12.07.2015 Views

Divergent Trajectories: Healthcare Insurance Reforms in East Asia ...

Divergent Trajectories: Healthcare Insurance Reforms in East Asia ...

Divergent Trajectories: Healthcare Insurance Reforms in East Asia ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or cite<strong>Divergent</strong> <strong>Trajectories</strong>: <strong>Healthcare</strong> <strong>Insurance</strong> Reform <strong>in</strong> <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> andLat<strong>in</strong> AmericaThe prospects for the welfare state have been the subject of a spirited and livelydebate. Ever s<strong>in</strong>ce the decl<strong>in</strong>e of the full employment-welfare state contract <strong>in</strong> WesternEurope <strong>in</strong> the 1970s, the question about the state’s role <strong>in</strong> protect<strong>in</strong>g citizens aga<strong>in</strong>st thevicissitudes of the market economy has sparked an animated discussion that hasresonated not only <strong>in</strong> the advanced <strong>in</strong>dustrial economies, but also <strong>in</strong> the new develop<strong>in</strong>gdemocracies of Lat<strong>in</strong> America and <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>. While optimists asserted that the systemsof social protection created <strong>in</strong> the early twentieth century largely resisted cutbacks,pessimists po<strong>in</strong>ted to evidence of the welfare state’s demise – the tighten<strong>in</strong>g of eligibilityrules, reduction <strong>in</strong> benefits, and shr<strong>in</strong>kage of public services – and warned direly thatwelfare programs were converg<strong>in</strong>g towards a m<strong>in</strong>imum level of services that wouldworsen <strong>in</strong>equality.Yet, contrary to claims that globalization is caus<strong>in</strong>g a trend towards a “race to thebottom,” a rich variety of welfare programs are tak<strong>in</strong>g shape across <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> and Lat<strong>in</strong>America. These programs reveal contrast<strong>in</strong>g degrees of universalism and redistributionthat are underp<strong>in</strong>ned by differ<strong>in</strong>g notions of citizenship and solidarity. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1980sand 1990s, along with deepen<strong>in</strong>g capital and trade markets openness, Lat<strong>in</strong> Americanstates adopted “neoliberal” policies that encompassed privatization of state-owned andoperated services. 1These countries decentralized state services, <strong>in</strong>creased private-sector1 See Raul Madrid, Retir<strong>in</strong>g the State: the Politics of Pension Privatization <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America and Beyond(Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2003); Sarah M. Brooks, Social Protection and the Market <strong>in</strong> lat<strong>in</strong>America (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2009); Carmelo Mesa-Lago, Ascent to Bankruptcy:F<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g Social Security <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America (Pittsburgh: Pittsburgh University Press, 1989); Carmelo Mesa-1


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citeparticipation <strong>in</strong> welfare provision<strong>in</strong>g, and engaged <strong>in</strong> considerable cost-cutt<strong>in</strong>g, whichresulted <strong>in</strong> a general decl<strong>in</strong>e and neglect of welfare programs dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1980s. With thereturn to democracy <strong>in</strong> the 1990s and the evident failure of market-oriented reforms toameliorate the problems of poverty and <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong> the region, Lat<strong>in</strong> Americanpolicymakers began to cast greater attention upon social policy. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1990s, socialexpenditures <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America, evident <strong>in</strong> higher per capita spend<strong>in</strong>g and the<strong>in</strong>troduction of new <strong>in</strong>struments and programs to tackle the problems of poverty and lackof access for lower-<strong>in</strong>come groups. 2However, the most heralded of the new <strong>in</strong>itiatives,which <strong>in</strong>clude social emergency or social <strong>in</strong>vestment funds, emergency employmentschemes, and direct (conditional) transfers and subsidies, adhere to the pr<strong>in</strong>ciple oftarget<strong>in</strong>g social policy towards the poorest and most vulnerable groups. Policymakershave been challenged <strong>in</strong> mov<strong>in</strong>g beyond these k<strong>in</strong>ds of programs towards more universaland redistributive ones. While advocates contend that targeted policies “make the bestuse of scarce resources for poverty alleviation,” 3 critics accuse such policies ofperpetuat<strong>in</strong>g a two-tier system that relegated the poor to <strong>in</strong>ferior benefits and re<strong>in</strong>forced“<strong>in</strong>equalities between poor people and the rest of society.” 4At the same time that social spend<strong>in</strong>g and program retrenchment were tak<strong>in</strong>gplace <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America, a debate about the need for greater state responsibility for socialwelfare ga<strong>in</strong>ed traction <strong>in</strong> <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> <strong>in</strong> the late 1980s-early 1990s. S<strong>in</strong>ce their transitionsto democracy <strong>in</strong> the late 1980s, Korea and Taiwan have passed new legislation expand<strong>in</strong>gLago, “Social Welfare Reform <strong>in</strong> the Context of Economic-Political Liberalization <strong>in</strong> the Lat<strong>in</strong> AmericanCases,” World Development 25:4 (1997); M. Victoria Murillo, “Political Bias <strong>in</strong> Policy Convergence:Privatization Choices <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America,” World Politics (54:4) 20022 Social Panorama of Lat<strong>in</strong> America, 1990-2001, (Santiago: CEPAL, 2001)3 Karl Ove Moene and Michael Wallerste<strong>in</strong>, “Target<strong>in</strong>g and political support for welfare spend<strong>in</strong>g,”Economics of Governance (2001).4 Shap<strong>in</strong>g the Future of Social Protection: Access, F<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g, and Solidarity (Santiago: CEPAL, 2006).2


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citeprovisions for social assistance, medical <strong>in</strong>surance, and pension programs. As a result,both countries now have national pension systems as well as s<strong>in</strong>gle-payer national health<strong>in</strong>surance programs. 5These programs are cast broadly along the l<strong>in</strong>es of traditionalsocial <strong>in</strong>surance programs based on collective pool<strong>in</strong>g of risk, with responsibilitiesdistributed among state, capital, and labor. 6Reflect<strong>in</strong>g this, levels of social spend<strong>in</strong>ghave risen steadily <strong>in</strong> many develop<strong>in</strong>g democracies <strong>in</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>, especially <strong>in</strong> the former“<strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n tigers” of South Korea and Taiwan as well as, to a lesser degree, <strong>in</strong> Thailand.While the <strong>in</strong>dustrialization thesis may account for some of these states’ <strong>in</strong>creasedspend<strong>in</strong>g, what is more to the po<strong>in</strong>t is that the <strong>in</strong>creased spend<strong>in</strong>g took on quite differentforms among countries <strong>in</strong> <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that there was more at stake than merelyan <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> social spend<strong>in</strong>g.That states govern<strong>in</strong>g a sizeable portion of the world’s population haveimplemented programs represent<strong>in</strong>g a markedly dist<strong>in</strong>ct paradigm of welfare/pensionprograms casts doubt upon naysayers’ prophesies of globalization’s <strong>in</strong>evitable “race tothe bottom.” The puzzle that emerges from a comparison of welfare state developments<strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America and <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> is that <strong>in</strong> some countries <strong>in</strong> the latter region, over therelatively brief course of 15 years, a limited and segmented welfare system that cateredlargely to formal sector workers, was m<strong>in</strong>imally f<strong>in</strong>anced by the state, and was heavilydependent on private responsibility – on the part of households and companies – has beentransformed <strong>in</strong>to a national system that provides universal coverage and benefits to allcitizens. This has been accompanied by a shift <strong>in</strong> attitude among citizens as well as <strong>in</strong> the5 Kwon Huck Ju, “Transform<strong>in</strong>g the Developmental State <strong>in</strong> <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>,” Development and Change (36:3)2005, Joseph Wong, Healthy Democracies, Soonman Kwon, “Economic Crisis and Social Policy Reform<strong>in</strong> Korea,” International Journal of Social Welfare (10:2) 20026 Robert Holzmann, “Pension Systems <strong>in</strong> <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> and the Pacific: Challenges and Opportunities,” SocialProtection Unit [World Bank] June 2000.3


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citelanguage of the debate about the state and its responsibilities for social welfare spend<strong>in</strong>g.Whereas dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1970s and even 1980s, the notion of state responsibility for welfareprovision<strong>in</strong>g would have struck ord<strong>in</strong>ary citizens <strong>in</strong> Korea and Taiwan as unfamiliar oreven as an “unpatriotic” burden that impeded the state’s more urgent and overrid<strong>in</strong>gobjective of pursu<strong>in</strong>g national economic growth, by the 1990s, citizens’ attitudes hadshifted dramatically. Leftist newspapers, <strong>in</strong>tellectuals and activists, and civil societyorganizations stridently called upon the state to deliver protection to vulnerable citizensand to create a nation based on socioeconomic equality.Welfare state development <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America and <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> are marked by twodist<strong>in</strong>ct outcomes. The first is along the dimension of universality of access, and thesecond along the dimension of solidarity or redistribution. Among the patterns thatemerge, we f<strong>in</strong>d that <strong>in</strong> several countries <strong>in</strong> <strong>East</strong>/Southeast <strong>Asia</strong> – Thailand, South Korea,and Taiwan – over the course of the 1990s and 2000s, more and more citizens came tobenefit from a universal access to healthcare. Whereas the reach of the healthcareprograms previously had been conf<strong>in</strong>ed to a select group of formal sector workers,benefits were expanded to encompass more segments of the population, most notably therural and <strong>in</strong>formal sector workers. However, we also f<strong>in</strong>d that reforms that greatlyimproved the solidarity and equity of programs were undertaken <strong>in</strong> only some <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>ncountries. For <strong>in</strong>stance, while <strong>in</strong> Korea and Taiwan, s<strong>in</strong>gle-payer national funds wereestablished that enhanced the solidaristic elements of healthcare <strong>in</strong>surance across bothformal and <strong>in</strong>formal sector workers, <strong>in</strong> Thailand, separate programs cont<strong>in</strong>ued to bema<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>ed for formal sector workers.4


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citeIn contrast, <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America, dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1980-90s, most countries put <strong>in</strong> place amixed system of private-public health systems. While healthcare systems <strong>in</strong> thesecountries ostensibly extended access to all citizens, <strong>in</strong> reality, coverage <strong>in</strong> many countriesfell short of be<strong>in</strong>g universal. Moreover, <strong>in</strong>evitably, lower-<strong>in</strong>come citizens were pricedout of the private system and came to be concentrated <strong>in</strong> the public health sector,burden<strong>in</strong>g the latter with a greater pool of higher-risk patients and creat<strong>in</strong>g a dual systemof care that discrim<strong>in</strong>ated between higher- and lower-<strong>in</strong>come citizens. As a result, poorercitizens often faced healthcare provision<strong>in</strong>g that was plagued by lower quality services,overcrowd<strong>in</strong>g, and lack of capacity. Policymakers sought to ameliorate some of theseproblems through measures that improved access, particularly for the lowest <strong>in</strong>comegroups. On the other hand, efforts at <strong>in</strong>tegrat<strong>in</strong>g the public and private systems havebeen far more limited, and hence, the degree of redistribution or equity with<strong>in</strong> thehealthcare system is low.Why do we see variation with respect to these two dimensions of healthcarereform, both with<strong>in</strong> as well as across regions? I argue that the divergence <strong>in</strong> policyoutcomes depended upon two factors: first, the nature of electoral party competition <strong>in</strong>these new democracies provided different <strong>in</strong>centives and payoffs to parties forimplement<strong>in</strong>g universal versus targeted social policies. I claim that where party systemsare less <strong>in</strong>stitutionalized, have weakly nationalized presences, and are underp<strong>in</strong>ned byanemic or fluid partisan attachments, a universaliz<strong>in</strong>g social policy <strong>in</strong>itiative is morelikely to yield greater electoral payoffs. In this k<strong>in</strong>d of electoral landscape, sweep<strong>in</strong>gsocial policy <strong>in</strong>itiatives may be efficacious means of replac<strong>in</strong>g clientelistic networks oroverlay<strong>in</strong>g new socioeconomic cleavages that create more programmatic partisan5


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citeattachments among voters. Conversely, <strong>in</strong> countries where party systems are more<strong>in</strong>stitutionalized, have nationalized presence, and stronger partisan attachments, partieshave weaker <strong>in</strong>centives to propose universaliz<strong>in</strong>g social policy <strong>in</strong>itiatives; such policiesentail higher fiscal costs, are likely to meet resistance from stakeholders whose <strong>in</strong>terestthey threaten, and, <strong>in</strong> a more stable electoral environment, the political payoffs – theextent to which parties can attract more voters – may not be fruitful enough to justify itscosts. Under these circumstances, social policies that selectively target groups of citizensmay be more cost-effective strategies for solidify<strong>in</strong>g or carv<strong>in</strong>g out <strong>in</strong>cremental ga<strong>in</strong>samong a voter base.Secondly, I argue that policy <strong>in</strong>itiatives that enhanced solidarity or redistributionbetween lower- and higher-<strong>in</strong>come workers depended upon the will<strong>in</strong>gness of higher<strong>in</strong>comeworkers to pool their <strong>in</strong>come and health risks with less-privileged citizens. Ingeneral, <strong>in</strong> these develop<strong>in</strong>g democracies, formal sector workers (a category that,generally speak<strong>in</strong>g, encompasses highly-skilled manual and white-collar groups)benefited from higher-quality healthcare <strong>in</strong>surance and services, while <strong>in</strong>formal sectorworkers had poorer terms of <strong>in</strong>surance and access to healthcare. Whether moresolidaristic reform efforts succeeded depended upon whether privileged workers werewill<strong>in</strong>g shoulder the costs of greater risk pool<strong>in</strong>g. I argue that this will<strong>in</strong>gnessimportantly was <strong>in</strong>fluenced, <strong>in</strong> part, by grow<strong>in</strong>g labor market <strong>in</strong>security dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1990s,to which the more privileged workers also grew susceptible, but even more so by howlevels of <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong> a society mediated formal sector workers’ perceptions of shared<strong>in</strong>terests <strong>in</strong> solidaristic social protection. Levels of equality shaped the perceptions of6


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citedistance that privileged workers felt between themselves and their less privilegedbrethren and <strong>in</strong>fluenced their will<strong>in</strong>gness to mobilize for more equitable reforms.CASE SELECTION: SOUTH KOREA, THAILAND, AND CHILEThis project seeks to theorize about welfare reform outcomes, specificallyfocus<strong>in</strong>g upon healthcare <strong>in</strong>surance reform, <strong>in</strong> a universe of middle-<strong>in</strong>come develop<strong>in</strong>gdemocracies <strong>in</strong> <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> and Lat<strong>in</strong> America that <strong>in</strong>cludes South Korea, Taiwan,Thailand, the Philipp<strong>in</strong>es, Indonesia, Venezuela, Argent<strong>in</strong>a, Brazil, Chile, and Uruguay.Dur<strong>in</strong>g the past twenty years, many of these countries <strong>in</strong>itiated healthcare <strong>in</strong>surancereforms, along with efforts <strong>in</strong> other social policy areas such as pensions, education, andsocial assistance programs. For many of these countries, the proposed health <strong>in</strong>surancereforms represented bold and ambitious efforts to change systems <strong>in</strong>herited from priorauthoritarian periods and attempted vary<strong>in</strong>g degrees to <strong>in</strong>troduce mechanisms of greatersolidarity and redistribution to their exist<strong>in</strong>g systems.From among this group, I exam<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> closer detail the trajectories and outcomesof health <strong>in</strong>surance reform <strong>in</strong> three countries, South Korea, Thailand, and Chile. In allthree,the proposed reforms attempted to <strong>in</strong>troduce mean<strong>in</strong>gful changes to both axes –universality and solidarity – although their success varied considerably. Korea achievedsignificant ga<strong>in</strong>s towards both universality and solidarity. Thailand substantiallyexpanded coverage for a quarter of its population with a new national program, althoughit failed to merge this program with already exist<strong>in</strong>g programs that covered formal sectorworkers. F<strong>in</strong>ally, Chile passed legislation that improved access to those who weremarg<strong>in</strong>alized <strong>in</strong> the exist<strong>in</strong>g system; however, efforts to implement greater redistributionbetween lower-<strong>in</strong>come and higher-<strong>in</strong>come segments did not succeed.7


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citeKOREAIn 2000, the South Korean National Assembly passed legislation that <strong>in</strong>tegratedthe country’s fragmented corporatist healthcare <strong>in</strong>surance societies <strong>in</strong>to a nationaluniversal s<strong>in</strong>gle-payer health <strong>in</strong>surance system managed by the state. The “IntegrationReform” represented the culm<strong>in</strong>ation of a series of changes to the healthcare system thatsignificantly expanded coverage and <strong>in</strong>creased the system’s mechanisms ofredistribution. Between 1987 – the year of democratic transition – and 2001, coverageexpanded from 41% of the population to 97%. At the time of transition, only formalsector workers who were employed by firms larger than 100 workers – were guaranteed<strong>in</strong>surance through their employers. In a succession of measures, the first democraticallyelected government of Roh Tae-woo expanded coverage to the rural and <strong>in</strong>formal sectors.In 1987, farmers were handed out healthcare <strong>in</strong>surance cards. Two years later, a programto cover the self-employed was implemented. These extensions were achieved throughthe <strong>in</strong>cremental establishment of quasi-private <strong>in</strong>surers that pooled workers by workplaceor geographic location. As a result, South Korea’s health <strong>in</strong>surance system came toresemble a corporatist system that was composed of hundreds of quasi-private <strong>in</strong>surers,each of which offered different benefits packages and charged different premiums todifferent pools of workers. The system generated considerable <strong>in</strong>equity between largecompanyand small-company employees and between urban and rural workers, asworkers at large companies paid lower premiums and received better benefits while theself-employed/<strong>in</strong>formal and rural workers paid higher premiums for poorer services. By8


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citeconsolidat<strong>in</strong>g all of these separately-run schemes <strong>in</strong>to a s<strong>in</strong>gle payer fund, the 2000legislation reduced systemic <strong>in</strong>equity.THAILANDIn 2001, the Thaks<strong>in</strong> Sh<strong>in</strong>awatra government passed legislation that extendedcoverage to 18.5 million people (or 27% of the population) who were previouslyun<strong>in</strong>sured. Follow<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>stitution of the “30-baht card” scheme, the coverage rate <strong>in</strong>Thailand reached 95.6%. Prior to this reform, Thailand’s health <strong>in</strong>surance programsconsisted of four separate schemes that covered different segments of workers: civilservants, formal sector workers, the rural poor, and low <strong>in</strong>come families and theirdependents. These various programs, which were separately managed, had been<strong>in</strong>troduced on a piecemeal basis between 1975 and 1990. All of these programs chargedwidely vary<strong>in</strong>g benefits and fees that generated considerable <strong>in</strong>equity <strong>in</strong> healthcare<strong>in</strong>surance. The objective of the 2001 legislation was to provide equal access to qualitycare regardless of a citizen’s socioeconomic qualifications. To ensure this, the “30 bahtcard” program guaranteed that no citizen would pay more than 30 baht on any cl<strong>in</strong>ic visit,<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g for pharmaceuticals. While some procedures were exempted (cosmeticprocedures, chemotherapy, renal dialysis, organ transplants), the “30 baht card” improvedaccess to care for groups who were previously un<strong>in</strong>sured. At the same time, the <strong>in</strong>itialproposal’s call to merge these programs with those cover<strong>in</strong>g formal sector workers <strong>in</strong>to as<strong>in</strong>gle universal program was fiercely resisted by civil servants and formal sector workerswho wanted to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> their separate programs and not risk a dim<strong>in</strong>ishment of theirbenefits packages.CHILE9


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citeThe Chilean health system was a dual public/private system; those <strong>in</strong>dividualswho could afford private <strong>in</strong>surance or who worked for companies that purchased private<strong>in</strong>surance received healthcare at private cl<strong>in</strong>ics. The rest of the population was treated atfacilities <strong>in</strong> the public health sector, which generally was burdened by overcrowd<strong>in</strong>g,long wait<strong>in</strong>g l<strong>in</strong>es, and <strong>in</strong>ferior <strong>in</strong>frastructure. Although the question of dismantl<strong>in</strong>g thisparallel private-public system was never seriously enterta<strong>in</strong>ed, the health reformproposed <strong>in</strong> 2000 (“Plan AUGE”) forded mean<strong>in</strong>gful milestones towards connect<strong>in</strong>g thetwo systems by guarantee<strong>in</strong>g all Chileans timely treatment for 57 “priority diseases” atany facility, public or private. 7An important component of the reform called for apooled fund that would enhance the system’s f<strong>in</strong>ancial solidarity by redistribut<strong>in</strong>g moneyfrom the private to the public system, but the government ultimately abandoned thisproposal. Thus, while the more targeted component of the reform was implemented, theproposal to <strong>in</strong>crease f<strong>in</strong>ancial solidarity between the private and public systems was not.An exam<strong>in</strong>ation of these sets of reforms illustrates that the three cases varied <strong>in</strong>their efforts to achieve greater coverage and equity of benefits. If we map theseoutcomes onto a 2-dimensional graph, with the vertical axis represent<strong>in</strong>g solidarity andthe horizontal axis represent<strong>in</strong>g universality of coverage, we f<strong>in</strong>d that South Koreamoved from low coverage to high coverage and from low to high levels of risk-pool<strong>in</strong>g.Thailand, too, expanded coverage but fell short of <strong>in</strong>tegrat<strong>in</strong>g higher-<strong>in</strong>come formalsector workers <strong>in</strong>to its 30-baht card program. F<strong>in</strong>ally, Chile’s AUGE program achievedgreater access for lower-<strong>in</strong>come workers although its healthcare program alreadydelivered, <strong>in</strong> pr<strong>in</strong>ciple at least, universal coverage. Risk-pool<strong>in</strong>g, on the other hand,7 The list of “priority diseases” was set to be <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong>crementally over time.10


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citerema<strong>in</strong>s fragmented, with lower-<strong>in</strong>come and less healthy workers pooled <strong>in</strong>to the publicsector and higher-<strong>in</strong>come workers opt<strong>in</strong>g for the private <strong>in</strong>surance market.[Insert Graph]At the same time that the three cases manifest considerable variation with respectto outcomes, they also permit controll<strong>in</strong>g for important alternative explanatory variablessuch as the strength of labor organizations, political partisanship, state capacity, and tradeand capital openness. For one, as Table 1 (on p. 21) depicts, labor organizations arecomparably weak across all three countries. Compared to other Lat<strong>in</strong> American and <strong>East</strong><strong>Asia</strong>n countries, Korea, Thailand, and Chile have lower-than-average union density rates.In part, this reflects the legacy of the authoritarian regimes’ severe repression of work<strong>in</strong>gclass organizations dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1970s-80s. For the <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n states, keep<strong>in</strong>g labor costslow was <strong>in</strong>strumental to the success of the developmental economic models, while, <strong>in</strong>Chile, dismantl<strong>in</strong>g labor organizations was a fundamental part of forg<strong>in</strong>g a neoliberalpolitical economy. Although labor organizations ga<strong>in</strong>ed some ground post-transition,their organizational strength still rema<strong>in</strong>ed comparably anemic – Chile reported uniondensity of 16% <strong>in</strong> the late 1990s, South Korea reported a figure of 11.6%, whileThailand’s was lowest at 5%. 8Moreover, labor organizations are decentralized, andcollective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> all three countries takes place primarily at the enterprise unionlevel. 9Although central trade confederations do exist <strong>in</strong> Chile as well as <strong>in</strong> Korea, strongrivalries between two ma<strong>in</strong> confederations <strong>in</strong> Korea have h<strong>in</strong>dered labor solidarity.8 Labor Statistics (Seoul: Korea Labor Institute Press 2007).9 Frank Volker, “The Labor Movement <strong>in</strong> Democratic Chile, 1990-2000,” Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper #298 (2002).11


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citeSecond, the healthcare <strong>in</strong>surance <strong>in</strong>itiatives – as well as other welfare reformssuch as pensions and social assistance programs – were spearheaded by governments onboth sides of the partisan spectrum across the three countries and sometimes with<strong>in</strong>countries. In South Korea, the earlier <strong>in</strong>itiatives to expand coverage were undertaken bya right government (headed by the military regime’s candidate), while the 2001“Integration Reform” that established a s<strong>in</strong>gle-payer system was the legislativeachievement of a left-of-center government. In Thailand, the right-w<strong>in</strong>g Thaks<strong>in</strong>government was the key architect of the “30-baht card” scheme. F<strong>in</strong>ally, Chile’s AUGElegislation was proposed by the left-of-center Concertacion coalition. The lack of aconsistent relationship between partisanship and policy preferences casts doubt upon thepossibility that differences <strong>in</strong> ideological commitments accounted for the outcomes.More <strong>in</strong>trigu<strong>in</strong>gly, even <strong>in</strong> those cases where left parties were responsible for expansivepolicy <strong>in</strong>itiatives, such as the Integration Reform <strong>in</strong> South Korea and Plan AUGE <strong>in</strong>Chile, the ambitions of the reforms did not correspond to the strength and maturity ofparty organization and party system <strong>in</strong>stitutionalization. Party systems <strong>in</strong> South Koreaand Chile, for example, were characterized by significant disparities <strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>stitutionalization. On one hand, the Chilean party system rank<strong>in</strong>g as one of the moststable <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America, 10 while on the other, South Korean parties have long beenidentified as short-lived vehicles of electoral ambitions for charismatic politicians thatwere not characterized by any mean<strong>in</strong>gful ideological dist<strong>in</strong>ctions. 11 Accord<strong>in</strong>gly,conventional wisdom would lead us to expect the Concertación to implement more10 See Arturo Valenzuela, Chile: Politics and Society, Scott Ma<strong>in</strong>war<strong>in</strong>g and Tim Scully, Build<strong>in</strong>gDemocratic Institutions: Party Systems <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America, Siavelis, Peter, The President and Congress <strong>in</strong>Postauthoritarian Chile: Institutional Constra<strong>in</strong>ts to Democratic Consolidation11 Chung-In Moon and Jongryn Mo, Democratization and Globalization <strong>in</strong> Korea: Assessment andProspects (Seoul: Yonsei University Press 1999).12


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citeprogrammatically left policies. But <strong>in</strong> fact, the organizationally weak South Korean leftparty achieved some success <strong>in</strong> construct<strong>in</strong>g resonant ideological cleavages aroundsocial, political, and economic issues such as North-South reunification, corporategovernance, economic redistribution, and welfare policy, and pushed through policiesconsistent with these preferences, even <strong>in</strong> the face of a divided government. 12Third, these three cases exhibit strong and relatively consistent economicperformances. Between 1990 and 2002, Chile grew by an average rate of 5.7%, SouthKorea by 6.3% and Thailand by 5.0%. Second, the three governments demonstratedprudent budgetary management dur<strong>in</strong>g this time. Chile reported a fiscal surplus of 1.4%,while South Korea recorded a fiscal deficit of -1.0% and Thailand a deficit of -1.5%. 13While there is some dispersion <strong>in</strong> these performances, nonetheless, the gap isconsiderably narrower than other <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n and Lat<strong>in</strong> American countries. These threecases exhibited reasonably comparable macroeconomic <strong>in</strong>dicators that reduce thelikelihood that sharp contrasts <strong>in</strong> macroeconomic management <strong>in</strong>evitably forced themtowards divergent social policy choices.Fourth, the three countries have coherent state apparatuses that have high <strong>in</strong>ternalunity and organization. The developmental state scholarship <strong>in</strong>formed our understand<strong>in</strong>gof the importance of state structures <strong>in</strong> not only achiev<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustrial growth but also <strong>in</strong>implement<strong>in</strong>g social policy. As Evans stated, “[D]ifferent k<strong>in</strong>ds of state structures createdifferent capacities for action. Structures def<strong>in</strong>e the range of roles that the state iscapable of play<strong>in</strong>g.” 14In his study of redistributive policy <strong>in</strong> Brazil, Weyland argues that12 Song Ho Keun, “Politics, Generation, and the Mak<strong>in</strong>g of New Leadership <strong>in</strong> South Korea” Developmentand Society 32:1 (2003)13 World Development Indicators, 2006 14 Peter Evans, Embedded Autonomy (Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton: Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton University Press, 1995) 11.13


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citefollow<strong>in</strong>g decade. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>in</strong> South Korea, while trade did not change mean<strong>in</strong>gfullybetween the two decades, averag<strong>in</strong>g around 66% of GDP <strong>in</strong> both decades, the level ofFDI/GDP <strong>in</strong>creased from below 2% <strong>in</strong> 1990 to around 12% by 2000, while portfolio<strong>in</strong>vestment rose more significantly from 1% <strong>in</strong> 1990 to 23%. In Chile, the level ofFDI/GDP <strong>in</strong>creased from 30% <strong>in</strong> 1990 to 61% <strong>in</strong> 2000 while portfolio <strong>in</strong>vestments rosefrom around 8% to 13%. 18LITERATURE REVIEWTo expla<strong>in</strong> the divergent outcomes of healthcare <strong>in</strong>surance reform <strong>in</strong> South Koreaand Chile, my argument emphasizes the degree of solidarity between the formal and<strong>in</strong>formal sectors as well as the different <strong>in</strong>centives that electoral competition <strong>in</strong> weakly<strong>in</strong>stitutionalized and regionalized party systems generated versus more robustly<strong>in</strong>stitutionalized and nationalized party systems. This argument builds upon and extendsseveral important schools of thought with<strong>in</strong> the welfare state literature. I briefly reviewthese major contributions, evaluat<strong>in</strong>g both their shortcom<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the puzzle Iexplore <strong>in</strong> this project as well as the ways <strong>in</strong> which they <strong>in</strong>formed my own argument.The globalization argumentOne of the most vigorous debates <strong>in</strong> the welfare state literature centers on thecapacity of governments to susta<strong>in</strong> welfare spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the face of <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong>tegration<strong>in</strong> the markets for goods, capital, and services. The conventional wisdom aboutglobalization was that the competitive pressures brought about by <strong>in</strong>creased trade <strong>in</strong>goods and services and greater openness to capital flows would make it more difficult forstates to provide social welfare. Because these programs are f<strong>in</strong>anced by taxes on capital18 International F<strong>in</strong>ancial Statistics and Government F<strong>in</strong>ancial Statistics, various years (IMF)15


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citeand labor, they <strong>in</strong>crease the costs of production for capital. In an open-trade economy,the entry <strong>in</strong>to the domestic markets of goods made <strong>in</strong> lower-wage countries disadvantageslocal producers, encourag<strong>in</strong>g them to lobby their governments to reduce the burden off<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g welfare programs. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to this perspective, openness to capital flowsspurred a similar dynamic. With “footloose” capital, firms have the ability to move theirassets and <strong>in</strong>vestments across borders; consequently, profit-seek<strong>in</strong>g firms will locate their<strong>in</strong>vestments to countries where the costs of do<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess are lower and where states canprovide a stable macroeconomic environment, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g lower <strong>in</strong>flation and tighter fiscaldiscipl<strong>in</strong>e, which generous welfare programs are assumed to impede. 19 By impos<strong>in</strong>g thelogic of the market upon countries’ domestic policies, globalization forces states to forgocollective social protection schemes and to adopt neoclassical economic alternatives thatemphasize <strong>in</strong>dividual over collective responsibility.This logic is thought to be even more <strong>in</strong>exorable <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries becausethey rely more heavily on foreign capital <strong>in</strong>flows to supplement lower levels of domesticsav<strong>in</strong>gs, and their domestic producers are less competitive <strong>in</strong> world markets. Inparticular, analysts argued that the fiscal constra<strong>in</strong>ts imposed by neoliberal economicpolicy prescriptives left little room for states to negotiate protective social policy. 20Theimperatives of this policy regime significantly reduced domestic policymakers’<strong>in</strong>dependence s<strong>in</strong>ce their capacity to attract trade and capital <strong>in</strong>vestments depended onma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g budgetary discipl<strong>in</strong>e and flexible labor markets.19 Dani Rodrik, Has Globalization Gone Too Far? (Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.: Institute of International Economics,1997)20 Nita Rudra, “Globalization and the Decl<strong>in</strong>e of the Welfare State <strong>in</strong> Less-Developed Countries”International Organization 56:2 (2002)16


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citeThis first generation of literature has come under considerable fire. A substantialresponse to this earlier th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g presents persuasive evidence that left governments and<strong>in</strong>stitutions still yield salubrious effects on welfare spend<strong>in</strong>g and social policies.Garrett’s work on the advanced <strong>in</strong>dustrial economies perhaps best represents thisscholastic response; he found that <strong>in</strong> countries where left parties were allied withencompass<strong>in</strong>g labor organizations, governments were able to pursue economic policiesthat redistribute wealth and risk <strong>in</strong> favor of the more vulnerable, <strong>in</strong> spite of <strong>in</strong>creasedeconomic openness. 21 In a related ve<strong>in</strong>, Swank made the case that “the <strong>in</strong>stitutionalstructure of the polity and programmatic structures of the welfare state are fundamentallyimportant for determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the quality and character of <strong>in</strong>terest representation of prowelfarestate <strong>in</strong>terest, the relative political capacity of these <strong>in</strong>terests, and the broaderconstellation of supportive norms and values.” 22Scholars work<strong>in</strong>g on welfare spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries have <strong>in</strong>vestigatedthis relationship as well. Kaufman and Segura-Ubiergo (2001) demonstrates that amongLat<strong>in</strong> American countries, popularly-based governments (def<strong>in</strong>ed as governments thathave close historical l<strong>in</strong>ks with labor unions or a long-stand<strong>in</strong>g programmatic orientationtoward the “popular sector”) have a significant and positive short-term effect on socialspend<strong>in</strong>g. 23Rudra (2002), <strong>in</strong> a study of 53 less-developed countries, found that, <strong>in</strong>contrast to Garrett’s f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> the OECD sample of countries, <strong>in</strong>creased capital andtrade openness comb<strong>in</strong>ed with weak labor power produced a significant and negative21 Geoffrey Garrett, Partisan Politics <strong>in</strong> the Global Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,1998)22 Duane Swank, Global Capital, Political Institutions, and Policy Change <strong>in</strong> Developed Welfare States(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002)23 Robert Kaufman and Alex Segura-Ubiergo, “Globalization, Domestic Politics, and Social Spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>Lat<strong>in</strong> America: A Time-Series Cross-Section Analysis, 1973-97,” World Politics 53 (2001)17


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citeeffect on welfare spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> LDCs. Rudra’s results affirmed that governments’commitments to welfare spend<strong>in</strong>g depend on strong labor-market <strong>in</strong>stitutions. 24Notwithstand<strong>in</strong>g these <strong>in</strong>sights, the literature’s exploration of globalization’seffects leaves several important lacunae that merit further <strong>in</strong>vestigation. One area thatcompels further <strong>in</strong>quiry is whether deepened <strong>in</strong>tegration yielded comparable effects upondifferent segments of workers. Along with greater trade and capital openness, employers<strong>in</strong> advanced as well as develop<strong>in</strong>g countries <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly embraced flexible or atypicalhir<strong>in</strong>g practices dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1990s, as they turned to temporary and part-time contracts aswell as sub-contract<strong>in</strong>g that permitted them to shed workers more easily and to m<strong>in</strong>imizethe costs of pay<strong>in</strong>g employees welfare benefits. 25These developments are thought tohave produced new fissures <strong>in</strong> the labor market between workers with secureemployment (<strong>in</strong>siders) and those who face more precarious terms of employment(outsiders) (Rueda). These different groups of labor market participants are viewed tocomprise dist<strong>in</strong>ct voter constituencies with disparate policy preferences and <strong>in</strong>terests.Yet, it is not clear that the boundary between the preferences of these groups is asimpermeable outside of the OECD. Given that employment protection legislation <strong>in</strong> themiddle-<strong>in</strong>come develop<strong>in</strong>g countries is weaker than it is <strong>in</strong> OECD countries, it seemsplausible that the boundary between formal and <strong>in</strong>formal sector workers might be lesshardened <strong>in</strong> <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> and Lat<strong>in</strong> America. This raises the question of whether, <strong>in</strong> thesecountries that manifest weaker EPL for formal sector workers, the pressures ofglobalization generated more possibilities for <strong>in</strong>formal and formal sector workers to24 Nita Rudra, “Globalization and the Decl<strong>in</strong>e of the Welfare State <strong>in</strong> Less-Developed Countries”International Organization 56:2 (2002)25 OECD, Employment Outlook, several years, Kev<strong>in</strong> Gray, Korean Workers and Neoliberal Globalization(London: Routledge, 2008), Kirsten Sehnbruch, The Chilean Labor Market (New York: Palgrave, 2006)18


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citerecognize a common ground of shared <strong>in</strong>terests, yield<strong>in</strong>g greater scope for alliances andcoalitions to be formed across segments with<strong>in</strong> the labor force.Second, the globalization literature tends to focus on levels of social spend<strong>in</strong>g asthe measure of <strong>in</strong>terest. In privileg<strong>in</strong>g the importance of expenditures, the literature risksoverlook<strong>in</strong>g other equally, if not more important aspects of welfare policy such as theextent of redistribution and risk pool<strong>in</strong>g that perhaps more <strong>in</strong>cisively captures howglobalization shapes the political dynamic beh<strong>in</strong>d the welfare policy debate. Toparaphrase Esp<strong>in</strong>g-Anderson, to assume that all spend<strong>in</strong>g counts equally may be quitemislead<strong>in</strong>g. For <strong>in</strong>stance, a country’s welfare spend<strong>in</strong>g may be high because it allocatesgenerous benefits to a privileged group such as civil servants. Conversely, the costs<strong>in</strong>curred by a universal program that offers benefits to all citizens depend on thegenerosity of these benefits. If a universal program extends low levels of benefits, theoverall costs of the program may not be higher than that of a corporatist or liberal regime.Consequently, focus<strong>in</strong>g on spend<strong>in</strong>g levels or changes <strong>in</strong> spend<strong>in</strong>g levels may notbe as illum<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g as identify<strong>in</strong>g how these monies have been spent. As a case <strong>in</strong> po<strong>in</strong>t,total health spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> South Korea, Thailand, and Chile, for <strong>in</strong>stance, is roughly equalat around 6% of GDP. Notwithstand<strong>in</strong>g this, the programs are established uponcontrast<strong>in</strong>g objectives that are underscored by different rules regard<strong>in</strong>g the eligibility ofparticipation and benefits for groups of citizens. This choice of program type has at leastas much, if not more, to do with how groups contest the allocation of f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g,redistribution of <strong>in</strong>come, and pool<strong>in</strong>g of risk than merely spend<strong>in</strong>g. Voters and <strong>in</strong>terestgroups weigh not only the costs of the program, which often rema<strong>in</strong> variable and<strong>in</strong>determ<strong>in</strong>ate dur<strong>in</strong>g much of the policy discussion, but also what they stand to lose or19


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citega<strong>in</strong> by the proposed reform. The design of a program highlights these tradeoffs muchmore emphatically than its overall estimated cost.Power resources theoryThe central dynamic that animates the power resources theory is the conflictbetween workers and capitalists, two pr<strong>in</strong>cipal social groups <strong>in</strong> a capitalist democracythat have access to different resources. Capitalists wield market-based resources that putthem at considerable advantage aga<strong>in</strong>st workers. To mitigate their vulnerability to themarket economy, workers need to rely on their strength of numbers and formorganizations that articulate their <strong>in</strong>terests. Importantly, these work<strong>in</strong>g class demands aremediated by left parties <strong>in</strong> the political arena. 26Accord<strong>in</strong>g to power resources theory,variations <strong>in</strong> the size and shape of welfare regimes are produced by the relativedifferences between resources mobilized by the work<strong>in</strong>g class and left parties and thestrength of the organization of the capitalists and right parties (Castles, Esp<strong>in</strong>g-Anderson,Korpi, Huber and Stephens).An <strong>in</strong>fluential <strong>in</strong>sight underp<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g power resources theory is the recognition thatorganized power of the subord<strong>in</strong>ate classes can counterweigh the power of capital; thus,this school emphasizes that relative power organizations are critical to exercis<strong>in</strong>g voice <strong>in</strong>the political arena. In their absence, workers lack tools to be effective actors and <strong>in</strong>steadsubside <strong>in</strong>to a passive group that is “acted upon.” However, notwithstand<strong>in</strong>g theresonance of this <strong>in</strong>sight, it is unclear, given the weakness of labor organizations <strong>in</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g democracies, whether plac<strong>in</strong>g so much explanatory weight on a relativelyattenuated actor illum<strong>in</strong>ates the outcomes. While labor organizations dim<strong>in</strong>ished <strong>in</strong>26 Evelyn Huber and John D. Stephens, Development and Crisis of the Welfare State: Parties and Policies<strong>in</strong> Global Markets (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 2001)20


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citemembership and organizational breadth <strong>in</strong> the advanced <strong>in</strong>dustrial democracies dur<strong>in</strong>g thepast two decades, they experienced even more attenuation <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g democracies(Murillo 2001, Deyo 1989). As Table 1 below demonstrates, the number of workersbelong<strong>in</strong>g to unions <strong>in</strong> these regions is low relative to the levels evidenced <strong>in</strong> WesternEurope. Moreover, although union membership did rise slightly <strong>in</strong> some of thesecountries <strong>in</strong> the years lead<strong>in</strong>g up to democratic transition, it decl<strong>in</strong>ed subsequently dur<strong>in</strong>gthe 1990s, reflect<strong>in</strong>g the growth <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy and employers’ <strong>in</strong>creasedreliance on temporary contract labor. Additionally, labor organizations do not exerciseencompass<strong>in</strong>g breadth <strong>in</strong> these countries. Collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g, for <strong>in</strong>stance, takes placeprimarily at the enterprise level. Unions often belong to compet<strong>in</strong>g labor confederations,so that it is difficult to f<strong>in</strong>d centralized labor organizations that can credibly represent theunified <strong>in</strong>terests of labor (Yang 2005, María Lorena Cook 1998, V. María Murillo 2001,Volker 1996).Table 1: Comparison of Union DensityCountry Union density (%) Year Country Union density (%) YearArgent<strong>in</strong>a 24 1997 Belgium 52 2000Bolivia 18 1997 Denmark 76 2000Brazil 32 1997 F<strong>in</strong>land 76 2000Chile 16 1997 France 10 2000Colombia 11 1997 German 31 2000Ecuador 10 1997 Ireland 51 2000Mexico 30.5 1997 Italy 40 2000Peru 8 1997 Netherlands 25 2000Uruguay 11.5 1997 Norway 56 2000Venezuela 14 1997 Portugal 33 2000S. Korea 11.6 2001 Spa<strong>in</strong> 17 2000Taiwan 31.5 1998 Sweden 84 2000Thailand 5 2000 Switzerland 25 2000Indonesia 5 1998 U.K. 42 2000Philipp<strong>in</strong>es 4.2 2000 Canada 36 2000S<strong>in</strong>gapore 20 1997 U.S. 16 200021


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citeMalaysia 15 1998 Japan 24 2000Australia 44 2000New Zealand 35 2000Source: Inter-American Development Bank database, OECD database, <strong>Asia</strong>n Development BankA second generation of literature <strong>in</strong> the power resources tradition acknowledgedthe importance of contributions made by other social groups to welfare state outcomes;Esp<strong>in</strong>g-Andersen noted that the Scand<strong>in</strong>avian universal welfare states were achievedthrough the political support of a cross-class coalition of middle and work<strong>in</strong>g class voters.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to this account, the middle class’ preferences were <strong>in</strong>strumental <strong>in</strong> shap<strong>in</strong>g thedesign of more generous universal benefits. Recent scholarship on welfare reformoutcomes <strong>in</strong> <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> also noted the importance of other coalitional partners, <strong>in</strong>particular the role played by NGOs and civil society groups <strong>in</strong> champion<strong>in</strong>g progressivepolicy (Yang, Haggard and Kaufman, Wong). Labor organizations, while a part of thisbroader cross-class pro-welfare alliance, played junior, subord<strong>in</strong>ated roles <strong>in</strong> thecoalition, even <strong>in</strong> the countries where they were the most active. Contrary to laborspearhead<strong>in</strong>g such movements, we f<strong>in</strong>d that these coalitions were brought together underthe leadership of “middle-class” or white-collar based civil society groups, whichadvanced a platform for expansionist and more redistributive welfare policy that servedthe <strong>in</strong>terests of both <strong>in</strong>formal and formal workers. These <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n examples suggest,then, that while power resources theory’s <strong>in</strong>sights about the importance of theorganizational strength of subord<strong>in</strong>ate classes are powerful, the theory’s assumption thatthese mobilizational resources <strong>in</strong>here predom<strong>in</strong>antly <strong>in</strong> the work<strong>in</strong>g class may not standup as well <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g democracies. In these countries, other groups – <strong>in</strong> particular, thewhite-collar class – also demonstrated significant mobilizational and organizationalcapacity. Under circumstances where their <strong>in</strong>terests <strong>in</strong>tersect with those of lower-class22


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citesegments, we may expect to these groups to play a “vanguard” role <strong>in</strong> organiz<strong>in</strong>g crossclasscoalitions.Electoral competitionF<strong>in</strong>ally, recent literature highlights the important role that electoral competition <strong>in</strong>new democracies played <strong>in</strong> determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g social policy outcomes. In his account ofhealthcare policy expansion <strong>in</strong> Taiwan and South Korea, Wong claimed that the pressuresof democratic competition motivated politicians to respond pre-emptively to theiropposition by advocat<strong>in</strong>g for healthcare expansion <strong>in</strong> the late 1980s. In particular, Wongidentified the terms of democratic breakthrough as critical to shap<strong>in</strong>g the competitivepressures on rul<strong>in</strong>g regime parties. Variation <strong>in</strong> how democratic breakthrough wasachieved – whether the transition was managed by political elites or the abrupt outcomeof violent social mobilization from below, the tim<strong>in</strong>g of found<strong>in</strong>g elections – affected theextent of the threat to rul<strong>in</strong>g regime parties from opposition parties, which <strong>in</strong> turn, shapedthe trajectories of expansionist policy. Wong also noted that the absence of salientpolitical cleavages afforded an opportunity for politicians to <strong>in</strong>troduce socioeconomicissues <strong>in</strong> an effort to articulate new channels of partisan attachments. Thus, welfareexpansion <strong>in</strong> both these <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n countries reflected responses by the rul<strong>in</strong>g parties topre-empt the opposition and shore up voter support. Others work<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> this region havealso noted the importance of electoral pressures <strong>in</strong> motivat<strong>in</strong>g politicians to use socialpolicy <strong>in</strong>itiatives as a means for attract<strong>in</strong>g voters (Yang).These <strong>in</strong>sights help expla<strong>in</strong> why healthcare policy expansion <strong>in</strong> <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> did notseem to correspond to any partisan color of the parties that <strong>in</strong>troduced these measures.23


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citeYet, electoral pressures alone do not adequately expla<strong>in</strong> the variations we f<strong>in</strong>d withrespect to the two dimensions of social policy outcomes: for one, while competitivepressures may <strong>in</strong>duce parties to <strong>in</strong>troduce expansive social policy as an attractiveelectoral strategy, this does not tell us why they choose more targeted versus universalexpansion. Relatedly, electoral pressures also do not account for when parties f<strong>in</strong>dredistributive and solidaristic policies more attractive than less redistributive options.A more encompass<strong>in</strong>g explanation to at least some of these questions might befound if we exam<strong>in</strong>ed variations <strong>in</strong> policy strategy <strong>in</strong> the context of how party systemdevelopment and <strong>in</strong>stitutionalization structures electoral competition. While democratictransition certa<strong>in</strong>ly ushered <strong>in</strong> a more competitive electoral environment, the partysystems <strong>in</strong> which these elections were contested differed substantially, especiallybetween countries <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America and <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>. Disparities <strong>in</strong> the organizationalmaturity of the parties as well as <strong>in</strong> the levels of party system <strong>in</strong>stitutionalization anddegrees of nationalization generated different challenges and imperatives to bothreconstituted as well as newly formed parties. This, <strong>in</strong> turn, may affect their strategiccalculations about policy choice. Pars<strong>in</strong>g out differences <strong>in</strong> the effects that party system<strong>in</strong>stitutionalization, nationalization, and organizational maturity yielded upon electoralcompetition may offer a more theoretically robust framework for understand<strong>in</strong>g howelectoral pressures motivated different trajecotires of health policy prescriptives acrossthe cases.THE ARGUMENTThis work seeks to expla<strong>in</strong> the variation <strong>in</strong> healthcare <strong>in</strong>surance reform outcomeswith respect to scope of universalism and solidarity. The model I present privileges the24


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citerole that cross-class coalitions between formal and <strong>in</strong>formal sector workers played as wellas the effects of party system <strong>in</strong>stitutionalization <strong>in</strong> shap<strong>in</strong>g electoral competition toexpla<strong>in</strong> the divergent healthcare reform outcomes we f<strong>in</strong>d <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g democracies.S<strong>in</strong>ce the 1990s, deepened <strong>in</strong>tegration <strong>in</strong>to world trade and capital markets hasbeen accompanied by grow<strong>in</strong>g labor market <strong>in</strong>security for both formal and <strong>in</strong>formalsector workers. Along with greater openness, countries <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America and <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>implemented changes to labor market regulations that produced ris<strong>in</strong>g labor marketprecariousness dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1990s and beyond. Neoliberal reforms <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> Americasubstantially reduced the density and breadth of labor organizations and led to theattrition of formal-sector workers (Murillo, Roberts). Reform and downsiz<strong>in</strong>g of thepublic sector eroded the liv<strong>in</strong>g standards and size of middle class workers that this sectorhad created dur<strong>in</strong>g the import-substitution era. In <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>, too, globalization <strong>in</strong>troducedsignificant pressures upon the work<strong>in</strong>g and middle classes. A surpris<strong>in</strong>g feature of <strong>East</strong><strong>Asia</strong>n labor markets is that, although developmental policies created a large and vibrantclass of skilled and white-collar workers, many of these workers nonetheless belonged tothe “irregular” sector, as they were either self-employed or contract workers. These“irregular” employees accounted for more than a third of the active work<strong>in</strong>g populationdur<strong>in</strong>g the 1980s, and their share rose even higher dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1990s and 2000s.Yet, while workers across both regions experienced more <strong>in</strong>security <strong>in</strong> the termsand status of their employment, the policy response to compensat<strong>in</strong>g workers has beenquite varied, as has already been recounted. In South Korea, the policy response was topush for a reform that <strong>in</strong>creased redistribution between formal and <strong>in</strong>formal sectorworkers, and <strong>in</strong> particular, between upper-<strong>in</strong>come and lower-<strong>in</strong>come workers. In Chile,25


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citethe policy effort focused on extend<strong>in</strong>g access to those who were least privileged, whilethe component of the <strong>in</strong>itiative that was designed to enhance f<strong>in</strong>ancial solidarity betweenhigher-<strong>in</strong>come and lower-<strong>in</strong>come workers failed. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>in</strong> Thailand as well, whileaccess and coverage was dramatically <strong>in</strong>creased, formal sector workers resisted policyproposals to <strong>in</strong>tegrate their healthcare <strong>in</strong>surance program with those of <strong>in</strong>formal sectorworkers.I argue that the variability <strong>in</strong> the extent of solidarism <strong>in</strong> the reform outcomesreflects differences <strong>in</strong> perceptions that segments of workers held about the repercussionsof shared labor market <strong>in</strong>security, which, <strong>in</strong> turn, affected their <strong>in</strong>centives to mobilizesubsequently as part of a cross-class coalition. Given that these proposed reformsentailed vary<strong>in</strong>g costs and benefits for different groups, where the potential losers –largely, the formal sector workers, and <strong>in</strong> particular, white-collar formal sector workers –perceived that their <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly precarious labor status heightened the possibilities oftheir jo<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>formal or irregular sector, they were more will<strong>in</strong>g to support thereform, calculat<strong>in</strong>g that the higher costs they would pay were a form of <strong>in</strong>surance aga<strong>in</strong>stthe risks of deterioration <strong>in</strong> their employment status.Grow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>security yielded two possible outcomes for formal sector workers: one,they could become “irregularized;” or two, <strong>in</strong> the face of dim<strong>in</strong>ish<strong>in</strong>g employmentopportunities or more frequent cycles of high unemployment, they could be forced to takejobs that they would have considered themselves overqualified for dur<strong>in</strong>g more robustperiods of employment. In fact, <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly over the 1990s, employers’ efforts tom<strong>in</strong>imize labor costs <strong>in</strong> the face of deepened <strong>in</strong>tegration <strong>in</strong>to the world market resulted <strong>in</strong>the replacement of formal sector workers with irregularized workers on fixed-term26


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citecontracts. Somewhat surpris<strong>in</strong>gly, these adjustment strategies affected not only unskilledand skilled manual workers but also white-collar workers. In countries such as SouthKorea and Taiwan, where the developmental state’s growth strategy rested upon thecultivation of more value-added, skilled manufactur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries, <strong>in</strong>creased trade<strong>in</strong>tegration heightened vulnerabilities for not only work<strong>in</strong>g class but also white-collarworkers. This reflected the fact that export-oriented <strong>in</strong>dustrialization, a cornerstone ofthe <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n states’ developmental paradigm, was underp<strong>in</strong>ned by not only a large poolof skilled and semi-skilled labor but also by skilled adm<strong>in</strong>istrative and service-basedfunctions that composed a wide spectrum of white-collar jobs that supported these export<strong>in</strong>dustries.Thus, labor market flexibilization <strong>in</strong>creased employment precariousness for bothformal and <strong>in</strong>formal sector workers. Yet, the former’s proclivities for recogniz<strong>in</strong>g thisshared <strong>in</strong>security depended not merely upon the fact but also upon how levels of<strong>in</strong>equality mediated their perceptions of the boundaries between themselves and <strong>in</strong>formalworkers. I argue that <strong>in</strong> more equal societies, a rise <strong>in</strong> labor market <strong>in</strong>securityaccentuated the formal sector’s perception that the boundary between themselves and<strong>in</strong>formal sector workers was relatively permeable. Because the disparity <strong>in</strong> educationaland professional qualifications between formal and <strong>in</strong>formal sector workers is muchnarrower <strong>in</strong> more equal countries, privileged workers are less likely to dist<strong>in</strong>guish ayawn<strong>in</strong>g distance between themselves and <strong>in</strong>formal sector workers as well as more likelyto perceive a greater personal stake <strong>in</strong> redress<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>equities <strong>in</strong>herent <strong>in</strong> the healthcaresystem that discrim<strong>in</strong>ated aga<strong>in</strong>st <strong>in</strong>formal workers. Thus, these calculations are moreconducive to their recognition of a shared <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> more solidaristic healthcare and their27


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citewill<strong>in</strong>gness to subsidize lower-<strong>in</strong>come workers through a more redistributive program.This change <strong>in</strong> perception, especially among white-collar formal sector workers, waspivotal <strong>in</strong> spawn<strong>in</strong>g the formation of a broad cross-class coalition between labororganizations and more “middle-class”-based civil society groups that generated supportfrom both white-collar and work<strong>in</strong>g class voters for a more solidaristic s<strong>in</strong>gle-payer fund.In contrast, <strong>in</strong> countries that were plagued by higher <strong>in</strong>equality, I argue that the<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> labor market <strong>in</strong>security did not generate as much of a perception of sharedrisks between formal and <strong>in</strong>formal sector workers. In these countries, workers across allsegments also experienced grow<strong>in</strong>g precariousness dur<strong>in</strong>g the 1990s. Labor marketsurveys reveal that labor market flexibilization affected all classes of workers – fromunskilled and skilled manual labor to white-collar workers; across all segments, moreworkers were hired on short-term or fixed-term (honorario) as opposed to open-endedcontracts, which heightened employment <strong>in</strong>stability and correspond<strong>in</strong>gly, the risk ofbe<strong>in</strong>g unable to afford healthcare <strong>in</strong>surance or be<strong>in</strong>g bumped out of company-based<strong>in</strong>surance pools. But despite the growth <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>security, workers – blue-collar and whitecollarrema<strong>in</strong>ed atomized and virtually no cross-class coalitions of grassrootsorganizations emerged. While many have argued that the paucity of grassrootsmobilization was rooted <strong>in</strong> neoliberal labor market policies (most prom<strong>in</strong>ently, thedismantl<strong>in</strong>g of the public sector and the dim<strong>in</strong>ution of labor unions), fund<strong>in</strong>g constra<strong>in</strong>tsfor NGOs <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America, and the decimation of grassroots organizations dur<strong>in</strong>g theauthoritarian periods, an alternative explanation for the absence of cross-classmobilization may lie <strong>in</strong> the barriers posed by high levels of <strong>in</strong>equality. Even whenupscale and downscale workers faced some measure of shared <strong>in</strong>security, the chasm that28


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citethey perceived <strong>in</strong> other labor market status markers – educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment, professionalqualifications – made it difficult for them to identify with one another and less <strong>in</strong>cl<strong>in</strong>ed toview solidarity <strong>in</strong> social protection as a solution to grow<strong>in</strong>g labor market <strong>in</strong>security.While levels of <strong>in</strong>equality mediated different workers’ perceptions of shared riskthat affected their preferences for cross-class mobilization – most importantly, those offormal sector workers – the extent to which governments sought greater universality ofaccess reflected the nature of electoral party competition <strong>in</strong> these middle-<strong>in</strong>comedevelop<strong>in</strong>g countries, which I argue, <strong>in</strong> turn, was shaped by party system<strong>in</strong>stitutionalization and nationalization.In their 1995 work, Ma<strong>in</strong>war<strong>in</strong>g and Scully brought attention to the prevalence ofweak party system <strong>in</strong>stitutionalization <strong>in</strong> new Lat<strong>in</strong> American democracies, highlight<strong>in</strong>gthe important l<strong>in</strong>kages between party system stability and democratic consolidation.Follow<strong>in</strong>g on the heels of this work, scholars of <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n party systems also have<strong>in</strong>vestigated the extent of <strong>in</strong>stitutionalization <strong>in</strong> <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n regimes (Stockton, Kuhonta,Chang, Hicken). The general consensus reached by this raft of regional studies suggestedthat <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n party systems ev<strong>in</strong>ced comparably weak, if not weaker, <strong>in</strong>dicators of<strong>in</strong>stitutionalization, at least as far as the quantifiable aspects of the Ma<strong>in</strong>war<strong>in</strong>g-Scully<strong>in</strong>dex were concerned. Kuhonta and Hicken, for <strong>in</strong>stance, found that most <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>ndemocracies exhibited higher Pedersen scores of electoral volatility, on average, thanmany Lat<strong>in</strong> American countries (<strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n semi-authoritarian regimes such asS<strong>in</strong>gapore and Malaysia br<strong>in</strong>g down average volatility). Table 2 replicates theircalculations of the levels of electoral volatility across the two regions.29


Table 2 – Electoral Volatility Across Legislative ElectionsCountry Time Span Average VolatilityArgent<strong>in</strong>a 1983-2001 25.1Venezuela 1958-2001 31.4Brazil 1986-2002 21.8Chile 1989-2001 16.7Mexico 1988-2000 22.7Average 23.5Taiwan 1992-2004 16.2S. Korea 1988-2004 29.1Thailand 1992-2005 35.0Philipp<strong>in</strong>es 1992-1998 37.3Indonesia 1999-2004 26.7Average 28.9Source: Kuhonta and Hicken (2009)Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citeSimilarly, if average age is considered as an <strong>in</strong>dicator of party rootedness <strong>in</strong>society, <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n party systems scored poorly. The average age of parties is on averagelower <strong>in</strong> most <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n countries than <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America (with the exception of Taiwan,where the average age is skewed by the longevity of the KMT). If the average age ofparties hold<strong>in</strong>g 10% or more of legislative seats post-democratic transition is calculated,the oldest party <strong>in</strong> South Korea was only 2 years old. (Conversely, the average party ageof Taiwan, on the other hand, was 43.5 years; this reflects the longevity of the 81-yearoldKMT as well as a low level of fragmentation <strong>in</strong> the Taiwanese party system <strong>in</strong> whichonly one ma<strong>in</strong> opposition party, the DPP, is present.)Third, analysts concluded that <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n parties had high levels of non-partisanor unattached voters. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to survey results issued by <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong> Barometer, nearly60% of voters <strong>in</strong> Thailand responded that they did not feel close to any party while 46%of Philipp<strong>in</strong>e voters responded likewise. Even <strong>in</strong> countries that had more30


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or cite<strong>in</strong>stitutionalized systems such as Taiwan, more than 40% of voters declared themselvesto be unattached to any party (Cheng). In part, this may reflect voters’ disenchantmentwith the KMT’s strong-arm tactics dur<strong>in</strong>g the authoritarian era of manipulat<strong>in</strong>g electoraldistrict<strong>in</strong>g and other electoral rules that discredited the activities of political parties.Somewhat surpris<strong>in</strong>gly, only 27% of Korean voters responded that they did not feel closeto any political party. However, their relatively higher level of attachment may reflectstrong prov<strong>in</strong>cial identities that b<strong>in</strong>d them to a party whose leader was born <strong>in</strong> theirregion. Perhaps underscor<strong>in</strong>g the tenuousness of partisan ties even among those whoprofessed an attachment, <strong>in</strong> all the <strong>East</strong> <strong>Asia</strong>n countries, the overwhelm<strong>in</strong>g majority ofthose voters who identified themselves as “feel<strong>in</strong>g close” to a political party also revealedthemselves to feel “just a little close” as opposed to “somewhat close” or “very close.”At the same time that Ma<strong>in</strong>war<strong>in</strong>g and Scully’s <strong>in</strong>dex captures several importantmeasures of party system stability, it does not <strong>in</strong>dicate other important characteristics ofparty systems that would affect the dynamics of party competition. One such <strong>in</strong>dicator isthe extent to which party systems are nationalized. Jones and Ma<strong>in</strong>war<strong>in</strong>g noted that thelevel of nationalization – or the extent to which a party’s vote share is consistent fromone region or prov<strong>in</strong>ce to another – is an important factor that shapes parties’ electoralstrategies. They claimed that “if the level of nationalization diverges sharply between[these] two systems, the competitive dynamics are quite different.” We would expectparties whose electoral strength is based on their dom<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong> certa<strong>in</strong> regions to pursuedifferent strategies than those who have nationally consistent vote shares.I argue that variations <strong>in</strong> dimensions of party systems – <strong>in</strong>stitutionalization andregionalization – afforded parties different strategic opportunities to carve out electoral31


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citega<strong>in</strong>s by champion<strong>in</strong>g universal versus targeted social policy. In poorly <strong>in</strong>stitutionalizedand regionalized party systems, where partisan attachments were fluid or regionallyrooted, parties, <strong>in</strong> order to attract new voters or consolidate a more stable coreconstituency, had <strong>in</strong>centives to cultivate new cleavages that would either attach morefirmly float<strong>in</strong>g voters or cross-cut or complement exist<strong>in</strong>g regional attachments.Extend<strong>in</strong>g universal social policy benefits was an efficacious strategy for achiev<strong>in</strong>g this.To the extent that l<strong>in</strong>kages with voters were based on non-programmatic or clientelisticnetworks, universal social benefits could woo away or attract voters whose loyaltiesderived from patronage goods. Second, for parties look<strong>in</strong>g to expand beyond a regionalbase, social policy represented a potential wedge that could cross-cut regional (or ethnic,as <strong>in</strong> the case of Taiwan) cleavages and potentially attract voters who might previouslyhave voted based on these bases of identification. Here, universal social policy could beused as an electoral strategy to <strong>in</strong>troduce a programmatic cleavage that could becultivated to override regional or patronage-based partisanship. In party systems whereparties’ vote shares were hampered by fragmentation, unstable because of the presence oflarge numbers of float<strong>in</strong>g voters or limited by regional loyalties, universal social policy,<strong>in</strong> its sweep of breadth, could reach more potential adherents than targeted policy.In contrast, <strong>in</strong> party systems where parties had already achieved greaternationalization, <strong>in</strong>stitutionalization, and partisan attachments, universaliz<strong>in</strong>g social policywas not an efficient electoral gambit. Because voter attachments to their parties isalready firmer, there is less scope for social policy to serve as an issue that could detachvoters from compet<strong>in</strong>g bases of party identification. In more <strong>in</strong>stitutionalized systems,where the “territory” of new potential voters is less open, universal policy has a lower32


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citeprobability of return<strong>in</strong>g votes and could result <strong>in</strong> “wasted” resources. In a more stableelectoral environment, where exist<strong>in</strong>g cleavages already divided the electorate, detach<strong>in</strong>gvoters is more costly. In this environment, sweep<strong>in</strong>g universal benefits may not yield thesame efficacy at woo<strong>in</strong>g voters than <strong>in</strong> a more fluid party system. Thus, the costs ofmore universal policies may not be worth the narrower benefits. Instead, a policy thattargets benefits at specific constituencies whose loyalties a party may want to attract orre<strong>in</strong>force may be more cost-effective.CONCLUSIONThis study of healthcare reform outcomes <strong>in</strong> middle-<strong>in</strong>come develop<strong>in</strong>gdemocracies generates a number of <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g theoretical possibilities. First, it suggeststhat globalization can elicit demands for compensatory policy, but the form of thesedemands depends on whether the structure of the domestic political economy mediatesthe pressures of globalization <strong>in</strong> such ways as to foster cross-class solidarity. The studyalso elucidates that power resources may reside <strong>in</strong> more transient organizational formsthat are not as <strong>in</strong>stitutionalized as they emerged <strong>in</strong> the post-WWII advanced <strong>in</strong>dustrialeconomy landscape. Nonetheless, the mobilization of these organizational resources bysomewhat different class actors appears to make a difference <strong>in</strong> shap<strong>in</strong>g policy outcomes.Second, the study suggests that there is further room for study<strong>in</strong>g the effects of partysystem <strong>in</strong>stitutionalization. While we are led to believe that well-<strong>in</strong>stitutionalized partiesand party systems are more conducive to greater accountability, stability, and moreequitable outcomes, the outcome of the cases here suggest that <strong>in</strong> perhaps <strong>in</strong>termediatezones of <strong>in</strong>stitutionalization – where parties systems are weakly <strong>in</strong>stitutionalized but33


Illan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citemov<strong>in</strong>g towards deepened <strong>in</strong>stitutionalization – competitive pressures on partiesmotivates them to seek more broadly equitable policy than those <strong>in</strong> already stabilizedparty systems.Appendix 1.ATrade/GDP ratiosRegion/CountryAverage trade/GDP1980-1990Average trade/GDP1991-2004EAST ASIAS<strong>in</strong>gapore 59 57 -2Malaysia 115.3 194 68.3South Korea 66.4 66.2 -0.2Thailand 56.5 101.9 80.5Philipp<strong>in</strong>es 51.7 91.1 76.2Indonesia 47.9 59.8 24.8Taiwan 70.4 80 14.3Average 69.6 92.8 37.4LATIN AMERICAEcuador 53.6 55.6 3.7Chile 53.5 60.2 12.6Bolivia 47.3 49.3 4.3Venezuela 46.7 50.7 8.5Uruguay 41.5 41.5 -0.1Peru 34.2 32 -6.4Mexico 30.2 53.3 76.5Colombia 28.8 37.6 30.5Brazil 17.4 21.7 25.1Argent<strong>in</strong>a 15.2 24.1 58.6Average 36.8 42.6 21.3% change <strong>in</strong>average ratio34


Appendix 1.BFDI/GDPCountry/Region FDI/GDPPorfolio<strong>in</strong>vestments/GDPIllan Nam, Colgate University, Feb 2011Draft <strong>in</strong> progress, please do not quote or citeFDI+Portfolioflows/GDPTime periodEAST ASIAS<strong>in</strong>gapore 156 63.5 219.4 2001-2005Malaysia 38.1 25.5 63.6 2001-2005Thailand 12.8 9.3 22.1 1995-2002Philipp<strong>in</strong>es 15.2 23.8 38.9 2001-2005Indonesia 5.7 9.5 15.2 2001-2005South Korea 12.2 22.7 34.9 1997-2005Taiwan N/A N/A N/AAverage 40 25.7 65.7Avg m<strong>in</strong>us 16.8 18.2 35S<strong>in</strong>gaporeLATINAMERICAChile 58.8 14.3 73.1 1996-2005Bolivia 56.8 0.3 57.1 1997-2005Mexico 27 24.1 51 2001-2006Ecuador 32.7 24.2 56.9 1993-2004Argent<strong>in</strong>a 25.1 23.7 48.8 1995-2006Colombia 20.3 11.2 31.5 1995-2006Brazil 22.2 27.7 50 2001-2006Uruguay 12.8 19 31.8 1999-2005Venezuela 25.8 20.3 46.1 1999-2005Peru 18.1 12.6 30.8 1995-2006Average 30 17.8 47.735

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!