADBEGIAN 2003) that does not necessarily translate into an equally large cut (in relativeterms) in the teaching and administrati<strong>on</strong> comp<strong>on</strong>ents <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> school spending (e.g. DYE andMCGUIRE 1997), particularly if, as in the U.S., the administrative body <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a school has thepower to allocate financial resources quite aut<strong>on</strong>omously (FIGLIO 1997).During the 1990s, empirical multivariate analyses <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> newly introduced tax limits<strong>on</strong> student performance were carried out to test an educati<strong>on</strong>al producti<strong>on</strong> functi<strong>on</strong> 231 . In across-state analysis using individual data, FIGLIO (1997) finds a substantially loweringinfluence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax limits <strong>on</strong> student performance – particularly <strong>on</strong> science, social studies, andreading examinati<strong>on</strong>s – but less robust results for mathematics. Using individual data,DOWNEs and FIGLIO (1997) again find a sizeable and significant decline in statewide meanstudent performance in states with a tax limit compared to states without such a limit inmathematics but not in reading. A c<strong>on</strong>tradictory finding is reported by DOWNES et al. (1998)in an analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a local property tax cap <strong>on</strong> student performance in elementaryschools in the Chicago metropolitan area. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> authors find <strong>on</strong>ly a weak and small negativeimpact <strong>on</strong> student performance in mathematics and no effect <strong>on</strong> reading test scores. Oneexplanati<strong>on</strong> for this c<strong>on</strong>tradictory finding may be that, because affected and unaffected schooldistricts were in close proximity to each other, these neighborhood schools c<strong>on</strong>stituted asingle supply <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public schooling for their inhabitants, which created str<strong>on</strong>g competiti<strong>on</strong>. Thiscompetiti<strong>on</strong> between schools is c<strong>on</strong>jectured to have mitigated the otherwise detrimentalimpact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax limits (DOWNES and FIGLIO 1999, HOXBY 2000) and to have restricted the rentseekingbehavior by bureaucrats (DYE and MCGUIRE 1997, FIGLIO and O’SULLIVAN 2001).228 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> source ACIR (1995) provides a catalogue <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> existing tax limits.229 A brief overview <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the theoretical background <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this development can be found in DOWNES and FIGLIO(1997).230 See FIGLIO and RUEBEN (2001), FIGLIO (1997), DOWNES and FIGLIO (1997)231 Earlier c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s to this topic from the 1970s until the very early 1990s, some empirical but mostinformal, are described in DOWNES and FIGLIO (1999). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s, however, suffer frommethodological shortcomings.


– 209 –To identify the channels through which the deleterious impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these tax limits occurred,their influence <strong>on</strong> various revenue-driven input factors <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the educati<strong>on</strong>al producti<strong>on</strong> functi<strong>on</strong>has also been analyzed. Significant evidence is found that new tax limits brought about lesseducati<strong>on</strong>al spending (BRADBURY et al., 2001, SHADBEGIAN, 2003), larger class sizes, higherstudent-teacher ratios (SHADBEGIAN 2003, FIGLIO 1998), and lower wages for beginninginstructors (FIGLIO 1997, POTERBA and RUEBEN 1995) 232 that cause potentially well-qualifiedteachers to leave the pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>essi<strong>on</strong> (FIGLIO and RUEBEN 2001, FIGLIO 1997a). Moreover, inc<strong>on</strong>trast to voter expectati<strong>on</strong>s (TEMPLE 1996), administrator preferences remain unchanged(DOWNES 1996); that is, administrators still overstaff their administrati<strong>on</strong>s (DOWNES 1996)and reduce instructi<strong>on</strong>al expenses relative to administrative expenses (FIGLIO 1998) or fail toreduce administrative spending at all (FIGLIO 1997). Finally, the introducti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a property taxlimit does not appear to have induced an increased service level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> local public schoolprovisi<strong>on</strong> (FIGLIO 1998). In sum, these findings provide evidence that the rent-seekingbehavior <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> school bureaucrats is not limited by a cut in local school budget.2.4 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Educati<strong>on</strong>al Spending in SwitzerlandAs a first step in this present analysis, the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> combined local andcant<strong>on</strong>al spending for public schools in Switzerland is determined. For this purpose, a model<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> government spending is estimated. This influence will then be taken into account in thestructural form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the educati<strong>on</strong>al producti<strong>on</strong> functi<strong>on</strong> as the indirect effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directlegislati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> public educati<strong>on</strong> through endogenous variables (see secti<strong>on</strong> 3.1).Various previous studies investigate the effects that direct democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s inSwitzerland and in the U.S. have <strong>on</strong> the combined cant<strong>on</strong>al and communal budgets. ForSwitzerland, these studies show that direct democracy leads to both smaller revenue andsmaller expenditure (KIRCHGÄSSNER 2000, 2001, 2002). Regarding educati<strong>on</strong>al expenses,SCHALTEGGER (2001) documents an expenditure lowering impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong>almost all comp<strong>on</strong>ents <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al and communal expenditure 233 . It is not surprising that thislimiting impact is most noticeable in those policy areas in which Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s are granted232 SHADBEGIAN (2003) found no significant effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax limits <strong>on</strong> teachers' average wages but provided noanalysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> wages <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> starting teachers. In an older c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>, however, he showed that stringent tax limitshad a decreasing effect <strong>on</strong> local government wages, which also comprised the wages <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> teachers(SHADBEGIAN 2000).233 Since SCHALTEGGER (2001) employs a different model specificati<strong>on</strong>, this analysis could not be based solely<strong>on</strong> his results. Rather, this estimati<strong>on</strong> might be viewed as an omitted variable test for his estimati<strong>on</strong>.


– 210 –political aut<strong>on</strong>omy by the Swiss c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> (art. 3 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Swiss c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong> 234 ); specifically,educati<strong>on</strong>, the health system, and culture (GERMANN 2002). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> weak influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the federalgovernment is rooted in the very structure and divisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> power <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Swiss state developedin the nineteenth century. For the U.S., a restraining property tax revenue effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> (stringent)local tax limits <strong>on</strong> the local (school) budget and revenue is detected (SHADBEGIAN 1999,2003). Regarding the appropriati<strong>on</strong> effort for the financing <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> higher educati<strong>on</strong>, ARCHIBALDand FELDMAN (2004) also find a c<strong>on</strong>siderable lowering impact at the U.S. state level 235 . Based<strong>on</strong> these findings, it is here hypothesized that direct democracy should have a spendingrestraint impact <strong>on</strong> the 'educati<strong>on</strong>al spending' comp<strong>on</strong>ent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the subfederal budget inSwitzerland.In this model, government expenditure is regarded as a functi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong>(defined as share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> local expenses in total cant<strong>on</strong>al and local expenses), urbanizati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thecant<strong>on</strong>, average nati<strong>on</strong>al income, cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong>, tax competiti<strong>on</strong>, a fiscally effectivec<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al ‘break’, the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> young and old people (< 20 years, > 60 years,respectively), and government ideology (with positive values indicating a c<strong>on</strong>servativepositi<strong>on</strong>). Most important, government spending is thought to be dependent <strong>on</strong> the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>direct democracy and cant<strong>on</strong>al culture, measured by a dummy for French- and Italianspeakingcant<strong>on</strong>s. A predicti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these c<strong>on</strong>trols and their theoretical foundati<strong>on</strong>can be found in FELD and KIRCHGÄSSNER (2001). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> dependent variable is the combinedcant<strong>on</strong>al and local budgetary expenses for schooling per capita, which have beenlogarithmized 236 .All the budgetary, (macro)ec<strong>on</strong>omic, and sociodemographic c<strong>on</strong>trols were obtained from theFederal <strong>St</strong>atistical Office (BFS). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se aggregate data form a synthetic panel, with 26 cant<strong>on</strong>sas observati<strong>on</strong>al units per year between 1980 and 1998. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> estimati<strong>on</strong> technique is a twostageleast squares (2SLS) approach: both ideology <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> government and fiscal federalism aretreated as endogenous since higher educati<strong>on</strong>al spending might allow formerlydisenfranchised groups go to the polls and induce a shift in government ideology. Further, the234 Available at http://www.admin.ch/ch/d/sr/c101.html (10/11/2004).235 This study uses a broad definiti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax limits and included all existing types: both local and state propertytax limits, formal restricti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> state expenditures and <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> state revenue, statutory and c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al taxlimits, moving base and fixed base versi<strong>on</strong>s. <strong>St</strong>ate spending for higher educati<strong>on</strong> appears to be more sensitiveto the introducti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax limits than other comp<strong>on</strong>ents <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the state budget.236 A combinati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al and communal spending must be employed because in every single cant<strong>on</strong> thefinancing <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> schooling is shared differently between the cant<strong>on</strong> and its communes.


– 211 –dependent variable, the combined local and cant<strong>on</strong>al expenditure for educati<strong>on</strong>, forms part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the denominator <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> measure, which serves as a predictor. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>sevariables are instrumented with cant<strong>on</strong>al fixed effects. Newey-West standard errors correctfor heteroscedasticity and serial autocorrelati<strong>on</strong>. All m<strong>on</strong>etary variables are deflated to theyear 2000.Table 1: Determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Educati<strong>on</strong>al Spendingin Swiss Cant<strong>on</strong>s, 1980 – 1998Variable Coefficient t-value<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy -0.054** -2.65Cant<strong>on</strong>s with Italian or Frenchmain language -0.078 -1.43Fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> -0.440*** -5.04Tax competiti<strong>on</strong> -0.052 -1.17Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> lumpsum transfers 0.028 0.78C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>straint(fiscal break) 0.003 0.36C<strong>on</strong>servative ideology<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> government -0.138* -2.35Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> nati<strong>on</strong>al income 0.157(*) 1.92Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> 0.238*** 3.31Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> 0.018 1.06Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> young people -0.012 -1.39Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> old people -0.024*** -3.26C<strong>on</strong>stant 6.802*** 5.72Adjusted R 2 0.83F-statistic 80.280Jarcque-Bera test (χ-value) 7.161*Observati<strong>on</strong>s 4942SLS estimati<strong>on</strong> with Newey-West standard errors. ***indicatessignificance at the 0.1% level, **at the 1% level, *at the 5% level and(*)at the 10% level, respectively. Estimati<strong>on</strong> with year dummies.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> results indicate that direct democracy restricts the subfederal spending for educati<strong>on</strong> (seetable 1): its coefficient is negative and significant at the 1% level. Fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> alsoexhibits the expected dampening impact, whereas educati<strong>on</strong>al expenses rise with the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>urbanizati<strong>on</strong>. In additi<strong>on</strong>, the more retired pers<strong>on</strong>s reside in a cant<strong>on</strong>, the fewer financialresources are available for compulsory schooling. Moreover, higher wealth in a cant<strong>on</strong>


– 212 –weakly induces more spending for public schooling. In this model, more c<strong>on</strong>servativelyoriented governments tend to have a lower level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> educati<strong>on</strong>al expenses. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> remainingc<strong>on</strong>trols are not significant at any c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al level. An adjusted R 2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> about 0.83 c<strong>on</strong>firmsthe good explanatory power <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> normality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the residualscan be rejected. An exclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> statistical outliers leads to identical empirical results withrespect to the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> schooling expenses and for most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theremaining predictors (see table 11.5 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendix).3 Data and Model3.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Model: <strong>St</strong>ructural and Reduced FormThis analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> educati<strong>on</strong> assumes educati<strong>on</strong> in publicschools to be an output <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> an educati<strong>on</strong>al producti<strong>on</strong> process in which several factors ('inputs')play a role 237 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se factors can be grouped according to the following criteria: schoolcharacteristics, classroom-related characteristics, peer characteristics, and, most important,student background informati<strong>on</strong> (individual and family). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> selecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these determinantsis based <strong>on</strong> empirical (ec<strong>on</strong>ometric) analyses <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the PISA results and hence reflects a typicalmodel specificati<strong>on</strong> chosen by educati<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omists 238 . In additi<strong>on</strong>, the model employssociodemographic determinants at the cant<strong>on</strong>al level and is augmented by a culturalproducti<strong>on</strong> factor that reflects the mentality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the citizens in the school's locati<strong>on</strong> to take intoaccount the language gap that divides Switzerland. Finally, this model also c<strong>on</strong>tains aninstituti<strong>on</strong>al variable that is the variable <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest. As dependent variable, the model uses theweighted likelihood estimate <strong>on</strong> reading provided in the dataset.In this analysis, a reduced form and a structural form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model will be distinguished. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>structural form includes revenue-driven 'endogenous' input factors that are not part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thereduced form, which by definiti<strong>on</strong> is composed <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> exogenous variables <strong>on</strong>ly 239 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>seendogenous input factors, determined by cant<strong>on</strong>al and communal school expenses and shownin secti<strong>on</strong> 2.4 to be negatively influenced by the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy, are teacher237 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> most extensive set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> such determinants originates from the work <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> SUMMERS and WOLFE (1977).238 See FUCHS and WOESSMANN (2004), FERTIG (2003), FERTIG and SCHMIDT (2002), FERTIG and WRIGHT(2004). For specificati<strong>on</strong>s chosen by public ec<strong>on</strong>omists, see DOWNES and FIGLIO (1997) and FIGLIO (1997).239 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sec<strong>on</strong>d equati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this structural form is approximated in secti<strong>on</strong> 2.4 by the regressi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> educati<strong>on</strong>alexpenditure <strong>on</strong> direct democracy.


– 213 –qualificati<strong>on</strong>, teacher shortages, total hours <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> schooling, student-teacher ratio, availabilityand quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> instructi<strong>on</strong> material, and state <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> school building or availability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> space. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>reduced form includes the combined direct and indirect influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> political instituti<strong>on</strong>s,whereas the structural form includes <strong>on</strong>ly the direct influence because the indirect influence isfiltered out. Whereas both forms are estimated in the U.S. literature, the reduced form is usedmore frequently. Nevertheless, the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax limits is found to significantly lowerperformance for both forms.In the structural form, the relati<strong>on</strong> between student performance and all its predictors outlinedabove can be expressed by the following functi<strong>on</strong>:performance = f(democracy, culture, individual, peers, school, cant<strong>on</strong>, school inputs),where democracy denotes direct democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s, and culture the main regi<strong>on</strong>al culture<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the school locati<strong>on</strong>, which accounts for differences in people's mentality. Individualdenotes the student's individual and family characteristics such as gender and parents'educati<strong>on</strong>. Peers stands for peer group characteristics that aim at measuring the externaleffects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the peer group <strong>on</strong> an individual's academic performance: i.e. individual academicperformance might depend <strong>on</strong> the intellectual potential <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> peers 240 . School denotesschool/class-related characteristics like the selectivity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the instituti<strong>on</strong> or problems with classdiscipline. Cant<strong>on</strong> represents cant<strong>on</strong>al sociodemographics, which serve two purposes: first,they can be viewed as proxies for missing individual and peer group variables in class (e.g.religi<strong>on</strong>); sec<strong>on</strong>d, they account for the sociodemographic determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the demand forpublic goods 241 . Finally, school inputs denote revenue-driven school inputs as describedabove. A descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> variables can be found in table 11.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendix.For predicting the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the sociodemographic and peer c<strong>on</strong>trols, the reader is referred tothe literature cited in the fields <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> educati<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omics and public finance (e.g. WINSTONand ZIMMERMAN 2003, FIGLIO 1997). As regards the structural model, the influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>revenue-driven inputs <strong>on</strong> student performance is amply described in the educati<strong>on</strong>al240 In small classes, there might even exist a feedback relati<strong>on</strong> and c<strong>on</strong>tinuing interacti<strong>on</strong> between the <strong>on</strong>e andthe other(s) (for empirical literature <strong>on</strong> peer effects, see ZIMMER and TOMA (2000), SUMMERS and WOLFE(1977), KERCKHOFF (1986), EPPLE et al. (2003), HOXBY (2000a), RANGVID (2004)).241 See e.g. FELD, et al. (2004) for a justificati<strong>on</strong>.


– 214 –ec<strong>on</strong>omics literature. In general, empirical findings <strong>on</strong> the decisiveness <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these budgetrelatedinput factors tend to disagree or suffer from c<strong>on</strong>founding factors 242 .3.2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> estimati<strong>on</strong>s employ a composite index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy that measures the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>direct democracy at the cant<strong>on</strong>al level in Switzerland. It is an unweighted average <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foursubindices that evaluate the power <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative, the statutory initiative, thefiscal referendum, and the statutory referendum. This index takes <strong>on</strong> values between 1 and 6,with 6 indicating the highest degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> empowerment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al electorate. Nevertheless,this index measures the presence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these instituti<strong>on</strong>s rather than their actual use 243 . Its exactc<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> is dem<strong>on</strong>strated in STUTZER (1999) for the year 1996. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> values for the year2000 are displayed in the Appendix (table 11.2).Defining public schooling as a public good, this analysis first poses the questi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> whetherand how direct democracy affects the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this public good at the cant<strong>on</strong>al level.Based <strong>on</strong> the U.S. experience, a performance lowering impact in both forms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model isanticipated.3.3 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Data<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> individual, family, and school related determinants are taken directly from the nati<strong>on</strong>alPISA study. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se data were collected jointly with the 2000 OECD-PISA study usingidentical questi<strong>on</strong>naires and subject tests, with a primary focus <strong>on</strong> reading performance.However, in c<strong>on</strong>trast to the OECD-PISA study, the populati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the nati<strong>on</strong>al study includesall ninth graders 244 ; hence, student ages range c<strong>on</strong>siderably. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> procedure for data collecti<strong>on</strong>and treatment was roughly identical for both the Swiss nati<strong>on</strong>al sample and the PISA sample.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> primary sampling units are schools not cant<strong>on</strong>s (FERTIG 2003), and the dataset provides a242 For literature <strong>on</strong> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> financial resources in general available to schools <strong>on</strong> educati<strong>on</strong>, see HANUSHEK(1996), DOWNES (1992), HANUSHEK and SOMERS (1999), LUDWIG and BASSI (1998), CARD and PAYNE(2002); for the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> student-teacher-ratio <strong>on</strong> academic achievement, see HANUSHEK (1998), KRUEGER(2002), BUCKINGHAM (2003b), and FIGLIO (1999); for the influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> teachers’ wages, see HANUSHEK et al.(1999, 2001), FIGLIO (1999), and finally, for quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> teaching see HANUSHEK et al. (1998), HANUSHEK(2003), BUCKINGHAM (2003b, 2003a).243 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> such an instituti<strong>on</strong> is already sufficient to induce a change in allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> resources becauseit serves as a credible threat in a game theoretical c<strong>on</strong>text (FELD and KIRCHGÄSSNER 2001).244<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> OECD-PISA study focuses <strong>on</strong> pupils aged 15.


– 215 –weighted likelihood estimate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a student's performance that is a weighted average <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>correctly answered resp<strong>on</strong>ses, with the weights reflecting the level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> difficulty <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thequesti<strong>on</strong> (HAMBLETON and SWAMINATHAN 1985, WARM 1989). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> matching <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> schools andstudents also makes it possible to c<strong>on</strong>struct classroom-based peer variables.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> nati<strong>on</strong>al study sample is preferred over the original PISA sample for two reas<strong>on</strong>s: first, itcovers almost all cant<strong>on</strong>s 245 ; sec<strong>on</strong>d, the administrati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the questi<strong>on</strong>naires to completeclasses instead <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> age groups allows the c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> peer group/class mate predictors.Moreover, even though there exists an extensi<strong>on</strong> ('the French sample') to the nati<strong>on</strong>al studydataset that covers <strong>on</strong>ly French-speaking regi<strong>on</strong>s 246 , the nati<strong>on</strong>al study oversampled studentsfrom the German-speaking cant<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Bern, Zürich, and <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, to prevent anoverrepresentati<strong>on</strong>, both datasets are merged and all observati<strong>on</strong>s with missing values deleted.In a sec<strong>on</strong>d step, to prevent endogeneity in the peer group variables, all students who attendedtest language classes with less than 20 peers are also excluded. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> mean <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the reading testscore was originally normalized at 500, with a standard deviati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 90 for the whole nati<strong>on</strong>aldataset, but because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the deleti<strong>on</strong> process, the new mean is about 530, with a standarddeviati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> approximately 80 based <strong>on</strong> a final sample <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 3,411 observati<strong>on</strong>s. For moredescriptive statistics also for the other two test subjects, see tables 11.3 and 11.4 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theAppendix.3.4 MethodologyBoth the reduced and the structural model are estimated using two different ec<strong>on</strong>ometricmethods. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first approach uses ordinary least squares (OLS) and corrects the standard errors<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coefficients for heteroscedasticity. It also assumes that students who attend identicalschools share comm<strong>on</strong> factors both at the school and cant<strong>on</strong>al level – for example, c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>245 No observati<strong>on</strong>s exist from the cant<strong>on</strong>s Appenzell Innerrhoden and Uri. To the author's knowledge, there isno educati<strong>on</strong>al institute providing a ninth-grade educati<strong>on</strong> in the first cant<strong>on</strong>.246 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> extensi<strong>on</strong> dataset differs from the nati<strong>on</strong>al sample solely in that entire classes were administered thequesti<strong>on</strong>naires, whereas in the nati<strong>on</strong>al sample, students were drawn randomly from selected classes. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>original dataset included 4,833 students in 105 schools bel<strong>on</strong>ging to both samples. For the data, thecodebooks, and further informati<strong>on</strong>, see SIDOS 2000 (2004). A more detailed descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> data sources forthe determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> educati<strong>on</strong> can be found in the Appendix (table A.7). This table also provides informati<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> the chosen base categories. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> procedure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> normalizati<strong>on</strong> follows that for the internati<strong>on</strong>al PISA sample(FERTIG 2003).


– 216 –<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the school building and political instituti<strong>on</strong>s in the cant<strong>on</strong> – and it therefore employsclustering at the school level (MOULTON 1990) 247 .<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> sec<strong>on</strong>d approach applies a quantile regressi<strong>on</strong> method that, rather than estimating thec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al mean functi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the dependent variable as in OLS, estimates various c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>alfuncti<strong>on</strong>s for (predetermined) different porti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the test score distributi<strong>on</strong>. Hence, thismethod provides a more complete picture <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> how the predictors influence the resp<strong>on</strong>sevariable over its distributi<strong>on</strong>. It also becomes possible to uncover significant impacts <strong>on</strong> thetails that leave the mean unchanged, in c<strong>on</strong>trast to an OLS regressi<strong>on</strong> that would render thedeterminant in questi<strong>on</strong> insignificant. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> quantile regressi<strong>on</strong> method is also more efficient ifthe distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the dependent variable deviates from the normal distributi<strong>on</strong> in its highermoments. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> interpretati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a coefficient is the same as for an OLS estimate but is <strong>on</strong>lyvalid <strong>on</strong>ly for a particular quantile. As the specified quantile increases, the porti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> sampleobservati<strong>on</strong>s included (sorted in an ascending order) rises. In this model, the 10th, 25th, 50th,75th, and 90th quantiles <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the test score distributi<strong>on</strong> are selected for analysis 248 .Some determinants employed are subject to potential simultaneity: e.g. besides peer effects,performance at home or a higher age could be proxies for bad grades at school. Additi<strong>on</strong>ally,the selecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pupils into different school types and classes is not fully taken into accountwith these estimati<strong>on</strong> methods. Both might induce a bias in the estimated coefficients. Aninstrumentati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> endogenous variables or a correcti<strong>on</strong> for sample selecti<strong>on</strong>, however, cannotbe carried out because the PISA data do not provide the necessary exogenous instruments (fora discussi<strong>on</strong>, see also RANGVID 2004, GRADDY and STEVENS 2003).247 This estimati<strong>on</strong> method is also applied by educati<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omists to the analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> PISA results using aninternati<strong>on</strong>al sample c<strong>on</strong>taining several countries. However, no literature appears to exist using a multilevelanalysis approach for such data.248 For an introducti<strong>on</strong> to the quantile regressi<strong>on</strong> method, see KOENKER and BASSET (1978), KOENKER andHALLOCK (2001), BUCHINSKY (1998), CADE and NOON (2003).


– 217 –4 Estimati<strong>on</strong> Results for Reading4.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> and OLSTable 8.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendix displays the OLS estimati<strong>on</strong> results for reading for both thereduced form and the structural form that includes the educati<strong>on</strong>al input factors at the schooland class level that are financed through cant<strong>on</strong>al sources.In the reduced form, direct democracy exerts a performance lowering impact <strong>on</strong> an averagestudent from am<strong>on</strong>g the 3,411 students that remain in the sample (significance at the 5%level). As regards the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact, it appears to be c<strong>on</strong>siderable. Since this index rangesfrom 1 to 6, the maximum reducti<strong>on</strong> in the test score for an average student due to directlegislative instituti<strong>on</strong>s is about 46 difficulty adjusted test score points. Given the standarddeviati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> about 80 points, this impact is quite substantial. Nevertheless, compared to thesizes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the remaining determinants, the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> academicperformance is not c<strong>on</strong>siderable. <strong>St</strong>r<strong>on</strong>ger by far are, for example, the effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> high parentalincome, age, gender, the situati<strong>on</strong> and learning envir<strong>on</strong>ment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the pupil at home, and theselectivity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the attended school. In the structural form, the OLS estimate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>direct democracy is also negative, but in c<strong>on</strong>trast to the reduced form, it is far from beingsignificant at any c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al level. For an average student from am<strong>on</strong>g the 2,969 students,political instituti<strong>on</strong>s do not exert any significant impact <strong>on</strong> reading test scores if revenuedriveninput factors are explicitly taken into account. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> adjusted R 2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> around 0.26 for bothforms indicates a good fit <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this model for a cross secti<strong>on</strong>.As regards the remaining c<strong>on</strong>trols in the OLS regressi<strong>on</strong>, most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the individual, family, peer,and school characteristics coefficients are robust to the inclusi<strong>on</strong> and exclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> educati<strong>on</strong>alrevenue-driven input factors. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> most prominent change can be observed for the selectivity<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> school, which becomes smaller in size and insignificant if these revenue-driven inputs arec<strong>on</strong>trolled for. Selectivity is defined as students being admitted to a particular school basedeither <strong>on</strong> their previous grades or an entrance exam. This result could mean that the advantage<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> more selective schools in Switzerland issues from a better quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> particular inputs.Overall, most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the individual and family variables show signs already obtained in similarstudies <strong>on</strong> the determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> school performance using the PISA results, e.g. the betterperformance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> females (e.g. FERTIG 2003, FERTIG and SCHMIDT 2002, FERTIG and WRIGHT


– 218 –2002) 249 . One excepti<strong>on</strong> is the achievement dampening effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> higher levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> educati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>parents, which might be caused by some collinearity between them and higher levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>income 250 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>trol ‘homework feedback’ also shows an unexpected negative sign.Whereas a positive impact <strong>on</strong> a pupil's performance would be c<strong>on</strong>jectured, the grading <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>homework or its inclusi<strong>on</strong> in the final mark obviously leads to a reducti<strong>on</strong> in pupil'sperformance 251 . Regular testing does not c<strong>on</strong>siderably influence a student's academicachievement. Both the higher age <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a student and discussi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the student’s performance athome can be viewed as proxies for low performance at school, whereas younger age couldindicate excellent performance 252 .In terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> peer group effects, the heterogeneity measure in difficulty adjusted test scoresseems to capture the most important peer group effects, so that the coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the shares<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female and <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreign peers are rendered insignificant 253 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> heterogeneity measureemployed here is defined as the peer group's mean performance divided by its standarddeviati<strong>on</strong>. Thus, a positive estimate indicates that a better peer group performance and/or asmaller variati<strong>on</strong> in class causes an increase in the single student's test score. In both thereduced and the structural form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model, a positive and significant coefficient isobserved; this result is supported by the externality/peer group effect theory (see secti<strong>on</strong> 3.1).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> measured peer effect might also be a proxy for the school type, which the selectivityvariable is intended to c<strong>on</strong>trol for. Given that the heterogeneity measure for reading rangesbetween approximately 3 and 16, the quantitative size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this effect varies between about 20and 110 test score points, which is quite a c<strong>on</strong>siderable range.As regards cant<strong>on</strong>al characteristics, most cant<strong>on</strong>al variables are insignificant for the expectedmean <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the difficulty adjusted test score in reading. One excepti<strong>on</strong> is the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poorpers<strong>on</strong>s in both models, defined as pers<strong>on</strong>s unable to afford savings <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 100 Swiss Francs per249 In value-added analyses, the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> gender is reported insignificant (e.g. GRADDY and STEVENS 2003). Dueto the cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al structure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the data, such an analysis is not possible in this case.250 Although the numerical correlati<strong>on</strong> coefficient does not exceed 0.3 in absolute value, to the analysis takes intoaccount that the income variable is also c<strong>on</strong>structed <strong>on</strong> the basis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> educati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>trol. (<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> highest positivecorrelati<strong>on</strong>s are found between tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> father and the two highest levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income (~0.3),followed by the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> books with a low level (hisei2) and high levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income (hisei6 and hisei7) (~-0.2 and ~0.2, respectively). It should also be noted that the empirical studies <strong>on</strong> the PISA results use anidentical set <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> family background c<strong>on</strong>trols.251 A c<strong>on</strong>vincing explanati<strong>on</strong> is better left to specialists in pedagogy and psychology.252 As already noted in the methodology secti<strong>on</strong>, the potential endogeneity cannot be corrected because thedataset does not provide suitable instruments.253 An omissi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coefficient in reading renders the remaining two peer variables significant.


– 219 –m<strong>on</strong>th. This variable exhibits a significant decreasing impact <strong>on</strong> an average student's testscores, although not a very large <strong>on</strong>e. In the structural model, Protestantism is weaklyassociated with higher test scores. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> logarithm <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> is significant inthe reduced model, indicating that student performance is worse in more populated cant<strong>on</strong>s,but it is not decisive in the structural form.As regards the endogenous input variables for schooling, no access to a PC at school appearsto be detrimental for an average student's academic achievement. However a shortage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>teachers does not affect the average student's achievement at any c<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al level, althoughthe negative sign points in the predicted directi<strong>on</strong>. Tertiary qualificati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a school's teachers,<strong>on</strong> the other hand, is associated with a higher test score in reading. Nevertheless, thecoefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the remaining input factors are not significant for an average student at anyc<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al level.In sum, a significant performance decreasing impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy is observed in thereduced form and an insignificant coefficient in the structural form. Given that directdemocracy is shown to dampen subfederal expenditure for public schools and thus potentiallyrestrain spending for revenue-driven inputs at the school and class level, it can be c<strong>on</strong>jecturedthat the disappearance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> its significance in the structural form is due to the inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theseinput factors. For policy makers, this finding means that fewer financial means available atthe cant<strong>on</strong>al level for public schooling do translate into lower student performance, whetherdirectly (quasi-automatically) or through the strategic acts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> school bureaucrats. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> indirecteffect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> has a negative directi<strong>on</strong> and dominates the direct <strong>on</strong>e in the reducedform. It can also be c<strong>on</strong>cluded that revenue-driven inputs are important for schoolperformance in reading, a noteworthy epiphenomen<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the empirical results 254 . <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> nextstep is to take a closer look at the influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this predictor <strong>on</strong> various porti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al test score distributi<strong>on</strong> in reading.254 See also the discussi<strong>on</strong> in secti<strong>on</strong> 6.


– 220 –4.2 Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> Results<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Reduced Form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Model<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> quantile regressi<strong>on</strong> reveals a negative sign over the distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> test scores in thereduced form specificati<strong>on</strong> for the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the composite index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong>academic achievement (see table 8.2 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendix). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> variable <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest is significantfor all estimated quantiles, but the str<strong>on</strong>gest impact can be observed for the 75th and 50thpercentiles. Significance levels for the outer quantiles drop down to the 10% level. At thispoint, it should be noted that such a drop in significance levels can be expected given a risingdeviati<strong>on</strong> from the median at both tails <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al distributi<strong>on</strong>, because the t-statistic ismore likely to be c<strong>on</strong>founded by single statistical outliers. A test <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> joint n<strong>on</strong>significancereveals a joint significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this instituti<strong>on</strong>al impact at the 5% level for all estimatedquantiles. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> results also reveal the similarity in size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coefficients for the mean and themedian 255 .A quantile regressi<strong>on</strong> technique makes it possible to examine the development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the coefficient over the entire distributi<strong>on</strong>, as well as to test whether a seeming change in sizeis statistically significant. A graphic representati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>direct democracy over the entire c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al test score distributi<strong>on</strong> is presented in figure 1 256 .On the ordinate, the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coefficient is measured in test score points, while theabscissa depicts the percentiles <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the distributi<strong>on</strong> in 1% increments. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> estimated coefficientfor each percentile is plotted as a c<strong>on</strong>tinuous line and its 95% c<strong>on</strong>fidence intervals, as ashaded area. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> OLS estimate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy is depicted as a horiz<strong>on</strong>tal dashed line; inthis case, intersecting the x-axis at -7.9. As figure 1 illustrates, the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracydoes not appear to vary greatly between quantiles, particularly for the middle part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the testscore distributi<strong>on</strong>. Further, the coefficient(s) appear(s) to fluctuate closely around the dashedline. A closer inspecti<strong>on</strong> also shows the insignificance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coefficient in the very low andvery high percentiles at the 5% level. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> result <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a Wald test for equality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the entiredistributi<strong>on</strong> leads to the c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> that, given the pers<strong>on</strong>al, family, and peer characteristics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>a student, each individual is equally (negatively) affected by direct democratic instituti<strong>on</strong>s.255 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> author is aware <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the fact that this difference in significance could have been caused either by the factthat standard errors are not bootstrapped in the OLS regressi<strong>on</strong> or because no clustering <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>s waspossible in the quantile regressi<strong>on</strong>s.256 According to JOAO PEDRO W. DE AZEVEDO, author <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the user-written command grqreg with which the plotswere created, coefficients for the entire distributi<strong>on</strong> are estimated with c<strong>on</strong>fidence intervals based <strong>on</strong> thebootstrapped standard errors <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the last regressi<strong>on</strong> results (pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong>, 8th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> February, 2005).


– 221 –DirDem_2000-30.00 -20.00 -10.00 0.00 10.000 .2 .4 .6 .8 1QuantileFigure 1: Reading; Reduced FormFor the coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the remaining individual and cant<strong>on</strong>al sociodemographic c<strong>on</strong>trols andtheir variance over the test score distributi<strong>on</strong>, the interested reader is referred to the Appendix.Worthwhile factors for explorati<strong>on</strong> include the changing impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> higher income classes,number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> siblings, discussi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> student performance in the home, the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreign peersin class, as well as <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Protestants in the cant<strong>on</strong>s. Also noteworthy is that, again,the sign for higher educati<strong>on</strong> is c<strong>on</strong>trary to expectati<strong>on</strong>, possibly for the same reas<strong>on</strong>s asstated before. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> most variables, however, resembles the results obtained in theOLS model.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>ructural FormTable 8.3 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendix displays the quantile regressi<strong>on</strong> results for the structural form; i.e.after the inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> various input measures whose quality and/or quantity are probablydetermined by the given financial resources. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> structural form allows differentiati<strong>on</strong>between the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy through a mere lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> financial resources and animpact bey<strong>on</strong>d this purely financial influence. In other words, it is potentially possible toidentify a reallocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> given resources between students in the same grade. However, in all


– 222 –quantiles, the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy is rendered insignificant, which parallels the OLSregressi<strong>on</strong> results. Figure 2, in which the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy fluctuates around 0and its c<strong>on</strong>fidence interval always appears to include the 0-line, corroborates this finding forthe entire distributi<strong>on</strong>. Based <strong>on</strong> a successful Wald test for equality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> estimated coefficients,the hypothesis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> joint n<strong>on</strong>significance cannot be rejected. Hence, no redistributive impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>direct democracy between students can be observed in reading.DirDem_2000-40.00 -20.00 0.00 20.000 .2 .4 .6 .8 1QuantileFigure 2: Reading; <strong>St</strong>ructural FormSimilar effects to those already detected in the OLS model are observed for the various inputmeasures in the structural model. Again, significant coefficients can <strong>on</strong>ly be observed for theequipment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the school with PCs and the tertiary qualificati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> teachers. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first inputfactor appears to be detrimental <strong>on</strong>ly for the students in the lower part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the test scoredistributi<strong>on</strong> (10th and 25th quantiles), whereas the sec<strong>on</strong>d factor affects all students except forthose in the 90th quantile, which might be due to the low number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> observati<strong>on</strong>s. In additi<strong>on</strong>,a higher number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> total teaching hours seems to benefit most pupils in the lower 25thquantile, but <strong>on</strong>ly weakly (significance at the 10% level). N<strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the other coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>input factors reach statistical significance.


– 223 –With respect to the cant<strong>on</strong>al predictors, a similar pattern to the OLS results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the structuralmodel is observed. Moreover, the results are also similar to those obtained in the reducedmodel that show the input factors at the school level to be quite uncorrelated with thesociodemographic determinants at the cant<strong>on</strong>al level. As in the reduced model, thec<strong>on</strong>vincingly significant coefficients are those for the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Protestants, the logarithm <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong>, and the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor people, with the latter experiencing a decline insignificance from the 0.1% level in the reduced model down to the 5% or 10% level in thestructural model for almost the entire distributi<strong>on</strong>. This finding indicates that the str<strong>on</strong>gnegative impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor pers<strong>on</strong>s observed in the reduced model must occur through thecant<strong>on</strong>al budget transmissi<strong>on</strong> channel, probably because politicians face a trade-<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>f betweensupporting needy pers<strong>on</strong>s and financing cant<strong>on</strong>al educati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> identical observati<strong>on</strong> holdstrue for the cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong>, which was str<strong>on</strong>gly significant in the reduced model but lostc<strong>on</strong>siderable significance in the structural model, particularly for the lower and middlequantiles. This finding can again be interpreted to mean that the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al sizefor lower and middle quantiles obviously occurs through financial channels related to schoolexpenditure. In c<strong>on</strong>trast, for the higher quantiles, a different transmissi<strong>on</strong> channel seems to beat work for this effect not filtered out in the model specificati<strong>on</strong>.Several robustness checks assess whether the observed influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democraticinstituti<strong>on</strong>s in both forms depends <strong>on</strong> the inclusi<strong>on</strong> or exclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> particular c<strong>on</strong>trols or issensitive to a potentially unsolved endogeneity problem. In general, the results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the originalmodel specificati<strong>on</strong> are insensitive to slight variati<strong>on</strong>s in the specificati<strong>on</strong>, but the exclusi<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> peer effects appears to cause an omitted variable bias. In additi<strong>on</strong>, imputati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the medianand admissi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> class sizes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ten or more students, which increases the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>observati<strong>on</strong>s to roughly 9,000, do not alter the main findings. In the reduced form, directdemocracy again shows a performance lowering effect, which disappears in the structuralform.5 Estimati<strong>on</strong> Results for Mathematics and Natural Science<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> reduced and structural forms are also tested for mathematics and natural science usingboth OLS and quantile regressi<strong>on</strong> methods. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> measure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> peer performance, thequalificati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> teachers, and the shortage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> teachers are also adjusted according to the twosubjects taught. In additi<strong>on</strong>, classes with less than 20 students are eliminated <strong>on</strong> the basis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>


– 224 –the corresp<strong>on</strong>ding subject. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> rest <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this secti<strong>on</strong> discusses the results for both mathematicsand natural science.5.1 Results for Mathematics<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Reduced Form<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> OLS results for the reduced form reveal an insignificant impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy foran average student from am<strong>on</strong>g the 1,846 students tested (see table 9.1). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> quantileregressi<strong>on</strong> results corroborate this observati<strong>on</strong> for all estimated quantiles. Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, a test<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> joint n<strong>on</strong>significance for all estimated quantiles cannot be rejected.DirDem_2000-60.00 -40.00 -20.00 0.00 20.00 40.000 .2 .4 .6 .8 1QuantileFigure 3: Mathematics; Reduced FormIn the OLS model, am<strong>on</strong>g the remaining sociodemographic, school peer, and cant<strong>on</strong>al inputfactors, female students are observed to perform about 30 test score points worse than theirmale peers in all quantiles. <strong>St</strong>udents in selective schools perform weakly better than theirpeers in other school types, which is in line with the results for reading. Less heterogeneity inclass leads to higher test scores for the average student, as observed for reading. In c<strong>on</strong>trast,however, the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreign peers in class also exerts an achievement lowering impact,


– 225 –whereas the ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female peers does not appear influential. Am<strong>on</strong>g the cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>trols,<strong>on</strong>ce again, a higher ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor people and more populati<strong>on</strong> exhibit a performance decliningimpact for an average student. In c<strong>on</strong>trast to reading, the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> residents with at least a highschool degree and the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Protestants are str<strong>on</strong>gly associated with higher test scores.Similar results are obtained in the quantile regressi<strong>on</strong>s. For a detailed descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theempirical results for the OLS and the quantile regressi<strong>on</strong>s, see the Appendix <strong>on</strong> mathematics,table 9.2Figure 3 illustrates the development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy over the entirec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al test score distributi<strong>on</strong> in the reduced form. Again, the dashed line depicts the OLScoefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> about +2.2, while the c<strong>on</strong>tinuous line represents the coefficients for allquantiles. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>fidence interval always crosses the 0-line, indicating that the coefficientnever reaches significance at the 5% level. In c<strong>on</strong>trast to the results for reading, however, aclear upward trend <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coefficient is observable, starting with a negative value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> -6 in thelowest percentile and reaching about +8 in the 90th percentile. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> H 0 -hypothesis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> jointlyequal coefficients in the estimated quantiles, however, is not rejected 257 .<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>ructural Form<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> OLS estimate in the structural form reveals a significant performance enhancing effect <strong>on</strong>test scores in the structural form (at the 5% level; see table 9.1). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this coefficient isabout 11.6, which in a cant<strong>on</strong> with the theoretically highest level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 6index points would translate into a sizeable effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> about 70 adjusted test score points,almost as large as the standard deviati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 80 points in mathematics.<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> quantile regressi<strong>on</strong> estimates reveal different sizes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> impact and varying significancelevels (see table 9.3). In the lower porti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al test score distributi<strong>on</strong>, the size<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coefficient takes <strong>on</strong> the small, and thus insignificant, values <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1.1 and 5.3. In the 50th,75th, and 90th quantiles, however, direct democracy affects student performancec<strong>on</strong>siderably, with maximum test score points <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 64.5, 76.8, and 148.8 (significant at the 5%,5%, and 0.1% levels, respectively). A test <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> joint n<strong>on</strong>significance reveals that the estimatesare jointly significant at the 1% level, meaning that a test for equality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> coefficients shouldreveal whether the seeming differences in sizes are statistically significant. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> test shows257 A pairwise Wald test for equality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> coefficients does show that some <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these differences are statisticallysignificant, particularly between the lowest estimated quantile (the 10th) and the two highest (the 75th andthe 90th, respectively). Both, however, are <strong>on</strong>ly significant at the 10% level.


– 226 –that the H 0 -hypothesis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> equality can be rejected at the 10% level. In additi<strong>on</strong>, a pairwiseWald test reveals significant differences between the pairs in the 10th, 25th, 50th, and 75thpercentiles and those in the 90th percentile (all significant at the 5% level) but not am<strong>on</strong>g thelower and middle estimated quantiles. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se results can be viewed as weak evidence for aredistributive impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> given resources to the advantage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> students inthe 90th percentile <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al test score distributi<strong>on</strong>; i.e. to the advantage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> studentswho are already performing well.DirDem_2000-40.00 -20.00 0.00 20.00 40.000 .2 .4 .6 .8 1QuantileFigure 4: Mathematics; <strong>St</strong>ructural FormFigure 4 depicts the development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy over the entirec<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al test score distributi<strong>on</strong>. As in the reduced form, there is a clear upward trend <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thecoefficient. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> OLS coefficient crosses the ordinate at almost 12 test score points, and thec<strong>on</strong>tinuous line starts with 1.10 in the 10th quantile and finishes with almost 25 in the 90thquantile.As regards the remaining sociodemographic, peer and cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>trols in the OLS model,again, female students perform significantly worse than their male peers, whereas the averagestudents in selective schools do not perform significantly better than their peers in otherschool types. This result c<strong>on</strong>trasts with the finding in the reduced model, again possibly


– 227 –identifying the budgetary channel as the transmissi<strong>on</strong> channel. As in the reduced form, aperformance enhancing impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> peer performance and a test score lowering influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>foreign peers can be observed. Again, the ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female peers does not appear to be adecisive factor.Am<strong>on</strong>g the cant<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>trols, the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Protestants and <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> high school graduates stillreveals an achievement enhancing impact, whereas the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor pers<strong>on</strong>s has becomeinsignificant compared to the reduced model. As in the case for reading, the latter resultindicates that the detrimental impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor pers<strong>on</strong>s occurs through the financial-budgetarychannel <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> school expenses. This influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the highly educated might indicate a preferencefor a better educati<strong>on</strong> in mathematics at the cant<strong>on</strong>al level. As in the case for reading, theinclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> revenue-driven input variables makes the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the populati<strong>on</strong> disappear. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>remaining cant<strong>on</strong>al predictors do not appear to be influential. As regards the revenue-driveninput variables, influences similar to those obtained for reading are found; most particularly,the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> mathematics teachers with a tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> appears to have a test score raisinginfluence <strong>on</strong> students, and the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the tertiary staff in the teachingpers<strong>on</strong>nel is also positive and close to statistical significance for the average student.Moreover, no remaining input c<strong>on</strong>trols, including the equipment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> schools with PCs, are <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>importance for the average student in mathematics. Again, the findings in the quantileregressi<strong>on</strong>s are very similar to those for the OLS. For more detailed estimati<strong>on</strong> results, see theAppendix <strong>on</strong> mathematics.Reflecti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the findings for mathematics – particularly a comparis<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the results for bothforms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model – leads to the c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> that the insignificance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy in the reduced form must have been caused by the mutual cancellati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> apositive (direct) influence and an assumedly negative <strong>on</strong>e induced by the revenue-driven inputfactors. Hence, in the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> mathematics, the results reflect both a performance dampeningindirect impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy through the budget and an achievement raising directimpact. This latter finding could indicate that in more directly democratic cant<strong>on</strong>s, theteaching <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> mathematics is favored. A sec<strong>on</strong>d c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> might be that fewer financial meansat the subfederal level do matter for student performance. As the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the directlegislati<strong>on</strong> changes through c<strong>on</strong>trol <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these inputs, which are also influenced by thisinstituti<strong>on</strong>, these inputs must play a decisive role in academic achievement.


– 228 –Overall, the robustness tests corroborate the findings for the original specificati<strong>on</strong> quite well.In additi<strong>on</strong>, imputati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the median to replace missing values increases the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>observati<strong>on</strong>s to roughly 10,000. Using several model specificati<strong>on</strong>s, the results are shown notalter c<strong>on</strong>siderably 258 . Again, in the reduced form, direct democracy does not appear to affectstudent performance c<strong>on</strong>siderably, while in the structural form it appears to be performanceenhancing. <strong>St</strong>udents in the 90th quantile <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al test score distributi<strong>on</strong> particularlyappear to pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>it from such a reallocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> given resources in mathematics.5.2 Results for Natural Science<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Reduced FormIn the reduced form, the OLS estimate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> adjustedstudent test scores indicates that for the average student from am<strong>on</strong>g the 1,410 students, thereis no significant effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> student performance in natural science (seetable 10.1 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendix). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> quantile regressi<strong>on</strong> estimati<strong>on</strong> results show that the impact<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy in the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al test score distributi<strong>on</strong> develops from a negative scorefor the lowest estimated quantile (-7.67) to a positive <strong>on</strong>e (3.05) for the highest quantile. Withrespect to significance, <strong>on</strong>ly a statistically weak effect is found for the 25th quantile. Asexpected, the hypothesis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> joint n<strong>on</strong>significance for the estimated percentiles cannot berejected. As regards the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the remaining c<strong>on</strong>trols, the reader is referred to theAppendix for natural science (see table 10.2).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> graph for natural science (figure 5) illustrates the development <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theindex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy for the entire c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al test score distributi<strong>on</strong> when revenuedriveninputs are not c<strong>on</strong>trolled for. Again, the dashed line represents the OLS estimate with asize <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> about -3, while the c<strong>on</strong>tinuous line reveals the coefficients <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy for the various percentiles <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the distributi<strong>on</strong>. It is obvious that the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy never reaches a significance level <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 5% or higher because the 95% c<strong>on</strong>fidenceinterval always intersects the 0-line. A Wald test for equality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> all estimated quantiles leads258 In the reduced form, the OLS estimate is always insignificant for all specificati<strong>on</strong>s and sample sizes. In thestructural form, exclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> classes with less than twenty students again corroborates the main findings(about 2600 observati<strong>on</strong>s). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> exclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> classes with less than 10 students and the inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a classsize variable, which is highly significant (at the 0.1% level), also leads to identical results (5000observati<strong>on</strong>s). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> omissi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> class size, however, appears to cause an omitted variable bias which causes adecline in significance levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the democracy variable (14.5% in the OLS regressi<strong>on</strong>, but still significant atthe 10% level for the 50th and 75th quantiles) and a rejecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> joint significance for the estimated quantiles.


– 229 –to no rejecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the H 0 -hypothesis 259 . Thus, both the graph and the tests support theobservati<strong>on</strong> that in the reduced form, the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy is not decisive forstudent performance in natural science. Further, this impact is identical in size for all studentsindependent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their individual, peer, and family characteristics.DirDem_2000-40.00 -20.00 0.00 20.00 40.000 .2 .4 .6 .8 1QuantileFigure 5: Natural Science; Reduced FormAs regards the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the sociodemographic, peer, and cant<strong>on</strong>al variables in the OLSmodel, <strong>on</strong>e <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the most interesting findings is probably the systematically worse performance<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female students compared to their male peers. This observati<strong>on</strong> is identical to that made forthe mathematics results but, again, is in c<strong>on</strong>trast to the outcome for reading. As alreadyobserved for mathematics and reading, selectivity is significantly associated with higher testscores. This impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> selectivity <strong>on</strong> natural science appears to be far str<strong>on</strong>ger in both size andlevel <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> significance then that observed for mathematics. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> peer effects for natural sciencemirror those for mathematics: again, more homogeneity in class performance influences thestudent test score positively, whereas the ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreign peers exerts a (weakly) oppositeinfluence, and the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> females is insignificant. With respect to thecant<strong>on</strong>al determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> educati<strong>on</strong>, an achievement increasing effect <strong>on</strong> the259 A pairwise Wald test for equality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the estimated quantiles reveals a weakly significant difference (at the10% level) between the 25th quantile and the 90th quantile <strong>on</strong>ly.


– 230 –average student is found for the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Protestants and a performance lowering effect for theshare <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor pers<strong>on</strong>s. Moreover, cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> appears influential. In additi<strong>on</strong>, theseresults are similar to the findings for mathematics. In c<strong>on</strong>trast to mathematics, however, noaggregate peer impact seems to exist for the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> highly educated pers<strong>on</strong>s, but adeleterious impact is observed for the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> people over 60. For natural science, quantileregressi<strong>on</strong> results are close to the findings in the OLS model. For more detailed regressi<strong>on</strong>output tables, the reader is referred to the Appendix for natural science (table 10.2).<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>ructural Form<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> structural form tests the instituti<strong>on</strong>al influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy when revenue-driveninputs are c<strong>on</strong>trolled for. For an average student am<strong>on</strong>g the 1,100 test takers, the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the variable <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> interest is positive but insignificant (see table 10.1). <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> quantile regressi<strong>on</strong>results in the structural form for the estimated quantiles corroborate the OLS results byrevealing no significant impact for any quantile (see table 10.3). In additi<strong>on</strong>, the hypothesis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>a joint significance for all estimated quantiles cannot be supported, which corroborates theobservati<strong>on</strong> that the instituti<strong>on</strong>al impact is negligible for the entire distributi<strong>on</strong>. This result canbe interpreted to mean that filtering out the influence through the subfederal budgetarychannel reveals no impact bey<strong>on</strong>d the <strong>on</strong>e; that is, a reallocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the means betweenstudents with differing levels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> academic achievement.As figure 6 shows, for the entire distributi<strong>on</strong>, the coefficient <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the instituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directlegislati<strong>on</strong> fluctuates around the OLS estimate, which intersects the ordinate at 6.25. A test forequality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> coefficients for the all estimated quantiles jointly shows that the effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy is <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> equal size for all students 260 . Again, interested readers can find more detailedinformati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the remaining determinants in the Appendix (see table 10.3).As regards the remaining sociodemographic, peer, and cant<strong>on</strong>al covariates in the OLS model,as already observed in the reduced form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model, female student gender is associatedwith lower academic achievement. In c<strong>on</strong>trast to the structural form result, the selectivity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>school is found not to be influential. This observati<strong>on</strong> is similar to that for mathematics.Again, it is c<strong>on</strong>jectured that it is through the resource channel at the school and class level thatselectivity unfolds its influence in the reduced model.260 In additi<strong>on</strong>, a pairwise test for equality for the estimated percentiles was never rejected.


– 231 –DirDem_2000-40.00 -20.00 0.00 20.00 40.000 .2 .4 .6 .8 1QuantileFigure 6: Natural Science; <strong>St</strong>ructural FormAs regards peer effects, most interestingly, the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> peer performance disappears in thestructural form for natural science, which was never observed for reading or mathematics.Also in c<strong>on</strong>trast, the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female peers exerts a small but significant deleterious effect <strong>on</strong>the average student's test scores. As in mathematics but in c<strong>on</strong>trast to reading, the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>foreign peers is also associated with lower academic achievement. In terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>alcharacteristics, a Protestant culture appears beneficial for students in natural science, an effectthat is very similar to the <strong>on</strong>e detected in the reduced model and for mathematics. Neither theshare <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> well-educated pers<strong>on</strong>s nor <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> poor pers<strong>on</strong>s appears decisive. In the latter case, it canagain be hypothesized that the breakdown <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this link in the reduced form indicates that thepoor pers<strong>on</strong>s' influence occurs through the budgetary channel. Additi<strong>on</strong>ally, this finding is inline with the results for mathematics. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> people over 60, however, as alreadyobserved in the reduced form, still impacts students test scores significantly and in adeleterious way.Patterns similar to those for reading and mathematics are also observed for some factors <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theinput endogenous variables that form part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the structural form. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> qualificati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> (naturalscience) teachers appears to be a very decisive predictor <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> student performance. In c<strong>on</strong>trast toreading and mathematics, however, a shortage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> (natural science and overall) teachers also


– 232 –appears to be influential in the expected directi<strong>on</strong>, while more hours <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> schooling improvesacademic achievement. Further, the lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> instructi<strong>on</strong>al material appears to be str<strong>on</strong>glyassociated with lower test performance in natural science. As in mathematics but in c<strong>on</strong>trast toreading, however, the equipment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the school with PCs is not an influential factor <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> testscores in natural science. Again, OLS estimates are very similar to the quantile regressi<strong>on</strong>results. For further informati<strong>on</strong>, the reader should c<strong>on</strong>sult table 10.3 <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Appendix.To summarize the findings for natural science, instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> do not appearto influence student performance in any way. A comparis<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the findings for the reducedand structural forms reveals no achievement decreasing impact through the budgetary channelin the reduced form, nor is any reallocative effect observable <strong>on</strong>ce revenue-driven inputs arec<strong>on</strong>trolled for. One possible interpretati<strong>on</strong> is that in natural science, in c<strong>on</strong>trast to reading andmathematics, there is not link between fewer subfederal means available for schooling,ultimately c<strong>on</strong>strained by direct democracy, and the endogenous input variables which areinfluential for academic achievement - in other words: in natural science, there is no linkbetween the equipment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> school and direct democracy for students in the ninth grade.Moreover, because no significant instituti<strong>on</strong>al effect is observable even though the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>observed students for natural science is similar to the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> mathematics test-takers, it isunlikely that the observed insignificance is caused by a small sample size. Thus, it isc<strong>on</strong>cluded that str<strong>on</strong>ger empowerment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the people has no effect whatsoever <strong>on</strong> studentperformance in natural science in the ninth grade.Testing several model specificati<strong>on</strong>s through the inclusi<strong>on</strong> and exclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> particularcovariates and varying the sample sizes reveals patterns similar to those observed in theoriginal models and the 'original' sample size. In additi<strong>on</strong>, imputati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the median to replacemissing values and admissi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> class sizes in natural science <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ten or more students, whichincreases the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> observati<strong>on</strong>s to roughly 4,700, do not alter the main findingsc<strong>on</strong>siderably 261 . In general, the results support the finding that the instituti<strong>on</strong>al impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>direct democracy is negligible both in the reduced and structural form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model.261 In the reduced form, the OLS estimate is insignificant, whereas for some quantiles a negative impactsignificant at the 10% level can be observed. In c<strong>on</strong>trast to the OLS estimati<strong>on</strong>, however, standard errors <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the quantile regressi<strong>on</strong> estimates are not corrected by clustering <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> schools which leads to an inflati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>significance levels. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> hypothesis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a joint significance for the estimated quantiles, however, is rejected.Significance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the instituti<strong>on</strong>al coefficient(s) in the structural form was never found.


– 233 –6 Comparis<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Results for Reading, Mathematics and Natural Science<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> empirical results for reading, mathematics, and natural science reflect completelydifferent findings and elicit interesting interpretati<strong>on</strong>s. In particular, differences occurredbetween mathematics and natural science even though both subjects were taken by acomparable number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> students and despite the fact that both subjects are linked to logicalthinking. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se results are discussed in more detail below with respect to the direct andindirect impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> overall student performance in a subject, the allocati<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> resources within a class for a particular subject, and, finally, the allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> givenresources between subjects.For both reading and mathematics, the indirect effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> appears to be testscore lowering, and for both subjects, the lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> available financial means for publiceducati<strong>on</strong> at the subfederal level appears resp<strong>on</strong>sible. This finding is in line with the findings<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> similar studies for the U.S. In additi<strong>on</strong>, these results indicate that equipping schools withphysical and human capital resources is important for student performance in these twosubjects. This result c<strong>on</strong>tradicts empirical literature by educati<strong>on</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omists who found nolink between school resources and student performance 262 . Such an observati<strong>on</strong>, however, isnot made for natural science, possibly because, in c<strong>on</strong>trast to the mathematics and readingtaught from the very beginning <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> compulsory schooling, physics and chemistry areintroduced into the school curricula <strong>on</strong>ly in higher grades 263 .No reallocative impact within the same subject through instituti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>student performance is detected for reading and natural science. For mathematics, however,direct legislati<strong>on</strong> is observed to cause a reallocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> available resources, <strong>on</strong>e that str<strong>on</strong>glyfavors students in the top <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al test score distributi<strong>on</strong> (90th quantile). This findingc<strong>on</strong>trasts with what could be expected if the median voter's child were in the median porti<strong>on</strong><str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al test score distributi<strong>on</strong>. It would, however, support this theory if thepreferences <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> parents <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> outstanding performers were such that they demanded greater effortin public educati<strong>on</strong> for their child than was being demanded by classmates' parents.262 This debate was launched by the review <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> HANUSHEK (1986) and his various later analyses (e.g. HANUSHEKet al. 1996) who found no relati<strong>on</strong>ship. C<strong>on</strong>tradictory results are obtained, however, by more recent studies(GRADDY and STEVENS 2003; PAN et al. 2003a, 2003b) and the new evidence cited there.263 Depending <strong>on</strong> the cant<strong>on</strong>, physics and chemistry are introduced either in the 7th or 8th grade.


– 234 –Regarding the direct impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> student test scores, the findings indicate aperformance enhancing effect for mathematics and an insignificant <strong>on</strong>e for reading andnatural science. This result is completely in c<strong>on</strong>trast to the performance lowering influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>tax limits detected when endogenous input variables are c<strong>on</strong>trolled for. This observati<strong>on</strong> maybe related to the finding by DOWNES et al (1998) <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a deleterious effect for both the reducedand the structural form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the educati<strong>on</strong>al producti<strong>on</strong> functi<strong>on</strong> 264 .A c<strong>on</strong>jecture about reallocati<strong>on</strong> between test subjects is possible if the results in the structuralforms for several test subjects are compared. Based <strong>on</strong> such a comparis<strong>on</strong>, it might bec<strong>on</strong>cluded that a reallocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> given means between school subjects, particularly a shift <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>given resources to mathematics, could have occurred. However, given that the regressi<strong>on</strong>results reflect <strong>on</strong>ly a small porti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the school curriculum, it is unclear whether theadditi<strong>on</strong>al resources for mathematics have been withdrawn from these two specific schoolsubjects or from other school subjects. What is clear, however, is that this reallocati<strong>on</strong> is tothe advantage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> mathematics in more directly democratic cant<strong>on</strong>s.7 C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>For the U.S., FIGLIO (1997) shows that local tax limits which reduced local revenue andspending lead to larger class sizes, lower teacher wages, and worse teacher quality but not toany reducti<strong>on</strong> in administrative pers<strong>on</strong>nel. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se results suggest that instead <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the expectedefficiency gains in the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this public good <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> schooling, a decline in the quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>educati<strong>on</strong>al service must have occurred. This decline in academic achievement is indeedreflected and corroborated by recent analyses <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> tax limits <strong>on</strong> studentperformances in the U.S. (e.g. FIGLIO and RUEBEN 2001). Such tax limits were demanded byand implemented through citizen's initiatives, an instituti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong>, in variousU.S. states. Based <strong>on</strong> these results for the U.S., a test score decreasing impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy <strong>on</strong> student achievement would not be surprising for Switzerland, as its politicalinstituti<strong>on</strong>s have been shown to restrain subfederal expenses for schooling.This study aims to provide such evidence for similar or dissimilar effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong><strong>on</strong> public educati<strong>on</strong> in Switzerland. Using a cross secti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individual data <strong>on</strong> student264 <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> endogenous input factors are student-teacher ratios in the district, mean teaching experience <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> teachers,and the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> highly qualified teachers.


– 235 –performance in Switzerland obtained from a nati<strong>on</strong>al study accompanying the OECD-PISAstudy, an educati<strong>on</strong>al producti<strong>on</strong> functi<strong>on</strong> augmented by instituti<strong>on</strong>al determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy is estimated. This model is similar to those employed both in public financestudies and in analyses by educati<strong>on</strong>al ec<strong>on</strong>omists. Two major variati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the producti<strong>on</strong>functi<strong>on</strong> are estimated: first, a reduced form that excludes endogenous input factors at theschool and class level (the reduced form) and sec<strong>on</strong>d, a structural versi<strong>on</strong> that includes thesefactors (the structural form). This model specificati<strong>on</strong> makes it possible to distinguish thedirect instituti<strong>on</strong>al impact from an indirect impact. Employed as a measure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy is a composite index that indicates the degree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> overall empowerment <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>citizenry.In the reduced form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model, the findings from the OLS regressi<strong>on</strong> indicate that a higherdegree <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy leads to lower performance by students in reading, but does notaffect mathematics and natural science. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> quantile regressi<strong>on</strong> analysis shows a c<strong>on</strong>spicuousperformance reducing effect for direct democracy across the entire c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>al test scoredistributi<strong>on</strong> in reading, which is equally str<strong>on</strong>g for the estimated quantiles. However, after theinclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> variables c<strong>on</strong>trolling for various revenue-driven input factors at the school andclass level, the negative influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy disappears completely for reading,whereas a positive <strong>on</strong>e emerges for mathematics. From this result, it is c<strong>on</strong>cluded that schooland class input factors whose quality is dependent <strong>on</strong> the school district's financial equipmentare important for student academic achievement in mathematics and reading. Moreover, thisfinding indicates that the test score lowering impact occurs through the subfederal budget,which is very similar to results obtained for the U.S. Finally, the estimati<strong>on</strong> outcomes for thestructural form also suggest that (a) there is no instituti<strong>on</strong>al influence <strong>on</strong> the distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>given resources am<strong>on</strong>g students in the same class in reading and natural science, but inmathematics, and (b) there exists no deleterious effect that goes bey<strong>on</strong>d the purely budgetaryimpact for reading and mathematics. In case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> natural science, no budgetary impact seemspresent at all. This last outcomes c<strong>on</strong>tradict the U.S. results in which a performance loweringimpact in the structural form <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the model is also found for various test subjects.Future research should address the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy at the school district levelbecause communal governments have a substantial say in schooling issues and financing inSwitzerland. In additi<strong>on</strong>, selecti<strong>on</strong> into treatment at the school district level should be takeninto account. In terms <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the primary research questi<strong>on</strong> addressed in this chapter, the


– 236 –applicati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a standard methodological approach from the field <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public finance revealsthat direct democracy has a substantial impact <strong>on</strong> public educati<strong>on</strong>, particularly <strong>on</strong> Swissstudent performance in reading. Based <strong>on</strong> the empirical results presented in this chapter, theSwiss electorate is advised to avoid further cuts in spending for public educati<strong>on</strong> and toincrease the share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> teachers with a tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> in their schools.


– 237 –8 Appendix: ReadingTable 8.1: OLS Regressi<strong>on</strong>s for ReadingReduced Form<strong>St</strong>ructural FormCoeff. t Coeff. t<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy -7.595* -1.98 -0.695 -0.16Latin regi<strong>on</strong> 1.073 0.09 8.579 0.69hisei2 4.497 0.54 5.974 0.72hisei3 18.009* 2.52 15.840* 2.12hisei4 15.707* 2.13 13.714(*) 1.86hisei5 30.095* 3.25 31.338*** 3.34hisei6 26.767*** 3.37 25.991** 3.22hisei7 34.188*** 3.54 31.298** 3.12No income data 0.535 0.07 -2.335 -0.28Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> siblings -0.774** -2.64 -0.815** -2.61Old student -28.223*** -3.23 -27.748** -2.69Young student 11.081*** 3.67 10.715*** 3.43Books at home 9.075*** 10.58 8.574*** 9.26No late arrival 2.263 0.76 2.962 0.95No PC at home -15.107*** -3.30 -13.151** -2.70Female 17.610*** 7.68 15.878*** 6.65Both parents work 0.096 0.04 -0.913 -0.37Intact family 0.466 0.15 0.117 0.03Native 2.198 0.41 0.211 0.04Foreign parents -6.019 -1.23 -5.468 -1.02Sec<strong>on</strong>d generati<strong>on</strong> 2.575 0.79 3.234 0.88N<strong>on</strong>-test language -14.755** -3.15 -17.529*** -3.44Parents low educati<strong>on</strong> -11.286* -2.18 -8.318 -1.60Parents medium educati<strong>on</strong> -13.724*** -4.69 -11.770*** -3.87Mother tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -11.794*** -3.70 -11.589*** -3.44Father tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -2.997 -1.05 -1.147 -0.38Discuss politics 8.129** 2.61 8.922** 2.70Listen to music -5.950 -0.99 -3.936 -0.64Discuss performance -8.861*** -3.49 -8.975*** -3.49Main meal 1.763 0.32 1.832 0.31Regular talking 5.752* 2.06 5.982* 2.02Village school -4.811 -0.46 -3.071 -0.29Small town school -3.694 -0.68 0.790 0.12


– 238 –Table 8.1: OLS Regressi<strong>on</strong>s for Reading (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Reduced Form<strong>St</strong>ructural FormCoeff. t Coeff. tCity school 12.025 1.29 2.897 0.26Private school 1.876 0.24 -0.996 -0.09Selective school 13.290** 2.84 5.960 1.18Regular tests 5.652 0.99 4.813 0.80Homework feedback -13.482*** -4.56 -11.524*** -3.84Problem discipline -12.062*** -3.83 -12.061*** -3.93Coefficient reading 7.391*** 4.26 5.597** 2.90Ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female 0.135 0.57 -0.043 -0.16Ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreign peers -0.653 -1.50 -0.587 -1.23High educati<strong>on</strong> 1.539 1.47 1.332 1.14Old people -0.284 -0.13 -2.324 -0.99Unemployment rate 7.160 0.83 5.722 0.58Protestants 0.560 1.49 0.742(*) 1.74Muslims 2.209 0.71 1.292 0.37No religi<strong>on</strong> -0.943 -0.72 0.419 0.28Poor pers<strong>on</strong>s -2.214*** -4.16 -1.668* -2.39Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> -0.200 -0.62 -0.322 -0.78Log (populati<strong>on</strong>) -25.102** -2.69 -15.487 -1.34Poor c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s 1 0.287 0.03Poor c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s 2 -9.700 -0.77No PC at school -7.158* -2.32Shortage teacher -2.735 -0.24Tertiary reading 20.146(*) 1.97Tertiary staff 25.380* 2.15Total hours 0.030 0.89<strong>St</strong>udent-teacher ratio -0.495 -0.79C<strong>on</strong>stant 746.308*** 6.77 597.282*** 4.38F-Test 29.06 28.38Adjusted R 2 0.26 0.26Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> observati<strong>on</strong>s 3411 2969OLS Regressi<strong>on</strong> with robust standard errors obtained through clustering <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> schools (176/149schools). Observati<strong>on</strong>s with missing values and a class size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> less than 20 have been deleted.


– 239 –Table 8.2: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Reading without Revenue-Driven Inputs (Reduced Form)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy -7.141(*) -1.82 -5.865(*) -1.96 -7.964** -2.82 -8.903** -3.01 -6.167(*) -1.70Latin regi<strong>on</strong> 22.213 1.56 14.442 1.46 -8.798 -0.99 -9.811 -1.05 -8.472 -0.74hisei2 -0.232 -0.02 -0.408 -0.03 5.007 0.51 6.468 0.50 4.014 0.28hisei3 26.436* 2.08 26.441* 2.47 16.123(*) 1.75 11.487 0.96 0.180 0.01hisei4 22.743(*) 1.81 20.393(*) 1.86 13.657 1.47 12.236 1.04 -0.536 -0.04hisei5 34.291* 2.30 24.236* 2.03 21.543(*) 1.85 24.805(*) 1.77 33.050(*) 1.89hisei6 37.234** 2.98 28.497** 2.60 17.563(*) 1.80 20.244(*) 1.67 24.844(*) 1.75hisei7 37.512* 2.10 43.201*** 3.50 27.437* 2.36 24.965(*) 1.82 17.616 1.10No income data 2.338 0.17 6.363 0.53 0.403 0.04 0.191** 0.01 -3.395 -0.23Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> siblings -0.477 -0.96 -0.370 -0.80 -0.819(*) -1.92 -1.075*** -3.55 -1.581** -3.13Old student -35.165** -2.66 -37.738*** -3.19 -26.379* -2.32 -18.025 -1.57 -24.077* -2.13Young student 14.250** 2.78 9.677* 2.31 11.292** 3.11 13.785*** 3.43 12.441* 2.47Books at home 8.409*** 5.05 8.870*** 6.86 9.005*** 7.67 9.603*** 8.28 10.063*** 8.26No late arrival 2.386 0.49 4.405 1.12 -0.815 -0.23 -3.279 -0.98 0.322 0.08No PC at home -11.906 -1.29 -12.282* -2.04 -12.134(*) -1.85 -10.832(*) -1.72 -9.469 -1.43Female 21.619*** 4.65 17.007*** 5.22 17.446*** 5.56 12.901*** 4.06 17.228*** 4.58Both parents work -1.729 -0.39 4.949 1.43 1.935 0.62 1.464 0.43 0.523 0.13Intact family 8.657 1.31 1.722 0.36 -0.235 -0.05 -4.204 -0.93 -2.206 -0.44Native 7.340 0.78 0.210 0.03 -4.748 -0.81 2.005 0.31 8.614 1.06Foreign parents -5.619 -0.68 -9.580 -1.40 -9.848 -1.53 -5.638 -0.77 3.619 0.48Sec<strong>on</strong>d generati<strong>on</strong> 13.700* 2.42 2.874 0.68 2.947 0.70 1.051 0.26 -5.988 -1.28


– 240 –Table 8.2: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Reading without Revenue-Driven Inputs (Reduced Form) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. tN<strong>on</strong>-test language -16.348(*) -1.77 -12.174(*) -1.82 -11.120(*) -1.93 -14.362* -2.49 -13.413(*) -1.88Parents low educati<strong>on</strong> -3.668 -0.43 -10.496 -1.59 -13.301* -2.12 -10.272 -1.53 -13.848(*) -1.68Parents medium educati<strong>on</strong> -15.970** -3.08 -15.484*** -4.04 -15.510*** -4.49 -12.511*** -3.43 -7.220(*) -1.65Mother tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -13.246* -2.15 -8.288(*) -1.83 -10.942** -2.69 -11.590** -2.93 -10.639(*) -1.93Father tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -5.393 -1.05 -3.238 -0.76 -2.068 -0.56 -5.061 -1.35 -5.281 -1.06Discuss politics 12.842* 2.02 5.758 1.25 7.709 1.56 9.862* 2.15 12.506* 2.04Listen to music 6.068 0.53 -7.995 -0.86 -9.145 -1.02 -8.141 -1.03 -10.694 -0.83Discuss performance -14.802** -3.00 -6.992* -2.04 -8.589** -2.63 -7.321* -2.12 -6.968(*) -1.79Main meal 17.790(*) 1.92 5.006 0.52 -2.303 -0.43 1.603 0.22 -6.203 -0.76Regular talking 4.435 0.92 7.441* 1.98 3.367 0.95 4.456 1.27 3.228 0.78Village school -5.047 -0.46 -9.265 -1.18 -11.108 -1.44 8.274 0.95 4.132 0.51Small town school -0.026 0.00 -2.290 -0.54 -2.122 -0.57 -2.717 -0.66 -6.062 -1.23City school 25.348* 2.13 19.234* 2.42 7.168 1.17 9.837 1.28 3.415 0.41Private school -0.244 -0.02 2.366 0.26 5.334 0.79 5.155 0.71 5.462 0.64Selective school 15.652*** 3.29 14.758*** 4.20 10.898** 2.96 10.871** 2.83 11.743** 2.69Regular tests -2.801 -0.46 4.838 0.98 3.728 0.73 5.985 1.24 11.859(*) 1.93Homework feedback -11.686* -2.35 -6.567 -1.60 -11.062*** -3.51 -10.289** -2.72 -12.762** -3.15Problem discipline -13.087** -2.93 -11.285** -3.13 -9.638** -2.94 -12.329*** -3.40 -18.062*** -4.33Coefficient reading 7.367*** 4.67 6.920*** 6.07 8.121*** 7.68 7.361*** 6.59 5.955*** 4.43Ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female 0.264 0.57 -0.060 -0.31 0.130 0.72 0.419* 2.16 0.306 1.41Ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreign peers -1.281*** -3.88 -0.986*** -3.50 -0.394 -1.59 -0.234 -0.77 -0.182 -0.54


– 241 –Table 8.2: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Reading without Revenue-Driven Inputs (Reduced Form) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. tHigh educati<strong>on</strong> 1.668 1.26 1.382 1.35 1.503 1.58 1.236 1.42 0.691 0.63Old people -0.207 -0.07 -2.435 -1.17 0.622 0.28 -0.025 -0.01 -0.781 -0.27Unemployment 13.934 1.45 5.138 0.70 7.941 1.32 7.361 1.02 15.673(*) 1.85Protestant 0.827(*) 1.94 0.597(*) 1.86 0.368 1.23 0.833** 2.85 1.246*** 3.95Muslim 3.330 0.95 2.682 0.95 1.813 0.71 3.420 1.46 3.235 1.14No religi<strong>on</strong> -0.112 -0.07 -1.467 -1.17 -1.252 -1.09 -1.483 -1.52 -1.204 -0.98Poor -3.756*** -5.01 -1.994*** -3.59 -1.822*** -3.45 -1.931** -3.14 -2.504*** -3.86Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> -0.558 -1.12 0.140 0.41 -0.186 -0.61 -0.115 -0.41 -0.223 -0.60Log (populati<strong>on</strong>) -29.095** -2.61 -27.056** -2.70 -23.843** -2.78 -30.616*** -3.97 -32.067*** -3.61C<strong>on</strong>stant 702.680*** 5.37 736.512*** 6.56 736.482*** 7.73 847.780*** 8.87 919.927*** 8.08Pseudo R 2 0.20 0.16 0.14 0.13 0.16Quantile regressi<strong>on</strong> for the 10th, the 25th, the 50th, the 75th, and the 90th quantiles. <strong>St</strong>andard errors are bootstrapped (1,000 replicati<strong>on</strong>s). Observati<strong>on</strong>s with missingvalues and with a class size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> less than 20 students have been deleted. 3,411 observati<strong>on</strong>s.


– 242 –Table 8.3: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Reading Including Revenue-Driven Inputs (<strong>St</strong>ructural Form)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy 4.168 0.83 -0.001 0.00 -1.759 -0.53 0.966 0.29 -4.620 -1.00Latin regi<strong>on</strong> 27.427 1.55 6.609 0.63 6.735 0.62 4.869 0.43 -1.190 -0.09hisei2 7.893 0.50 7.497 0.57 5.858 0.55 10.464 0.76 7.946 0.51hisei3 28.115(*) 1.89 23.921* 1.98 11.883 1.18 12.296 0.94 2.950 0.20hisei4 25.477 1.63 17.758 1.41 9.892 0.98 14.638 1.14 4.918 0.34hisei5 38.552* 2.12 29.371* 2.15 17.447 1.42 32.093* 2.17 42.113* 2.13hisei6 37.487* 2.43 28.277* 2.25 17.409(*) 1.65 24.104(*) 1.85 31.643* 2.09hisei7 32.207(*) 1.65 35.223* 2.30 18.777 1.48 34.275* 2.24 30.750(*) 1.68No income data -2.169 -0.13 0.168 0.01 -1.231 -0.11 5.511 0.38 -0.569 -0.04Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> siblings -0.889 -1.48 -0.628 -1.14 -0.428 -1.06 -1.315*** -3.98 -1.935*** -3.49Old student -42.0783 -2.33 -27.080(*) -1.91 -30.785* -2.48 -26.527(*) -1.95 -25.361(*) -1.83Young student 9.192(*) 1.68 6.109 1.45 9.328* 2.34 10.870* 2.52 12.325* 2.19Books at home 7.394*** 4.01 8.119*** 6.02 9.479*** 7.38 9.534*** 8.16 10.067*** 6.90No late arrival 9.956(*) 1.93 5.926 1.29 -1.264 -0.31 -4.090 -1.06 -0.075 -0.02No PC at home -9.467 -0.93 -11.243 -1.58 -12.416(*) -1.75 -12.269(*) -1.81 -7.440 -0.93Female 17.176*** 3.83 16.597*** 4.59 14.939*** 4.29 11.754*** 3.27 17.776*** 4.28Both parents work -2.909 -0.61 3.225 0.83 -0.431 -0.13 -0.581 -0.15 1.538 0.34Intact family 9.881 1.45 2.868 0.53 -1.373 -0.28 -4.119 -0.79 -0.230 -0.04Native -0.156 -0.02 1.959 0.24 -2.173 -0.33 0.296 0.04 5.672 0.61Foreign parents -8.527 -0.88 -4.008 -0.52 -4.260 -0.56 -6.747 -0.82 1.124 0.12Sec<strong>on</strong>d generati<strong>on</strong> 11.637* 1.98 5.297 1.03 5.650 1.26 2.239 0.46 -3.170 -0.58


– 243 –Table 8.3: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Reading Including Revenue-Driven Inputs (<strong>St</strong>ructural Form) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. tN<strong>on</strong>-test language -19.271* -2.14 -14.434(*) -1.89 -13.200* -2.10 -13.893* -2.14 -14.858* -2.03Parents low educati<strong>on</strong> -0.893 -0.09 -10.193 -1.46 -10.526 -1.56 -9.948 -1.39 -12.256 -1.40Parents medium educati<strong>on</strong> -13.458* -2.44 -12.419** -3.04 -9.051* -2.27 -12.825** -3.06 -4.227 -0.87Mother tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -10.485(*) -1.69 -11.555* -2.11 -10.494* -2.42 -13.057** -2.89 -12.876* -2.22Father tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -6.425 -1.18 -0.554 -0.12 2.173 0.53 -4.974 -1.19 -4.375 -0.82Discuss politics 16.077** 2.56 8.338 1.54 9.177(*) 1.68 11.014* 2.41 13.576* 1.96Listen to music 6.285 0.55 -5.897 -0.61 -5.519 -0.65 -6.637 -0.82 -13.205 -0.95Discuss performance -14.163** -3.01 -8.236* -2.24 -7.066* -2.00 -7.280(*) -1.90 -5.507 -1.23Main meal 11.101 1.14 9.395 1.02 -8.204 -1.27 4.872 0.65 -0.658 -0.06Regular talking 4.931 1.01 4.895 1.25 3.773 1.05 4.202 1.13 2.677 0.59Village school -2.491 -0.23 -14.228 -1.60 -9.416 -1.11 14.142 1.56 12.378 1.36Small town school 5.228 0.81 2.581 0.52 0.053 0.01 7.015 1.26 -1.274 -0.20City school 5.379 0.38 6.971 0.65 -2.643 -0.35 -2.568 -0.29 1.714 0.17Private school -4.807 -0.34 5.044 0.40 1.904 0.24 -11.225 -1.19 4.288 0.36Selective school 9.208 1.64 7.531 1.63 2.560 0.58 -0.157 -0.03 7.725 1.27Regular tests -1.961 -0.27 3.118 0.62 5.072 0.91 4.426 0.78 8.797 1.14Homework feedback -11.331* -2.34 -5.499 -1.29 -10.354** -2.97 -5.626 -1.41 -13.749** -2.96Problem discipline -16.128* -3.56 -11.503** -2.99 -12.732*** -3.60 -11.502** -3.11 -19.205*** -4.38Coefficient reading 5.875** 3.02 5.416*** 3.90 5.975*** 4.51 6.438*** 4.63 5.918*** 3.78Ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female -0.054 -0.18 0.051 0.22 -0.259 -1.24 0.129 0.56 0.122 0.46Ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreign peers -0.789(*) -1.87 -0.876** -2.72 -0.686* -2.19 0.226 0.58 0.008 0.02


– 244 –Table 8.3: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Reading Including Revenue-Driven Inputs (<strong>St</strong>ructural Form) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. tHigh educati<strong>on</strong> 0.278 0.18 0.738 0.63 1.423 1.31 1.719 1.64 0.769 0.67Old people -1.393 -0.50 -4.136(*) -1.74 -1.470 -0.62 -1.303 -0.49 -2.146 -0.68Unemployment 19.306(*) 1.73 9.140 1.19 5.206 0.65 2.054 0.23 11.415 1.17Protestant 0.879* 1.96 0.489 1.49 0.833* 2.29 1.063** 3.17 1.389*** 3.52Muslim -0.088 -0.02 -1.883 -0.66 2.702 0.89 3.239 1.19 6.744(*) 1.79No religi<strong>on</strong> 2.655 1.51 1.097 0.79 -0.272 -0.21 -1.651 -1.45 -1.347 -0.90Poor -3.160*** -3.58 -1.321* -2.20 -1.445* -2.12 -1.315(*) -1.85 -1.687(*) -1.93Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> -1.053(*) -1.89 -0.338 -0.83 -0.180 -0.54 0.119 0.34 -0.050 -0.12Log (populati<strong>on</strong>) -10.315 -0.79 -7.655 -0.77 -21.362* -2.06 -25.664** -2.99 -33.117** -2.90Poor c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s 1 9.562 0.89 0.736 0.08 8.175 0.94 -4.365 -0.53 -12.415 -1.31Poor c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s 2 -13.062 -0.79 -6.122 -0.49 -9.447 -0.79 -9.785 -0.76 -13.771 -0.86No PC at school -9.800(*) -1.65 -8.881* -1.99 -1.966 -0.47 -4.638 -1.06 -7.881 -1.43Teacher shortage -17.794 -1.53 -10.907 -1.23 5.125 0.71 8.580 1.07 7.948 0.71Tertiary reading 23.746(*) 1.92 26.727** 3.14 21.799** 2.56 13.595(*) 1.73 11.069 1.05Tertiary staff 29.565* 2.10 21.325(*) 1.82 26.327** 2.58 31.932** 3.10 15.983 1.40Total hours 0.030 0.70 0.058(*) 1.86 0.028 1.03 -0.006 -0.17 0.004 0.12<strong>St</strong>udent-teacher ratio -0.750 -0.94 -0.972 -1.40 -0.401 -0.69 -1.056 -1.46 0.904 0.98C<strong>on</strong>stant 433.718** 2.79 453.589*** 3.76 673.089*** 5.35 743.483*** 6.70 880.562*** 6.31Pseudo R 2 0.22 0.17 0.14 0.14 0.16Quantile regressi<strong>on</strong> for the 10th, the 25th, the 50th, the 75th, and the 90th quantiles <strong>St</strong>andard errors are bootstrapped (1000 replicati<strong>on</strong>s). Observati<strong>on</strong>s with missing valuesand with a class size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> less than 20 students have been deleted. 2,969 observati<strong>on</strong>s.


– 245 –9 Appendix: MathematicsTable 9.1: OLS Regressi<strong>on</strong> for MathematicsReduced Form<strong>St</strong>ructural FormCoeff. t Coeff. t<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy 2.220 0.52 11.582* 2.33Latin regi<strong>on</strong> 26.780* 1.99 37.743* 2.56hisei2 -1.501 -0.14 -4.443 -0.41hisei3 12.751 1.25 6.534 0.60hisei4 0.267 0.03 -4.423 -0.43hisei5 9.950 0.94 7.288 0.65hisei6 12.849 1.28 8.314 0.80hisei7 27.998* 2.23 27.284* 2.15No income data -9.630 -0.84 -15.622 -1.34Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> siblings -0.232 -0.53 0.094 0.21Old student -24.749* -2.35 -25.151* -2.16Young student 6.849 1.55 7.265 1.57Books at home 8.890*** 8.17 8.540*** 7.12No late arrival 4.280 1.09 5.301 1.18No PC at home -22.038** -2.81 -16.707(*) -1.88Female -27.889*** -8.43 -28.822*** -8.38Both parents work 0.963 0.26 -1.684 -0.42Intact family 2.926 0.59 6.075 1.17Native -2.324 -0.33 1.119 0.15Foreign parents -15.773* -2.25 -10.107 -1.35Sec<strong>on</strong>d generati<strong>on</strong> -4.854 -0.96 -4.794 -0.92N<strong>on</strong>-test language -16.148* -2.16 -15.995(*) -1.91Parents low educati<strong>on</strong> -3.878 -0.51 -6.177 -0.74Parents medium educati<strong>on</strong> -13.288*** -3.42 -12.330** -3.04Mother tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -8.908 -1.64 -8.060 -1.43Father tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -3.177 -0.70 -4.284 -0.89Discuss politics 2.099 0.46 2.555 0.50Listen to music -8.093 -0.88 -9.065 -0.95Discuss performance -10.117** -2.73 -7.556(*) -1.86Main meal 6.685 0.94 8.208 1.04Regular talking 3.720 0.97 2.343 0.59Village school -32.619** -2.97 -25.467** -2.74Small town school -10.232 -1.52 -6.170 -0.94


– 246 –Table 9.1: OLS Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Mathematics (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Reduced Form<strong>St</strong>ructural FormCoeff. t Coeff. tCity school 5.480 0.45 1.905 0.12Private school -7.076 -0.72 -5.211 -0.60Selective school 9.123(*) 1.69 3.302 0.69Regular tests 2.972 0.54 -1.391 -0.24Homework feedback -20.408*** -4.70 -19.054*** -4.15Discipline problem -2.706 -0.63 -5.117 -1.19Coefficient mathematics 3.642* 2.34 4.220*** 3.24Ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female peers 0.222 0.81 -0.093 -0.37Ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreign peers -1.141** -2.68 -1.223* -2.56High educati<strong>on</strong> 2.844* 2.10 3.392* 2.59Old people 0.465 0.13 -3.210 -0.91Unemployment rate 6.234 0.68 3.254 0.32Protestants 0.805(*) 1.88 1.064* 2.53Muslims 2.602 0.67 -0.520 -0.13No religi<strong>on</strong> -1.995 -1.24 -0.525 -0.30Poor pers<strong>on</strong>s -2.270** -2.91 -1.488 -1.57Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> 0.068 0.15 0.120 0.24Log (populati<strong>on</strong>) -19.773(*) -1.72 -9.486 -0.78Poor c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s 1 3.075 0.23Poor c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s 2 -2.871 -0.24No PC at school -5.650 -1.18Shortage teacher -1.981 -0.16Tertiary mathematics 23.373* 2.21Tertiary staff 20.806 1.59Total hours 0.071(*) 1.86<strong>St</strong>udent-teacher ratio -0.158 -0.24C<strong>on</strong>stant 678.331*** 5.06 452.594** 3.16F-Test 12.98 15.97Adjusted R 2 0.20 0.23Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Observati<strong>on</strong>s 1846 1596OLS Regressi<strong>on</strong> with robust standard errors obtained through clustering by schools (166/141schools). Observati<strong>on</strong>s with missing values and a class size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> less than 20 have been deleted.


– 247 –Table 9.2: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Mathematics without Revenue-Driven Inputs (Reduced Form)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy -6.182 -1.10 1.270 0.27 3.032 0.86 5.675 1.59 7.969 1.63Latin regi<strong>on</strong> 7.884 0.44 24.168(*) 1.77 34.891** 2.86 37.471*** 3.18 33.240* 2.13hisei2 -0.964 -0.04 5.178 0.35 7.650 0.53 -0.641 -0.04 -16.266 -0.85hisei3 22.655 0.91 19.985 1.60 14.063 1.03 13.193 0.85 6.303 0.34hisei4 10.859 0.44 -1.142 -0.08 0.269 0.02 -1.800 -0.11 -10.769 -0.54hisei5 11.636 0.42 6.807 0.37 11.717 0.70 10.734 0.60 -5.614 -0.25hisei6 19.262 0.77 9.122 0.66 11.834 0.80 20.576 1.27 8.220 0.42hisei7 43.173 1.55 24.552 1.43 33.660(*) 1.93 23.963 1.39 1.766 0.07No income data -8.870 -0.34 -10.062 -0.66 -4.985 -0.31 -5.159 -0.30 -10.362 -0.46Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> siblings -0.145 -0.17 0.034 0.06 -0.483 -0.97 -0.362 -0.51 -0.452 -0.58Old student -25.482 -1.30 -34.568* -2.15 -18.275 -1.05 -32.452** -2.71 -53.650** -3.15Young student 8.552 1.03 8.484 1.38 3.154 0.59 4.481 0.72 5.891 0.77Books at home 6.911** 2.74 6.255*** 3.30 9.949*** 6.08 8.766*** 5.23 10.324*** 4.37No late arrival 7.460 1.07 4.696 0.80 6.832 1.33 4.443 0.88 2.808 0.39No PC at home -34.039* -2.38 -31.027** -2.70 -15.052(*) -1.81 -17.873(*) -1.90 -12.300 -0.96Female -38.814*** -6.50 -32.787*** -6.86 -27.603*** -6.10 -18.859*** -4.15 -20.438** -3.11Both parents work 5.226 0.74 1.817 0.34 1.650 0.34 -0.232 -0.05 0.107 0.02Intact family 9.765 1.09 6.194 0.74 -2.499 -0.40 -5.628 -0.79 -5.865 -0.66Native 0.415 0.03 -6.652 -0.54 -3.014 -0.33 1.114 0.12 -12.847 -0.91Foreign parents -13.902 -1.04 -15.096 -1.38 -23.312** -2.65 -4.503 -0.47 -18.860(*) -1.75Sec<strong>on</strong>d generati<strong>on</strong> -5.344 -0.54 -1.293 -0.17 -4.966 -0.76 -0.788 -0.12 -5.030 -0.66


– 248 –Table 9.2: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Mathematics without Revenue-Driven Inputs (Reduced Form) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. tN<strong>on</strong>-test language -21.235 -1.59 -21.178* -2.07 -10.553 -1.25 -17.477(*) -1.81 -9.212 -0.90Parents low educati<strong>on</strong> 7.269 0.59 1.484 0.15 -9.782 -1.10 -17.951* -2.00 -6.731 -0.48Parents medium educati<strong>on</strong> -20.587** -2.98 -16.337** -2.87 -14.837** -2.78 -5.020 -0.94 -3.287 -0.45Mother tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -21.731** -2.58 -7.119 -0.91 -3.255 -0.45 -10.308 -1.63 -4.374 -0.47Father tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -5.650 -0.80 0.219 0.03 -5.402 -0.95 1.802 0.32 5.085 0.65Discuss politics 0.115 0.01 3.489 0.43 0.230 0.03 4.458 0.68 -0.680 -0.08Listen to music 2.007 0.10 -8.128 -0.61 -17.842 -1.28 -10.312 -0.87 -13.345 -0.85Discuss performance -7.167 -1.00 -11.957* -2.19 -11.636* -2.38 -12.753** -2.74 -17.779** -2.74Main meal 17.957 1.33 11.982 1.12 10.113 1.17 3.942 0.40 5.239 0.41Regular talking -0.250 -0.04 10.631 1.88 4.115 0.79 1.107 0.22 1.189 0.17Village school -34.066* -2.18 -30.874** -2.62 -31.713** -2.87 -14.331 -1.45 -40.886*** -3.48Small town school -10.461 -1.32 -11.061(*) -1.79 -8.522(*) -1.68 -9.184(*) -1.71 -13.958 -1.64City school -0.478 -0.02 17.551 1.61 10.231 0.92 -0.143 -0.01 -15.060 -1.19Private school 16.106 1.20 3.584 0.33 -15.419 -1.49 -12.129 -0.94 -1.415 -0.11Selective school 2.047 0.29 9.964(*) 1.66 13.453** 2.69 10.145 1.79 -1.579 -0.23Regular tests -13.185 -1.53 -4.249 -0.59 9.971 1.61 7.114 0.99 7.158 0.67Homework feedback -15.988* -2.08 -21.009*** -3.70 -21.045*** -3.92 -18.326*** -3.49 -15.133* -2.15Problem discipline 2.951 0.42 -1.940 -0.34 -2.548 -0.52 -6.117 -1.29 -12.677* -2.08Coefficient mathematics 3.224* 2.06 3.133* 2.28 3.449** 2.72 5.849*** 4.23 6.084** 2.77Ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female peers -0.046 -0.13 0.345 1.18 0.458(*) 1.68 0.217 0.77 -0.021 -0.06Ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreign peers -1.468** -2.91 -1.606*** -3.82 -1.090** -2.80 -0.270 -0.72 -0.272 -0.50


– 249 –Table 9.2: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Mathematics without Revenue-Driven Inputs (Reduced Form) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. tHigh educati<strong>on</strong> 2.973 1.56 1.376 0.88 2.612(*) 1.81 3.976** 3.05 4.415* 2.51Old people -2.129 -0.55 -4.336 -1.26 1.695 0.39 5.838(*) 1.69 7.836(*) 1.65Unemployment rate 12.184 0.91 10.302 1.09 2.891 0.34 5.942 0.65 1.156 0.09Protestants 0.796 1.60 1.007** 3.00 0.888* 2.19 0.943* 2.03 0.603 1.27Muslims 4.022 0.90 0.761 0.23 4.245 1.12 4.562 1.18 4.134 1.03No religi<strong>on</strong> -1.270 -0.60 -1.555 -0.93 -2.649(*) -1.83 -3.105(*) -1.99 -2.861 -1.52Poor pers<strong>on</strong>s -3.003** -2.87 -2.026** -2.61 -2.023(*) -1.95 -2.709*** -3.29 -1.966(*) -1.73Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> -0.134 -0.21 0.331 0.64 0.295 0.67 -0.022 -0.05 -0.022 -0.04Log (populati<strong>on</strong>) -29.590* -2.00 -19.901(*) -1.90 -24.789* -2.20 -17.679 -1.58 -9.096 -0.72C<strong>on</strong>stant 811.463*** 4.60 727.519*** 5.55 687.969*** 5.25 555.037*** 4.02 488.471** 3.09Pseudo R 2 0.15 0.14 0.13 0.13 0.12Quantile regressi<strong>on</strong> for the 10th, the 25th, the 50th, the 75th, and the 90th quantiles. <strong>St</strong>andard errors are bootstrapped (1,500 replicati<strong>on</strong>s). Observati<strong>on</strong>s with missingvalues and with a class size in natural science <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> less than 20 students have been deleted. 1,846 observati<strong>on</strong>s.


– 250 –Table 9.3: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Mathematics Including Revenue-Driven Inputs (<strong>St</strong>ructural Form)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy 1.103 0.14 5.326 0.89 10.961* 2.24 12.767* 2.54 24.816*** 3.83Latin regi<strong>on</strong> 2.708 0.14 12.154 0.67 48.398*** 3.58 48.053*** 3.45 46.662** 3.06hisei2 -2.873 -0.11 6.587 0.34 -0.001 0.00 -5.518 -0.36 -22.759 -1.16hisei3 18.679 0.82 21.598 1.22 5.641 0.38 3.222 0.23 -0.518 -0.03hisei4 0.718 0.03 9.288 0.52 -8.353 -0.56 -12.045 -0.87 -11.045 -0.55hisei5 3.284 0.12 23.803 1.02 5.701 0.32 8.962 0.53 -1.487 -0.07hisei6 5.345 0.23 16.873 0.93 3.760 0.24 11.989 0.81 3.218 0.16hisei7 29.109 1.10 44.554* 2.05 29.366 1.63 15.408 0.95 6.521 0.24No income data -11.722 -0.48 -12.459 -0.59 -14.993 -0.89 -9.097 -0.52 3.813 0.17Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> siblings 0.463 0.54 0.541 0.79 -0.426 -0.68 -0.356 -0.47 -0.480 -0.55Old student -11.635 -0.55 -32.042 -1.57 -19.748 -0.99 -34.641* -2.03 -52.359* -2.00Young student 11.605 1.38 6.588 0.92 1.226 0.20 6.101 0.90 6.745 0.85Books at home 7.450** 2.72 6.124** 2.97 9.206*** 5.16 9.182*** 4.89 11.337*** 4.56No late arrival 12.609(*) 1.72 9.313 1.45 1.727 0.31 2.786 0.48 -4.190 -0.52No PC at home -37.626** -2.56 -19.068 -1.56 -13.201 -1.38 -15.205 -1.54 -7.312 -0.51Female -31.683*** -5.18 -33.300*** -6.35 -26.771*** -5.55 -18.343*** -3.57 -21.269*** -3.33Both parents work 1.714 0.23 -4.377 -0.74 -4.433 -0.86 -1.923 -0.34 -4.741 -0.64Intact family 14.418 1.45 11.840 1.33 -2.492 -0.37 -2.447 -0.31 -6.689 -0.74Native 5.292 0.34 1.317 0.11 -5.473 -0.49 6.776 0.63 -16.856 -1.13Foreign parents -11.203 -0.86 -8.613 -0.74 -24.807* -2.32 -0.675 -0.07 -19.469(*) -1.70Sec<strong>on</strong>d generati<strong>on</strong> -7.052 -0.73 -1.528 -0.19 -12.136 -1.63 -1.921 -0.28 -2.430 -0.27


– 251 –Table 9.3: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Mathematics Including Revenue-Driven Inputs (<strong>St</strong>ructural Form) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. tN<strong>on</strong>-test language -9.658 -0.68 -18.676(*) -1.83 -20.858* -2.16 -16.484(*) -1.65 -5.471 -0.43Parents low educati<strong>on</strong> 1.419 0.10 -3.545 -0.35 -8.450 -0.85 -18.982(*) -1.76 -5.843 -0.37Parents medium educati<strong>on</strong> -22.634** -3.03 -16.028* -2.54 -11.825* -2.20 -5.182 -0.91 -0.873 -0.13Mother tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -16.514(*) -1.72 -6.935 -0.95 -6.778 -0.97 -7.010 -0.94 -6.868 -0.74Father tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -6.483 -0.80 -7.063 -1.11 -5.465 -0.90 -2.254 -0.33 6.212 0.71Discuss politics -5.734 -0.61 4.263 0.50 -1.808 -0.25 3.608 0.47 8.321 0.87Listen to music -11.395 -0.67 -14.060 -1.01 -14.275 -0.96 -11.298 -0.83 -7.873 -0.45Discuss performance 3.049 0.41 -4.370 -0.75 -7.006 -1.44 -10.833(*) -1.94 -22.159** -3.10Main meal 19.004 1.47 11.211 0.87 4.904 0.48 9.139 0.86 1.048 0.07Regular talking -3.317 -0.46 9.291 1.42 1.398 0.26 -3.002 -0.55 0.492 0.07Village school -30.301(*) -1.91 -23.462(*) -1.65 -21.638(*) -1.82 -11.246 -1.07 -22.569(*) -1.87Small town school -8.155 -0.83 -5.873 -0.75 -6.186 -1.02 -5.075 -0.82 -1.196 -0.13City school 8.978 0.40 12.806 0.92 10.606 0.83 3.596 0.31 -23.947(*) -1.77Private school 5.870 0.40 0.893 0.08 -10.995 -1.00 -6.948 -0.56 -5.172 -0.37Selective school -2.740 -0.30 -1.919 -0.26 9.947 1.66 7.491 1.16 1.962 0.22Regular tests -7.738 -0.81 -5.746 -0.71 2.730 0.37 1.772 0.22 -1.526 -0.14Homework feedback -22.410** -2.70 -19.059** -3.11 -18.683*** -3.26 -18.388*** -3.34 -11.123 -1.52Discipline problem -4.919 -0.64 1.307 0.21 -3.276 -0.64 -7.627 -1.45 -9.926 -1.57Coefficient mathematics 2.843 1.33 2.842 1.62 3.803** 2.68 5.055*** 3.35 6.113* 2.37Ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female peers -0.010 -0.02 0.068 0.20 -0.142 -0.49 -0.144 -0.44 -0.358 -0.96Ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreign peers -1.859* -2.38 -1.743*** -3.43 -1.282** -2.94 -0.473 -0.96 -0.141 -0.24


– 252 –Table 9.3: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Mathematics Including Revenue-Driven Inputs (<strong>St</strong>ructural Form) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. tHigh educati<strong>on</strong> 1.833 0.80 1.776 1.03 2.442 1.63 4.917** 2.93 5.785** 2.99Old people -6.140 -1.38 -6.314 -1.56 -3.958 -0.92 1.483 0.39 0.196 0.04Unemployment rate 8.652 0.64 8.073 0.65 1.565 0.16 7.899 0.67 1.595 0.11Protestants 0.660 1.33 0.680 1.55 1.375*** 3.18 1.627*** 3.39 1.434* 2.28Muslims 0.771 0.16 -1.406 -0.34 -0.068 -0.02 4.085 1.01 -2.429 -0.50No religi<strong>on</strong> 0.891 0.30 1.433 0.69 -1.559 -0.96 -3.532(*) -1.89 -2.919 -1.40Poor pers<strong>on</strong>s -1.253 -1.05 -1.424 -1.33 -1.109 -1.03 -2.408* -2.43 -0.798 -0.61Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> -0.265 -0.32 -0.355 -0.53 0.445 0.87 0.371 0.65 0.896 1.55Log (populati<strong>on</strong>) -12.298 -0.59 -0.214 -0.02 -16.676 -1.42 -25.489* -1.97 -17.996 -1.26Poor c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s 1 -10.837 -0.54 7.515 0.42 -1.319 -0.11 6.586 0.51 6.575 0.45Poor c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s 2 27.850 1.26 -1.384 -0.08 -12.745 -0.72 3.455 0.20 -30.795 -1.39No PC at school -5.127 -0.59 -11.987 -1.54 -8.201 -1.39 -6.610 -0.94 4.858 0.56Teacher shortage 5.725 0.40 -2.757 -0.23 4.332 0.45 -7.934 -0.85 -16.573 -1.22Tertiary mathematics 51.826*** 3.28 24.753(*) 1.89 17.357 1.49 14.842 1.40 31.509* 2.45Tertiary staff -5.885 -0.28 27.775 1.47 34.614* 2.23 13.884 1.05 5.280 0.29Total hours 0.077 1.19 0.044 0.93 0.045 1.22 0.052 1.29 0.073 1.50<strong>St</strong>udent-teacher ratio -0.661 -0.65 -0.131 -0.16 -0.449 -0.48 0.101 0.11 0.080 0.08C<strong>on</strong>stant 540.222* 2.02 441.658* 2.36 600.131*** 4.03 579.891*** 3.60 477.995** 2.61Pseudo R 2 0.17 0.16 0.15 0.14 0.14Quantile regressi<strong>on</strong> for the 10th, the 25th, the 50th, the 75th, and the 90th quantiles. <strong>St</strong>andard errors are bootstrapped (1,500 replicati<strong>on</strong>s). Observati<strong>on</strong>s with missing valuesand with a class size in mathematics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> less than 20 students have been deleted. 1,596 observati<strong>on</strong>s.


– 253 –10 Appendix: Natural ScienceTable 10.1: OLS Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Natural ScienceReduced Form<strong>St</strong>ructural FormCoeff. t Coeff t<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy -3.128 -0.63 6.255 1.39Latin regi<strong>on</strong> 30.738* 2.09 6.950 0.46hisei2 -18.209 -1.15 -26.336 -1.58hisei3 1.891 0.13 -10.887 -0.68hisei4 -0.969 -0.06 -16.220 -0.99hisei5 25.826 1.51 10.176 0.56hisei6 21.398 1.39 6.325 0.38hisei7 32.522(*) 1.96 19.064 1.06No income data -14.473 -0.90 -20.495 -1.16Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> siblings -1.358(*) -1.73 -1.872* -2.13Old student -21.996 -1.41 -19.335 -1.15Young student 10.746(*) 1.65 7.802 1.00Books at home 7.879*** 4.97 6.666*** 3.62No late arrival 17.796*** 3.33 17.255** 2.87No PC at home -14.857 -1.49 -24.519* -2.47Female -18.157*** -4.54 -21.516*** -4.82Both parents work -3.436 -0.89 0.646 0.14Intact family 7.967 1.44 10.941(*) 1.75Native 18.718(*) 1.70 11.629 0.92Foreign parents -8.991 -0.78 -15.866 -1.09Sec<strong>on</strong>d generati<strong>on</strong> 4.463 0.68 -0.820 -0.12N<strong>on</strong>-test language -5.894 -0.62 -12.885 -1.19Parents low educati<strong>on</strong> -10.944 -1.21 -4.962 -0.56Parents medium educati<strong>on</strong> -17.858*** -3.44 -15.786** -2.78Mother tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -4.382 -0.72 -1.681 -0.25Father tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -5.291 -1.17 -0.785 -0.15Discuss politics 4.714 0.86 2.770 0.45Listen to music 9.846 0.75 21.285 1.34Discuss performance -12.514** -2.66 -8.716(*) -1.78Main meal -1.778 -0.18 -5.469 -0.52Regular talking -2.183 -0.52 0.130 0.03Village school -20.445(*) -1.81 -19.693 -1.50Small town school -6.104 -0.79 -6.177 -0.81City school 17.477 1.16 18.253 1.04


– 254 –Table 10.1: OLS Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Natural Science (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Reduced Form<strong>St</strong>ructural FormCoeff. t Coeff tPrivate school 2.186 0.26 11.749 1.51Selective school 17.758** 2.82 1.953 0.25Regular tests 11.837 1.26 7.537 0.83Homework feedback -10.158* -2.02 -8.329 -1.44Discipline problem -11.850** -2.60 -4.504 -0.95Coefficient natural science 4.876* 2.36 1.606 0.66Ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female peers -0.356 -1.11 -0.868* -2.20Ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreign peers -1.015(*) -1.82 -1.038(*) -1.93High educati<strong>on</strong> -0.621 -0.43 -0.216 -0.13Old people -7.291* -2.26 -10.033** -2.73Unemployment rate 1.882 0.15 -0.755 -0.05Protestants 1.025* 2.11 1.014(*) 1.95Muslims 1.884 0.50 -1.566 -0.36No religi<strong>on</strong> -0.643 -0.36 1.288 0.58Poor pers<strong>on</strong>s -1.579* -2.13 -0.451 -0.42Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> 0.334 0.84 -0.062 -0.15Log (populati<strong>on</strong>) -25.123* -2.14 -12.017 -0.88Poor c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s 1 6.668 0.46Poor c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s 2 -41.770* -2.02No PC at school 4.068 0.65Teacher shortage -33.854* -2.47Tertiary Science 25.256* 2.37Tertiary staff 39.016** 2.61Total hours 0.097(*) 1.83<strong>St</strong>udent-teacher ratio 0.960 1.30C<strong>on</strong>stant 884.143*** 6.61 664.068*** 4.16F-Test 16.13 33.47Adjusted R 2 0.25 0.29Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> observati<strong>on</strong>s 1410 1126OLS regressi<strong>on</strong> with robust standard errors obtained through clustering by schools (157schools). Observati<strong>on</strong>s with missing values and a class size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> less than 20 have been deleted


Table 10.2: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Natural Science without Revenue-Driven Inputs (Reduced Form)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy -7.668 -1.08 -8.105(*) -1.81 -2.702 -0.60 0.102 0.02 3.052 0.56Latin regi<strong>on</strong> 23.925 1.02 24.685 1.51 34.196* 2.13 43.662* 2.42 24.046 1.20hisei2 18.192 0.53 -16.347 -0.88 -21.155 -1.22 -9.598 -0.45 -19.095 -0.69hisei3 47.900 1.48 5.878 0.35 1.030 0.07 17.408 0.88 -14.504 -0.57hisei4 46.898 1.43 -0.672 -0.04 0.572 0.04 5.943 0.30 -26.053 -1.00hisei5 52.135 1.29 31.577 1.55 14.278 0.78 24.123 1.01 15.166 0.49hisei6 73.672* 2.23 20.383 1.17 21.058 1.32 25.921 1.26 3.524 0.13hisei7 83.204* 2.15 36.642(*) 1.68 27.842 1.47 30.615 1.32 6.239 0.18No income data 23.238 0.62 -10.606 -0.53 -16.859 -0.88 2.891 0.12 -23.048 -0.85Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> siblings -1.069 -0.72 -0.783 -0.89 -1.461(*) -1.66 -1.169 -1.35 -1.388 -1.32Old student -38.491 -1.16 -30.285 -1.58 -17.624 -0.68 10.355 0.58 -0.578 -0.04Young student 3.081 0.29 13.119 1.54 7.181 0.82 7.517 0.97 11.932 1.04Books at home 6.494(*) 1.91 8.720*** 3.87 7.726*** 3.63 8.711*** 3.91 9.592*** 3.47No late arrival 30.102** 3.05 16.838* 2.12 18.391** 2.63 4.024 0.59 12.426(*) 1.65No PC at home 16.707 1.29 -12.746 -1.20 -29.327* -2.50 -30.552** -2.89 -29.986* -2.16Female -21.175** -2.69 -19.311** -3.09 -22.508*** -4.15 -19.166*** -3.44 -18.084* -2.56Both parents work 6.535 0.72 -3.456 -0.56 -2.379 -0.42 -4.743 -0.73 -10.254 -1.29Intact family 2.831 0.23 7.640 0.88 5.932 0.67 10.141 1.37 8.864 0.89Native 48.299* 2.20 17.710 1.23 5.689 0.47 10.547 0.94 -2.370 -0.13Foreign parents 2.378 0.12 -3.523 -0.27 -16.742 -1.34 -29.717* -2.36 -23.802 -1.49Sec<strong>on</strong>d generati<strong>on</strong> 15.142 1.50 10.159 1.11 3.360 0.44 -2.983 -0.42 -9.661 -0.87


– 256 –Table 10.2: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Natural Science without Revenue-Driven Inputs (Reduced Form) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. tN<strong>on</strong>-test language -7.871 -0.41 -12.892 -1.02 -0.820 -0.06 5.278 0.40 -0.618 -0.05Parents low educati<strong>on</strong> -38.094 -1.61 -11.194 -0.71 -5.072 -0.42 -5.091 -0.42 -20.558 -1.35Parents medium educati<strong>on</strong> -35.475*** -3.74 -20.690** -2.72 -8.098 -1.23 -7.788 -1.23 -13.412(*) -1.72Mother tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -15.724 -1.43 0.800 0.09 -3.504 -0.45 -1.983 -0.26 -9.908 -1.01Father tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -14.113 -1.46 -6.266 -0.80 -2.586 -0.40 -3.513 -0.52 -6.365 -0.78Discuss politics 8.800 0.74 4.706 0.50 1.636 0.19 8.777 1.11 7.763 0.69Listen to music -0.548 -0.03 -14.796 -0.84 -3.706 -0.19 14.894 1.00 1.332 0.05Discuss performance -14.735(*) -1.67 -13.374(*) -1.80 -7.711 -1.20 -12.634* -2.07 -15.571(*) -1.91Main meal 10.022 0.51 -0.674 -0.05 -6.299 -0.48 -7.318 -0.82 2.081 0.18Regular talking 3.170 0.36 2.389 0.39 -3.951 -0.64 -4.285 -0.74 -5.737 -0.81Village school -24.427 -1.25 -20.149(*) -1.67 -20.939 -1.57 -12.984 -1.16 -12.948 -0.86Small town school 1.579 0.14 -11.794 -1.52 -9.572 -1.32 -4.529 -0.61 -2.643 -0.25City school 1.236 0.05 5.034 0.22 25.843 1.27 23.779 1.49 13.501 0.61Private school -6.097 -0.35 10.464 0.75 10.591 0.96 -5.948 -0.59 -8.323 -0.57Selective school 15.228(*) 1.72 16.660* 2.28 18.967** 2.66 17.453** 2.58 12.238 1.41Regular tests 19.585 1.43 18.001(*) 1.77 10.309 1.07 5.635 0.57 -3.442 -0.27Homework feedback 5.279 0.60 -12.558(*) -1.82 -11.284 -1.54 -13.152(*) -1.83 -14.765(*) -1.73Discipline problem -12.826 -1.45 -9.625 -1.53 -10.372(*) -1.70 -18.503** -3.08 -18.434* -2.52Coefficient natural science 3.354 1.06 4.852* 2.38 6.044** 3.08 4.495* 2.02 6.823* 2.40Ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female peers -0.314 -0.55 -0.253 -0.72 -0.297 -0.93 -0.346 -1.01 -0.585 -1.31Ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreign peers -0.615 -0.90 -1.418*** -3.25 -1.400** -2.78 -1.088(*) -1.94 -0.506 -0.67


– 257 –Table 10.2: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Natural Science without Revenue-Driven Inputs (Reduced Form) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. tHigh educati<strong>on</strong> -1.379 -0.51 -0.317 -0.16 -1.891 -1.20 0.432 0.25 3.020 1.35Old people -6.461 -0.88 -7.204 -1.56 -7.428(*) -1.76 -2.586 -0.64 1.923 0.44Unemployment rate 2.006 0.12 -7.824 -0.58 0.927 0.08 4.835 0.35 14.295 0.81Protestants 0.817 1.10 0.922(*) 1.87 0.776* 1.98 1.292** 2.78 0.721 1.23Muslims 4.603 0.68 1.028 0.23 2.008 0.58 5.943 1.53 2.475 0.51No religi<strong>on</strong> -0.102 -0.04 -0.091 -0.05 0.526 0.35 -2.545 -1.41 -3.237 -1.41Poor pers<strong>on</strong>s -2.313 -1.40 -1.860(*) -1.82 -1.412 -1.49 -2.012(*) -1.93 -1.433 -1.20Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> 0.422 0.61 0.469 0.85 0.342 0.76 0.551 1.04 -0.057 -0.10Log (populati<strong>on</strong>) -34.727* -1.98 -26.746* -2.21 -17.145(*) -1.79 -31.944* -2.52 -23.616 -1.35C<strong>on</strong>stant 847.703*** 4.05 878.293*** 5.36 820.816*** 6.27 911.757*** 6.07 790.745*** 3.99Pseudo R 2 0.19 0.18 0.16 0.15 0.16Quantile regressi<strong>on</strong> for the 10th, the 25th, the 50th, the 75th, and the 90th quantiles. <strong>St</strong>andard errors are bootstrapped (1000 replicati<strong>on</strong>s). Observati<strong>on</strong>s with missingvalues and with a class size in natural science <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> less than 20 students have been deleted. 1,410 observati<strong>on</strong>s.


– 258 –Table 10.3: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Natural Science Including Revenue-Driven Inputs (<strong>St</strong>ructural Form)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy -0.349 -0.04 3.590 0.57 5.624 1.00 7.973 1.41 13.179 1.61Latin regi<strong>on</strong> -49.684* -2.10 -18.261 -0.95 18.636 1.07 37.696(*) 1.94 55.552** 2.57hisei2 15.494 0.46 -24.616 -1.13 -32.866(*) -1.72 -25.373 -1.15 -40.191 -1.48hisei3 32.949 1.02 -6.015 -0.28 -3.173 -0.18 -10.986 -0.52 -38.014 -1.57hisei4 28.565 0.87 -9.447 -0.45 -7.630 -0.43 -16.546 -0.78 -47.827(*) -1.94hisei5 49.230 1.29 28.754 1.14 5.602 0.27 2.690 0.10 -10.751 -0.33hisei6 48.165 1.46 8.686 0.39 12.532 0.68 5.105 0.24 -23.589 -0.91hisei7 89.089* 2.35 37.999 1.53 19.621 0.93 12.972 0.50 -24.288 -0.63No income data 42.696 1.13 -7.708 -0.31 -15.461 -0.73 -13.408 -0.52 -43.255 -1.56Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> siblings -0.613 -0.39 -0.505 -0.42 -1.428 -1.61 -0.963 -0.80 -2.085(*) -1.75Old student -15.846 -0.59 -34.456(*) -1.66 0.604 0.02 -1.408 -0.08 -2.771 -0.15Young student 10.647 0.87 8.382 0.83 10.127 1.10 -0.171 -0.02 3.008 0.25Books at home 8.308* 2.31 6.479* 2.21 6.862** 2.93 6.379* 2.51 6.462(*) 1.90No late arrival 34.569** 2.94 16.798(*) 1.84 19.212** 2.60 9.125 1.16 15.828(*) 1.69No PC at home 2.253 0.14 -9.348 -0.73 -33.596** -2.73 -36.155** -2.81 -38.189* -2.54Female -25.156** -3.09 -18.090** -2.66 -26.397*** -4.41 -21.960*** -3.33 -16.857* -2.21Both parents work 11.314 1.17 0.546 0.07 1.344 0.22 -3.926 -0.57 0.201 0.02Intact family 1.402 0.11 6.584 0.61 10.829 1.18 4.541 0.48 3.435 0.33Native 60.175* 2.06 19.665 1.16 -7.516 -0.56 11.883 0.83 5.688 0.26Foreign parents 17.782 0.81 -5.241 -0.31 -38.623* -2.47 -23.185 -1.49 -27.194 -1.41


– 259 –Table 10.3: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Natural Science Including Revenue-Driven Inputs (<strong>St</strong>ructural Form) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. tSec<strong>on</strong>d generati<strong>on</strong> -3.726 -0.34 -0.751 -0.07 0.583 0.07 -8.643 -0.92 -12.267 -0.96N<strong>on</strong>-test language -35.496(*) -1.65 -20.902 -1.25 4.996 0.34 -6.084 -0.44 5.521 0.35Parents low educati<strong>on</strong> -38.046(*) -1.72 -14.404 -0.88 -1.170 -0.09 -0.516 -0.04 -27.905(*) -1.69Parents medium educati<strong>on</strong> -33.955** -3.12 -24.413** -2.74 -7.710 -1.06 -4.227 -0.58 -3.416 -0.40Mother tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -3.211 -0.26 -0.709 -0.07 -0.577 -0.07 2.744 0.30 9.556 0.75Father tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> -8.995 -0.83 -3.974 -0.44 -3.295 -0.45 -7.743 -1.02 0.225 0.02Discuss politics -1.769 -0.14 -6.244 -0.58 -0.148 -0.02 5.797 0.60 9.529 0.78Listen to music -20.442 -0.81 -12.316 -0.53 5.261 0.28 26.799 1.32 28.367 0.71Discuss performance -11.038 -1.07 -4.202 -0.50 -2.413 -0.38 -12.074(*) -1.80 -14.648 -1.61Main meal 10.828 0.54 -1.615 -0.11 -13.200 -1.08 -8.742 -0.80 1.162 0.09Regular talking -2.762 -0.31 2.452 0.32 0.206 0.04 2.374 0.36 -0.565 -0.07Village school -55.343* -2.55 -45.081* -2.37 -0.214 -0.01 -5.719 -0.41 7.661 0.45Small town school -18.726 -1.61 -15.835 -1.64 -3.892 -0.42 2.264 0.23 14.437 1.28City school -22.678 -0.57 38.774 1.63 24.526 1.27 31.989 1.46 29.730 1.05Private school 23.530 1.04 37.381* 2.47 12.965 1.15 -2.219 -0.18 -29.093(*) -1.75Selective school -17.119 -1.40 -4.357 -0.42 8.516 1.11 4.078 0.50 3.913 0.34Regular tests 14.751 1.03 15.260 1.23 15.491 1.43 9.013 0.74 -13.103 -0.84Homework feedback 6.197 0.66 -5.635 -0.66 -10.167 -1.39 -19.244* -2.46 -11.809 -1.17Discipline problem -3.843 -0.43 -7.270 -1.05 -6.966 -1.10 -9.283 -1.38 -5.834 -0.71Coefficient natural science -4.081 -0.89 -1.266 -0.38 3.720 1.40 4.278 1.43 8.146* 2.37


– 260 –Table 10.3: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Natural Science Including Revenue-Driven Inputs (<strong>St</strong>ructural Form) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. tRatio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female peers -1.748* -2.54 -1.072* -2.08 -0.694(*) -1.74 -0.815(*) -1.87 -0.531 -0.96Ratio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreign peers -1.799* -2.09 -2.042** -3.48 -1.342* -2.38 -0.717 -1.00 0.547 0.63High educati<strong>on</strong> 1.332 0.41 0.303 0.11 -0.525 -0.22 0.669 0.26 1.950 0.58Old people -7.777 -0.86 -14.358* -2.34 -8.376 -1.57 -6.717 -1.26 -0.417 -0.06Unemployment rate 11.210 0.49 2.175 0.13 -4.250 -0.29 -9.219 -0.55 -3.240 -0.15Protestants 0.979 1.12 1.291* 2.16 1.050* 2.14 1.065* 1.97 0.910 1.34Muslims -10.339 -1.32 -3.636 -0.64 -0.774 -0.17 2.960 0.60 7.312 1.12No religi<strong>on</strong> 5.393 1.41 1.859 0.60 1.548 0.66 -1.608 -0.62 -4.608 -1.27Poor pers<strong>on</strong>s -2.476 -1.18 -1.404 -0.92 -0.618 -0.43 -0.162 -0.12 -0.291 -0.17Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> -1.493 -1.69 -0.374 -0.48 0.224 0.37 0.619 1.04 0.700 1.03Log (populati<strong>on</strong>) -3.506 -0.14 -17.776 -1.01 -14.198 -1.17 -16.597 -1.19 -22.204 -1.17Poor c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s 1 -51.514* -2.07 -21.928 -1.11 21.593 1.14 18.442 1.13 22.430 1.19Poor c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s 2 -57.630 -1.23 -39.101 -1.10 -63.711(*) -1.93 -30.922 -0.91 -36.484 -0.97No PC at school 8.291 0.60 0.691 0.07 9.791 1.22 5.124 0.61 -1.104 -0.11Teacher shortage -38.262(*) -1.72 -32.346 -1.63 -32.586* -2.24 -27.201(*) -1.73 -17.926 -0.95Tertiary science 17.137 1.02 18.168 1.41 29.903** 2.58 26.854* 2.14 26.252(*) 1.83Tertiary staff 57.610* 2.24 57.703** 3.10 31.536* 2.09 33.029* 1.99 37.787(*) 1.76Total hours 0.235* 2.99 0.115* 2.16 0.071 1.43 0.072 1.26 0.016 0.24<strong>St</strong>udent-teacher ratio 1.532 1.01 1.481 1.28 1.240 1.22 -0.244 -0.22 -0.701 -0.47C<strong>on</strong>stant 376.348 1.17 782.396*** 3.55 667.196** 3.88 694.026*** 3.52 684.400** 2.96


– 261 –Table 10.3: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> for Natural Science Including Revenue-Driven Inputs (<strong>St</strong>ructural Form) (c<strong>on</strong>t.)q10 q25 q50 q75 q90Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. t Coeff. tPseudo R 2 0.25 0.22 0.20 0.18 0.19Quantile regressi<strong>on</strong> for the 10th, the 25th, the 50th, the 75th, and the 90th quantiles. <strong>St</strong>andard errors are bootstrapped (1,000 replicati<strong>on</strong>s). Observati<strong>on</strong>s with missingvalues and with a class size in natural science <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> less than 20 students have been deleted. 1,126 observati<strong>on</strong>s.


– 262 –11 Appendix: Descriptive <strong>St</strong>atisticsDependent variableTable 11.1: Descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> VariablesVariables Descripti<strong>on</strong> SourceWARM estimate (weighted likelihood estimate) in reading, mathematics or naturalscience: difficulty adjusted test score<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy Index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy from 1 (min.) to 6 (max.) in 2000Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyOwn calculati<strong>on</strong> based <strong>on</strong>STUTZER (1999)Latin regi<strong>on</strong> 1 if language community is either French- or Italian-speaking, 0 otherwise (cantreg) Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyIndividual and familyvariablesPISA Internati<strong>on</strong>al Socio-Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Occupati<strong>on</strong>al <strong>St</strong>atus <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the parents as ahisei2proxy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> income, 28 - 37 index pointsNati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyhisei3 38 - 47 index points Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyhisei4 48 - 57 index points Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyhisei5 58 - 67 index points Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyhisei6 68 - 77 index points Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyhisei7 >78 index points Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyNo income data 1 if missing value in hisei-Index (hisei), 0 otherwise Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyNumber <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> siblings Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> siblings (nsib) Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyOld student 1 if student older than 204 m<strong>on</strong>ths / 15 years (age), 0 otherwise Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyYoung student 1 if student younger than 180 m<strong>on</strong>ths / 17 years (age), 0 otherwise Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyBooks at home Number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> books at home (st37q01) Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA study1 if student claims never to have arrived late for school in the last two school weeksNo late arrival(st29q03), 0 otherwiseNati<strong>on</strong>al PISA study


– 263 –Table 11.1: Descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Variables (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Variables Descripti<strong>on</strong> SourceNo PC at home 1 if student never has access to a PC at home (it01q01), 0 otherwise Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyFemale 1 if student is female, 0 otherwise (st03q01) Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyBoth parents work 1 if both parents work, either full time or part time (st07q01, st06q01), 0 otherwise Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyIntact family 1 if student usually lives with father and mother (st04q01, st04q03), 0 otherwise Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyNative 1 if country <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> birth is Switzerland (st16q01), 0 otherwise Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA study1 if country <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> birth <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> both father and mother is not Switzerland (st16q02,Foreign parentsst16q03), 0 otherwiseNati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studySec<strong>on</strong>d generati<strong>on</strong> 1 if <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>e parent is born abroad (st16q02, st16q03), 0 otherwise Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyN<strong>on</strong>-test language 1 if language spoken at home is not test-language (st17q01), 0 otherwise Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyFather and/or mother completed <strong>on</strong>ly primary educati<strong>on</strong> or did not go to schoolParents low educati<strong>on</strong> (fisced, misced)Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyParents medium educati<strong>on</strong> Father and/or mother completed lower sec<strong>on</strong>dary level (fisced, misced) Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyMother tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> Mother completed tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> (misced) Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyFather tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> Father completed tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> (fisced) Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA study1 if student regularly discusses political or social issues with parents (st19q01), 0Discuss politicsotherwiseNati<strong>on</strong>al PISA study1 if student regularly listens to classical music together with parents (st19q03), 0Listen to musicotherwiseNati<strong>on</strong>al PISA study1 if student regularly discusses school performance with parents (st19q04), 0Discuss performanotherwiseNati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyMain meal togetherRegular talkingSchool and class variables1 if several times a week parents eat main meal with student (st19q05), 0 otherwise Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA study1 if several times a week parents spend time just talking to the student (st19q06), 0Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyotherwiseVillage school 1 if school is located in a village (< 3000 E) (sc01q01), 0 otherwise Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studySmall town school 1 if school is located in a small town (3000 - 15,000) (sc01q01), 0 otherwise Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyCity school 1 if school is located in a city (100,000 to 1,000000) (sc01q01), 0 otherwise Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyPrivate school 1 if school is private, 0 otherwise (sc03q01) Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA study


– 264 –Selective schoolRegular testsHomework feedbackTable 11.1: Descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Variables (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Variables Descripti<strong>on</strong> SourceDiscipline problemPeer variablesCoefficient reading /mathematics / natural scienceRatio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> femalesRatio <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> foreign studentsCant<strong>on</strong>al variables1 if admissi<strong>on</strong> to school is always based <strong>on</strong> student's record <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> academicperformance including placement tests, 0 otherwise1 if students are assessed four or more times a year using standardized or teacherdeveloped tests, 0 otherwise (sc16q01, sc16q02)1 if homework is counted as part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> mark or teachers grade homework most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thetime or always (st32q07, st32q03), 0 otherwise1 if in most less<strong>on</strong>s or in every less<strong>on</strong>, students d<strong>on</strong>'t listen to what the teacher says,students d<strong>on</strong>'t start working for a l<strong>on</strong>g time after the less<strong>on</strong> begins, there is noiseand disorder, or at the start <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> class more than five minutes are spent doing nothing(st26q13, st16q14, st26q16, st26q17)Peers' mean performance divided by peers' standard deviati<strong>on</strong> in test subjectShare <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> female students in student's peer groupShare <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> students born abroad in student's peer groupNati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyNati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyNati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyNati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyCalculati<strong>on</strong> based <strong>on</strong> Nati<strong>on</strong>alPISA studyCalculati<strong>on</strong> based <strong>on</strong> Nati<strong>on</strong>alPISA studyCalculati<strong>on</strong> based <strong>on</strong> Nati<strong>on</strong>alPISA studyHigh educati<strong>on</strong> Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al residents with a tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> or a high school degree Swiss Federal <strong>St</strong>atistical OfficeOld people Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al residents older than 65 years Swiss Federal <strong>St</strong>atistical OfficeUnemployment Cant<strong>on</strong>al unemployment rate Swiss Federal <strong>St</strong>atistical OfficeProtestant Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Protestant residents in cant<strong>on</strong> Swiss Federal <strong>St</strong>atistical OfficeMuslim Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Muslim residents in cant<strong>on</strong> Swiss Federal <strong>St</strong>atistical OfficeNo religi<strong>on</strong> Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> residents with no religious affiliati<strong>on</strong> Swiss Federal <strong>St</strong>atistical OfficePoor peopleShare <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> pers<strong>on</strong>s who cannot afford savings <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 100 Swiss Francs per m<strong>on</strong>thOwn calculati<strong>on</strong> based <strong>on</strong> SwissHousehold Panel, wave 2000Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> residents living in agglomerati<strong>on</strong>s with at least 100,000 inhabitants Swiss Federal <strong>St</strong>atistical OfficeLog (populati<strong>on</strong>) Natural logarithm <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al residential populati<strong>on</strong> Swiss Federal <strong>St</strong>atistical Office


– 265 –Table 11.1: Descripti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Variables (c<strong>on</strong>t.)Variables Descripti<strong>on</strong> SourceRevenue-driven inputs1 if school suffers from poor building, poor heating and/or inadequate spacePoor c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s 1(sc11q01 sc11q02 sc11q03), 0 otherwiseNati<strong>on</strong>al PISA study1 if school suffers from a lack <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> instructi<strong>on</strong>al material and /or a poor library [a lot]Poor c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s 2(sc11q04 sc11q06 ), 0 otherwiseNati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyNo PC at school 1 if student has no access to PC at school (it01q02), 0 otherwise Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA study1 if a shortage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> teachers in general and/or test subject teachers in particularNati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyTeacher shortage[Some/a lot] (sc21q01, sc21q02/ sc21q03/ sc21q04), 0 otherwiseTertiary reading / mathematics Proporti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> language teachers with tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> at school/ natural science(propread / propmath / propscie)Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyProporti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> teachers with a tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> teaching staff at schoolNati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyTertiary staff(propqual)Total hours Total number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> schooling hours per year (tothrs) Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA study<strong>St</strong>udent-teacher ratio <strong>St</strong>udent-teacher ratio as school size divided by number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> teachers (stratio) Nati<strong>on</strong>al PISA studyNotes: In parentheses are the names <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the variables <strong>on</strong> which the determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> student performance are based. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se labels are identical to those used in theOECD-PISA study c<strong>on</strong>ducted by the OECD in 2000. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> questi<strong>on</strong>naires used for the Swiss nati<strong>on</strong>al study are also identical to those used for the PISA study withthe excepti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a few questi<strong>on</strong>s which are irrelevant to this model specificati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se labels also provide informati<strong>on</strong> about which questi<strong>on</strong>naire c<strong>on</strong>tained theoriginal questi<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first two letters either indicate 'st' for student questi<strong>on</strong>naire, 'it' for the informati<strong>on</strong> technology questi<strong>on</strong>naire, or 'sc' for the schoolquesti<strong>on</strong>naire. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> first two digits then stand for the number <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the general issue, and 'qXX' for the related single questi<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> following variables have alreadybeen derived and computed by the issuing instituti<strong>on</strong>: wleread, hisei, nsib, miscedu, fiscedu, stratio, tothrs and are already part <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the dataset. More informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>the c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> these variables can be obtained from the issuing instituti<strong>on</strong> at http://www.sidos.ch/data/projects/pisa/ (13/04/2004). Base categories are schoolsin small towns (15,000 to 100,000 inhabitants), a low parental income (hisei1: below 28 index points), and a high but not tertiary educati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> parents (misced = 4or 5, fisced = 4 or 5).


– 266 –Table 11.2: Indices <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> for the Year 2000VIR GIR GRR FRR<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>Zürich 3.333 3.333 3.333 4.000 3.500Bern 2.667 2.667 3.000 3.750 3.021Luzern 4.667 5.333 3.667 4.000 4.417Uri 5.333 5.333 5.333 4.500 5.125Schwyz 5.333 5.333 4.667 4.375 4.927Obwalden 5.333 5.333 4.333 3.500 4.625Nidwalden 4.000 4.333 4.667 4.750 4.438Glarus 6.000 6.000 6.000 5.000 5.750Zug 5.000 5.000 3.667 4.000 4.417Freiburg 3.000 3.000 2.667 2.500 2.792Solothurn 5.333 5.333 5.333 5.000 5.250Basel-<strong>St</strong>adt 4.667 4.667 4.000 4.250 4.396Basel-Land 6.000 6.000 5..167 4.750 5.479Schaffhausen 5.333 5.333 5.167 5.000 5.208AppenzellAusserrhoden6.000 6.000 6.000 4.000 5.500AppenzellInnerrhoden6.000 6.000 6.000 3.750 5.438<strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong> 3.333 4.000 3.000 3.500 3.458Graubünden 4.333 5.000 6.000 4.000 4.833Aargau 5.667 5.667 6.000 4.500 5.458Thurgau 4.000 4.000 4.333 5.000 4.333Tessin 1.333 2.667 2.000 3.000 2.250Waadt 2.333 2.667 2.000 3.000 2.500Wallis 4.333 5.000 4.000 1.000 3.583Neuenburg 2.667 2.667 1.667 1.750 2.188Genf 2.000 2.000 2.000 1.000 1.750Jura 4.667 4.667 3.000 2.500 3.708VIR indicates index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> c<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al initiative, GIR index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> statutory initiative, GRRindex <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> statutory referendum, and FRR index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fiscal referendum, respectively. Swisscant<strong>on</strong>s appear in so-called historical sequence and in German denominati<strong>on</strong>.


– 267 –Table 11.3: Distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Observati<strong>on</strong>s for Reading in Swiss Cant<strong>on</strong>sReduced form<strong>St</strong>ructural formComplete data set(French & nati<strong>on</strong>al sample)Zürich 157 134 1102Bern 364 332 1062Luzern 63 54 256Uri - - -Schwyz 25 25 109Obwalden 18 18 120Nidwalden - - 39Glarus 8 8 20Zug 11 11 78Freiburg 567 510 998Solothurn 18 18 113Basel-<strong>St</strong>adt 42 41 173Basel-Landschaft 50 26 200Schaffhausen - - 46Appenzell- - 27AusserrhodenAppenzell- - -Innerrhoden<strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong> 370 240 1061Graubünden 20 20 155Aargau 210 167 470Thurgau 62 50 207Tessin - - 903Waadt 220 204 1101Wallis 350 346 1046Neuenburg 362 362 869Genf 319 228 919Jura 175 175 722<strong>St</strong>udents in1418 1144 5126German-speakingcant<strong>on</strong>s<strong>St</strong>udents in Frenchspeaking1993 1825 5655cant<strong>on</strong>sSum 3411 2969 11796Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s appear in so-called historical sequence and in German denominati<strong>on</strong>.


– 268 –Table 11.4: Descriptive <strong>St</strong>atistics for Reading, Mathematics and Natural ScienceVariable Obs. Mean <strong>St</strong>d. Dev. Min MaxFull samplewleread 11781 500.6531 89.52575 23.89 884.49wlescie 6557 500.6293 95.24182 168.60 830.09wlemath 6545 531.7902 90.78325 202.14 815.90Nati<strong>on</strong>al samplewleread 7979 498.2971 92.53197 27.60 884.49wlescie 4443 497.6009 95.63797 168.60 830.09wlemath 4440 529.5631 94.06256 202.14 815.90Reduced form samplewleread 3411 534.2979 77.08092 98.22 812.88wlescie 1410 533.6809 87.79413 186.60 804.54wlemath 1846 560.9948 79.62094 202.14 815.9<strong>St</strong>ructural formsamplewleread 2969 535.5002 76.71042 166.01 812.88wlescie 1126 537.611 88.60316 168.60 804.54wlemath 1596 560.9478 80.14506 202.14 815.9


– 269 –Table 11.5: Determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Educati<strong>on</strong>al Spending in SwissCant<strong>on</strong>s, Outliers Excluded, 1980–1998Variable Coefficient t-value<str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> democracy -0.056** 2.75Cant<strong>on</strong>s with Italian orFrench main language -0.087 1.62Fiscal decentralizati<strong>on</strong> -0.420*** 5.11Tax competiti<strong>on</strong> -0.058 1.35Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> lump sum transfers 0.025 0.69C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>straint(fiscal break) 0.005 0.54C<strong>on</strong>servative ideology<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> government -0.141* 2.48Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> nati<strong>on</strong>al income 0.158(*) 1.95Urbanizati<strong>on</strong> 0.242*** 3.40Log <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>al populati<strong>on</strong> 0.016 0.93Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> young people -0.013 1.51Share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> old people -0.024*** 3.39C<strong>on</strong>stant 6.863*** 5.82Adjusted R 2 0.83F-statistic 83.64Jarcque-Bera test (χ-value) 4.52Observati<strong>on</strong>s 4912SLS estimati<strong>on</strong> with Newey-West standard errors. ***indicates significance atthe 0.1% level, **at the 1% level, *at the 5% level and (*) at the 10% level,respectively. Estimati<strong>on</strong> with year dummies.


– 270 –Chapter VII:C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>


– 271 –C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>This dissertati<strong>on</strong> began with the statement that ec<strong>on</strong>omic theory predicts that a directdemocracy should result in greater citizen happiness compared to more representativedemocratic systems because it enables an allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> goods and resources that is closer tocitizens' preferences. Transmissi<strong>on</strong> channels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy may include higher pers<strong>on</strong>alincome induced by shrunken government budgets and more efficient allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> publicgoods caused by the taming <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Leviathan-like bureaucrats and politicians.In this dissertati<strong>on</strong>, I investigate the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> happiness and exploreadditi<strong>on</strong>al channels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> transmissi<strong>on</strong> bey<strong>on</strong>d those already detected in previous studies. Mostparticularly, as channels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> transmissi<strong>on</strong>, I focus <strong>on</strong> income redistributi<strong>on</strong>, studentperformance, and public safety. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se individual studies have been realized using cant<strong>on</strong>aldata <strong>on</strong> redistributi<strong>on</strong>, crime rates, police and educati<strong>on</strong>al expenditure, and individual data <strong>on</strong>student performance and life satisfacti<strong>on</strong> for Switzerland.As a first step, reported in chapter II, I carry out an update <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the composite index <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy for the years 1997 to 2003, necessitated by the many revisi<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> cant<strong>on</strong>alc<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s that took place during this period. Despite these amendments, the index valuesappear to be very stable over time. Most <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the empirical analyses outlined in the remainingchapters are performed using this updated index. Chapter III reinvestigates the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>direct democracy <strong>on</strong> happiness using a more recent dataset than the <strong>on</strong>e employed in previousstudies; namely, Swiss panel data from 2000 to 2002. It is shown that there is no l<strong>on</strong>ger anystatistically significant relati<strong>on</strong> between direct democracy and life satisfacti<strong>on</strong> in the Swissdata. This breakdown for the Swiss data is possibly caused by the inclusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> variables thatc<strong>on</strong>trol for culture which removes too much variati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the instituti<strong>on</strong>al variable to allowc<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al significance levels. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>refore, statistical insignificance does not mean that inreal life direct democracy has no (positive) impact <strong>on</strong> subjective well-being in Switzerland.Based <strong>on</strong> these results, the next natural step is to search for possible channels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> transmissi<strong>on</strong>.First to be analyzed was the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> income redistributi<strong>on</strong>. Based <strong>on</strong> atraditi<strong>on</strong>al public choice approach and using a time-series cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al panel from 1980 to1998, it is shown that direct democracy leads to fewer financial resources available forincome redistributi<strong>on</strong> and a smaller absolute volume, which was actually redistributed (asmeasured by the difference between the pre- and after-tax income distributi<strong>on</strong>). This policy


– 272 –should lead, <strong>on</strong> average, to a higher after-tax income for citizens. Moreover, the after-taxincome inequality appears to be lower in more direct democratic cant<strong>on</strong>s than in those with amore representative political system. Finally, it is also shown that citizens in directdemocracies are flexible enough to actually increase their financial volume for redistributi<strong>on</strong>if the pre-tax income inequality is high. Based <strong>on</strong> these results, it can be c<strong>on</strong>cluded that,ceteris paribus, redistributi<strong>on</strong> is carried out more efficiently in direct democracies than inmore representative democratic systems, e.g. through that needy pers<strong>on</strong>s in the lowestquantile(s) pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>it more from redistributi<strong>on</strong>.Another transmissi<strong>on</strong> channel <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> happiness is the public safety policycarried out by the Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s. Using a bounded rati<strong>on</strong>ality theory combined with a publicchoice analysis and estimating an ec<strong>on</strong>omic model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> crime with Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>al data from1986 to 2001, I show that in direct democracies, scarce resources are allocated in such a waythat the median voter’s preferences are better met than in more representative systems. First,the results corroborate the hypothesis that the median voter prefers fewer means to be spent<strong>on</strong> crime preventi<strong>on</strong> and investigati<strong>on</strong> because he or she underestimates the probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>occurrence. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, the c<strong>on</strong>jecture that because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> bounded rati<strong>on</strong>ality the voter prefers thefighting <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> property crime to the preventi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> hate crime is found to be in line with myregressi<strong>on</strong> analysis outcomes. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>se additi<strong>on</strong>al costs <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> fighting crime – particularly propertyspecificcrimes – appear to be financed through efficiency gains in the preventi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> thosecrimes that are less prominent in the median voter's memory. Hence, my findings support bothprimary hypotheses: (a) direct democracy leads to an allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> goods and resources closerto the median voter’s preferences and (b) it induces gains in efficiency.Finally, I also investigate the impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> public educati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ninth gradersusing a cross-secti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> individual data from 2000 for reading, mathematics, and naturalscience. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> results for the first two subjects indicate that an educati<strong>on</strong>al expenditurerestrainingimpact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy appears to translate into lower student performance.For both subjects, it is mainly teacher qualificati<strong>on</strong>s that play a dominant role am<strong>on</strong>g therevenue-driven school input factors. Separating the direct impact from the indirect budgetaryeffect reveals a performance increasing influence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy <strong>on</strong> mathematics;however, the direct impact <strong>on</strong> reading becomes insignificant. This finding is very important inthat it c<strong>on</strong>trasts with the negative results found for a similar instituti<strong>on</strong> in a comparablepolitical setting for the U.S. Bey<strong>on</strong>d the negative budgetary impact, no further performance


– 273 –lowering impact is detected, which might indicate the n<strong>on</strong>existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Leviathan-likebehavior by the school administrati<strong>on</strong>. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> positive effect <strong>on</strong> reading might either hint at aredistributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> given means am<strong>on</strong>g subjects taught at school or an unobserved engagement<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> parents or family culture that favors mathematics. In general, in the case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>the educati<strong>on</strong>, I find no evidence that the median voter's preferences are not addressed by theschool administrati<strong>on</strong>.In sum, although in my reestimati<strong>on</strong> for Switzerland the happiness increasing impact <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> directdemocracy in Swiss cant<strong>on</strong>s ranges <strong>on</strong>ly from weak to insignificant, I identify up to threefurther transmissi<strong>on</strong> channels <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct legislative instituti<strong>on</strong>s. In all, the median voter'spreferences are found to be more closely adhered to in more direct democratic cant<strong>on</strong>s than inmore representative democratic systems, and no evidence for the existence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a Leviathan-likebureaucracy is revealed. Hence, the basic hypotheses <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> public choice regarding the utilityincreasing allocative effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> direct democracy can be viewed as more or less supported bythese empirical findings <strong>on</strong> redistributi<strong>on</strong>, public safety, and educati<strong>on</strong>.


– 274 –References


– 275 –ReferencesABRAMOWITZ, M. (1959), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Welfare Interpretati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Secular Trends in Nati<strong>on</strong>al Incomeand Product, in: M. ABRAMOWITZ et al. (eds.), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Allocati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Resources:Essays in H<strong>on</strong>or <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Bernard Francis Haley, <strong>St</strong>anford University Press, <strong>St</strong>anford 1959, pp.1 – 22.ACIR (U.S. Advisory Commissi<strong>on</strong> in Intergovernmental Relati<strong>on</strong>s) (1995), Tax andExpenditure Limits <strong>on</strong> Local Governments: An Informati<strong>on</strong> Report, M-194, Center forUrban Policy and the Envir<strong>on</strong>ment, Indiana University and ACIR, Washingt<strong>on</strong> D.C. 1995.(http://www.library.unt.edu/gpo/acir/Reports/informati<strong>on</strong>/M-194.pdf) (01/02/2004)AHUVIA, A.C. (2002), Individualism/Collectivism and Cultures <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Happiness: A <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>oreticalC<strong>on</strong>juncture <strong>on</strong> the Relati<strong>on</strong>ship between C<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>, Culture and Subjective Well-Being at the Nati<strong>on</strong>al Level, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Happiness <strong>St</strong>udies 3 (2002), pp. 23 – 36.ALESINA, A. and R. PEROTTI (1996), Income Distributi<strong>on</strong>, Political Instability, andInvestment, European Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review 81 (1996), pp. 1170 – 1189.ALESINA, A. and D. RODRIK (1994), Distributive Politics and Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Growth, QuarterlyJournal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 109 (1994), pp. 465 – 490.ALESINA, A. and D. RODRIK (1992), Distributi<strong>on</strong>, Political C<strong>on</strong>flict, and Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Growth: ASimple <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory and Some Empirical Evidence, in: A. CUKIERMAN, Z. HERCOWITZ and L.LEIDERMAN (eds.), Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy, Growth and Business Cycles, MIT Press,Cambridge 1992, pp. 23 – 50.ALESINA, A., R. DI TELLA and R. MACCULLOCh (2004), Inequality and Happiness: AreEuropeans and Americans Different? Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 88 (2004), pp. 2009 –2042.ALLOTT, R. (1999), Evoluti<strong>on</strong> and Culture: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Missing Link, in: J.M.G. VAN DER DENNEN,D. SMILLIE and D.R. WILSON (eds.), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Darwinian Heritage and Sociobiology, Praeger,Westport 1999, pp. 67 – 81.ARCHIBALD, R.D. and D.H. FELDMAN (2004), <strong>St</strong>ate Higher Educati<strong>on</strong> Spending and the TaxRevolt, College <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> William and Mary, Department <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics Working Paper No 9,November 2004.ARNOULD, R.H. and H. GRABOWSKI (1981), Auto Safety Regulati<strong>on</strong>: An Analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> MarketFailure, Bell Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 12 (1981), pp. 27 – 48.


– 276 –ARTALE, A. and H.-P. GRÜNER (2000), A Model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>ability and Persistence in a <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>,Games and Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Behavior 33 (2000), pp. 20 – 40.BARANKAY, I. (2002), Referendums, Citizens' Initiatives and the Quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Public Goods:<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory and Evidence, unpublished manuscript, University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Warwick, January 2002.BARRO, R.J., (2000), Inequality and Growth in a Panel <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Countries, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omicGrowth 5 (2000), pp. 5 – 32.BASSET, W.F., J.P. BURKETT and L. PUTTERMAN (1999), Income Distributi<strong>on</strong>, GovernmentTransfers, and the Problem <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Unequal Influence, European Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy15 (1999), pp. 207 – 228.BECKER, G.S. (1968), Crime and Punishment: An Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Approach, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> PoliticalEc<strong>on</strong>omy 76 (1968), pp. 169 – 193.BÉNABOU, R., (1996), Inequality and Growth, in: B. BERNANKE and J. ROTEMBERG (eds.),NBER Macroec<strong>on</strong>omics Annual, Nati<strong>on</strong>al Bureau <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research, Cambridge 1996,pp. 11 – 74.BESLEY, T. and S. COATE (2003), Elected vs. Appointed Regulators: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory and Evidence,Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the European Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Associati<strong>on</strong> 1 (2003), pp. 1176 – 1206.BESLEY, T. and S. COATE (2001), Issue Unbundling via Citizens' Initiatives, CEPRDiscussi<strong>on</strong> Paper No 2857, June 2001.BESLEY, T. and S. COATE (1998), Sources <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Inefficiency in a Representative <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>: ADynamic Analysis. American Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review 88 (1998), pp. 139 – 156.BESLEY, T. and S. COATE (1997), An Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Representative <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>.Quarterly Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 112 (1997), pp. 85 – 114.BJØRNSKOV, C., (2003), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Happy Few: Cross-Country Evidence <strong>on</strong> Social Capital and LifeSatisfacti<strong>on</strong>, Kyklos 56 (2003), pp. 3 – 16.BOADWAY, R. and M. KEEN (2000), Redistributi<strong>on</strong>, in: A.B. ATKINSON and F. BOURGUIGNON(eds.), Handbook <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Income Distributi<strong>on</strong> Vol. 1, Elsevier, Amsterdam 2000, pp. 677 – 789.BOLLEN, K.A., (1980), Issues in the Comparative Measurement <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>,American Sociological Review 45 (1980), pp. 370 – 390.BORNER, S.A. BRUNETTI and TH. STRAUBHAAR (1994), Die Schweiz im Alleingang, NeueZürcher Zeitung, Zürich 1994


– 277 –BOURGUIGNON, F. (1998), Crime as a Social Cost <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Poverty and Inequality: A ReviewFocusing <strong>on</strong> Developing Countries, unpublished manuscript, World Bank, 1998.BOURGUIGNON, F., F. SANCHEZ and J. NUÑEZ (2003), A <strong>St</strong>ructural Model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Crime andInequality in Colombia, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the European Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Associati<strong>on</strong> 1 (2003),pp. 2 – 3.BRADBURY, K.L., C. J. MAYER and K. E. CASE (2001), Property Tax Limits, Local FiscalBehavior, and Property Values: Evidence from Massachusetts under Propositi<strong>on</strong> 2 1/2,Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 80 (2001), pp. 287 – 311.BRENNAN, G. and HAMLIN, A. (2000), Democratic Devices, Cambridge University Press,Cambridge, 2000.BRENNAN, G. and L. LOMASKY, (1993), <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Decisi<strong>on</strong>: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Pure <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Electoral Preference, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge 1993.BRETON, A. (1996), Competitive Governments. An Ec<strong>on</strong>omic <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Politics and PublicFinance, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK 1996.BROOKS, M.A. and B.J. HEIJDRA (1989), An Explorati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Rent-Seeking, Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Record65 (1989), pp. 32 – 50.BUCHINSKY, M. (1998), Recent Advances in Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong>: A Practical Guideline forEmpirical Research, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Human Resources 33 (1998), pp. 88 – 126.BUCKINGHAM, J. (2003a), Reflecti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> Class Size and Teacher Quality, Issue Analysis 29a(2003), Centre for Independent <strong>St</strong>udies, Mar 2003.BUCKINGHAM, J. (2003b), Reforming School Educati<strong>on</strong>: Class Size and Teacher Quality,Policy 19 (2003), pp. 15 – 20.CADE, B.S. and B.R. NOON (2003), A Gentle Introducti<strong>on</strong> to Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong> forEcologists, Fr<strong>on</strong>tiers in Ecology and the Envir<strong>on</strong>ment 1 (2003), pp. 412 – 420.CAMERER, C.F. and H. KUNREUTHER (1989), Decisi<strong>on</strong> Processes for Low Probability Events:Policy Implicati<strong>on</strong>s, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Policy Analysis & Management 8 (1989), pp. 565 – 592.CAMERON, S. (1988), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Crime Deterrence: A Survey <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory andEvidence, Kyklos 41 (1988), pp. 301 – 323.CAMOBRECO, J.F. (1998), Preferences, Fiscal Policies, and the Initiative Process, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Politics (60), pp.819 – 29.


– 278 –CARD, D. and A. PAYNE (2002), School Finance Reform: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> SchoolSpending, and the Distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>udent Test Scores, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 83(2002), pp. 49 – 82.CHAMPERNOWNE, D.G. and F.A. COWELL (1998), Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Inequality and IncomeDistributi<strong>on</strong>, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge 1998.CHERRY, T.L. and J.A. LIST (2002), Aggregati<strong>on</strong> Bias in the Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Crime,Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Letters 75 (2002), pp. 81 – 86.CHIU, W.H. and P. MADDEN (1998), Burglary and Income Inequality, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> PublicEc<strong>on</strong>omics 69 (1998), pp. 123 – 141.COHEN, L.E. and K.C. LAND (1987), Age <strong>St</strong>ructure and Crime: Symmetry versus Asymmetryand the Projecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Crime Rates through the 1990s, American Sociological Review 52(1987), pp. 170 – 183.COHEN, L.E., J.R. KLUEGEL and K.C. LAND (1981), Social Inequality and Predatory CriminalVictimizati<strong>on</strong>: An Expositi<strong>on</strong> and Test <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a Formal <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory, American Sociological Review44 (1981), pp. 505 – 524.COMBS, B. and P. SLOVIC (1979), Newspaper Coverage <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Causes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Death, JournalismQuarterly 56 (1979), pp. 832 – 849.CORNWELL, C. and W.N. TRUMBULL (1994), Estimating the Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Crime withPanel Data, Review <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and <strong>St</strong>atistics 76 (1994), pp. 360 – 366.COURANT, P.N., E.M. GRAMLICH and D.L. RUBINFELD (1980), Why Voters Support TaxLimitati<strong>on</strong> Amendments: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Michigan Case, Nati<strong>on</strong>al Tax Journal 33 (1980), pp. 1 – 20.DE HAAN, J. and J.-E. STURM (1997), Political and Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Budget Deficitsand Government Spending: A Reinvestigati<strong>on</strong>, European Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 13(1997), pp. 739 – 750.DIXIT, A. and J. LONDREGAN (1998), Ideology, Tactics, and Efficiency in RedistributivePolitics, Quarterly Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 113 (1998), pp. 497 – 529.DOWNS, A. (1957), An Ec<strong>on</strong>omic <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>, Harper and Row, New York 1957.DASGUPTA, N. and A.G. GREENWALD (2001), On the Malleability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Automatic Attitudes:Combating Automatic Prejudice with Images <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Admired and Disliked Individuals,Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Pers<strong>on</strong>ality and Social Psychology 81 (2001), pp. 800 – 814.


– 279 –DEJOY, D.M. (1989), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Optimism Bias and Traffic Accident Risk Percepti<strong>on</strong>, AccidentAnalysis and Preventi<strong>on</strong> 21 (1989), pp. 333 – 340.DOWNES, T.A. (1996), An Examinati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the <strong>St</strong>ructure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Governance in California SchoolDistricts Before and After Propositi<strong>on</strong> 13, Public Choice 86 (1996), pp. 279 – 307.DOWNES, T.A. (1992), Evaluating the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> School Finance Reform <strong>on</strong> the Provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Public Educati<strong>on</strong>: the California Case, Nati<strong>on</strong>al Tax Journal 45 (1992), pp. 405 – 419.DOWNES, T.A., R.F. DYE and T.J. MCGUIRE (1998), Do Limits Matter? Evidence <strong>on</strong> theEffects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Tax Limitati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> <strong>St</strong>udent Performance, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Urban Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 43(1998), pp. 401 – 417.DOWNES, T.A. and D.N. FIGLIO (1999), Do Tax and Expenditure Limits Provide a FreeLunch? Evidence <strong>on</strong> the Link between Limits and Public Sector Service Quality, Nati<strong>on</strong>alTax Journal 52 (1999), pp. 113 – 128.DOWNES, T.A. and D.N. FIGLIO (1997), School Finance Reforms, Tax Limits and <strong>St</strong>udentPerformance: Do Reforms Level Up or Dumb Down? Institute for Research <strong>on</strong> Poverty,Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper No 1142 – 97, September 1997.DOWNS, A. (1967), Inside Bureaucracy, Little Brown and Company, Bost<strong>on</strong> 1967.DOYLE, J.M., E. AHMED and R.N. HORN (1999), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Labor Markets and IncomeInequality <strong>on</strong> Crime: Evidence from Panel Data, Southern Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Journal 65 (1999),pp. 717 – 738.DUSTMANN, C., N. RAJAH and A. VON SOEST (2003), Class Size, Educati<strong>on</strong>, and Wages, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Journal 113 (2003), pp. F99 – F120.DYE, R.F. and T.J. MCGUIRE (1997), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Property Tax Limitati<strong>on</strong> Measures <strong>on</strong>Local Government Fiscal Behavior, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 66 (1997), pp. 496 –487.D’AMBROSIO, C. and J. FRICK (2004), Subjective Well-Being and Relative Deprivati<strong>on</strong>: AnEmpirical Link, IZA, B<strong>on</strong>n, Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper No 1351, October 2004.EASTERLIN, R.A. (2003), Building a Better <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Well-Being, IZA, B<strong>on</strong>n, Discussi<strong>on</strong>Paper No 742, March 2003.EASTERLIN, R.A. (2001), Income and Happiness: Towards a Unified <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory, Ec<strong>on</strong>omicJournal 111 (2001), pp. 465 – 484.


– 280 –EASTERLIN, R.A. (1974), Does Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Growth Improve the Human Lot? Some EmpiricalEvidence, in: P.A. DAVID and M.W. REDER (eds.), Nati<strong>on</strong>s and Households in Ec<strong>on</strong>omicGrowth, Academic Press, New York, L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong> 1974, pp. 89 – 125.EHRLICH, I. (1996), Crime, Punishment and the Market for Offenses, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omicPerspectives 10 (1996), p. 43 – 67.EHRLICH, I. (1973), A Participati<strong>on</strong> in Illegitimate Activities: A <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>oretical and EmpiricalInvestigati<strong>on</strong>, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 81 (1973), pp. 521 – 566.EIDE, E. (1994), Deterrence and the Rati<strong>on</strong>al Offender, North-Holland, Amsterdam1994.EKELUND, R.B. and R.D. TOLLISON (2001), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Interest-Group <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Government, in:W.F. SHUGART II and L. RAZZOLINI (eds.), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Elgar Compani<strong>on</strong> to Public Choice,Edward Elgar, Cheltenham 2001, pp. 357 – 378.ENTORF, H. and H. SPENGLER (2000), Socio-Ec<strong>on</strong>omic and Demographic Factors <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Crime inGermany: Evidence from Panel Data <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the German <strong>St</strong>ates, Internati<strong>on</strong>al Review <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lawand Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 20 (2000), pp. 75 – 106.EPPLE, D., and M.H. RIORDAN (1987), Cooperati<strong>on</strong> and Punishment under Repeated MajorityVoting, Public Choice 55 (1987), pp. 41 – 73.EPPLE, D., R. ROMANO and H. SIEG (2003), Peer Effects, Financial Aid and Selecti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><strong>St</strong>udents into Colleges and Universities: An Empirical Analysis, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> AppliedEc<strong>on</strong>ometrics 18 (2003), pp. 501 – 25.EPPLE, D., and T. ROMER (1991), Mobility and Redistributi<strong>on</strong>, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy99 (1991), pp. 828 – 858.EXPERTENKOMMISSION (1997), Aus 29 mach 1: K<strong>on</strong>zept einer eidgenössischen<strong>St</strong>rafprozessordnung, Bericht der Expertenkommissi<strong>on</strong> “Vereinheitlichung des<strong>St</strong>rafprozessrechts”, Eidgenössisches Justiz- und Polizeidepartment (ed.), Bern, 1997.FAJNZYLBER, P., D. LEDERMAN and N. LOYAZA (2002), Inequality and Violent Crime, Journal<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Law and Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 45 (2002), pp. 1 – 40.FELD, L.P., J.A.V. FISCHER and G. KIRCHGÄSSNER (2004), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong>Income Redistributi<strong>on</strong>: Evidence for Switzerland, Paper presented at the Annual C<strong>on</strong>gress<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the German Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Associati<strong>on</strong> (Verein für Socialpolitik), Dresden, 28.09. – 1.10.2004.


– 281 –FELD, L.P. (2000), <strong>St</strong>euerwettbewerb und seine Auswirkungen auf Allokati<strong>on</strong> und Distributi<strong>on</strong>:Ein Überblick und eine empirische Analyse für die Schweiz, Mohr (Siebeck), Tübingen2000.FELD, L.P. (1997), Exit, Voice and Income Taxes: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Loyalty <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Voters, European Journal<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 13 (1997), pp. 455 – 478.FELD, L.P. and B.S. FREY (2002), Trust Breeds Trust: How Taxpayers are Treated, Ec<strong>on</strong>omics<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Governance 3 (2002), pp. 87 – 99.FELD, L.P. and B.S. FREY (2001), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Tax Authority and the Taxpayer: An exploratoryAnalysis, unpublished manuscript, University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>, 2001.FELD, L.P., G. KIRCHGÄSSNER and C.A. SCHALTEGGER (2003), Decentralized taxati<strong>on</strong> and theSize <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Government: Evidence from Swiss <strong>St</strong>ate and Local Governments, CESIfo WorkingPaper No 1087, November 2003FELD, L.P. and G. KIRCHGÄSSNER (2003), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Role <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> in the EuropeanUni<strong>on</strong>, CESifo Working Paper No. 1083, November 2003FELD, L.P. and G. KIRCHGÄSSNER (2001), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> Legislati<strong>on</strong>: <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> in Local and Regi<strong>on</strong>al Decisi<strong>on</strong>-Making, Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Policy 33 (2001), pp. 329– 367.FELD, L.P., and G. KIRCHGÄSSNER (2001a), Does <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> Reduce Public Debt?Evidence from Swiss Municipalities, Public Choice 109 (2001), pp. 347 – 370.FELD, L.P: and G. KIRCHGÄSSNER (2000), <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>, political culture, and theoutcome <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ec<strong>on</strong>omic policy: a report <strong>on</strong> the Swiss experience. European Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 16 (2000), pp. 287 – 306.FELD, L.P. and G. KIRCHGÄSSNER (1999), Public Debt and Budgetary Procedures: Top Downor Bottom Up? Some Evidence from Swiss Municipalities in: J.M. POTERBA and J. VONHAGEN (eds.), Fiscal Instituti<strong>on</strong>s and Fiscal Performance University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Chicago Press,Chicago 1999, pp. 151 – 179.FELD, L.P. and G. KIRCHGÄSSNER (1998), Die politische Ök<strong>on</strong>omie der direkten Demokratie:Eine Übersicht, Universität <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>, Discussi<strong>on</strong> paper No 9807, June 1998.FELD, L.P. and J.G. MATSUSAKA (2003), Budget Referendums and Government Spending,Evidence from Swiss Cant<strong>on</strong>s, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 87 (2003), pp. 2703 – 2724.


– 282 –FELD, L.P. and J.G. MATSUSAKA (2000), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Tax <strong>St</strong>ructure, Some PanelEvidence for Swiss Cant<strong>on</strong>s, unpublished manuscript, University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>, 2000.FELD, L.P. and J.G. MATSUSAKA (1999), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Tax <strong>St</strong>ructure: Some PanelEvidence for Swiss Cant<strong>on</strong>s, unpublished manuscript, University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>,Switzerland.FELD, L.P., M.R. SAVIOZ and G. KIRCHGÄSSNER (1999), Die direkte Demokratie: Modern,erfolgreich, entwicklungs- und exportfähig, Helbig und Lichtenhahn/Vahlen, Basel,München 1999.FELD, L.P. and M.R. SAVIOZ (1997), <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> Matters for Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Performance:An Empirical Investigati<strong>on</strong>, Kyklos 50 (1997), pp. 507 – 538.FERRER-CARBONELLI, A. and P. FRIJTERS (2004), How Important is Methodology for theEstimates <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Happiness? Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Journal 114 (2004), pp. 641 – 659.FERRIS, A.L. (2002), Religi<strong>on</strong> and the Quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Life, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Happiness <strong>St</strong>udies 3 (2002),pp. 199 – 215.FERTIG, M. (2003), Who's To Blame? <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> German <strong>St</strong>udents' Achievement inthe PISA 2000 <strong>St</strong>udy, RWI Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper No 4, March 2003.FERTIG, M. and C.M. SCHMIDT (2002), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Role <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Background Factors for Reading Literacy:<strong>St</strong>raight Nati<strong>on</strong>al Scores in the PISA 2000 <strong>St</strong>udy, IZA Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper No 545, August2002.FERTIG, M. and R.E. WRIGHT (2004), School Quality, Educati<strong>on</strong>al Attainment andAggregati<strong>on</strong> Bias, RWI Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper No 9, January 2004.FIGLIO, D.N. (1999), Functi<strong>on</strong>al Form and the Estimated Effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> School Resources,Ec<strong>on</strong>omics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Educati<strong>on</strong> Review 18 (1999), pp. 241 – 252.FIGLIO, D.N. (1998), Short-Term Effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a 1990s-ERA Property Tax Limit: Panel Evidence<strong>on</strong> Oreg<strong>on</strong>'s Measure 5, Nati<strong>on</strong>al Tax Journal, 51 (1998), pp. 55 – 70.FIGLIO, D.N. (1997), Did the “Tax” Revolt Reduce School Performance? Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> PublicEc<strong>on</strong>omics 65 (1997), pp. 245 – 269.FIGLIO, D.N. (1997a), Teacher Salaries and Teacher Quality, Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Letters 55 (1997),pp. 267 – 271.


– 283 –FIGLIO, D.N. and A. O’SULLIVAN (2001), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Local Resp<strong>on</strong>se to Tax Limitati<strong>on</strong> Measures:Do Local Governments Manipulate Voters to Increase Revenues? Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Law andEc<strong>on</strong>omics 44 (2001), pp. 233 – 257.FIGLIO, D.N. and K.S. RUEBEN (2001), Tax Limits and the Qualificati<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> New Teachers,Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 80 (2001), pp. 49 – 71.FISCHER, J.A.V. (2005), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> Public Educati<strong>on</strong>: Performance<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Swiss Pupils in Reading, University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>, Working Paper No 2005-10, April2005.FISCHHOFF, B. (2002), Heuristics and Biases in Applicati<strong>on</strong>, in: G. THOMAS, D. GRIFFIN ANDD. KAHNEMAN (eds.), Heuristics and Biases: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Psychology <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Intuitive Judgment,Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K. 2002, pp. 730 – 748.FISCHHOFF, B. (1982), Debiasing, in: KAHNEMAN P. SLOVIC and A. TVERSKY (eds.) (1982),Judgement under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, Cambridge University Press,Cambridge, U.K. 1982, pp. 422 – 444.FLÜCKIGER, Y., and M. ZARIN-NEJADAN (1994), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Macroec<strong>on</strong>omic Variables <strong>on</strong>the Distributi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Income. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Case <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Switzerland, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Income Distributi<strong>on</strong> 4(1994), pp. 25 – 39.FRANK, R.H. (1997), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Frame <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Reference as a Public Good, Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Journal 107(1997), pp. 1832 – 1847.FRECHETTE, G. (2001), Random-Effects Ordered Probit (sg158), <strong>St</strong>ata Technical Bulletin 59(2001), pp. 23 – 27.FRECHETTE, G. (2001a), Update to Random-Effects Ordered Probit (sg158:1), <strong>St</strong>ata TechnicalBulletin 61 (2001), p. 12.FREITAG, M. and A. VATTER (2000), Direkte Demokratie, K<strong>on</strong>kordanz und Wirtschaftsleistung:Ein Vergleich der Schweizer Kant<strong>on</strong>e, Schweizerische Zeitschrift fürVolkswirtschaft und <strong>St</strong>atistik 136 (2000), pp. 579 – 606.FREY, B.S. (1971), Why Do High Income people Participate More in Politics?, Public Choice11 (1971), pp. 101 – 105.FREY, B.S. and A. STUTZER (2002), What Can Ec<strong>on</strong>omists Learn from Happiness Research?Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Literature 60 (2000), pp. 402 – 435.


– 284 –FREY, B.S. and A. STUTZER (2000), Happiness, Ec<strong>on</strong>omy and Instituti<strong>on</strong>s, Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Journal110 (2000), pp. 918 – 938.FREY, B.S. and A. STUTZER (2000a), Maximizing Happiness? German Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review 1(2000), pp. 145 – 167.FREY, B.S. and A. STUTZER (2000b), Happiness Prospers in <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Happiness<strong>St</strong>udies 1 (2000), pp. 79 – 102.FREY, B.S., M. KUCHER and A. STUTZER (2001), Outcome, Process and Power in <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>, Public Choice 107 (2001), pp. 271 – 293.FRIJTERS, P, J.P. HAISKEN-DENEW, and M.A. SHIELDS (2004), Investigating the Patterns andDeterminants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Life Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> in Germany Following Reunificati<strong>on</strong>, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> HumanResources 39 (2004), pp. 649 – 674.FUCHS, T. and L. WOESSMANN (2004), What Accounts for Internati<strong>on</strong>al Differences in <strong>St</strong>udentPerformance? A Re-Examinati<strong>on</strong> Using PISA Data, IZA Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper No 1287,September 2004.FUNK, P. and P. KUGLER (2003), Identifying Efficient Crime-combating Policies by VARModels: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Example <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Switzerland, C<strong>on</strong>temporary Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Policy, 21 (2003), pp. 525– 538.FUNK, P. and P. KUGLER (2002), Dynamic Interacti<strong>on</strong>s Between Crimes, Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Letters 79(2003), pp. 291 – 298.GERBER, E.R. (1999), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Populist Paradox: Interest Group Influence and the Promise <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> Legislati<strong>on</strong>, Princet<strong>on</strong> University Press, Princet<strong>on</strong> 1999.GERBER, E.R. (1996), Legislative Resp<strong>on</strong>se to the Threat <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Initiatives, American Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Political Science 40 (1996), pp. 99 – 128.GERMANN, R.E. (2002), Die Kant<strong>on</strong>e: Gleichheit und Disparität, in: U. KLÖTI et al. (eds.),Handbuch der Schweizer Politik, 3rd, revised editi<strong>on</strong>, NZZ Verlag, Zurich 2002, pp. 385 –419.GIGER, H. (ed.) (2002), SVG: <strong>St</strong>rassenverkehrsgesetz: mit Kommentaren sowie ergänzendenGesetzen und Bestimmungen, edited and commented by H. GIGER, 6th, revised editi<strong>on</strong>,Orell Füssli, Zurich 2002.GLAESER, E.L and B. SACERDOTE (1999), Why Is <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>re More Crime in Cities?, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 107 (1999), pp. S225 – S258.


– 285 –GRILLO, M. (1997), <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>, Competiti<strong>on</strong>, and the principle <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Os<strong>on</strong>omia: An ec<strong>on</strong>omicanalysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the political exchange as an incomplete c<strong>on</strong>tract, in: A. BRETON, G. GALEOTTI,P.SALMON AND R. WINTROBE (eds.), Understanding <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>: Ec<strong>on</strong>omic and PoliticalPrespectives; Cambridge University Press, New York, 47 – 63.GUPPY, A. (1993), Subjective Probability <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Accident and Apprehensi<strong>on</strong> in Relati<strong>on</strong> to Self-Other Bias, Age, and Reported Behavior, Accident Analysis and Preventi<strong>on</strong> 25 (1993),pp. 375 – 382.GRADDY, K. and M. STEVENS (2003), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> School Inputs <strong>on</strong> <strong>St</strong>udent Performance:An Empirical <strong>St</strong>udy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Private Schools in the United Kingdom, CEPR Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper No3776, February 2003.GRADSTEIN, M. and B. MILANOVIC, (2004), Does Liberté = Egalité? A Survey <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theEmpirical Evidence <strong>on</strong> the Links between Political <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Income Inequality withSome Evidence <strong>on</strong> the Transiti<strong>on</strong> Ec<strong>on</strong>omies, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Surveys, 18 (2004),pp. 515 – 537.GRADSTEIN, M., B. MILANOVIC,, Y. YING (2001); <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> and Income Inequality: anEmpirical Analysis, Policy Research Working Paper No. 2561, March 2001.GREENE, W. (2004), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Behaviour <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Maximum Likelihood Estimator <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> LimitedDependent Variable Models in the Presence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fixed Effects, Ec<strong>on</strong>ometrics Journal 7(2004), pp. 98 – 119.HAMBLETON, R.K. and H. SWAMINATHAN (1985), Item Resp<strong>on</strong>se <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory: Principles andApplicati<strong>on</strong>s, Kluwer-Nijh<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>f, Bost<strong>on</strong> 1985.HAMMAR, H. and O. JOHANSSON-STENMAN (2004), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Risk-Free Cigarettes: DoSmokers Underestimate the Risk? Health Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 13 (2004), pp. 59 – 71.HANUSHEK, E.A. (2003), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Failure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Input-Based Schooling Policies, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omicJournal 113 (2003), pp. F64 – F98.HANUSHEK, E.A. (1998), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Evidence <strong>on</strong> Class Size, W. Allen Wallis Institute <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> PoliticalEc<strong>on</strong>omy, Wallis Working Paper No 10 / University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Rochester, Occasi<strong>on</strong>al Paper No98-1, February 1998.HANUSHEK, E.A. (1996), School Resources and <strong>St</strong>udent Performance, in: G. BURTLESS (ed.),Does M<strong>on</strong>ey Matter? <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> School Resources <strong>on</strong> <strong>St</strong>udent Achievement and AdultSuccess, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Brookings Instituti<strong>on</strong>, Washingt<strong>on</strong>, D.C. 1996, pp 43 – 73.


– 286 –HANUSHEK, E.A. (1986), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Schooling: Producti<strong>on</strong> and Efficiency in PublicSchools, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Literature 24 (1986), pp. 1141 – 1177.HANUSHEK, E.A., J.F. KAIN and S.G. RIVKIN (2001), Why Public Schools Lose Teachers,NBER Working Paper No 8599, November 2001.HANUSHEK, E.A., J.F. KAIN and S.G. RIVKIN (1999), Do Higher Salaries Buy BetterTeachers? NBER Working Paper No 7082, April 1999.HANUSHEK, E.A., J.F. KAIN and S.G. RIVKIN (1998), Teachers, Schools and AcademicAchievement, NBER Working Paper No 6691, August 1998.HANUSHEK, E.A., S.G. RIVKIN and L.L. Taylor (1996), Aggregati<strong>on</strong> and the Estimated Effects<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> School Resources, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Review <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and <strong>St</strong>atistics 78 (1996), pp. 611 – 627HANUSHEK, E.A. and J.A. SOMERS (1999), Schooling, Inequality, and the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Government, NBER Working Paper No 7450, December 1999.HARMS, P., and S. ZINK (2003), Limits to Redistributi<strong>on</strong> in a <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>: A Survey,European Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 19 (2003), pp. 651 – 668.HEADEY, B. and M. WOODEN (2004), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Wealth and Income <strong>on</strong> Subjective Well-Being and Ill-Being, Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Record 80 (2004), pp. S24 – S33.HEADEY, B., R. MUFFELS and M. WOODEN (2004), M<strong>on</strong>ey Doesn’t Buy Happiness …, OrDoes It? A Rec<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> Based <strong>on</strong> the Combined Effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Wealth, Income, andC<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong>, IZA, B<strong>on</strong>n, Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper No 1218, July 2004.HESTON, A., R. SUMMERS and B. ATEN (2002), Penn World Table Versi<strong>on</strong> 6.1, Center forInternati<strong>on</strong>al Comparis<strong>on</strong>s at the University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Pennsylvania (CICUP), Philadelphia,October 2002.HÖHN, E. and R. WALDBURGER (2001), <strong>St</strong>euerrecht Band 1, Schriftenreihe Finanzwirtschaftund Finanzrecht, 9th revised and extended editi<strong>on</strong>, Haupt, Bern 2001.HOLCOMBE, R.G. (1980), An Empirical Test <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Median Voter, Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Inquiry 18(1980), pp. 260 – 274.HOXBY, C.M. (2000), Does Competiti<strong>on</strong> Am<strong>on</strong>g Public Schools Benefit <strong>St</strong>udents andTaxpayers? American Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review 90 (2000), pp. 1209 – 1238.HOXBY, C.M. (2000a), Peer Effects in the Classroom: Learning from Gender and RaceVariati<strong>on</strong>, NBER Working Paper No 7867, August 2000.


– 287 –HUG, S. (2004), Policy C<strong>on</strong>sequences <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> Legislati<strong>on</strong> in the American <strong>St</strong>ates: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory,Empirical Models and Evidence, Paper presented at the Annual Meeting <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the PublicChoice <strong>Society</strong>, San Ant<strong>on</strong>io (U.S.), 2001, and at the Brown Bag Seminar, University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong> (CH), revised versi<strong>on</strong> 2004.IMROHOROGLU, A., A. MERLO and P. RUPERT (2000), On the Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> IncomeRedistributi<strong>on</strong> and Crime, Internati<strong>on</strong>al Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review 41 (2000), pp. 1 – 25.INGLEHART, R. and H. KLINGEMANN (2000), Genes, Culture, <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>, and Happiness, in:DIENER, E. and E.M. SUH, (eds.), Culture and Subjective Well-Being, Cambridge/L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>:MIT Press 2000, pp. 165 – 183.INMAN, R.P. (1979), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fiscal Performance <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Local Governments: An InterpretativeReview, in: P. MIESZKOWSKI and M. STRASZHEIM (eds.), Current Issues in UrbanEc<strong>on</strong>omics, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> John Hopkins University Press, Baltimore 1979, pp. 270 – 321.JUNGEILGES, J. and G. KIRCHGÄSSNER (2002), Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Welfare, Civil Liberty, and Suicide:An Empirical Investigati<strong>on</strong>, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Socio-Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 31 (2002), pp. 215 – 231.JOLLS, C. (2004), On Law Enforcement with Boundedly Rati<strong>on</strong>al Actors, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Law School,University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Chicago, Harvard Law School, Discussi<strong>on</strong> Paper No 494, September 2004.JOLLS, C. (1998), Behavioral Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Redistributive Legal Rules, Symposium:Behavioral Law and Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, 51 Vanderbilt Law Review 1653 (1998), pp. 1659 – 1662.KAHNEMAN, D. and A. TVERSKY (1983), Extensi<strong>on</strong>al Versus Intuitive Reas<strong>on</strong>ing: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>C<strong>on</strong>juncti<strong>on</strong> Fallacy in Probability Judgement, Psychological Review, 90, (1983), pp. 293– 315.KAHNEMAN, D. and A. TVERSKY (1979), Prospect <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory: An Analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Decisi<strong>on</strong> underRisk, Ec<strong>on</strong>ometrica 47 (1979), pp. 263 – 292.KARATNYCKY, A. (ed.) (2000), Freedom in the World. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Annual Survey <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Rights& Civil Liberties 1999-2000, Freedom House, New York 2000.KELLY, M. (2000), Inequality and Crime, Review <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and <strong>St</strong>atistics 82 (2000), pp.530 – 539.KENNY, C. (1999), Does Growth Cause Happiness, or Does Happiness Cause Growth? Kyklos52 (1999), pp. 2 – 26.KERCKHOFF, A.C. (1986), Effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ability Grouping in British Sec<strong>on</strong>dary Schools.American Sociology Review 51 (1986), pp. 842 – 858.


– 288 –KESSLER, A. (2003), Representative versus <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Role <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Informati<strong>on</strong>alAsymmetries; CEPR Discussi<strong>on</strong> Papers No 3911, May 2003.KEYNES, J.M. (1936), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> General <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Employment, Interest and M<strong>on</strong>ey, MacMillan,L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong> 1936.KIEWIET D.R. and K. SZAKALY (1996), C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>al Limitati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> Borrowing: AnAnalysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>ate B<strong>on</strong>ded Indebtedness, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Law, Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Organizati<strong>on</strong> 12(1996), pp. 62 – 97.KIRCHGÄSSNER, G. (2002), Auswirkungen der direkten Demokratie auf die öffentlichenFinanzen: Empirische Ergebnisse für die Schweiz, Schweizerische Zeitschrift fürVolkswirtschaft und <strong>St</strong>atistik/Swiss Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and <strong>St</strong>atistics 183 (2002), pp.411 – 26KIRCHGÄSSNER, G. (2002a), Direkte Demokratie: Das Beispiel der Schweiz, Zeitschrift fürPolitik 49 (2002), pp. 306 – 331.KIRCHGÄSSNER, G. (2001), Direkte Demokratie und die Effizienz des demokratischen <strong>St</strong>aates,Ordo 52 (2001), pp. 155 – 173.KIRCHGÄSSNER, G. (2000), Wirtschaftliche Auswirkungen der direkten Demokratie,Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 1 (2000), pp. 161 – 180.KIRCHGÄSSNER, G. (1996), Bemerkungen zur Minimalmoral, Zeitschrift für Wirtschafts- undSozialwissenschaften 116 (1996), pp. 223 – 251.KIRCHGÄSSNER, G. (1992), Towards a <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Low-Cost Decisi<strong>on</strong>s, European Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 8 (1992), pp. 305 – 320.KIRCHGÄSSNER, G., L.P. FELD and M.R. SAVIOZ (1999), Die direkte Demokratie: Erfolgreich,modern entwicklungs- und exportfähig, Vahlen, Basel, München 1999.KIRCHGÄSSNER, G. and H. HAUSER (2001), Abwanderungsgefahr v<strong>on</strong> <strong>St</strong>euersubstrat insAusland im Rahmen der Neugestaltung des Finanzausgleichs und der Aufgaben (NFA),Gutachten zuhanden der Eidgenössischen Finanzverwaltung sowie der K<strong>on</strong>ferenz derKant<strong>on</strong>sregierungen, Universität <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>, Aug 2001.KIRCHGÄSSNER, G. and W.W. POMMEREHNE (1996), Tax Harm<strong>on</strong>izati<strong>on</strong> and Tax Competiti<strong>on</strong>in the European Uni<strong>on</strong>: Less<strong>on</strong>s from Switzerland, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 60, pp.351 – 371.


– 289 –KIRCHGÄSSNER, G. and W.W. POMMEREHNE (1992), Approaches to Explain FiscalRedistributi<strong>on</strong> in <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>, mimeo, University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Saarland, Saarbrücken.KLIEMT, H. (1986), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Veil <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Insignificance, European Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 2(1986), pp. 333 – 344.KOENKER, R. and K. HALLOCK (2001), Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong>, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omicPerspectives 51 (2001), pp. 143 – 156.KOENKER, R. and G. BASSET (1978), Regressi<strong>on</strong> Quantiles, Ec<strong>on</strong>ometrica 46 (1978), pp. 33 –50.KONTOPOULOS, Y. and R. PEROTTI (1999), Government Fragmentati<strong>on</strong> and Fiscal PolicyOutcomes: Evidence from OECD Countries, in: J.M. POTERBA and J. VON HAGEN (eds.),Fiscal Instituti<strong>on</strong>s and Fiscal Performance, Chicago University Press, Chicago 1999, pp.81 – 102.KRUEGER, A.B. (2003), Ec<strong>on</strong>omic C<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s and Class Size, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Journal 113(2003), pp. F34 – F63.KRUEGER, A.B. (2002), Understanding the Magnitude and Effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Class Size <strong>on</strong> <strong>St</strong>udentAchievement, in: M. LAWRENCE and R. ROTHSTEIN (eds.), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Class Size Debate,Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Policy Institute, Washingt<strong>on</strong> D.C. 2002, p. 31 c<strong>on</strong>t.KUNREUTHER, H. (1976), Limited Knowledge and Insurance Protecti<strong>on</strong>, Public Policy 24(1976), pp. 227 – 261.KURAN, T. and C. SUNSTEIN (1999), Availability Cascades and Risk Regulati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>St</strong>anford LawReview 51 (1999), pp. 683 – 768.LADD, H.F. and J.B. WILSON (1982), Why Voters Support Tax Limitati<strong>on</strong>s: Evidence fromMassachusetts' Propositi<strong>on</strong> 2 1/2, Nati<strong>on</strong>al Tax Journal 35 (1982), pp. 121 – 147.LANE, R.E. (1991), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Market Experience, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K.1991.LASCHER, E.L. JR., M.G. HAGEN, and ST. A. ROCHLIN (1996), Gun Behind the Door? BallotInitiatives, <strong>St</strong>ate Policies, and Public Opini<strong>on</strong>, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Politics 58 (1996), pp.760 – 75.LAZEAR, E.P. (1999), Culture and Language, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 107 (1999), pp. 95– 126.LEE, W. and J.E. ROEMER (1998), Income Distributi<strong>on</strong>, Redistributive Politics, and Ec<strong>on</strong>omicGrowth, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Growth 3 (1998), pp. 217 – 240.


– 290 –LEHMAN, D.R., R.O. LEMPERT and R.E. NISBETT (1988), American Psychologist, 43 (1988),pp. 431 – 442.LERNER, J.S., R.M. GONZALEZ, D.A. SMALL and B. FISCHHOFF (2003), Effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Fear andAnger <strong>on</strong> Perceived Risks <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Terrorism: A Nati<strong>on</strong>al Field Experiment, PsychologicalScience 14 (2003), pp. 144 – 150.LEU, R.E., S. BURRI and T. PRIESTER (1997), Lebensqualität und Armut in der Schweiz, Haupt,Bern 1997.LICHTENSTEIN, S., P. SLOVIC, B. FISCHHOFF, M. LAYMAN and B. COMBS (1978), JudgedFrequency <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Lethal Events, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Experimental Psychology: Human Learning andMemory 4 (1978), pp. 551 – 578.LIEFMANN-KEIL, E. (1961), Ök<strong>on</strong>omische <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>orie der Sozialpolitik, Springer, Berlin 1961.LIJPHART, A. (1979), Religious vs. Linguistic vs. Class Voting. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> ‘Crucial Experiment’ <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Comparing Belgium, Canada, South Africa, and Switzerland, American Political ScienceReview 73 (1979), pp. 442 – 458.LINDERT, P.H. (1994), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Rise <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Social Spending, 1880 – 1930, Explorati<strong>on</strong>s in Ec<strong>on</strong>omicHistory 31 (1994), pp. 1 – 37.LOCHNER, L. (2003), Individual Percepti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Criminal Justice System, NBER WorkingPaper No 9474, January 2003.LOTT, J.R., and L.W. KENNY (1999), Did Women’s Suffrage Change the Size and Scope <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Government? Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 107 (1999), pp. 1163 – 1198.LUDWIG, J. and L. BASSI (1998), School Spending and <strong>St</strong>udent Achievement: New Estimatesfrom L<strong>on</strong>gitudinal Data, Institute for Policy Research, Northwestern University, WorkingPaper No 98-4, Spring 1998.LUTZ, G. and D. STROHMANN (1998), Wahl- und Abstimmungsrecht in den Kant<strong>on</strong>en, Haupt,Bern, 1998.MACDONALD, Z. (2002), Official Crime <strong>St</strong>atistics: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ir Use and Interpretati<strong>on</strong>, Ec<strong>on</strong>omicJournal 112 (2002), pp. F85 – F106.MARINO, A. M.; and J.G. MATSUSAKA, Decisi<strong>on</strong> Processes, Agency Problems, andInformati<strong>on</strong>: An Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Capital Budgeting Procedures, Review <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Financial <strong>St</strong>udies, 18 (2005), pp. 301 – 325.


– 291 –MARSHALL, M.G. and K. JAGGERS (2003), Polity IV Project: Political Regime Characteristicsand Transiti<strong>on</strong>s, 1800-2002. <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Polity IV Dataset, 2003(http://www.cidcm.umd.edu/inscr/ polity/) (15.04.2005).MATSUSAKA, J.G. (2004), For the Many or the Few: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Initiative, Public Policy, andAmerican <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>, University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Chicago Press, Chicago 2004.MATSUSAKA, J.G. (2001), Problems with a Methodology Used to Evaluate the VoterInitiative, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Politics (63) 2001, pp.1250 – 1256MATSUSAKA, J.G. (2000), Fiscal Effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Voter Initiative in the First Half <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> theTwentieth Century, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Law and Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 43 (2000), pp. 619 – 650.MATSUSAKA, J.G. (1995), Fiscal Effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Voter Initiative: Evidence from the Last 30Years, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 103 (1995), pp. 587 – 623.MATSUSAKA, J.G. and N.M. MCCARTY (2001), Political Resource Alllocati<strong>on</strong>: Benefits andCosts <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Voter Initiatives, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Law, Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and Organizati<strong>on</strong> (17) 2001, pp.413 – 448.MCBRIDE, M. (2001), Relative-Income Effects <strong>on</strong> Subjective Well-Being in the Cross-Secti<strong>on</strong>, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Behaviour and Organisati<strong>on</strong> 45 (2001), pp. 251 – 278.MCCHESNEY, F.S. (2001), Rent-Seeking and Rent Extracti<strong>on</strong>, in: W.F. SHUGART II and L.RAZZOLINI (eds.), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Elgar Compani<strong>on</strong> to Public Choice, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham2001 pp. 379-395.MELTZER, A. and S. RICHARD (1981), A Rati<strong>on</strong>al <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Government, Journal<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omy 89 (1981), pp. 914-927.MERKHOFER, M.W. (1987), Quantifying Judgment Uncertainty: Methodology, Experiences,and Insights. IEEE Transacti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> Systems, Man and Cybernetics 17 (1987), pp. 741 –752.MILESI-FERRETI, G.-M., R. PEROTTI and M. ROSTAGNO (2002), Electoral Systems and theCompositi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Public Spending, Quarterly Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 117 (2002), pp. 609 –657.MOLLER, V. and H. DICKOW (2002), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Role <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Quality <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Life Surveys in ManagingChange in Democratic Transiti<strong>on</strong>s: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> South African Case, Social Indicators Research 58(2002), pp. 267 – 292.


– 292 –MORGAN, M.C. and M. HENRION (1990), Uncertainty: A Guide to Dealing with Uncertaintyin Quantitative Risk and Policy Analysis, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K.1990.MORGAN, M.G. and D.W. KEITH (1995), Subjective Judgments by Climate Experts,Envir<strong>on</strong>mental Science and Technology 29 (1995), pp. 468A – 476A.MOULTON, B. (1990), An Illustrati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a Pitfall in Estimating the Effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> AggregateVariables <strong>on</strong> Micro Units, <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Review <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and <strong>St</strong>atistics 72 (1990), pp. 334 –338.MUELLER, D.C. (2003), Public Choice III, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.MYERS, S.L. JR. (1983), Estimating the Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Crime: Employment versusPunishment Effects, Quarterly Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 98 (1983), pp. 157 – 166.NISKANEN, W. (1975), Bureaucrats and Politicians, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Law and Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 18 (1975),pp. 617 – 643.NITZAN, S. (1994), Modelling Rent-Seeking C<strong>on</strong>tests, European Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy10 (1994), pp. 41 – 60.OECD (2004), Income-Related Inequalities in the Use <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Medical Care in 21 OECDCountries, OECD Health Working Paper No 14, May 2004.OSWALD, A:J. (1997), Happiness and Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Performance, Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Journal 107 (1997),pp. 1815 – 1831.PAN, D., Z. RUDO, L. SMITH-HANSEN (2003a), Resource Allocati<strong>on</strong> Does Matter in Improving<strong>St</strong>udent Performance, SEDL Working Paper and paper presented at the Annual C<strong>on</strong>ferencepf the American Educati<strong>on</strong> Finance Associati<strong>on</strong>, Orlando Mar 27-29, 2003.PAN, D., Z. RUDO, C.L. SCHNEIDER, and L. SMITH-HANSEN (2003b), Examinati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> ResourceAllocati<strong>on</strong> in Educati<strong>on</strong>: C<strong>on</strong>necting Spending to <strong>St</strong>udent Performance, Research Report,Austin: Southwest Educati<strong>on</strong>al Development Laboratory (SEDL), 2003.PAMPEL, F.C. and J.B. WILLIAMSON (1988), Welfare Spending in Advanced IndustrialDemocracies, 1950-1980, American Sociological Review 93 (1988), pp. 1424 – 1456.PAMPEL, F.C. and J.B. WILLIAMSON (1985), Age <strong>St</strong>ructure, Politics, and Cross-Nati<strong>on</strong>alPatterns <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Public Pensi<strong>on</strong>s, American Sociological Review 50 (1985), pp. 782 – 799.PELTZMAN, S. (1992), Voters as Fiscal C<strong>on</strong>servatives, Quarterly Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics (107)1992, pp.327 – 361.


– 293 –PEROTTI, R. (1996), Growth, Income Distributi<strong>on</strong> and <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>: What the Data Say,Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Growth 1 (1996), pp. 149 – 187.PEROTTI, R. (1993), Political Equilibrium, Income Distributi<strong>on</strong> and Growth, Review <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Ec<strong>on</strong>omic <strong>St</strong>udies 60 (1993), pp. 755 – 776.PEROTTI, R. (1992), Income Distributi<strong>on</strong>, Politics and Growth, American Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review,Papers and Proceedings 82 (1992), pp. 311 – 316.PERSSON, T. and G. TABELLINI (1992), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Politics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> 1992: Fiscal Policy and EuropeanIntegrati<strong>on</strong>, Review <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic <strong>St</strong>udies 59 (1992), pp. 689 – 701.PERSSON, T. and G. TABELLINI (1994), Is Inequality Harmful for Growth, American Ec<strong>on</strong>omicReview 84 (1994), pp. 600 – 621.PERSSON, T. and G. TABELLINI (1999), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Size and Scope <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Government: ComparativePolitics with Rati<strong>on</strong>al Politicians, European Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review 43 (1999), pp. 699 – 735.PERSSON, T. and G. TABELLINI (2000), Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omics: Explaining Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Policy,MIT Press, Cambridge 2000.PERSSON, T. and G. TABELLINI (2003), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> C<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>s: What Do theData Say?, MIT Press, Cambridge, 2003.PIORE, M.J. (1968), Public and Private Resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities in On-the-Job Training <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Disadvantaged Workers, Department <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, MIT, Working Paper No 23, June1968.POMMEREHNE, W.W. (1983), Private vs. öffentliche Müllabfuhr, nochmals betrachtet,Finanzarchiv 41 (1983), pp. 466 – 475.POMMEREHNE, W.W. (1978), Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Approaches to Public Expenditure: EmpiricalEvidence from Swiss Municipalities, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 9 (1978), pp. 255 – 280.POMMEREHNE, W.W. (1975), Öffentliche Güter und öffentliche Ausgaben in der direktenDemokratie, Dissertati<strong>on</strong>, University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> K<strong>on</strong>stanz, 1975.POMMEREHNE, W.W. and H. WECK-HANNEMANN (1996), Tax Rates, Tax Administrati<strong>on</strong>, andIncome Tax Evasi<strong>on</strong> in Switzerland, Public Choice 88 (1996), pp. 161 – 170.POTERBA, J.M. and K.S. RUEBEN (1995), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Property-Tax Limits <strong>on</strong> Wages andEmployment in the Local Public Sector, American Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review 85 (1995), pp. 384 –389.


– 294 –PROKHOROV, A.V., C. WARNEKE, C. DE MOOR, K.M. EMMONS, M. MULLIN JONES, C.ROSENBLUM, K. SUCHANEK HUDMON and E.R. GRITZ (2003), Self-Reported Health <strong>St</strong>atus,Health Vulnerability and Smoking Behavior in College <strong>St</strong>udents: Implicati<strong>on</strong>s forInterventi<strong>on</strong>, Nicotine and Tobacco Research 5 (2003), pp. 545 – 552.PROTOCOL (2000), Protocol <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grosser Rat in <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong> <strong>on</strong> the 24th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> February, 2000(Protokoll des Grossen Rates des Kant<strong>on</strong>s <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>), first reading <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>alparliament (Erste Lesung des Kant<strong>on</strong>sparlamentes), 1996/2000 Nr. 601/2-6.PROTOCOL (2000a), <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the sec<strong>on</strong>d reading <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Grosser Rat in <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong> <strong>on</strong> the 25th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>September, 2000, sec<strong>on</strong>d reading <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the cant<strong>on</strong>al parliament, 2000/2004, N.50/18-19.PUDNEY, S., D.F. DEADMAN and D.J. PYLE (2000), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Relati<strong>on</strong>ship Between Crime,Punishment and Ec<strong>on</strong>omic C<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s: Is Reliable Inference Possible When Crimes AreUnder-Recorded?, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Royal <strong>St</strong>atistical <strong>Society</strong>, Series A 163 (2000), pp. 81 –97.PUTNAM, R.D. (2000), Bowling Al<strong>on</strong>e: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Collapse and Revival <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> American Community,Sim<strong>on</strong> & Schuster, New York 2000.RANGVID, B.S. (2004), School Compositi<strong>on</strong> Effects in Denmark: Quantile Regressi<strong>on</strong>Evidence from Denmark with PISA 2000 Data, unpublished manuscript, Ǻrhus School <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Business, Denmark, 2004.ROBERTS K. (1977), Voting over Income Tax Schedules, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 8(1977), pp. 329 – 340.ROEMER, J.E. (1998), Why the Poor Do Not Expropriate the Rich: An Old Argument in NewGarb, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 70 (1998), pp. 399 – 424.ROMER, T. (1975), Individual Welfare, Majority Voting and the Properties <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> a Linear IncomeTax, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Public Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 7 (1975), pp. 163 – 168.ROMER, T. and H. ROSENTHAL (1983), Voting and Spending: Some Empirical Relati<strong>on</strong>ships inthe Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Local Public Finance, in: G. ZODROW (ed.), Local Provisi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Public Services: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Tiebout Model after Twenty-Five Years, Academic Press, New York1983, pp. 165 – 182.ROMER, T. and H. ROSENTHAL (1982), Median Voters or Budget Maximizers: Evidence fromSchool Expenditure Referenda, Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Inquiry 20 (1982), pp. 556 – 578.


– 295 –ROMER, T. and H. ROSENTHAL (1979), Bureaucrats versus Voters: On the Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Resource Allocati<strong>on</strong> by <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g>, Quarterly Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 93 (1979), pp.563 – 587.ROMER, T. and H. ROSENTHAL (1978), Political Resource Allocati<strong>on</strong>, C<strong>on</strong>trolled Agendas, andthe <strong>St</strong>atus Quo, Public Choice 33 (1978), pp. 27 – 43.ROMER, T., H. ROSENTHAL and V.G. MUNLY (1992), Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Incentives and PoliticalInstituti<strong>on</strong>s: Spending and Voting in School Budget Referenda, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> PublicEc<strong>on</strong>omics 49 (1992), pp. 1 – 33.ROTH, A. (ed.) (2003), Das Schweizerische <strong>St</strong>rassenverkehrsrecht; Nachschlagewerk zu allenFragen rund um das <strong>St</strong>rassenverkehrsrecht, mit aktuellen Gerichtsentscheiden undKommentaren., Band 2, Teil 6, Loseblatt-Ausgabe Grundwerk July 1996, AktualisierungJune 2003, WEKA Verlag, Zürich 2003.ROUBINI, N. and J. SACHS (1989), Political and Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Determinants <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Budget Deficits inthe Industrial Democracies, European Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review 33 (1989), pp. 903 – 938.RUEBEN, K. (1997), Tax Limitati<strong>on</strong>s and Government Growth: <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>ate Tax andExpenditure Limits <strong>on</strong> <strong>St</strong>ate and Local Governments, MIT PhD thesis, 1997.RUTTER, D.R., L. QUINE AND I.P. ALBERY (1998), Percepti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Risk in Motorcyclists:Unrealistic Optimism, Relative Realism and Predicti<strong>on</strong>s <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Behavior, British Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Psychology 89 (1998), pp. 681 – 696.SAH, R.K. (1991), Social Osmosis and Patterns <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Crime, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy, 99(1991), pp. 1272 – 1295.SAINT-PAUL, G. and T. VERDIER (1996), Inequality, Redistributi<strong>on</strong> and Growth: A Challengeto the C<strong>on</strong>venti<strong>on</strong>al Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy Approach, European Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Review 40 (1996),pp. 719 – 728.SCHALTEGGER, CH. (2002), Budgetregeln und ihre Wirkung auf die öffentlichen Haushalte:Empirische Ergebnisse aus den US-Bundesstaaten und den Schweizer Kant<strong>on</strong>en,Schmollers Jahrbuch 122 (2002), pp. 369 – 413.SCHALTEGGER, CH. (2001), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Federalism and <str<strong>on</strong>g>Democracy</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>on</strong> the Size <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Government: Evidence from Swiss Sub-Nati<strong>on</strong>al Jurisdicti<strong>on</strong>s, ifo <strong>St</strong>udien 47 (2001),pp. 145 – 162.


– 296 –SCHALTEGGER, CH. and L.P: FELD (2001), On Government Centralizati<strong>on</strong> and BudgetReferendums: Evidence from Switzerland, CESifo Working Paper No 615, December2001.SCHNEIDER, F. (1985), Der Einfluss v<strong>on</strong> Interessengruppen auf die Wirtschaftspolitik, Haupt,Bern/<strong>St</strong>uttgart, 1985.SCHNEIDER, F. and W.W. POMMEREHNE (1983), Macroec<strong>on</strong>omia della crescita in disequilibrioe settore pubblico in espansi<strong>on</strong>e: il peso delle differenze istituzi<strong>on</strong>ali, RivistaInternazi<strong>on</strong>ale di Scienze Ec<strong>on</strong>omiche e Commerciali 33 (1983), pp. 306 – 420.SCHWARZ, N. and L.A. VAUGHN (2002), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Availability Heuristic Revisited: Ease <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Recalland C<strong>on</strong>tent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Recall as Distinct Sources <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Informati<strong>on</strong>, in: T. GILOVICH, D.GRIFFIN andD. KAHNEMAN (eds.), Heuristics and Biases, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge,U.K. 2002, pp. 103 – 119.SCHYNS, P. (2002), Wealth <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Nati<strong>on</strong>s, Individual Income and Life Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> in 42Countries: A Multilevel Approach, Social Indicators Research 60 (2002), pp. 5 – 40.SCHYNS, P. (1998), Crossnati<strong>on</strong>al Differences in Happiness: Ec<strong>on</strong>omic and Cultural FactorsExplored, Social Indicators Research 43 (1998), pp. 3 – 26.SHADBEGIAN, R.J. (2003), Did the Property Tax Revolt Affect Local Public Educati<strong>on</strong>?Evidence from Panel Data, Public Finance Review 31 (2003), pp. 91 – 120.SHADBEGIAN, R.J. (2000), Did the Property Tax Revolt Affect Local Government Wages andEmployment? Evidence from the <strong>St</strong>ates, Global Business and Ec<strong>on</strong>omics Review 2 (2000),pp. 104 – 122.SHADBEGIAN, R.J. (1999), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Effect <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Tax and Expenditure Limitati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> the Revenue<strong>St</strong>ructure <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Local Government, 1962 – 87, Nati<strong>on</strong>al Tax Journal 52 (1999), pp. 221 – 237.SIDOS 2000 (2004), PISA 2000 – Program for Internati<strong>on</strong>al <strong>St</strong>udent Assessment.(http://www.sidos.ch/data/projects/pisa/default.asp?lang=de&menu=0) (13/04/2004)STEUNENBERG, B. (1992), Referendum, Initiative and Veto Power: Budgetary Decisi<strong>on</strong>-Making in Local Government, Kyklos 45 (1992), pp. 501 – 529.STEVANS, L.K. (1988), An Empirical Model <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Property Crime: Deterrence versusRedistributi<strong>on</strong>, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Post Keynesian Ec<strong>on</strong>omics 10 (1988), pp. 572 – 584.STIGLER, G.J. (1970), <str<strong>on</strong>g>Direct</str<strong>on</strong>g>or’s Law <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Public Income Distributi<strong>on</strong>, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Law andEc<strong>on</strong>omics 13 (1970), pp. 1 – 10.


– 297 –STUTZER, A. (1999), Demokratieindizes für die Kant<strong>on</strong>e der Schweiz, IEW Working Paper No23, Zurich, October 1999.STUTZER, A. and B.S. FREY (2003), Instituti<strong>on</strong>s Matter for Procedural Utility: An Ec<strong>on</strong>omic<strong>St</strong>udy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the <str<strong>on</strong>g>Impact</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Participati<strong>on</strong> Possibilities, in: R. MUDAMBI, et al. (eds.),Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Welfare, Internati<strong>on</strong>al Business and Global Instituti<strong>on</strong>al Change, Edward Elgar,Cheltenham 2003, pp. 81 – 99.STUTZER, A. and B.S. FREY (2000), <strong>St</strong>ärkere Volksrechte – Zufriedenere Bürger: Einemikroök<strong>on</strong>ometrische Untersuchung für die Schweiz, Swiss Political Science Review 6(2000), pp. 1 – 30.SUMMERS, A.A. and B.L. WOLFE (1977), Do Schools Make a Difference? American Ec<strong>on</strong>omicReview 67 (1977), pp. 639 – 652.SVENSON, O., B. FISCHHOFF and D. MCGREGOR (1985), Perceived Driving Safety and SeatbeltUsage, Accident Analysis and Preventi<strong>on</strong> 17 (1985), pp. 119 – 133.SWISS CONSTITUTION (abbreviated as SC), available at http//ww.admin.ch/ch/X/sr/c101.htmlwith X = d, f, i indicating the German, French or Italian versi<strong>on</strong>, in power since 1st <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>January 2000, and http://www.admin.ch/ch/itl/rs/1/c101ENG.pdf for an English versi<strong>on</strong>(15.04.2005).TOLLISON, R.D. (1982), Rent-Seeking: A Survey, Kyklos 35 (1982), pp. 575 – 602.TOLLISON, R.D. (1996), Rent Seeking, in: D.C. MUELLER (ed.), Perspectives <strong>on</strong> PublicChoice, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge 1996, pp. 373 – 390.TULLOCK, G. (1971), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Charity <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Uncharitable, Western Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Journal 9(1971), pp. 379 – 392.TAYLOR, S.E. and J.D. BROWN (1988), Illusi<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Well-Being: A Social PsychologicalPerspective <strong>on</strong> Mental Health, Psychological Bulletin 103 (1988), pp. 193 – 210.TEMPLE, J.A. (1996), Community Compositi<strong>on</strong> and Voter Support for Tax Limitati<strong>on</strong>s:Evidence from Home-Rule Electi<strong>on</strong>s, Southern Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Journal 62 (1996), pp. 1002 –1016.TIEBOUT, CH.M. (1956), A Pure <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Local Expenditures, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy64 (1956), pp. 416 – 424.


– 298 –TRECHSEL, A. and U. SERDÜLT (1999), Kaleidoskop Volksrechte: Die Instituti<strong>on</strong>en derdirekten Demokratie in den schweizerischen Kant<strong>on</strong>en 1970 – 1996, Faculté de Droit deGenève and Helbig & Lichtenhahn, Basel, Genf, München 1999.TULLOCK, G. (1959), Problems with Majority Voting, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy, 67(1959), pp. 571 – 579.TVERSKY, A. and D. KAHNEMAN (1973), Availability: A Heuristic for Judging Frequency andProbability, Cognitive Psychology 5 (1973), pp. 207 – 232.TYLER, T.R. (1997), Procedural Fairness and Compliance with the Law, Swiss Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and <strong>St</strong>atistics 133 (1997), pp. 219 – 240.VATTER, A. and M. FREITAG (2002), Die Janusköpfigkeit v<strong>on</strong> Verhandlungsdemokratien: ZurWirkung v<strong>on</strong> K<strong>on</strong>kordanz, direkter Demokratie und dezentraler Entscheidungsstrukturenauf den öffentlichen Sektor der Schweizer Kant<strong>on</strong>e, Swiss Political Science Review 8(2002), pp. 53 – 80.VEENHOVEN, R. (2001), Are the Russians as Unhappy as <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y Say <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>y Are? Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Happiness <strong>St</strong>udies 2 (2001), pp. 111 – 136.VEENHOVEN, R. (2000), Freedom and Happiness: A Comparative <strong>St</strong>udy in Forty-Four Nati<strong>on</strong>sin the Early 1990s, in: DIENER, E. and E.M. SUH (eds.), Culture and Subjective Well-Being,Cambridge/L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: MIT Press 2000, pp. 257 – 288.VEENHOVEN, R. (2000a), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Four Qualities <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Life: Ordering C<strong>on</strong>cepts and Measures <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Good Life, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Happiness <strong>St</strong>udies 1 (2000), pp. 1 – 39.VISCUSI, W.K. (1992), Fatal Trade<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>fs: Public and Private Resp<strong>on</strong>sibilities for Risk, OxfordUniversity Press, Oxford, U.K. 1992.VOLKERINK B. and J. DE HAAN (2001), Fragmented Government Effects <strong>on</strong> Fiscal Policy: NewEvidence, Public Choice 109 (2001), 221 – 242.WAGNER, A. (1892), Grundlegung der politischen Ök<strong>on</strong>omie, Winter'sche Verlagshandlung,Leipzig, 1892.WARM, T.A. (1989), Weighted Maximum Likelihood Estimati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ability in Item Resp<strong>on</strong>se<str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory, Psychometrika 54 (1989), pp.427 – 450.WECK-HANNEMANN, H. and W.W. POMMEREHNE (1989), Einkommenssteuerhinterziehung inder Schweiz: Eine empirische Analyse, Schweizerische Zeitschrift für Volkswirtschaft und<strong>St</strong>atistik 125 (1989), pp. 515 – 556.


– 299 –WEEDE, E. (1981), Income Inequality, Average Income, and Domestic Violence, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>C<strong>on</strong>flict Resoluti<strong>on</strong> 24 (1981), pp. 639 – 654.WEINGAST, B.R., K.A. SHEPSLE, and C. JOHNSEN (1981), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Benefitsand Costs: A Neoclassical Approach to Distributive Politics, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Political Ec<strong>on</strong>omy(89) 1981, pp. 642 – 64WEINSTEIN, N.D. (1980), Unrealistic Optimism about Future Life Events, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>Pers<strong>on</strong>ality and Social Psychology 39 (1980), pp. 806 – 820.WILLIAMSON, O.E. (1964), <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Discreti<strong>on</strong>ary Behavior: Managerial Objectivesin a <str<strong>on</strong>g>The</str<strong>on</strong>g>ory <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the Firm, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, N.J. 1964.WINMAN, A., P. JUSLIN and P. HANSON (2004), Subjective Probability Intervals: How toReduce Overc<strong>on</strong>fidence by Internal Evaluati<strong>on</strong>, Journal <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Experimental Psychology:Learning, Memory and Cogniti<strong>on</strong> 30 (2004), pp. 1167 – 1175.WINSTON, G.C: and D.J. ZIMMERMAN (2003), Peer Effects in Higher Educati<strong>on</strong>, NBERWorking Paper No 9501, February 2003.WITHERS, G. (1988), Crime, Punishment and Deterrence in Australia: An EmpiricalInvestigati<strong>on</strong>, Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Record 60 (1988), pp. 176 – 185.WITTE, A.D. and H. TAUCHEN (1994), Work and Crime: An Explorati<strong>on</strong> Using Panel Data,Public Finance 49 (1994), pp. 155 – 167.WOLPIN, K.L. (1980), A Time Series-Cross Secti<strong>on</strong> Analysis <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Internati<strong>on</strong>al Variati<strong>on</strong> inCrime and Punishment, Review <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics and <strong>St</strong>atistics 62 (1980), pp. 417 – 423.ZISK, B.H. (1987), M<strong>on</strong>ey, Media and the Grass Roots: <strong>St</strong>ate Ballot Issues and the ElectoralProcess, Sage, Newbury Park, 1987.ZWICKY, H. (1982), Einkommensverteilung und Kriminalität in den Schweizer Kant<strong>on</strong>en,1960 und 1970, Schweizerische Zeitschrift für Soziologie 8 (1982), pp. 541 – 565.


– 300 –Curriculum VitaeBorn <strong>on</strong> the 20th <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> October, 1971, Karlsruhe, GermanyParents: Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Dr. Peter-Michael Fischer and Maja-Ev Fischer, née Römer1991 Graduati<strong>on</strong> from High School 'Bismarckgymnasium', Karlsruhe, GermanyCore subjects: Latin, History, Mathematics, Fine Arts1991 - 1992 <strong>St</strong>udy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Law at the University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Regensburg, Germany1992 - 1999 <strong>St</strong>udy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics at the University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Heidelberg, GermanyDiplom-Volkswirtin1996 - 1997 <strong>St</strong>udy <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omics at the University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, U.S.A.2000 Assistant at the University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Mannheim (Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Vaubel)2000 - 2002 Postgraduate study at the European University Institute, Florence, ItalyDAAD Grant, M.A. in Ec<strong>on</strong>omics2002 Internship at the Headquartes <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Daimler-Chrysler,Ec<strong>on</strong>omic Research Department2002 - 2005 Doctoral <strong>St</strong>udy at the University <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <strong>St</strong>. <strong>Gallen</strong>, SwitzerlandAssistant <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Pr<str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g>. Gebhard Kirchgässner, SIAW-HSG

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!