12.07.2015 Views

Money, Bank Credit, and Economic Cycles - The Ludwig von Mises ...

Money, Bank Credit, and Economic Cycles - The Ludwig von Mises ...

Money, Bank Credit, and Economic Cycles - The Ludwig von Mises ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

A Critique of Monetarist <strong>and</strong> Keynesian <strong>The</strong>ories 541precisely predict the course of events. 46 Defenders of thishypothesis fail to realize that, as <strong>Mises</strong> correctly explained, theconcept of neutral money is a contradiction in terms:<strong>The</strong> notion of a neutral money is no less contradictory thanthat of a money of a stable purchasing power. <strong>Money</strong> withouta driving force of its own would not, as people assume,be a perfect money; it would not be money at all. 47Under these circumstances it is not surprising that newclassical economists lack a satisfactory theory of the cycle, asdid their monetarist predecessors, that their only explanationfor the cycle is based on mysterious, unpredictable, realshocks, 48 <strong>and</strong> that they are ultimately incapable of explaining46 See Robert E. Lucas’s, refined <strong>and</strong> concise exposition in his “NobelLecture: Monetary Neutrality,” Journal of Political Economy 104, no. 4(August 1996): 661–82. Lucas has described cycles as the real results ofmonetary shocks unanticipated by economic agents. Consequently variousauthors have pointed out supposed similarities between the theoristsof the Austrian School <strong>and</strong> those of new classical economics. Inview of the fact that new classical economists lack a capital <strong>and</strong> malinvestmenttheory, <strong>and</strong> that Austrians consider the equilibrium model,maximizing representative agent <strong>and</strong> aggregates their new classicaleconomist colleagues use unrealistic <strong>and</strong>/or meaningless, we may reasonablyconclude that the “similarities” are more apparent than real. SeeRichard Arena, “Hayek <strong>and</strong> Modern Business Cycle <strong>The</strong>ory,” in <strong>Money</strong><strong>and</strong> Business <strong>Cycles</strong>: <strong>The</strong> <strong>Economic</strong>s of F.A. Hayek, M. Colonna <strong>and</strong> H.Hagemann, eds., vol. 1, chap. 10, pp. 203–17; see also Carlos UsabiagaIbáñez <strong>and</strong> José María O’Kean Alonso, La nueva macroeconomía clásica(Madrid: Ediciones Pirámide, 1994), pp. 140–44. A detailed analysis ofthe profound differences between the Austrian approach <strong>and</strong> the neoclassicalperspective, which constitutes the microeconomic basis forLucas’s views, appears in Huerta de Soto, “<strong>The</strong> Ongoing Methodenstreitof the Austrian School”; see also Garrison, Time <strong>and</strong> <strong>Money</strong>, esp.chaps. 10–12.47 <strong>Mises</strong>, Human Action, p. 418. We must emphasize that Austrians donot consider money neutral even in the long term, since the productivestructure which remains following all of the readjustments credit expansionprovokes bears no resemblance to the one which would haveformed in the absence of inflation.48 See Finn E. Kydl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Edward C. Prescott, “Time to Build <strong>and</strong>Aggregate Fluctuations,” Econometrica 50 (November 1982): 1345–70;

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!