12.07.2015 Views

Organization and Performance of Cotton Sectors in Africa ... - infoDev

Organization and Performance of Cotton Sectors in Africa ... - infoDev

Organization and Performance of Cotton Sectors in Africa ... - infoDev

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

WCA than <strong>in</strong> ESA (US$0.025 to US$0.040 per kg <strong>of</strong> l<strong>in</strong>t, compared with zeroto US$.029 per kg <strong>of</strong> l<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> ESA), <strong>and</strong> they are highest <strong>in</strong> Mali, because thescope <strong>of</strong> extension <strong>in</strong>cludes rural development functions beyond cotton.Extension <strong>in</strong> Cameroon also covers rural development, but its cost is sharedbetween the cotton company <strong>and</strong> the farmer association. The monopoly cottoncompanies also contribute to road ma<strong>in</strong>tenance <strong>and</strong> research costs, thoughprobably less <strong>in</strong> Mozambique than <strong>in</strong> the WCA countries. 81MACRO IMPACTSThe two macro impact <strong>in</strong>dicators are per capita total value added from the cottonsector <strong>and</strong> per capita net budgetary contributions <strong>of</strong> the sector. Valueadded at the farm level is calculated by subtract<strong>in</strong>g nonlabor production costsfrom the farm gate value <strong>of</strong> seed cotton production. In the absence <strong>of</strong> mean figuresacross all farmers, the data for the farmer group that conta<strong>in</strong>s the medianfarmer are used (see table 11.4 <strong>and</strong> figure 11.3).Value added is calculated us<strong>in</strong>g two different def<strong>in</strong>itions <strong>of</strong> nonlabor productioncosts. In the first case, <strong>in</strong>put costs are deducted from the gross value <strong>of</strong>seed cotton production. In the second case, costs <strong>of</strong> animal traction <strong>and</strong>motorized services are also deducted, although the latter are extremely rare.The most appropriate def<strong>in</strong>ition can be debated. The argument for deduct<strong>in</strong>ganimal traction costs from value added is that they <strong>in</strong>clude rental or amortization<strong>of</strong> equipment, plus veter<strong>in</strong>ary <strong>and</strong> feed<strong>in</strong>g costs for oxen. These <strong>in</strong>termediate<strong>in</strong>puts account for about 80 percent <strong>of</strong> the estimated animal tractioncosts <strong>in</strong> WCA sectors. The argument for not deduct<strong>in</strong>g animal traction costs isthat oxen (<strong>and</strong>, <strong>in</strong>deed, equipment) are assets that farm households have accumulated<strong>in</strong> large part through their engagement with cotton production.Deduct<strong>in</strong>g animal traction costs would have the perverse effect <strong>of</strong> lower<strong>in</strong>g theestimates <strong>of</strong> the value added generated by WCA sectors (because these sectorshave proceeded further with animal traction than ESA) when this progressowes much to cotton.Value added at the g<strong>in</strong>nery stage can be estimated by subtract<strong>in</strong>g all nonlabor<strong>and</strong> nontax costs for purchase <strong>and</strong> collection <strong>of</strong> seed cotton <strong>and</strong> for process<strong>in</strong>g<strong>and</strong> market<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> l<strong>in</strong>t cotton from the total FOT value <strong>of</strong> l<strong>in</strong>t <strong>and</strong>seeds. The two value-added numbers are then summed, <strong>and</strong> the result is convertedto per capita figures by multiply<strong>in</strong>g by production <strong>and</strong> divid<strong>in</strong>g by totalcountry population (table 11.4, figure 11.3).WCA countries perform relatively poorly on total value added per kg <strong>of</strong>l<strong>in</strong>t. Yet Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso <strong>and</strong> Mali perform quite well when this number isadjusted to the country’s total population; the two different treatments <strong>of</strong> animaltraction costs have no impact on overall conclusions. The high valueadded per capita <strong>in</strong> Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso <strong>and</strong>, to a lesser degree Mali, flows directlyfrom the orientation <strong>of</strong> the national monopolies (now local monopolies <strong>in</strong>Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso) to extend cotton cultivation to all farmers <strong>in</strong> areas deemedCOST EFFICIENCY, SECTOR COMPETITIVENESS, AND MACRO IMPACT 147

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!