11.07.2015 Views

Informality in Africa: A Review - WIEGO

Informality in Africa: A Review - WIEGO

Informality in Africa: A Review - WIEGO

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g PapersThe global research-policy-action network Women <strong>in</strong> Informal Employment: Globaliz<strong>in</strong>gand Organiz<strong>in</strong>g (<strong>WIEGO</strong>) Work<strong>in</strong>g Papers feature research that makes either an empiricalor theoretical contribution to exist<strong>in</strong>g knowledge about the <strong>in</strong>formal economy especiallythe work<strong>in</strong>g poor, their liv<strong>in</strong>g and work environments and/or their organizations. Particularattention is paid to policy-relevant research <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g research that exam<strong>in</strong>es policyparadigms and practice. This series <strong>in</strong>cludes statistical profiles of <strong>in</strong>formal employmentand critical analysis of data collection and classification methods. Methodological issuesand <strong>in</strong>novations, as well as suggestions for future research, are considered. All <strong>WIEGO</strong>Work<strong>in</strong>g Papers are peer reviewed by the <strong>WIEGO</strong> Research Team and/or external experts.The <strong>WIEGO</strong> Publication Series is coord<strong>in</strong>ated by the <strong>WIEGO</strong> Research Team.This paper was prepared for the Swedish International Development Cooperation Agency– Sida.About the Authors:James He<strong>in</strong>tz is Research Professor at the Political Economy Research Institute ofthe University of Massachusetts, Amherst. He holds a Ph.D. from the University ofMassachusetts and a master’s degree from the University of M<strong>in</strong>nesota. He has written ona wide range of economic policy issues, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g job creation, global labour standards,egalitarian macroeconomic strategies, and <strong>in</strong>vestment behavior.Imraan Valodia is Associate Professor <strong>in</strong> the School of Development Studies, Universityof KwaZulu-Natal. His research <strong>in</strong>terests <strong>in</strong>clude employment, the <strong>in</strong>formal economy,gender and economic policy, and <strong>in</strong>dustrial development. He has worked with lead<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>ternational development organizations, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the United Nation Research Institutefor Social Development (UNRISD), the International Labour Organization (ILO), the UnitedNations Development Programme (UNDP) and the World Bank.Publication date: September 2008ISBN number: 978-92-95095-19-9Published by Women <strong>in</strong> Informal Employment: Globaliz<strong>in</strong>g and Organiz<strong>in</strong>g (<strong>WIEGO</strong>)A Charitable Company Limited by Guarantee – Company No. 6273538, Registered CharityNo. 1143510<strong>WIEGO</strong> Secretariat<strong>WIEGO</strong> LimitedHarvard Kennedy School,521 Royal Exchange79 John F. Kennedy Street Manchester, M2 7EN,Cambridge, MA 02138, USA United K<strong>in</strong>gdomwww.wiego.orgCopyright © <strong>WIEGO</strong>.This report can be replicated for educational and organiz<strong>in</strong>g purposes as long as thesource is acknowledged.Cover photograph by: Patricia Carney


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3Table of ContentsIntroduction.............................................................................................................................................1Structure of Informal Employment <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>: Statistical Overview......................................1Def<strong>in</strong>itions of Informal Employment and Measurement Issues.................................................................4Informal Employment <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>: Statistical Overview from Selected Countries...................6Employment <strong>in</strong> the Informal Sector......................................................................................................7Informal Employment..........................................................................................................................9Employment, Earn<strong>in</strong>gs, and Poverty: Illustrative Statistics....................................................................12Causes of <strong>Informality</strong>.............................................................................................................................17Case Studies and Policy Issues..............................................................................................................19Market Development.........................................................................................................................19The F<strong>in</strong>ancial Sector.........................................................................................................................21Access to Assets...............................................................................................................................24Conclusions............................................................................................................................................26References.............................................................................................................................................27List of TablesTable 1 Estimates of Labour Force Participation Rates, <strong>Africa</strong>n Countries and Regions...............................2Table 2 Employment <strong>in</strong> the Informal Sector, Selected countries, Urban and Rural, Disaggregatedby Sex. Estimates from National Statistics Offices Collected by the ILO Bureau of Statistics.........................7Table 3 Structure of Employment <strong>in</strong> Five <strong>Africa</strong>n Countries. Distribution of Formal and InformalEmployment by Employment Status...........................................................................................................9Table 4 Distribution of Men’s Total Employment and Women’s Total Employment by Employment Status.......... 10Table 5 Most Significant Sectors/Activities for Non-Agricultural Informal Workers......................................12Table 6 Estimated Hourly Earn<strong>in</strong>gs as a Per Cent of Average Hourly Earn<strong>in</strong>gs for All EmployedIndividuals by Employment Status and Sex..............................................................................................14Table 7 Women’s Hourly Earn<strong>in</strong>gs as a Per Cent of Men’s Hourly Earn<strong>in</strong>gs...............................................15Table 8 “Work<strong>in</strong>g Poor” Poverty Rates by Employment Status and Sex.....................................................16Table 9 Primary Source of Start-Up Capital for Enterprises Operated by Own-Account Workers andUnpaid Family Members.........................................................................................................................22Table 10 Location of Un<strong>in</strong>corporated Household Enterprises, Kenya 2005/6............................................25


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3In the statistical overview, both concepts of <strong>in</strong>formal employment are used – employment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formalsector and <strong>in</strong>formal employment. In general, the self-employed are classified as formal or <strong>in</strong>formal basedon the characteristics of the enterprise. Paid employees are generally classified based on the natureof the employment relationship. However, the surveys used to construct the estimates presented herevary significantly from country to country. Therefore, the criteria used to dist<strong>in</strong>guish formal from <strong>in</strong>formalemployment are not identical across countries. We therefore focus on compar<strong>in</strong>g relative patterns ofemployment across countries, not absolute statistics. 4 In the next section, we present estimates ofemployment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector and <strong>in</strong>formal employment for a set of <strong>Africa</strong>n countries. Specifically forthe estimates of <strong>in</strong>formal employment, details with regard to def<strong>in</strong>itions and <strong>in</strong>dicators used are conta<strong>in</strong>ed<strong>in</strong> the appendix to this paper.Informal Employment <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>:Statistical Overview from Selected CountriesEmployment <strong>in</strong> the Informal SectorAs discussed above, earlier concepts of <strong>in</strong>formal employment focused on employment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formalsector (i.e., employment <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal enterprises). Statistical estimates of employment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sectorexist for a reasonable number of <strong>Africa</strong>n countries. The ILO Bureau of Statistics ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>s a database ofofficial estimates of employment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector as generated by national statistics offices. Table 2summarizes the <strong>in</strong>formation available <strong>in</strong> this database on employment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector for <strong>Africa</strong>ncountries. The database <strong>in</strong>cludes official estimates of employment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector for a total of 20<strong>Africa</strong>n countries.The <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> table 2 suggests that a reasonable amount of <strong>in</strong>formation exists on employment <strong>in</strong> the<strong>in</strong>formal sector <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n countries. It should be noted that the countries <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> table 2 only representcountries found <strong>in</strong> the ILO Bureau of Statistics database. That is, these are countries whose nationalstatistics offices generated estimates of employment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector and shared these estimates withthe ILO <strong>in</strong> the process of compil<strong>in</strong>g the database over the years. Not all countries analyze the available dataon <strong>in</strong>formal employment and generate estimates. Therefore, the potential <strong>in</strong>formation on employment <strong>in</strong> the<strong>in</strong>formal sector <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n countries is greater than that captured <strong>in</strong> table 2. Nevertheless, the ILO databasegives us a sense of the scope of exist<strong>in</strong>g statistics. In almost all cases, employment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sectorrepresents a significant share of total employment <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n countries.Caution must be exercised when compar<strong>in</strong>g the estimates <strong>in</strong> table 2 across countries. The estimates differacross a number of dimensions:(1) the def<strong>in</strong>ition of <strong>in</strong>formal sector;(2) the survey type used to develop estimates;(3) the coverage (e.g., urban/rural, agricultural/non-agricultural, and employment status); and(4) the degree of disaggregation by sex.Perhaps most significantly, def<strong>in</strong>itions vary across countries <strong>in</strong> ways that make comparisons orgeneralizations unreliable. In many cases, countries develop their own def<strong>in</strong>itions of <strong>in</strong>formal enterprises4 The emphasis on mak<strong>in</strong>g relative comparisons (<strong>in</strong>stead of absolute comparisons) across countries should still be approached withsome caution. Large differences across countries – for example, <strong>in</strong> measur<strong>in</strong>g women’s employment or labour force participation– will affect relative comparisons. For example, if women <strong>in</strong> the most precarious forms of employment are excluded from thedatasets for particular countries, the analysis may suggest a relatively high degree of gender equality when the statistics would be,<strong>in</strong> reality, <strong>in</strong>dicative of just the opposite: an extreme level of social exclusion.6


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3Table 2 Employment <strong>in</strong> the Informal Sector, Selected countries, Urban and Rural, Disaggregated by Sex. Estimates from National Statistics OfficesCollected by the ILO Bureau of StatisticsCountry Year Source Def<strong>in</strong>ition Region Number <strong>in</strong> Thousands Percent of Total EmploymentTotal Male Female Total Male FemaleBen<strong>in</strong> 2002 Household survey National Total 2,425.3 1,196.8 1,228.6 94.5 92.1 97.1Botswana 1999 Labour force survey National Total 222.6 99.6 123.0 n.a. n.a. n.a.Cameroon 1993 Mixed National Urban 119.0 n.a. n.a. 57.3 n.a. n.a.CA Republic 2003 Population census Related concept Total 18.5 19.0 16.0 16.2 13.8 2.5Côte d’Ivoire 1996 Household survey Related concept Urban 414.2 167.7 246.5 52.7 37.3 73.4Egypt 2003 Enterprise survey Related concept Urban 1,386.4 1,176.8 209.6 44.4 41.9 58.7Ethiopia 2004 Labour force survey National Urban 1,088.6 528.1 560.5 38.1 32.5 45.6The Gambia 1993 Household survey Related concept Urban 100.7 56.7 44.0 72.4 66.1 82.7Ghana 1997 Household survey National Urban n.a. n.a. n.a. 78.5 n.a. n.a.Rural n.a. n.a. n.a. 93.4 n.a. n.a.Total n.a. n.a. n.a. 89.0 n.a. n.a.Kenya 1999 Mixed Small or micro Total 1,881.0 1,090.4 790.6 36.4 43.9 29.5Madagascar 1995 Mixed National Urban 239.0 n.a. n.a. 57.5 n.a. n.a.Mali 2004 Mixed National Total 1,029.4 447.3 582.1 41.3 30.8 56.1Mauritius 2004 Household Related concept Total 33.8 24.7 9.1 6.9 7.5 5.7Niger 1995 Mixed National Urban 302.6 169.9 132.7 n.a. n.a. n.a.Senegal 1996 Official estimates Small or micro Urban 665.0 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.South <strong>Africa</strong> 2004 Labour force survey National Total 1,678.7 898.6 780.1 13.8 13.1 14.7Tunisia 1997 Enterprise survey Small or micro Total 423.1 361.3 61.7 21.6 24.5 12.8Uganda 2003 Household survey Small or micro Total 2,589.0 1,418.0 1,142.0 26.5 30.6 22.2Zambia 1993 Household survey Related concept Total 2,300.0 n.a. n.a. 80.7 n.a. n.a.Zimbabwe 1999 Labour force survey National Total 1,864.9 n.a. n.a. 40.0 n.a. n.a.7


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3that adopt the <strong>in</strong>ternational recommendations to vary<strong>in</strong>g degrees. In a few cases, statistics have beendeveloped us<strong>in</strong>g a related concept that will not capture the full extent of employment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector.For example, the estimates for Côte d’Ivoire <strong>in</strong> table 2 capture self-employment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector, butdo not capture the number of employees work<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal enterprises.Another important difference is the source of the data for compil<strong>in</strong>g the estimates. Two broad surveytypes are used for estimat<strong>in</strong>g employment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector: enterprise surveys and householdsurveys. Household surveys can be further disaggregated <strong>in</strong>to labour force surveys and general purposehousehold surveys (often used to measure liv<strong>in</strong>g standards and poverty rates among other variables).In many cases, general purpose household surveys conta<strong>in</strong> modules on the labour force and/orun<strong>in</strong>corporated household enterprises. In these cases, the household survey is a mixture of a typicallabour force survey and a general purpose household survey. Enterprise surveys, labour force surveys,general purpose household surveys, and mixed surveys collect different <strong>in</strong>formation on <strong>in</strong>formal workers.Also, the coverage of the surveys may differ. For example, enterprise surveys may not identify very smallhousehold enterprises operat<strong>in</strong>g out of residences (e.g., home-based work) to the same extent as dohousehold surveys. Similarly, household surveys may not have complete <strong>in</strong>formation on the enterpriseswhere wage employees work.Estimates of <strong>in</strong>formal employment also vary <strong>in</strong> terms of the workers they <strong>in</strong>clude or exclude. For example, itis not uncommon for estimates to focus on only urban workers or workers <strong>in</strong> a particular metropolitan area.Given the importance of agricultural employment <strong>in</strong> many <strong>Africa</strong>n countries, it becomes critical to understandwhether agricultural employment is <strong>in</strong>cluded or excluded from the estimates. As we will see <strong>in</strong> greater detail,patterns of <strong>in</strong>formal employment are highly gendered – therefore, disaggregat<strong>in</strong>g statistics by sex is of criticalimportance.Despite all these caveats, the estimates <strong>in</strong> table 2 are <strong>in</strong>structive. With the exception of a few countriesthat possess high levels of wage employment (e.g., South <strong>Africa</strong> and Mauritius), employment <strong>in</strong> the<strong>in</strong>formal sector is clearly an important livelihood strategy across the <strong>Africa</strong>n cont<strong>in</strong>ent. For countries thathave sex-disaggregated statistics, employment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector often accounts for a larger shareof women’s employment than men’s (although exceptions exist <strong>in</strong> table 2). Moreover, the ILO estimatesdemonstrate that a foundation of statistical <strong>in</strong>formation exists for understand<strong>in</strong>g the nature of <strong>in</strong>formalemployment <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n countries. More progress is needed <strong>in</strong> analyz<strong>in</strong>g the exist<strong>in</strong>g data (and collect<strong>in</strong>gnew data) <strong>in</strong> such a way as to produce a more comprehensive picture of the nature of employment <strong>in</strong> the<strong>in</strong>formal sector <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>.Informal EmploymentStatistics on the broader concept of <strong>in</strong>formal employment have also been developed for several <strong>Africa</strong>ncountries. Informal employment generally <strong>in</strong>cludes workers <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector and workers <strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>formal jobs outside of the <strong>in</strong>formal sector. Table 3 presents statistics on the structure of employment– <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formal employment – for five countries <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>: Ghana, Madagascar, Mali,Kenya, and South <strong>Africa</strong>. These countries are diverse <strong>in</strong> terms of their geography, their level of economicdevelopment, and the structure of their economies. The statistics provide a snapshot of <strong>in</strong>formalemployment <strong>in</strong> these different contexts. Although the estimates <strong>in</strong> table 3 are <strong>in</strong>dicative of the nature of<strong>in</strong>formal employment <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n countries, they cannot be taken to be truly representative of the situation<strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong> as a whole. As data is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly collected and analyzed, a more completeportrait will emerge.8


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3Table 3 Structure of Employment <strong>in</strong> Five <strong>Africa</strong>n Countries. Distribution of Formal and InformalEmployment by Employment StatusKenya(2005)Ghana(1998/9)Mali(2004)Madagascar(2005)South <strong>Africa</strong>(2004)Formal EmploymentFormal, private wage employment 6.9% 1.0% n/a 2.5% 40.8%Formal, public wage employment 5.4% 4.1% n/a 2.7% 16.5%Total formal wage employment 12.3% 5.1% 5.8% 5.2% 57.3%Formal, self-employment 1.3% 3.6% 5.1% 1.6% 4.2%Informal EmploymentInformal wage employment 18.0% 9.3% 11.0% 9.3% 22.8%Informal self-employment 64.8% 81.6% 78.1% 83.8% 14.4%Other/undeclared 3.6% 0.4% 0.0% 0.0% 1.3%TOTAL 100% 100% 100% 100% 100%… of which …Agricultural wage employment n/a 1.2% 0.9% 3.3% 10.6%Agricultural self-employment 50.0% 52.3% 41.2% 77.2% 4.7%Source: Kenya, authors’ calculations based on the 2005 Household Integrated Budget Survey; Ghana, authors’ calculations based onthe 1998/9 Ghana Liv<strong>in</strong>g Standards Survey; Mali, ILO Bureau of Statistics; and South <strong>Africa</strong>, He<strong>in</strong>tz and Posel (2007). See appendixfor more detail.The estimates show that formal employment represents a small fraction of total employment <strong>in</strong> most sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>n countries. Formal employment, both wage employment and self-employment, accountsfor an estimated 13.6 per cent of all employment <strong>in</strong> Kenya, 8.7 per cent of all employment <strong>in</strong> Ghana,10.9 per cent <strong>in</strong> Mali, and 6.8 per cent <strong>in</strong> Madagascar. The notable exception is South <strong>Africa</strong>, whereformal wage employment dom<strong>in</strong>ates. In South <strong>Africa</strong>, over 60 per cent of all employment is formal.The statistics <strong>in</strong> table 3 show that <strong>in</strong>formal self-employment is the s<strong>in</strong>gle most important source ofemployment for many countries <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>. The high rates of <strong>in</strong>formal self-employment arethe result of the importance of agricultural employment <strong>in</strong> these countries. Informal self-employment <strong>in</strong>agriculture accounts for roughly 40-50 per cent of all employment <strong>in</strong> Ghana, Kenya, and Mali, and over 77per cent <strong>in</strong> Madagascar. Given its size, the agricultural sector cannot be ignored <strong>in</strong> a comprehensive analysisof <strong>in</strong>formal employment <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>. Aga<strong>in</strong>, of the countries featured <strong>in</strong> table 3, South <strong>Africa</strong> is anexception: <strong>in</strong>formal self-employment <strong>in</strong> agricultural accounts for a relatively small share of all employment.If we focus only on non-agricultural (i.e., non-farm) <strong>in</strong>formal employment, the relative importance of <strong>in</strong>formalwage employment (i.e., <strong>in</strong>formal paid employees) and <strong>in</strong>formal self-employment varies from country to country.Us<strong>in</strong>g the examples <strong>in</strong> table 3, <strong>in</strong> Ghana and Mali <strong>in</strong>formal self-employment is relatively more important than<strong>in</strong>formal wage employment. However, <strong>in</strong> Kenya, Madagascar, and South <strong>Africa</strong>, <strong>in</strong>formal wage employmentis more prevalent than <strong>in</strong>formal self-employment outside of the agricultural sector. In South <strong>Africa</strong>, a largenumber of <strong>in</strong>formal domestic workers contribute significantly to the overall number of <strong>in</strong>formal wage workers. 55Domestic work is also common <strong>in</strong> Kenya. However, <strong>in</strong> the survey results analyzed here “domestic worker” is not used as anemployment status category. Domestic workers are identified by their <strong>in</strong>dustrial sector, which is comprised of domestic workersand laundry workers. Therefore, domestic workers cannot be specifically identified as an employment status category.9


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3Gender differences are evident <strong>in</strong> the structure of employment and the distribution of <strong>in</strong>formalemployment. Table 4 presents the distribution of employment disaggregated by sex, us<strong>in</strong>g the samegeneral categories as table 3. In all five countries, formal wage employment accounts for a larger shareof men’s employment than women’s employment. If we focus only on formal wage employment, thepublic sector is often a more important source of formal wage employment for women than for men<strong>in</strong> terms of relative comparisons. This is true for Kenya, Ghana, and South <strong>Africa</strong>. Based on theseestimates, the exception among the countries <strong>in</strong> table 4 is Madagascar (estimates of the public/privatedist<strong>in</strong>ction were not available for Mali).Table 4 Distribution of Men’s Total Employment and Women’s Total Employment by Employment StatusKenya Ghana Mali Madagascar South <strong>Africa</strong>M F M F M F M F M FFormal employment (%)Formal, private wageemploymentFormal, public wageemploymentTotal formal wageemployment8.1 2.6 1.4 0.3 n.a. n.a. 4.3 3.4 44.1 36.95.5 3.1 6.5 2.0 n.a. n.a. 3.2 1.6 14.4 18.313.6 5.7 7.9 2.3 5.5 5.4 7.5 5.0 58.5 55.2Formal, self-employment 1.3 1.0 3.5 3.6 7.1 2.2 4.7 8.5 5.1 3.1Formal, agricultural 2.5 1.3 0.5


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3between employment women and men differ somewhat from country to country. One differenceis agricultural employment. In Kenya, Madagascar, Mali, and South <strong>Africa</strong>, self-employment <strong>in</strong>agriculture accounts for a larger share of women’s total employment than men’s. In particular, a largenumber of women work <strong>in</strong> Kenya’s small-holder agricultural sector. In contrast, Ghanaian men aremore likely to work <strong>in</strong> agricultural self-employment than Ghanaian women. The dist<strong>in</strong>ction betweenself-employment and wage employment is critical here. In all five countries, wage employment <strong>in</strong>agriculture is more common among men than among women. In addition, the type of self-employmentmatters. In Madagascar, a large number of self-employed women work as unpaid contribut<strong>in</strong>g familymembers. A much smaller proportion of men work as unpaid family members. In this case, womenare disproportionately self-employed <strong>in</strong> agriculture and work <strong>in</strong> more marg<strong>in</strong>alized forms of selfemployment.In all countries except South <strong>Africa</strong>, <strong>in</strong>formal wage employment accounts for a larger share of men’semployment than women’s. However, as has already been noted, South <strong>Africa</strong> is unusual <strong>in</strong> that it hasa large number of domestic workers, the vast majority of whom are women. If we were to treat domesticworkers separately, then South <strong>Africa</strong> would look more like the other countries <strong>in</strong> table 4 with regard to thegendered pattern of <strong>in</strong>formal wage employment.We can draw a number of broad <strong>in</strong>ferences from tables 3 and 4 that should generally be <strong>in</strong>dicativeof the structure of employment <strong>in</strong> many sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>n countries, recogniz<strong>in</strong>g that South <strong>Africa</strong>rema<strong>in</strong>s an exception <strong>in</strong> many cases. First, <strong>in</strong>formal employment accounts for a significantly largershare of total employment than formal employment. Second, the agricultural sector rema<strong>in</strong>s a criticalsource of employment opportunities and cannot be easily disregarded. Third, <strong>in</strong>formal self-employment– both agricultural and non-agricultural – provides a large number of economic opportunities to menand women. Fourth, the public sector is often an important source of more formal jobs. Fifth, womentend to disproportionately work <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal employment and often more precarious forms of <strong>in</strong>formalemployment. Sixth, men tend to have greater access to wage employment – both formal and <strong>in</strong>formal –than do women.At the same time, there are differences between countries. The importance of agriculture <strong>in</strong> the structure ofemployment varies as does the gendered distribution of agricultural employment. Outside of the agriculturalsector, the relative importance of wage employment and self-employment also varies from country tocountry. In general, <strong>in</strong>formal wage employment accounts for a larger share of men’s employment thanwomen’s. However, the importance of <strong>in</strong>formal wage employment for men and women depend on thenature of the labour market – for example, do domestic workers constitute a significant fraction of totalemployment?Employment status categories (e.g., “own-account worker” or “wage employee”) give us a sense of thenature of the employment relationship, but they do not reveal the nature of the productive activities<strong>in</strong>dividuals are actually engaged <strong>in</strong>. Moreover, different employment relationships are more prevalent <strong>in</strong>certa<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustries than <strong>in</strong> others. We have exam<strong>in</strong>ed the broad sectoral division between agricultural andnon-agricultural employment, but not the variations with<strong>in</strong> non-agricultural activities. Table 5 summarizesthe dom<strong>in</strong>ant sectors/activities for non-agricultural <strong>in</strong>formal wage employees and <strong>in</strong>formal self-employedworkers <strong>in</strong> Ghana, Kenya, and Madagascar. In all cases, trade (e.g., street vendors) and various <strong>in</strong>formalservices (e.g., hair cutt<strong>in</strong>g, repairs, etc.) account for the largest share of <strong>in</strong>formal self-employmentoutside of agriculture. Only <strong>in</strong> the case of Ghana is <strong>in</strong>formal self-employment <strong>in</strong> manufactur<strong>in</strong>g activitiesa significant fraction of non-agricultural employment. 6 The variety of activities associated with <strong>in</strong>formalwage employment is more diverse: construction, transportation, services, trade, and, <strong>in</strong> the case of Kenya,domestic work/laundry services.6 Interest<strong>in</strong>gly, <strong>in</strong> Ghana, women tend to be disproportionately represented <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal manufactur<strong>in</strong>g self-employment while menare disproportionately represented <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal manufactur<strong>in</strong>g wage employment.11


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3Table 5 Most Significant Sectors/Activities for Non-Agricultural Informal WorkersCountry Employment category Dom<strong>in</strong>ant sectors/activitiesGhana Informal wage employee Various services, transportation,manufactur<strong>in</strong>g, constructionInformal self-employment Trade, manufactur<strong>in</strong>gKenya Informal wage employee Trade, transportation, domesticwork/laundriesInformal self-employment Trade, various servicesMadagascar Informal wage employee Various services, construction,transportationInformal self-employment Trade, various servicesSource: See notes to Table 3.The nature of the economic activities <strong>in</strong> which <strong>in</strong>formal workers are engaged is critical for understand<strong>in</strong>gthe dynamics of <strong>in</strong>formal employment <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. This evidence suggests that the majority of the <strong>in</strong>formallyself-employed <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong> work<strong>in</strong>g outside of agriculture are engaged <strong>in</strong> the provision ofservices (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formal forms of retail trade). This has important implications for how we th<strong>in</strong>k aboutthe determ<strong>in</strong>ants of earn<strong>in</strong>gs and productivity. Productivity <strong>in</strong> services is dist<strong>in</strong>ct from productivity <strong>in</strong>manufactur<strong>in</strong>g and other <strong>in</strong>dustrial activities. Productivity <strong>in</strong> services, and by extension earn<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> serviceactivities, is strongly <strong>in</strong>fluenced by the level of demand and development of markets. For example, astreet trader’s productivity will be largely determ<strong>in</strong>ed by the quantity of goods she sells with<strong>in</strong> a given timeperiod. In manufactur<strong>in</strong>g, productivity is often thought of as a “supply-side” factor l<strong>in</strong>ked to the nature ofproduction technology. In services, the boundary between the supply-side and demand-side is blurred <strong>in</strong>the determ<strong>in</strong>ation of overall productivity.The heterogeneity of <strong>in</strong>formal employment is evident from this analysis. The character of <strong>in</strong>formalemployment varies across sectors and the nature of the employment relationship (wage employment,own-account work, etc.). Earlier studies have recognized that a wide range of class dist<strong>in</strong>ctions areevident with<strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy as is a plurality of relationships with the formal economy, asituation that has forced a reth<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g of approaches that assign a unified, <strong>in</strong>variable role to <strong>in</strong>formalactivities <strong>in</strong> the economy (Gerry 1987; Hart 1973; ILO 1973). Nevertheless, it is not uncommon tof<strong>in</strong>d analysis of <strong>in</strong>formal forms of employment as if such employment were homogenous. Similarly,some studies focus on one segment of the <strong>in</strong>formal labour market (e.g., employers or “entrepreneurs”)and generalize to all forms of <strong>in</strong>formal employment. Care must be taken to recognize the diversityof <strong>in</strong>formal employment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Africa</strong>n context and limit the tendency to generalize when it is notwarranted.12


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3Employment, Earn<strong>in</strong>gs, and Poverty:Illustrative StatisticsThe previous sections have provided a statistical sketch of the structure of employment <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan<strong>Africa</strong>n countries with a particular emphasis on <strong>in</strong>formal employment and employment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formalsector. However, we have not said very much about the relative quality of different employmentopportunities. In this section, we illustrate some general patterns <strong>in</strong> the quality of employment for select<strong>Africa</strong>n countries with a particular emphasis on earn<strong>in</strong>gs and poverty outcomes.There are several challenges when compar<strong>in</strong>g earn<strong>in</strong>gs and poverty rates across countries. First, the<strong>in</strong>formation on employment earn<strong>in</strong>gs differs from survey to survey. This is a particular problem with regard toself-employment earn<strong>in</strong>gs. In some cases, questions about earn<strong>in</strong>gs from agricultural self-employment maynot be explicitly <strong>in</strong>cluded. When there is a lack of reliable <strong>in</strong>formation on earn<strong>in</strong>gs, similar comparisons can bemade by look<strong>in</strong>g at liv<strong>in</strong>g standard measurements and poverty <strong>in</strong>dicators. The ways <strong>in</strong> which self-employmentearn<strong>in</strong>gs are calculated also may differ. For example, some surveys may record self-reported net earn<strong>in</strong>gsfrom self-employment. Others may ask a series of questions about the revenues of household enterprises andmajor categories of expenses. Net earn<strong>in</strong>gs are then calculated as revenues less expenses. S<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>in</strong>formalenterprises typically do not keep formal accounts, the earn<strong>in</strong>gs responses are subject to measurement errors.With wage employment, estimated earn<strong>in</strong>gs are more straight-forward. Nevertheless, even here there areissues. For example, <strong>in</strong>dividuals <strong>in</strong> formal wage employment often receive various benefits that may or maynot be <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> estimated earn<strong>in</strong>gs (e.g., a hous<strong>in</strong>g or automobile allowance). For <strong>in</strong>formal wage workers,earn<strong>in</strong>gs may be volatile. Therefore, it may be hard to know whether reported earn<strong>in</strong>gs are typical or not.Poverty measurements suffer from similar problems. In addition, there are numerous approaches toassess<strong>in</strong>g the prevalence of poverty <strong>in</strong> a particular sett<strong>in</strong>g. In some cases, measures of <strong>in</strong>come poverty areused – e.g., does a household’s <strong>in</strong>come fall below a certa<strong>in</strong> threshold. Given the problems with measur<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>come, many researchers argue that consumption expenditures constitute a better foundation formeasur<strong>in</strong>g poverty. Nevertheless, there can be problems with calculat<strong>in</strong>g total consumption. For example,people often have poor recall as to their actual expenditures over a particular period. Also, some categoriesof expenditure – e.g., consumer durables – occur <strong>in</strong>frequently, but have a huge impact on total spend<strong>in</strong>gwhen they do occur. Perhaps more importantly, apart from the choice of <strong>in</strong>come or consumption as a basisfor measur<strong>in</strong>g poverty, the very def<strong>in</strong>ition of poverty varies across countries. All of these concerns makecomparable estimates across countries difficult.Despite these challenges, it is still worthwhile analyz<strong>in</strong>g statistics on earn<strong>in</strong>gs and poverty <strong>in</strong> order toidentify broad patterns. F<strong>in</strong>er dist<strong>in</strong>ctions may be impossible to identify accurately, so, as always, somecaution is warranted <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>terpret<strong>in</strong>g these results.Earn<strong>in</strong>gs estimates are difficult to compare across countries for reasons other than those outl<strong>in</strong>ed above.Earn<strong>in</strong>gs will be measured <strong>in</strong> local currencies. They can be converted to a common currency us<strong>in</strong>gmarket exchange rates, but exchange rates may be subject to macro-economic factors that confoundand blur comparisons of the domestic return to labour <strong>in</strong> different countries. It is hard to guarantee thata particular market exchange rate is the “right” one for comparison purposes. Similarly, prices may differbetween countries <strong>in</strong> ways that are not fully reflected <strong>in</strong> the exchange rate (i.e., purchas<strong>in</strong>g power parityadjustments). While conversion techniques are available, they <strong>in</strong>troduce another set of assumptions anduncerta<strong>in</strong>ties <strong>in</strong>to the statistics.To m<strong>in</strong>imize these various problems, we focus on compar<strong>in</strong>g relative earn<strong>in</strong>gs – i.e., average earn<strong>in</strong>gs with<strong>in</strong> aparticular type of employment relative to average earn<strong>in</strong>gs across all employed <strong>in</strong>dividuals. In this way, we can13


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3see if the patterns of relative earn<strong>in</strong>gs are similar or different across countries. This exercise gives us someadditional <strong>in</strong>sight <strong>in</strong>to the commonalities and differences <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal employment across <strong>Africa</strong>n countries.Table 6 presents relative earn<strong>in</strong>gs estimates for three of the five countries highlighted <strong>in</strong> the previoussection based on average estimated hourly earn<strong>in</strong>gs. These relative earn<strong>in</strong>gs estimates are disaggregatedby sex. The countries <strong>in</strong>cluded are Ghana, Kenya, and South <strong>Africa</strong>. From these estimates, we canidentify several broad patterns. Earn<strong>in</strong>gs are generally highest <strong>in</strong> formal non-agricultural employment andlowest <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal agricultural employment. Earn<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal non-agricultural employment generallylie somewhere between these extremes. Not all formal employment is necessarily superior to <strong>in</strong>formalemployment. For example, formal agricultural employment may have lower average earn<strong>in</strong>gs than certa<strong>in</strong>types of <strong>in</strong>formal non-agricultural employment. Also, <strong>in</strong>formal employers – as a subset of the <strong>in</strong>formally selfemployed– can earn, on average, more than formal wage workers <strong>in</strong> some countries.Table 6 Estimated Hourly Earn<strong>in</strong>gs as a Per Cent of Average Hourly Earn<strong>in</strong>gs for All EmployedIndividuals by Employment Status and SexKenya Ghana South <strong>Africa</strong>M F M F M FFormal employmentFormal, private wage employment 155% 256% n.a. n.a. 112% 130%Formal, public wage employment 156% 284% 173.5% 193.3% 167% 199%Formal, self-employment 803% 290% 171.0% 123.5% 287% 325%Formal, agricultural 56% 39% n.a. n.a. 79% 52%Informal non-agricural employmentInformal wage employment 40% 37% 150.5% 139.1% 34% 38%Informal-self employment n.a. n.a. 116.3% 118.9% n.a. n.a.Informal own-account 74% 63% 112.4% 119.3% 54% 43%Informal employer 158% 123% n.a. n.a. 84% 61%Informal agricultural employmentInformal agricultural wage employment 19% 23% n.a. n.a. 19% 21%Informal agricultural self-employment n.a. n.a. 82.1% 70.6% 6% 7%Source: See notes to Table 3.Gender differences are <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g. The estimates <strong>in</strong> table 6 suggest that the wage premium for access toformal jobs is higher for women than men – at least when measured relative to average earn<strong>in</strong>gs. Similarly,the penalty for <strong>in</strong>formal employment is higher for women then men. This is not surpris<strong>in</strong>g when weconsider that women are more likely to work <strong>in</strong>formally and, when they do work <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal employment,are often employed <strong>in</strong> less favourable activities. However, we need to exercise some caution when<strong>in</strong>terpret<strong>in</strong>g these results. We are only exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g three countries, and even with<strong>in</strong> these three countriesthere are exceptions and differences.We can exam<strong>in</strong>e gender earn<strong>in</strong>gs gaps more explicitly by look<strong>in</strong>g at women’s average earn<strong>in</strong>gs expressedas a per cent of men’s for different categories of employment. Table 7 summarizes these estimates for ourthree illustrative countries. In general, we f<strong>in</strong>d evidence of a gender earn<strong>in</strong>gs gap across countries <strong>in</strong> many14


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3of the employment categories we are focus<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>in</strong> this review. Women’s hourly earn<strong>in</strong>gs are typicallylower than men’s. One exception is formal wage employment <strong>in</strong> Kenya – here, estimates of women’shourly earn<strong>in</strong>gs are actually higher than men’s. This may be a consequence of the fact that women aresignificantly less likely to work <strong>in</strong> formal employment than are men. Therefore, the women who do manageto secure a formal wage job may have better qualifications on average compared to the average for men <strong>in</strong>the same broad employment category. 7Table 7 Women’s Hourly Earn<strong>in</strong>gs as a Per Cent of Men’s Hourly Earn<strong>in</strong>gsKenya Ghana South <strong>Africa</strong>Formal employmentM F MFormal, private wage employment 131% n.a. 92%Formal, public wage employment 144% 84.2% 94%Formal, self-employment 29% 54.6% 89%Formal, agricultural 55% n.a. 52%Informal non-agricural employmentInformal wage employment 74% 69.8% 88%Informal-self employment n.a. 77.2% n.a.Informal own-account 67% 80.2% 63%Informal employer 62% n.a. 57%Informal agricultural employmentInformal agricultural wage employment 93% n.a. 84%Informal agricultural self-employment n.a. 65.0% 83%ALL EMPLOYED 79% 75.6% 79%Source: See notes to Table 3.The variation <strong>in</strong> earn<strong>in</strong>gs across different categories of employment – both formal and <strong>in</strong>formal – suggeststhat labour markets <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n countries may be segmented. That is, work<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dividuals face barriers tomobility that prevent them from receiv<strong>in</strong>g the best possible returns to their labour. While the tabulationspresented here are suggestive of such segmentation, they are not conclusive. This is because thetabulations do not account for <strong>in</strong>dividual variations <strong>in</strong> terms of education, skills, experience, or otherdeterm<strong>in</strong>ants of <strong>in</strong>dividual productivity. However, econometric studies have produced evidence suggest<strong>in</strong>gthat <strong>Africa</strong>n labour markets are <strong>in</strong>deed segmented. Günther and Launov (2006) present evidencesuggest<strong>in</strong>g that the structure of employment <strong>in</strong> Côte d’Ivoire is segmented not simply between formal andcerta<strong>in</strong> types of <strong>in</strong>formal employment but also with<strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal labour market itself. He<strong>in</strong>tz and Posel(2008) show that many <strong>in</strong>formal workers <strong>in</strong> South <strong>Africa</strong> could often improve their earn<strong>in</strong>gs if they wereable to move <strong>in</strong>to formal employment or a different category of <strong>in</strong>formal employment. The early studies byHart (1973) and the ILO (1973) describe the importance of k<strong>in</strong>ship networks and social relationships <strong>in</strong>determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g access to employment – factors that would lead to segmented labour markets.7 For example, <strong>in</strong> Kenya, the average educational atta<strong>in</strong>ment of women <strong>in</strong> private formal wage employment is higher than thatof men. 19 per cent of women work<strong>in</strong>g as formal private sector paid employees have completed secondary or higher levels ofeducation compared to 11 per cent of men <strong>in</strong> the same category of employment.15


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3We now turn from a discussion of <strong>in</strong>dividual earn<strong>in</strong>gs to poverty status. One approach to exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the relationshipbetween different types of employment and poverty outcomes is to measure the “work<strong>in</strong>g poor” poverty rate. In thisreport, we def<strong>in</strong>e the “work<strong>in</strong>g poor” as those <strong>in</strong>dividuals who are (1) employed and (2) liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> households whose<strong>in</strong>come or consumption levels fall below a poverty threshold. The work<strong>in</strong>g poor poverty rate is simply the number ofwork<strong>in</strong>g poor <strong>in</strong> a particular employment category expressed as a percentage of the total number of people <strong>in</strong> thesame employment category. This gives us one measure of poverty risk: a simple assessment of the likelihood thatworkers <strong>in</strong> particular types of employment will live <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>come or consumption poverty.It should be highlighted that we are stress<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong> this analysis, the connection between types of employmentand poverty status. The focus is on the “work<strong>in</strong>g poor” population. Therefore, poverty rates among<strong>in</strong>dividuals who are not employed are not directly <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> this particular analysis. Care must be takennot to confuse the estimated poverty rates of employed <strong>in</strong>dividuals with general poverty rates among all<strong>in</strong>dividuals <strong>in</strong> the population as a whole. For example, the gender differentials discussed <strong>in</strong> this section<strong>in</strong>dicate how the poverty rates of employed women differ from those of employed men, but do notadequately capture the aggregate poverty risk of all women.Table 8 presents estimates of the “work<strong>in</strong>g poor” poverty rate by employment status disaggregated by sex.Poverty risk by employment category follows a similar pattern to average earn<strong>in</strong>gs. That is, <strong>in</strong>dividuals <strong>in</strong>formal employment tend to have lower than average rates of poverty. The risk of poverty rises as we movefrom formal to <strong>in</strong>formal employment. Informal agricultural workers experience some of the highest povertyrates. The exceptions to this general pattern are similar to the exceptions with regard to average earn<strong>in</strong>gs.For example, formal agricultural workers face a higher risk of poverty than workers <strong>in</strong> non-agriculturalformal employment. Informal employers generally face a lower-than-average poverty risk.Table 8 “Work<strong>in</strong>g Poor” Poverty Rates by Employment Status and SexKenya Ghana Madagascar South <strong>Africa</strong>M F M F M F M FFormal employmentFormal, private wage employment 16.5 11.9 26.5 n.a. 21.3 12.9 24.7 32.7Formal, public wage employment 18.5 8.0 43.9 36.5 27.5 24.1 18.0 20.2Formal, self-employment 11.6 13.3 45.8 52.0 17.5 24.9 28.7 36.3Formal, agricultural 32.1 27.8 n.a. n.a. 31.6 33.0 45.4 45.5Informal non-agric. employmentInformal wage employment 34.6 29.4 43.8 40.3 51.2 53.1 52.3 64.9Informal-self employment n.a. n.a. 58.8 57.4 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a.Informal own-account 33.5 32.8 57.4 58.5 49.5 53.3 60.9 75.9Informal employer 18.9 20.5 n.a. n.a. n.a. n.a. 42.1 57.6Informal unpaid family 30.5 35.2 60.0 70.0 48.5 53.2 n.a. n.a.Informal agriculturalInformal agricultural wage employment 41.1 50.1 56.9 n.a. 79.1 79.9 65.6 70.2Informal agricultural self-employment 45.2 54.0 72.9 74.4 68.0 62.2 95.1 94.2Agricultural unpaid family 36.3 45.1 80.7 87.8 73.7 73.2 n.a. n.a.ALL EMPLOYED 30.5 30.5 63.7 67.1 63.8 66.4 35.6 47.1Source: See notes to Table 3.16


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3The differences between women and men <strong>in</strong> terms of average earn<strong>in</strong>gs are not necessarily reflected <strong>in</strong>a comparison of their respective poverty rates. Based on the estimates <strong>in</strong> table 8, we see that employedwomen may have a lower average poverty rate than employed men <strong>in</strong> specific categories of employment.This holds true even when women’s average returns to labour are well below those of men. However, thepattern is not consistent even with<strong>in</strong> a given country. In some employment status categories, women’spoverty rates are higher than men’s, while <strong>in</strong> other categories, the reverse holds true.Why might employed women – who are disadvantaged <strong>in</strong> terms of earn<strong>in</strong>gs – actually have lower povertythan men <strong>in</strong> similar categories of employment? The answer has to do with the fact that poverty statusis determ<strong>in</strong>ed at the level of the household while analyses of labour market and employment dynamicsfocus on the <strong>in</strong>dividual. Employed women frequently have lower poverty rates on average because theircontribution to family <strong>in</strong>come makes the difference as to whether the household is poor or not – even whenwomen’s employment is of very low quality. In many cases, it is women’s employment that keeps a familyabove the poverty l<strong>in</strong>e. This seem<strong>in</strong>gly contradictory result emerges because aggregate household <strong>in</strong>come(or consumption), not an <strong>in</strong>dividual’s position <strong>in</strong> the labour market, determ<strong>in</strong>es poverty status.Also, it is important to recall that women often earn less than men with<strong>in</strong> the same broad employmentstatus categories. However, women are concentrated <strong>in</strong> forms of employment with high risks of poverty –e.g., <strong>in</strong>formal employment, particularly the more precarious forms of <strong>in</strong>formal employment. If we look at aweighted average of the “work<strong>in</strong>g poor” poverty rate across all employed women and all employed men,then women’s average poverty rate is often higher than men’s (table 7). For example, <strong>in</strong> the four countriesused for illustration here, employed women’s poverty rates are higher than men’s <strong>in</strong> three countries: Ghana,Madagascar, and South <strong>Africa</strong>. In Kenya, the average poverty rate is the same for women and men.One of the key debates about the characteristics of workers <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy is whether, as hasoften been argued by the ILO, <strong>in</strong>formal work is primarily a function of poverty or whether, as de Soto (1989)and Maloney (2004) have argued for Lat<strong>in</strong> America, the <strong>in</strong>formal economy is made up of entrepreneurswho choose to operate <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy <strong>in</strong> order to escape from the burden of hav<strong>in</strong>g to complywith onerous regulations on small entrepreneurs. Our statistical overview and most of the detailedqualitative fieldwork that has been done suggests that for most sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>n countries while somepockets of high <strong>in</strong>comes might exist, most workers <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy earn extremely low <strong>in</strong>comes –hardly the sorts of <strong>in</strong>comes that would need to be concealed from the tax authorities.Besides South <strong>Africa</strong>, no <strong>Africa</strong>n country has panel data that allows for explorations of entry and exit <strong>in</strong> the<strong>in</strong>formal economy. The evidence from South <strong>Africa</strong> (see Valodia 2008) suggests high levels of churn<strong>in</strong>g betweenformal and <strong>in</strong>formal employment over a relatively short period of time. This suggests that low-waged workers areunlikely to benefit significantly from shift<strong>in</strong>g from <strong>in</strong>formal to formal employment and vice-versa. Second, unlikethe case <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America where Maloney (2004) and others have argued that workers choose to move <strong>in</strong>to the<strong>in</strong>formal sector to escape onerous legislative requirements, there are two arguments that appear to counter afree-choice view. First, the movements occur <strong>in</strong> both directions, not just formal to <strong>in</strong>formal as one would expectif the free-choice view dom<strong>in</strong>ates. Second, as the gross <strong>in</strong>comes above suggest, there seems to be very little, ifany, economic benefits associated with movements from formal to <strong>in</strong>formal employment.In summary, the estimates presented here give us a sense of the relative quality of employment opportunities.Earn<strong>in</strong>gs are higher and poverty risks lower <strong>in</strong> formal compared to <strong>in</strong>formal employment – the one possibleexception be<strong>in</strong>g formal agricultural employment. In general, earn<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> agricultural activities are lower than those<strong>in</strong> non-agricultural, <strong>in</strong>formal work, and the risk of poverty is correspond<strong>in</strong>gly higher. There is evidence of a genderearn<strong>in</strong>gs gap that persists across employment arrangements <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g forms of self-employment. That is, womenearn less than men. In the cases were the gender earn<strong>in</strong>gs gap disappears – e.g., formal wage employment <strong>in</strong>Kenya – it reflects the extent to which women have been excluded from formal wage employment and is notan <strong>in</strong>dicator of gender equality. Differences <strong>in</strong> poverty rates between employed women and employed men arecomplex and consistent patterns may be hard to identify. This is because the very fact that women have access17


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3to paid employment may mean that the households where they live are less likely to be poor. Nevertheless, thecomb<strong>in</strong>ation of a gender earn<strong>in</strong>gs gap and women’s marg<strong>in</strong>alization <strong>in</strong> more precarious forms of paid work oftenmeans that, on average, employment women have higher rates of poverty than employed men.Causes of <strong>Informality</strong>The causes of <strong>in</strong>formality <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> are complex but related broadly to some key factors prom<strong>in</strong>ent <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>neconomies of the last few decades: the lack of economic development and the deep-seat<strong>in</strong>g structuraladjustment that has characterized economic policy s<strong>in</strong>ce the 1970s.First, most of the <strong>Africa</strong>n cont<strong>in</strong>ent has experienced extremely low and patchy rates of economic growth.Employment creation, <strong>in</strong> this environment, has been very poor. At the same time, labour force participationrates, particularly among women, are often high, and for some countries large numbers of new entrants,aga<strong>in</strong> particularly women (see Casale and Posel 2004 <strong>in</strong> South <strong>Africa</strong>), have entered the labour market.Many of these workers, unable to f<strong>in</strong>d employment <strong>in</strong> the formal sector, have had to subsist on low <strong>in</strong>comesgenerated <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy. A number of studies <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> have highlighted the rapid <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong>levels of urbanization, which has contributed to a growth <strong>in</strong> the urban labour force. Many of these workersliv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> urban slum areas around the major cities earn their livelihoods <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy.Second, follow<strong>in</strong>g structural adjustment policies implemented <strong>in</strong> most <strong>Africa</strong>n countries, and these countries’<strong>in</strong>tegration <strong>in</strong>to the <strong>in</strong>ternational trad<strong>in</strong>g system, segments of the <strong>in</strong>digenous manufactur<strong>in</strong>g economy <strong>in</strong><strong>Africa</strong> have been underm<strong>in</strong>ed by cheaper imports. This is probably best illustrated by the decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> cloth<strong>in</strong>gmanufactur<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> many <strong>Africa</strong>n cities and by the rise <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal manufactur<strong>in</strong>g activity. Rogerson and McCormick(2004) provide a good overview of the cloth<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, and the rise of <strong>in</strong>formal manufactur<strong>in</strong>g activity.In addition, the deficit reduction and privatization components of structural adjustment programmes reducedpublic sector employment <strong>in</strong> government wage employment and <strong>in</strong> public enterprises. As we have seen, publicemployment is an important source of formal employment <strong>in</strong> most <strong>Africa</strong>n countries. Private sector employmentgrowth has not compensated for this loss of formal jobs, lead<strong>in</strong>g to higher rates of <strong>in</strong>formalization.Third, although there are significant differences from country to country, it would be safe to suggest that anot <strong>in</strong>considerable amount of <strong>in</strong>formal production <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>n countries is <strong>in</strong>formal production<strong>in</strong> agriculture. The reasons why women cont<strong>in</strong>ue to produce <strong>in</strong> this manner are multifaceted. Agriculturalproductivity has stagnated <strong>in</strong> many sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>n countries <strong>in</strong> recent decades. Lack of <strong>in</strong>vestment<strong>in</strong> basic <strong>in</strong>frastructure – <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g roads, transport, storage facilities, and susta<strong>in</strong>able irrigation systems – isprobably an important contribut<strong>in</strong>g factor.Fourth, and related, women cont<strong>in</strong>ue throughout <strong>Africa</strong> to be significantly disadvantaged <strong>in</strong> the labourmarket (and <strong>in</strong> other spheres of social and economic life). As our statistical overview has highlighted,women are concentrated <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy. For many women <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>, disadvantaged <strong>in</strong> theeducation system and discrim<strong>in</strong>ated aga<strong>in</strong>st <strong>in</strong> the formal economy, the <strong>in</strong>formal economy offers the onlyopportunity for <strong>in</strong>come generation.Fifth, <strong>in</strong>stitutional and legal barriers may make it costly for small-scale, <strong>in</strong>formal enterprises to formalize.Bus<strong>in</strong>ess licens<strong>in</strong>g and registration procedures often fail to cater to the realities of <strong>in</strong>formal self-employment.These processes may be overly complex and prohibitively expensive, leav<strong>in</strong>g own-account workers and othersmall-scale enterprise workers no option but to work <strong>in</strong>formally. Moreover, there is no <strong>in</strong>centive to formalizewhen public support for <strong>in</strong>formal workers, through policy <strong>in</strong>itiatives, service provision, and <strong>in</strong>frastructure<strong>in</strong>vestment, is underdeveloped or non-existent. Other critical sectors of the economy – commercial banks andthe formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial sector – may not extend credit to small enterprises, regardless of their <strong>in</strong>formality status.Aga<strong>in</strong>, when the costs of formalization exceed the benefits, workers <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal activities – whose earn<strong>in</strong>gsalready often fall below a basic poverty threshold – may f<strong>in</strong>d it impossible to operate formally.18


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3Sixth, <strong>in</strong> a number of <strong>Africa</strong>n countries, much of the population has had to earn their <strong>in</strong>comes <strong>in</strong> anenvironment characterized by high levels of violence. In some economies war has been endemic, leav<strong>in</strong>gbeh<strong>in</strong>d frayed social and economic relationships, ru<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong>frastructure, and fundamentally disruptedpossibilities for remunerative employment. This has had the impact of not only underm<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g economicactivity but has also displaced large numbers of <strong>Africa</strong>ns who, as political refugees, have had to earn theirlivelihoods <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy.One approach to expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formalization stresses the costs of formal regulations. Enterprises <strong>in</strong> the<strong>in</strong>formal sector choose to operate <strong>in</strong>formally because the costs of formalization so outweigh the benefits(e.g., Maloney 2004; Levenson and Maloney 1998; Loayza 1996; Sarte 2000; Ihrig and Moe 2001). Thecost-benefit approach has been used to expla<strong>in</strong> why <strong>in</strong>formalization is common among small-scale firmsor with<strong>in</strong> labour-<strong>in</strong>tensive activities. For small firms and the self-employed, the transaction costs of formalregulation are likely to exceed the benefits these firms derive from the legal system. However, as firms grow<strong>in</strong> size or become more capital-<strong>in</strong>tensive, the need to participate <strong>in</strong> social <strong>in</strong>stitutions that protect property,enforce contracts, provide access to low-cost credit, or pool risk expands. When the benefits of formalityoutweigh the costs, rates of <strong>in</strong>formalization can be expected to decl<strong>in</strong>e.The regulatory approach does generate useful <strong>in</strong>sights <strong>in</strong>to how a prevail<strong>in</strong>g regulatory environment can<strong>in</strong>fluence pressures toward <strong>in</strong>formalization. But this perspective overlooks some major facts about theconditions <strong>in</strong> which <strong>in</strong>formalization has been ris<strong>in</strong>g, particularly <strong>in</strong> context of structural adjustment reforms thathave embraced a strategy of market liberalization and deregulation. Despite pressures to reduce governmentregulations <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries over the past several decades – <strong>in</strong> the areas of labour markets specificallybut more generally as well – evidence suggests that <strong>in</strong>formalization has risen <strong>in</strong> many of these economies.This suggests that there are “push” and “pull” factors relat<strong>in</strong>g to patterns of <strong>in</strong>formality. The reformspursued under structural adjustment may have been, <strong>in</strong> many cases, detrimental to employment creation,caus<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g fraction of the population to rely on <strong>in</strong>formal activities (“push” factors). At the sametime, <strong>in</strong>stitutions frequently fail to encourage formalization – e.g., the cost of registration of small enterprisesand lack of benefits from do<strong>in</strong>g so – the “pull” factors, represent<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>centives to operat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formally. Itshould be noted that many of the analytical studies that emphasize only “pull” factors and that assume<strong>in</strong>formal employment is freely chosen focus on the more developed economies of Lat<strong>in</strong> America and Asia,and not sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>.Case Studies and Policy IssuesOur statistical overview and a number of more detailed micro-level studies of <strong>in</strong>formal activities <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>, for example by the ILO (2002), shows that services and <strong>in</strong> particular street vend<strong>in</strong>g isthe dom<strong>in</strong>ant <strong>in</strong>formal activity. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the ILO report, <strong>in</strong> Angola, Nigeria, South <strong>Africa</strong> and Uganda,almost half of workers <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector are <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> retail trade.Sk<strong>in</strong>ner (2008) provides an excellent review of <strong>in</strong>formal street trad<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>. Her review highlights thedom<strong>in</strong>ance of street trad<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal employment <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> and the high levels of growth <strong>in</strong> the numbersof <strong>in</strong>formal vendors. She argues that this growth is a result of a comb<strong>in</strong>ation of factors, especially economicdevelopment, urbanization and migration. With<strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>, cross border trade is a significantelement of <strong>in</strong>formal activities. South <strong>Africa</strong>, for example, attracts a substantial proportion of temporarymigrants who buy merchandise for resale <strong>in</strong> their home countries. Given the thriv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formal market <strong>in</strong>Zimbabwe, it is estimated that a fifth of women <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector <strong>in</strong> Zimbabwe are <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> crossborder trade. Women from Zimbabwe ma<strong>in</strong>ly purchase merchandise from South <strong>Africa</strong>, Botswana, Zambia,and to a limited extent from Hong Kong and Ch<strong>in</strong>a for resale back home. In West <strong>Africa</strong>, whilst the bulkof trade is <strong>in</strong> the region, traders equally travel as far as Dubai to “purchase high quality goods” that areotherwise unaffordable <strong>in</strong> their home countries (ILO 2002).19


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3Thus, the majority of the <strong>in</strong>formally self-employed <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong> are engaged <strong>in</strong> the provisionof services. This has important implications for how we th<strong>in</strong>k about policies to improve earn<strong>in</strong>gs andproductivity. Productivity <strong>in</strong> services is dist<strong>in</strong>ct from productivity <strong>in</strong> manufactur<strong>in</strong>g and other <strong>in</strong>dustrialactivities. Productivity <strong>in</strong> services, and by extension earn<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> service activities, is strongly <strong>in</strong>fluenced bythe level of demand and development of markets. For example, a street trader’s productivity will be largelydeterm<strong>in</strong>ed by the quantity of goods she sells with<strong>in</strong> a given time period. In manufactur<strong>in</strong>g, productivityis often thought of as a “supply-side” factor l<strong>in</strong>ked to the nature of production technology. In services, theboundary between the supply-side and demand-side is blurred <strong>in</strong> the determ<strong>in</strong>ation of overall productivity.In order to keep this policy discussion tractable, we focus here on economic policy that may facilitateproductivity growth <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>. Specifically, we focus on marketdevelopment, f<strong>in</strong>ance, and assets.Market DevelopmentFor the <strong>in</strong>formal self-employed and those work<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> very small enterprises, the domestic market isthe primary source of demand for goods and services. Therefore, barriers to market access and/or<strong>in</strong>sufficient local demand will limit the ability of these <strong>in</strong>dividuals to realize <strong>in</strong>come from their productiveefforts. As po<strong>in</strong>ted out earlier, <strong>in</strong>sufficient demand can limit productivity growth, particularly <strong>in</strong> serviceproduc<strong>in</strong>gactivities. Relax<strong>in</strong>g other constra<strong>in</strong>ts – e.g., improv<strong>in</strong>g access to productive assets – may havelimited impact when limited market access and <strong>in</strong>sufficient demand are significant obstacles.Empirical evidence underscores the importance of the domestic market for <strong>in</strong>formal activities <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>. For example, research has found that, <strong>in</strong> Ghana, <strong>in</strong>formal employment depends ondomestic demand <strong>in</strong> local markets (Barwa 1995). This is not surpris<strong>in</strong>g s<strong>in</strong>ce trad<strong>in</strong>g and serviceprovision account for most urban <strong>in</strong>formal employment. Similarly, survey evidence shows that less thanone per cent of all household enterprises <strong>in</strong> Kenya produce ma<strong>in</strong>ly for export (author’s calculationsbased on the Kenya Integrated Household Budget Survey). Domestic markets are of overwhelm<strong>in</strong>gimportance to very small-scale operators. As observed <strong>in</strong> the classic ILO (1973) report on Kenya,improv<strong>in</strong>g the quality of <strong>in</strong>formal employment requires a shift <strong>in</strong> the composition of demand growth fromformal activities, products, and services to <strong>in</strong>formal ones. This implies that the development of domesticmarkets and forg<strong>in</strong>g closer l<strong>in</strong>ks between <strong>in</strong>formal and formal activities is critical.There are a number of targeted <strong>in</strong>terventions that can <strong>in</strong>crease access to domestic markets. Forexample, improvement <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>frastructure and other forms of public <strong>in</strong>vestment are critical. Betterroads will <strong>in</strong>crease access to population centers where demand is more concentrated and will lowertransportation costs through efficiency ga<strong>in</strong>s. When small-scale producers can access marketsthemselves, their reliance on <strong>in</strong>termediaries can be reduced and their terms of trade can improve.Provision of public assets <strong>in</strong> urban areas can also help to create markets or enhance marketopportunities, often <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g relatively small costs.For example, the municipal government of Durban/eThekw<strong>in</strong>i – <strong>in</strong> cooperat<strong>in</strong>g with organizations of<strong>in</strong>formal sector workers – established buy-back centers <strong>in</strong> the city to purchase recyclable materials (e.g.,cardboard) from self-employed waste collectors. Prior to the establishment of the buy-back centers,waste collectors often had to rely on <strong>in</strong>termediaries for market access, which reduced their terms oftrade and the share of value-added they were able to realize. The establishment of such centers formarket<strong>in</strong>g recyclables allowed the self-employed to sell their services more directly to the companiesprocess<strong>in</strong>g the materials collected. In this way, a targeted, municipal-level <strong>in</strong>tervention was able to<strong>in</strong>crease market access and to create a type of market exchange that was not prevalent before. Thedevelopment of markets often exhibits economies of scale that reduce transactions costs. Operat<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>dividually, the <strong>in</strong>formal self-employed cannot take advantage of these potential benefits. However, byconsolidat<strong>in</strong>g the purchase and sale of recyclables by establish<strong>in</strong>g market<strong>in</strong>g centers, self-employed20


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3<strong>in</strong>dividuals can improve access to markets, raise productivity, and improve their earn<strong>in</strong>gs. Cooperationbetween municipal government bodies and organizations of the <strong>in</strong>formal self-employed was necessary torealize these collective benefits.Although we have emphasized that the development of the domestic market is critically important forworkers <strong>in</strong> very small-scale enterprises, there are specific examples where facilitat<strong>in</strong>g export l<strong>in</strong>kageshas been successful. In these cases, the <strong>in</strong>formal self-employed generally operate at the base of a globalsupply cha<strong>in</strong> (also called global commodity cha<strong>in</strong>s). Household and small-scale enterprises supply goodsto <strong>in</strong>termediaries who, <strong>in</strong> turn, supply the products to transnational bus<strong>in</strong>esses. There are numerousexamples of goods produced <strong>in</strong> this way: garments, sports equipment, and agricultural products. Thestructure of the supply cha<strong>in</strong> determ<strong>in</strong>es market access and the terms of trade for the self-employed.Because of the reliance on various <strong>in</strong>termediaries for access to the markets, terms of trade are oftenunfavourable for self-employed workers <strong>in</strong> these situations. This can reduce <strong>in</strong>centives for pursu<strong>in</strong>gproductivity improvements s<strong>in</strong>ce the ga<strong>in</strong>s of higher productivity may be captured elsewhere along thesupply cha<strong>in</strong>, where market power is more concentrated.There are numerous examples of <strong>in</strong>terventions to improve access to export markets on more favorableterms – often <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g NGOs that foster “fair trade” relationships. These <strong>in</strong>itiatives typically requirecoord<strong>in</strong>ation between the transnational corporation (ultimately sell<strong>in</strong>g to the consumer market), a “fairtrade” <strong>in</strong>termediary that helps to facilitate sourc<strong>in</strong>g arrangements, and organizations of producers. Bysecur<strong>in</strong>g market access and improv<strong>in</strong>g the terms of exchange, such programs raise earn<strong>in</strong>gs, encourageproductivity improvements, and may be a step towards upgrad<strong>in</strong>g activities so as to move <strong>in</strong>to highervalueadded production. However, it is important to keep <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>d that these export-oriented programsmust necessarily be targeted at specific niches of the <strong>in</strong>formal sector and are not a viable option for themajority of the <strong>in</strong>formal self-employed <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong> who rely on the domestic market.The F<strong>in</strong>ancial SectorThe lack of private assets, both f<strong>in</strong>ancial and productive, represents one of the key constra<strong>in</strong>ts fac<strong>in</strong>g the<strong>in</strong>formal self-employed. As already discussed, the need to acquire assets is often cited as one of the mostformidable barriers fac<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>formal self-employed. Moreover, the earn<strong>in</strong>gs and productivity of verysmall-scale enterprises improve when private productive assets <strong>in</strong>crease. Private sav<strong>in</strong>gs – <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g thesav<strong>in</strong>gs of family members and relatives – is the s<strong>in</strong>gle most important source of start-up f<strong>in</strong>ance used toestablish small-scale enterprises. Once aga<strong>in</strong> us<strong>in</strong>g data from Kenya and Madagascar to illustrate this fact,table 9 shows the source of start-up capital for enterprises operated by own-account workers and unpaidcontribut<strong>in</strong>g family members. Note that credit from f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions – formal, <strong>in</strong>formal, and microlend<strong>in</strong>g– is a relatively unimportant source of start-up capital for these enterprises. Credit from f<strong>in</strong>ancial<strong>in</strong>stitutions becomes somewhat more important as the enterprises <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> size. For example, <strong>in</strong> Kenya,5.8 per cent of enterprises with 1 to 4 employees raised their start-up capital from SACCOs and 1.3 percent raised the capital us<strong>in</strong>g commercial bank loans. Nevertheless, own-sav<strong>in</strong>gs still dom<strong>in</strong>ated as a sourceof <strong>in</strong>itial f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g.21


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3Table 9 Primary Source of Start-Up Capital for Enterprises Operated by Own-Account Workers andUnpaid Family MembersKenya 2005/6 Madagascar 2005Sav<strong>in</strong>gs 62.2% 77.3 %Family/relatives 20.7 6.7SACCO 1.8Microf<strong>in</strong>ance 0.5Commercial bank 0.5 0.1Other 14.8 15.4Source: Authors’ calculations.The importance of own-sav<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> provid<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>itial source of f<strong>in</strong>ance for these enterprises raises animportant problem. If sav<strong>in</strong>gs is the most important source of f<strong>in</strong>ance for these very small-scale enterprisesand poor households lack sufficient f<strong>in</strong>ancial resources, how can <strong>in</strong>dividuals successfully participate <strong>in</strong>these forms of employment? It is important to recognize that the sav<strong>in</strong>gs of poor households may be small,but often such sav<strong>in</strong>gs exist. The issue then becomes how to leverage small quantities of sav<strong>in</strong>gs to realizereal improvements <strong>in</strong> productivity and earn<strong>in</strong>gs. Informal sav<strong>in</strong>gs schemes <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong> often helpsolve this problem by allow<strong>in</strong>g groups of <strong>in</strong>dividuals to pool sav<strong>in</strong>gs. Pooled sav<strong>in</strong>gs then can be used tof<strong>in</strong>ance small-scale enterprises and <strong>in</strong>formal activities.F<strong>in</strong>ancial services and f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>termediation are often seen as the means through which sav<strong>in</strong>gs can bepooled and f<strong>in</strong>ancial resources allocated to where they are needed. Research suggests that access to creditcan be an important determ<strong>in</strong>ant of productivity. For example, <strong>in</strong> Ghana, a study of <strong>in</strong>formal enterprises <strong>in</strong>Cape Coast has shown that the availability of credit has a significant <strong>in</strong>fluence on the enterprise’s efficiencyand, therefore, its <strong>in</strong>come-generat<strong>in</strong>g potential (Bhas<strong>in</strong> and Akpalu 2001). But as we have seen, verysmall-scale enterprises are often cut off from such f<strong>in</strong>ancial services. Therefore, it is helpful to exam<strong>in</strong>e whythis may be the case and what could be done to alleviate the situation.In most <strong>Africa</strong>n countries, the developmental role of the f<strong>in</strong>ancial sector is circumscribed by limited accessto the appropriate type of f<strong>in</strong>ancial services that would encourage an expansion of productive activities.Barriers to credit and f<strong>in</strong>ancial markets are a particularly severe problem for smaller enterprises, thoseoperat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy, and agricultural activities. S<strong>in</strong>ce these activities account for the vastmajority of employment <strong>in</strong> the country, f<strong>in</strong>ancial constra<strong>in</strong>ts have a negative impact on efforts to improveemployment opportunities.Not only is access to credit limited, the cost of credit is typically high throughout <strong>Africa</strong>. Many factors arefrequently identified as contribut<strong>in</strong>g to the high cost of credit: large <strong>in</strong>terest rate spreads, poor <strong>in</strong>formationsystems, the asset portfolio of banks (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g reserves), and high transactions costs, <strong>in</strong> some casesl<strong>in</strong>ked to <strong>in</strong>adequate <strong>in</strong>formation. Banks rema<strong>in</strong> the dom<strong>in</strong>ant formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions <strong>in</strong> much of<strong>Africa</strong>. Therefore, we will focus primarily on the structure of the bank<strong>in</strong>g sector <strong>in</strong> this short discussion of<strong>in</strong>stitutional constra<strong>in</strong>ts. Interest rate spreads – that is, the difference between lend<strong>in</strong>g and deposit rates– tend to be high throughout much of <strong>Africa</strong>. The higher the spread, the higher the cost of credit for anygiven deposit rate. A high spread also may <strong>in</strong>dicate that deposit rates are unusually low. Low deposit ratesdiscourage sav<strong>in</strong>gs and limit the resources available to f<strong>in</strong>ance bank credit, particularly <strong>in</strong> the absence of ahighly developed f<strong>in</strong>ancial sector.22


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3Two factors are particularly important <strong>in</strong> expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the relatively large spreads <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n bank<strong>in</strong>g systems.First, the risk premium that borrowers must pay <strong>in</strong> formal credit markets is extremely high. This is due toperceptions, often <strong>in</strong>correct, that most creditors are high risk borrowers and not bankable (Atieno 2001).The reliance on perceptions is important s<strong>in</strong>ce many commercial bank<strong>in</strong>g sectors never developed thecapacity to collect <strong>in</strong>formation on the creditworth<strong>in</strong>ess of potential borrowers outside of their traditionalclientele (Kimuyu and Omiti 2000; Nissanke and Aryeetey 1998; Steele et al. 1997). Risk premiums aretherefore likely to be particularly high for small-scale and rural borrowers. This creates a situation <strong>in</strong> whichlenders often only extend credit with excessively high collateral requirements relative to the resources at theborrowers’ disposal (UNECA 2005).In recent years, there has been notable growth <strong>in</strong> the number of credit registries <strong>in</strong> certa<strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n countriesthat provide <strong>in</strong>formation on credit worth<strong>in</strong>ess to commercial lenders (Mylenko 2008). Although creditregistries have been used to assess the risk of consumer loans, these new credit report<strong>in</strong>g services oftendo not yet adequately cover other under-served segments of the population – particularly loans to supportthe productive activities of the <strong>in</strong>formal self-employed. The nature of very small scale <strong>in</strong>formal enterprises– e.g., they often lack formal accounts of their f<strong>in</strong>ancial activities – can constitute a barrier to establish<strong>in</strong>gtheir creditworth<strong>in</strong>ess us<strong>in</strong>g standard methods.A second contribut<strong>in</strong>g factor to the sizeable <strong>in</strong>terest rate spreads observed <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> is the fact that bank<strong>in</strong>gtends to be highly concentrated, with a few large banks dom<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g the sector. Under these conditions,banks have a degree of market power to raise lend<strong>in</strong>g rates and lower deposit rates.For small-scale and rural borrowers, transactions costs frequently raise the cost of credit from commercialbanks. A large number of small-scale loans are more costly to deal with than a few large ones. Becausemany commercial banks <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> have traditionally extended credit to the public sector or to f<strong>in</strong>ance<strong>in</strong>ternational trade, they may be <strong>in</strong>efficient <strong>in</strong> manag<strong>in</strong>g loans to small producers (Steele et al. 1997).Therefore, small-scale borrowers require more of the banks’ time and resources <strong>in</strong> terms of monitor<strong>in</strong>g.The high cost of bank credit is only one aspect of the credit problem. Often, potential borrowers have noaccess to credit even if they were will<strong>in</strong>g to borrow at the prevail<strong>in</strong>g market rate. That is, credit is rationed.One reason beh<strong>in</strong>d the low levels of credit to the private sector is that banks <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong> tendto hold large amounts of excess liquidity (Sacerdoti 2005; Mkandawire 1999; Steele et al. 1997). Banksfrequently prefer to hold low-risk assets with strong real returns rather than extend<strong>in</strong>g loans to borrowerswhom they perceive to be high-risk. Short-term government securities are often the asset of choicebecause returns are often high and such <strong>in</strong>vestments are virtually risk-free. Aga<strong>in</strong>, credit ration<strong>in</strong>g is likelyto be particularly severe for rural and small-scale borrowers for the same reasons that <strong>in</strong>terest rates areextremely high: lack of credit <strong>in</strong>formation systems and perceptions of risk.We have discussed, <strong>in</strong> some detail, the problems of the formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial sector. However, formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial<strong>in</strong>stitutions – and formal commercial banks – represent only a fraction of the f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions operat<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n countries. The limitations of the formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions, and the ration<strong>in</strong>g of f<strong>in</strong>ancialservices, have fueled <strong>in</strong>novation <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions. In many cases, <strong>in</strong>formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial<strong>in</strong>stitutions have already solved some of the problems associated with the formal sector although they faceconstra<strong>in</strong>ts of their own. Similarly, various micro-f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong>itiatives, often run as NGOs, have aimed to fillthe void <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ancial services for small-scale enterprises and the <strong>in</strong>formal self-employed <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan<strong>Africa</strong>. When strategiz<strong>in</strong>g about f<strong>in</strong>ancial reform, it is important to recognize the <strong>in</strong>stitutional diversity thatalready exists throughout <strong>Africa</strong>.Informal entrepreneurs and small-scale bus<strong>in</strong>esses that cannot access formal credit markets may rely on<strong>in</strong>formal sources of credit. Research suggests that, <strong>in</strong> some circumstances, <strong>in</strong>formal credit <strong>in</strong>stitutionshave dist<strong>in</strong>ct advantages vis-à-vis formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions. Informal credit <strong>in</strong>stitutions frequently havemore detailed knowledge of local conditions, their clients, and the communities <strong>in</strong> which they operate23


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3(Aryeetey and Udry 1997). They often face lower transactions costs when extend<strong>in</strong>g credit to underservedcommunities and regions. Moreover, research suggests that default rates among <strong>in</strong>formal borrowers areoften low relative to those of the commercial bank<strong>in</strong>g sector (Steele et al. 1997). Informal credit <strong>in</strong>stitutionsare able to extend credit to such credit-worthy borrowers when formal <strong>in</strong>stitutional fail to do so. In theserespects, <strong>in</strong>formal suppliers of credit have successfully relaxed some of the constra<strong>in</strong>ts that <strong>in</strong>hibit accessto formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial services for people work<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> small-scale enterprises or <strong>in</strong>formal self-employment.The historic development of bank<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> many <strong>Africa</strong>n countries partially expla<strong>in</strong>s the duality between formaland <strong>in</strong>formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions. As noted previously, lend<strong>in</strong>g to government and public enterprisesdom<strong>in</strong>ated the extension of credit <strong>in</strong> the country dur<strong>in</strong>g the decades follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dependence. Many banksnever had an <strong>in</strong>centive to develop the <strong>in</strong>stitutional capacity to collect <strong>in</strong>formation and monitor small-scaleprivate lenders (Kimuyu and Omiti 2000; Nissanke and Aryeetey 1998). Under these conditions, <strong>in</strong>formalf<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions helped to fill this gap.Informal and small-scale suppliers of credit face constra<strong>in</strong>ts of their own. Informal suppliers of creditare seldom <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>in</strong>to the bank<strong>in</strong>g system, limit<strong>in</strong>g the resources at their disposal. Formal credit<strong>in</strong>stitutions enjoy economies of scale and can mobilize large amounts of deposits for credit extension.Informal credit networks lack the resources and scale economies of formal banks. However, largecommercial banks currently cannot serve small-scale borrowers efficiently. By foster<strong>in</strong>g l<strong>in</strong>kages betweenformal and <strong>in</strong>formal credit <strong>in</strong>stitutions, more f<strong>in</strong>ancial resources could be made available to support theexpansion and improvement of <strong>in</strong>formal activities, with potentially large positive impacts on employmentoutcomes (Aryeetey 2003; Amoako-Tuffour 2002).However, there are numerous <strong>in</strong>stitutional barriers that could prevent the realization of mutually beneficialcoord<strong>in</strong>ation between formal and <strong>in</strong>formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions. As has already been po<strong>in</strong>ted out, thecommercial bank<strong>in</strong>g sector <strong>in</strong> many <strong>Africa</strong>n countries has few <strong>in</strong>centives to alter their current lend<strong>in</strong>gpractices and asset portfolios. These <strong>in</strong>centives would have to change to make such formal-<strong>in</strong>formall<strong>in</strong>kages viable. In addition, the lack of prudential regulations for <strong>in</strong>formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions may h<strong>in</strong>derthe ability to forge l<strong>in</strong>ks between formal and <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>in</strong>stitutions. Formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions may bereluctant to enter <strong>in</strong>to a relationship with <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>in</strong>stitutions if there are no safeguards <strong>in</strong> place to ensurestability <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial sector. An appropriate regulatory framework will need to be developed <strong>in</strong>order to <strong>in</strong>tegrate the activities of the two types of <strong>in</strong>stitutions. Therefore, reform of public policies govern<strong>in</strong>gthe f<strong>in</strong>ancial sector may be necessary before <strong>in</strong>formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions and other alternatives such asmicro-f<strong>in</strong>ance can be more fully <strong>in</strong>tegrated <strong>in</strong>to the formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial sector.Access to AssetsAccess to assets is a critically important determ<strong>in</strong>ant of earn<strong>in</strong>gs and productivity for the <strong>in</strong>formal selfemployed.A lack of productive assets represents a potential barrier to entry <strong>in</strong>to these activities. We haveemphasized the role of private assets. However, access to public assets or the services generated by such<strong>in</strong>vestments – for example, economic <strong>in</strong>frastructure and utility services – also affects private productivityand earn<strong>in</strong>gs. We have already touched on the role of public assets, such as transportation <strong>in</strong>frastructure,<strong>in</strong> improv<strong>in</strong>g market access. However, public assets can also enhance supply-side performance <strong>in</strong> additionto facilitat<strong>in</strong>g access to sufficient demand. It has been well-documented that access to basic electricityand water services can make a crucial difference <strong>in</strong> productivity levels <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong> (UNECA2005). Similarly, urban amenities that aim to support the livelihoods of traders by provid<strong>in</strong>g safe marketspaces with the necessary facilities can be effective <strong>in</strong> reduc<strong>in</strong>g risks and rais<strong>in</strong>g productivity for <strong>in</strong>dividualsengaged <strong>in</strong> these activities.Nevertheless, <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> public assets may not always serve the needs of the <strong>in</strong>formal self-employedand very small enterprises, and <strong>in</strong>frastructure priorities often reflect the demands of larger <strong>in</strong>dustrialproducers. Spatial <strong>in</strong>equalities <strong>in</strong> the distribution of public assets may be a problem if <strong>in</strong>frastructure24


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3rema<strong>in</strong>s underdeveloped <strong>in</strong> areas where <strong>in</strong>formal enterprises operate. Under these conditions, the <strong>in</strong>formalself-employed are further marg<strong>in</strong>alized, be<strong>in</strong>g asset-poor <strong>in</strong> terms of both private and public resources.Much has been written on the role of traditional <strong>in</strong>frastructure projects and the impact on privateproductivity. In many cases, similar relationships between public assets and private productivity apply tosmall-scale producers. For example, electrification programs that extend the power network to underservedhouseholds allow the adoption of productivity-enhanc<strong>in</strong>g equipment (e.g., sew<strong>in</strong>g mach<strong>in</strong>es). Here weillustrate this central po<strong>in</strong>t by focus<strong>in</strong>g on a particular category of public asset, one that often receivesless attention, but is particularly relevant for the urban self-employed <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formal enterprises <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> –public space <strong>in</strong> urban centers. Similar issues, but from a different perspective, are also discussed <strong>in</strong> theaccompany<strong>in</strong>g background paper on legal issues and challenges.The governance of urban space <strong>in</strong> general – and public space <strong>in</strong> particular – is central to the livelihoodstrategies of many of the <strong>in</strong>formal self-employed. Moreover, the issue will only become more important <strong>in</strong>the future given the rates of rural-to-urban migration and the projected growth rates of the urban population<strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>. The <strong>in</strong>formal self-employed need more space <strong>in</strong> order to operate their enterprises.However, because the majority of these workers are asset-poor, they lack private property rights over suchspace. In some cases, it is possible to operate the <strong>in</strong>formal bus<strong>in</strong>ess from a residential structure. Even then,the tenure rights of these households may be uncerta<strong>in</strong>. In other cases, the activities cannot be restricted toprivate homes. For example, street traders need to go to their markets – their markets may not come to them.To illustrate the importance of location and space, table 10 provides estimates of the distribution ofhousehold enterprises <strong>in</strong> Kenya by the location of operation (as reported by survey respondents).About a third of all <strong>in</strong>formal household enterprises <strong>in</strong> Kenya operate out of a residence. Therefore, thesupply of basic economic services to these homes and the state of urban <strong>in</strong>frastructure <strong>in</strong> poor areasis a potentially important determ<strong>in</strong>ant of productivity. Approximately 47 per cent of the <strong>in</strong>formal selfemployedwork <strong>in</strong> locations <strong>in</strong> which access to and use of space (other than residences) is likely to be asignificant issue – <strong>in</strong> local markets, along the roadside, <strong>in</strong> mobile activities, and <strong>in</strong> kiosks. The contrastwith formal enterprises is <strong>in</strong>structive – over a third of these activities are located <strong>in</strong> a shop or relativelypermanent establishment and an additional 14 per cent report “other locations” – many of which wereconsidered by the respondent to be permanent. Nevertheless, even for formal enterprises, the use ofurban space is likely to be a significant issue.Table 10 Location of Un<strong>in</strong>corporated Household Enterprises, Kenya 2005/6InformalFormalResidence 33.6% 14.5%Jua Kali Shack 1.7% 2.7%Local Market 21.2% 15.8%Shop/establishment 11.1% 35.4%Roadside 12.1% 9.5%Mobile 11.4% 5.8%Kiosk 2.3% 2.1%Other 5.8% 14.1%Undeclared/unknown 0.8% 0.0%Source: Kenya Integrated Household Budget Survey.Jua Kali (“hot sun”) typically refers to <strong>in</strong>formal manufactur<strong>in</strong>g activities and specific types of services (e.g., mechanics and repairshops). Informal enterprises are not registered with a government authority.25


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3Urban public space may be considered a type of public asset – although with specific properties. For example,access may not be entirely unrestricted or non-monitored, so some level of exclusion is possible. Moreover,urban spaces are only partly non-rival. That is, the use of urban public spaces by one <strong>in</strong>dividual doesnot necessarily preclude its use by others (e.g., mobile roadside retailers), but issues of congestion anddim<strong>in</strong>ish<strong>in</strong>g returns can become serious problems. One approach to address<strong>in</strong>g problems of congestion,<strong>in</strong>secure tenancy, and “tragedy of the commons” effects is to <strong>in</strong>crease the excludability of such space bydef<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g enforceable private property rights (de Soto 1989). In certa<strong>in</strong> cases, such an approach may beeffective – e.g., when the distribution of property rights is equitable and external benefits are m<strong>in</strong>imal ornon-existent.However, privatiz<strong>in</strong>g public space may be socially sub-optimal <strong>in</strong> the presence of positive externalities (e.g.,cluster effects that <strong>in</strong>crease aggregate demand and the development of markets), economies of scale (e.g.,when multiple uses of public space are possible without significantly rais<strong>in</strong>g costs/lower<strong>in</strong>g productivity ofother users), and concern over equity (if the poor are unable to secure access to privatized property rights).Nevertheless, as already discussed, urban space is unlikely to exhibit the characteristics of a “pure publicgood” s<strong>in</strong>ce there will be limits to the number of users who can benefit. Therefore, a viable regulatoryframework for the urban environment is needed, one that improves the security of access to public assetsamong the <strong>in</strong>formal self-employed. Some of the approaches to the management of urban spaces, adoptedby municipal governments <strong>in</strong> many <strong>Africa</strong>n countries, that aim to “clean up the streets” can be disastrousfor the livelihoods of the <strong>in</strong>formal self-employed <strong>in</strong> very small enterprises. The available research highlightssome examples of more <strong>in</strong>novative and facilitative urban spatial policies that take account of the role of the<strong>in</strong>formal self-employed <strong>in</strong> urban development.Nnkya (2006) discusses the 1992 Susta<strong>in</strong>able Dar es Salaam Project (SDP), which was a turn<strong>in</strong>g po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong>the city’s previous approach to urban spaces that sought to repress and restrict <strong>in</strong>formal trade. This project,<strong>in</strong> collabouration with United Nations agencies, identified <strong>in</strong>formal trad<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the city as an economicdevelopment issue. By the mid-1990s, as a direct consequence of the SDP, a Work<strong>in</strong>g Group on Manag<strong>in</strong>gInformal Micro-Trade was established. This group identified constra<strong>in</strong>ts street traders faced and madenumerous recommendations to city planners. One example of appropriate urban plann<strong>in</strong>g that arose outof the recommendations was the development of 24 types of steel shelves for street traders to displaytheir goods. This was a design solution that addressed concerns of the health authorities particularlywith food traders but also facilitated the clean<strong>in</strong>g of public space. Another consequence of the SDP wasthe Guidel<strong>in</strong>es for Petty Trade adopted by the City Commission <strong>in</strong> 1997, which set out the framework formanag<strong>in</strong>g street trade. Nnkya does, however, po<strong>in</strong>t out that there are implementation <strong>in</strong>consistencies – withmanagement be<strong>in</strong>g haphazard <strong>in</strong> parts – and that while some traders are <strong>in</strong>cluded, others, most notablywomen traders, are not. This was particularly the case <strong>in</strong> the more lucrative trad<strong>in</strong>g sites <strong>in</strong> the centre ofthe city. In comparison to many other cities <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n overall, he argues, Dar es Salaam has created anenabl<strong>in</strong>g environment for street traders.Another case that has been cited as a better practice <strong>in</strong> the management of street trad<strong>in</strong>g is Durban, South<strong>Africa</strong> (Sk<strong>in</strong>ner 2008):[a] particularly <strong>in</strong>novative approach has been adopted <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>ner-city district that conta<strong>in</strong>s the ma<strong>in</strong>transport node – the Warwick Junction. On an average day the area is estimated to accommodate460,000 commuters, and at least 5,000 street traders. In 1996 the city council launched anarea based urban renewal <strong>in</strong>itiative. In careful consultation with traders, trader <strong>in</strong>frastructure wasestablished. For example nearly 1,000 traditional medic<strong>in</strong>e traders were accommodated <strong>in</strong> a newmarket and corn-on-the-cob sellers and those cook<strong>in</strong>g and sell<strong>in</strong>g the Zulu delicacy, boiled cowsheads, were provided with tailor-made facilities. Through this, the Project piloted an economically<strong>in</strong>formed, sector by sector approach to support<strong>in</strong>g street traders. In parallel with <strong>in</strong>frastructuredevelopment there was a focus on improv<strong>in</strong>g management of the area. The area-based teamestablished a number of operations teams to deal with issues as diverse as curbside clean<strong>in</strong>g,26


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3ablution facilities, child-care facilities and pavement sleep<strong>in</strong>g. In 2001 the local authority <strong>in</strong> thecity – the eThekw<strong>in</strong>i Municipality – adopted an Informal Economy Policy. This policy acknowledgedthe <strong>in</strong>formal economy as an important component of the city’s economy and, draw<strong>in</strong>g on some ofthe lessons learned from the Warwick Junction Project, suggested a number of management andsupport <strong>in</strong>terventions.This was an attempt to standardize a progressive approach across the city. Like Dar es Salaam, theapproach developed suggests <strong>in</strong>clusive approaches to design, plann<strong>in</strong>g and management of public spacefor street traders are possible.ConclusionsAlthough there are significant gaps <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formation available on the <strong>in</strong>formal economy <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong> and there is significant diversity <strong>in</strong> the nature, form, and contribution of the <strong>in</strong>formaleconomy across countries, from the statistics that we have presented, we are able to draw a reliablepicture of the key trends. Our estimates show that formal employment represents a small fraction oftotal employment <strong>in</strong> most sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>n countries. Employment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy is animportant livelihood strategy <strong>in</strong> the cont<strong>in</strong>ent. Informal self-employment, particularly <strong>in</strong> services andagriculture is the dom<strong>in</strong>ant activity <strong>in</strong> many <strong>Africa</strong>n countries. Although there are variations acrosscountries, women tend, <strong>in</strong> relative terms, to be over-represented <strong>in</strong> these activities (largely becausethey are under-represented <strong>in</strong> formal employment).In terms of earn<strong>in</strong>gs, the estimates show that earn<strong>in</strong>gs are lower and risks much higher <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formalemployment. There is evidence of a gender earn<strong>in</strong>gs gap that persists across employmentarrangements – <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g forms of self-employment. That is, women earn less than men. The cases<strong>in</strong> which the gender earn<strong>in</strong>gs gap disappears as <strong>in</strong> formal wage employment <strong>in</strong> Kenya reflect theextent to which women have been excluded from formal wage employment and are not an <strong>in</strong>dicatorof gender equality. Differences <strong>in</strong> poverty rates between employed women and employed men arecomplex and consistent patterns may be hard to identify. This is because the very fact that womenhave access to paid employment may mean that the households where they live are less likely to bepoor. Nevertheless, the comb<strong>in</strong>ation of a gender earn<strong>in</strong>gs gap and women’s marg<strong>in</strong>alization <strong>in</strong> moreprecarious forms of paid work often means that, on average, employed women have higher rates ofpoverty than employed men.The causes of <strong>in</strong>formality <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong> are complex but related broadly to the lack of economicdevelopment and the structural adjustment programmes that many countries have undergone. Insome cases, war and political upheaval have contributed to the displacement of large sections of thepopulation who have migrated and now earn livelihoods <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy. There are also importantconsiderations related to women’s disadvantaged position <strong>in</strong> the formal labour market and to <strong>in</strong>stitutionaland legal barriers that discrim<strong>in</strong>ate aga<strong>in</strong>st very small enterprises.Our policy discussion has focused on identify<strong>in</strong>g appropriate economic strategies to facilitate supportfor <strong>in</strong>formal workers. We highlighted three issues: market development, f<strong>in</strong>ance, and access to assets.With respect to market development, we note that given the predom<strong>in</strong>ance of service and agriculture,the domestic markets are overwhelm<strong>in</strong>gly important for <strong>in</strong>formal workers. Improved <strong>in</strong>frastructure andthe provision of public assets are possible ways <strong>in</strong> which market opportunities could be significantlyenhanced. A lot of the literature on the <strong>in</strong>formal economy <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong> has focussed on issues of f<strong>in</strong>ance. Wehave highlighted the fact that the issues are often more complex than simple access to f<strong>in</strong>ance. In relationto assets, we have highlighted the need for appropriate urban policy and provided some examples ofsuccessful policy <strong>in</strong> this regard.27


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3ReferencesAmoaka-Tuffour, Joe. 2002. “Forg<strong>in</strong>g L<strong>in</strong>kages Between Formal and Informal F<strong>in</strong>ancial Sectors: Emerg<strong>in</strong>gPractices <strong>in</strong> Ghana.” The <strong>Africa</strong>n F<strong>in</strong>ance Journal. Vol. 4, Part I, 1-31.Aryeetey, Ernest. 2003. “Recent Developments <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n F<strong>in</strong>ancial Markets: Agenda for FurtherResearch.” Journal of <strong>Africa</strong>n Economies, 12, Supp 2, ii111-ii152.Aryeetey, Ernest and Christopher Udry. 1997. “The Characteristics of Informal F<strong>in</strong>ancial Markets <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>.” Journal of <strong>Africa</strong>n Economies, Vol. 8, No. 1, 161-203.Atieno, Rosemary. 2001. “Formal and Informal Institutions’ Lend<strong>in</strong>g Policies and Access to Credit by Small-Scale Enterprises <strong>in</strong> Kenya: An Empirical Assessment.” AERC Research Paper 111. Nairobi: <strong>Africa</strong>nEconomic Research Consortium.Barwa, S.D. 1995. “Structural Adjustment Programmes and the Urban Informal Sector <strong>in</strong> Ghana.” Issues<strong>in</strong> Development Discussion Paper 3. Geneva: International Labour Office.Bhas<strong>in</strong>, Vijay and Wisdom Akpaulu. 2001. “Impact of micro-f<strong>in</strong>ance on the efficiency of micro-enterprises<strong>in</strong> Cape Coast.” IFLIP Research Paper 01-5. Geneva: International Labour Organization.Casale, Daniela and Dorrit Posel. 2004. “The cont<strong>in</strong>ued fem<strong>in</strong>ization of the labour force <strong>in</strong> South <strong>Africa</strong>.”South <strong>Africa</strong>n Journal of Economics, Vol. 70, No. 1, 156-84.Charmes, Jacques. 2007. “Statistics on Informal Employment <strong>in</strong> the Arab region.” Background paper forthe ILO project Gender and Rights <strong>in</strong> the Informal Economies of Arab States.Chen, M., Vanek, J., Lund, F., He<strong>in</strong>tz, J., Jhabvala, R., and Bonner, C. 2005. Progress of the World’sWomen 2005: Women, Work, and Poverty. New York: UNIFEM.De Soto, Hernando. 1989. The Other Path: the Hidden Revolution <strong>in</strong> the Third World. New York: Harperand Row.Gerry, Chris. 1987. “Develop<strong>in</strong>g Economies and the Informal Sector <strong>in</strong> Historical Perspective.” The Annualsof the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 493 (September): 100-19.Günther, Isabel and Andrey Launov. 2006. Competitive and Segmented Informal Labour Markets.Discussion Paper No. 2349. Bonn: IZA (Forschungs<strong>in</strong>stitut zur Zukunft der Arbeit).Hart, Keith. 1973. “Informal <strong>in</strong>come opportunities and urban employment <strong>in</strong> Ghana.” Journal of Modern<strong>Africa</strong>n Studies. 11 (1): 61-89.He<strong>in</strong>tz, James and Dorrit Posel. 2008. “Revisit<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formal employment and segmentation <strong>in</strong> the South<strong>Africa</strong> labour market.” South <strong>Africa</strong>n Journal of Economics. 76(1): 26-44.Hussmanns, Ralf. 2004. “Statistical Def<strong>in</strong>ition of Informal Employment: Guidel<strong>in</strong>es Endorsed by the 17thInternational Conference of Labour Statisticians.” Paper prepared for the 7th Meet<strong>in</strong>g of the ExpertGroup on Informal Sector Statistics (Delhi Group). New Delhi, Feb. 2-4.Hussmanns, Ralf and Brigitte du Jeu. 2002. “ILO Compendium of Official Statistics on Employment <strong>in</strong> theInformal Sector.” STAT Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 2002 – No. 1. ILO Bureau of Statistics.ILO. 1973. Employment, Incomes and Equality: A Strategy for Increas<strong>in</strong>g Productive Employment <strong>in</strong> Kenya.Geneva: International Labour Office.ILO. 2002. Women and Men <strong>in</strong> the Informal Economy. Geneva: International Labour Office.Ihrig, Jane and Kar<strong>in</strong>e Moe. 2001. “Tax Policies and Informal Employment: The Asian Experience.” AsianEconomic Journal. 15(4), 369-83.Kaspos, Stephen. 2004. “Estimat<strong>in</strong>g Growth Requirements for Reduc<strong>in</strong>g Work<strong>in</strong>g Poverty: Can theWorld Halve Work<strong>in</strong>g Poverty by 2015?” Employment Strategy Papers. No. 2004/14. Geneva, ILO,Employment Strategy Department.Kimuyu, Peter and John Omiti. 2000. “Institutional Impediments to Access to Credit by Micro and Small ScaleEnterprises <strong>in</strong> Kenya.” Institute of Policy Analysis and Research Discussion Paper 26. Nairobi: IPAR.Levenson, Alec and William Maloney. 1998. “The Informal Sector, Firm Dynamics, and InstitutionalParticipation.” Policy Research Work<strong>in</strong>g paper # 1988. Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C: World Bank.Loayza, Norman. 1996. “The Economics of the Informal Sector: A Simple Model and Some EmpiricalEvidence from Lat<strong>in</strong> America.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 45, 129-62.Maloney, William. 2004. “<strong>Informality</strong> Revisited.” World Development, Vol. 32, No. 7, 1159-1178.28


<strong>WIEGO</strong> Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper N o 3Mkandawire, Thandika. 1999. “The Political Economy of F<strong>in</strong>ancial Reform <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>.” Journal ofInternational Development, 11, 321-42.Moser, Carol<strong>in</strong>e. 1977. “The Informal Sector or Petty Commodity Production: Autonomy or Dependence <strong>in</strong>Urban Development.” DPU Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper #3. London: University College.Mylenko, Nataliya. 2008. “Develop<strong>in</strong>g Credit Report<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>: Opportunities and Challenges.” Paperprepared for IMF Sem<strong>in</strong>ar on <strong>Africa</strong>n F<strong>in</strong>ance for the 21st Century, Tunis: March 4-5.Nissanke, Machiko and Aryeetey, Ernest. 1998. F<strong>in</strong>ancial Integration and Development: Liberalization andReform <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>. London and New York: Routledge.Nnkya, T. 2006. “An Enabl<strong>in</strong>g Framework? Governance and Street Trad<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Dar es Salaam, Tanzania.”In A. Brown (ed.), Contested Space: Street Trad<strong>in</strong>g, Public Space and Livelihoods <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Cities.Warwickshire: Intermediate Technology Publications.Quijano, A. 1974. “The Marg<strong>in</strong>al Pole of the Economy and the Marg<strong>in</strong>alised Labour Force.” Economy andSociety, Vol. 3, No. 4, 393-428.Rogerson, Chris and Dorothy McCormick (eds). 2004. Cloth<strong>in</strong>g and Footwear <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>n Industrialization.Pretoria: <strong>Africa</strong> Institute of South <strong>Africa</strong>.Sacerdoti, Emilio. 2005. “Access to Bank Credit <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan <strong>Africa</strong>: Key Issues and Reform Strategies.”IMF Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 166. New York: International Monetary Fund.Sarte, Pierre-Daniel. 2000. “<strong>Informality</strong> and Rent-Seek<strong>in</strong>g Bureaucracies <strong>in</strong> a Model of Long-Run Growth.”Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 46, No. 1, 173-97.Sk<strong>in</strong>ner, Carol<strong>in</strong>e. 2008. “Street Trade <strong>in</strong> <strong>Africa</strong>: A <strong>Review</strong>.” Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper # 51. Durban: School ofDevelopment Studies, University of KwaZulu-Natal.Steele, William, Ernest Aryeetey, Hemamala Hettige, Machiko Nissanke. 1997. “Informal F<strong>in</strong>ancial MarketsUnder Liberalization <strong>in</strong> Four <strong>Africa</strong>n Countries.” World Development, Vol. 25, No. 5, 817-30.UNECA. 2005. Economic Report on <strong>Africa</strong> 2005: Meet<strong>in</strong>g the Challenge of Unemployment and Poverty.Addis Ababa: UN Economic Commission for <strong>Africa</strong>.Valodia, Imraan. 2008. “Informal Employment, Labour Markets and Social Protection: Some considerationsbased on South <strong>Africa</strong>n estimates.” IDS Bullet<strong>in</strong>. 39 (2): 57-62.29


About <strong>WIEGO</strong>: Women <strong>in</strong> Informal Employment: Globaliz<strong>in</strong>gand Organiz<strong>in</strong>g is a global research-policy-actionnetwork that seeks to improve the status of the work<strong>in</strong>gpoor, especially women, <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy. <strong>WIEGO</strong>builds alliances with, and draws its membership from,three constituencies: membership-based organizationsof <strong>in</strong>formal workers, researchers and statisticians work<strong>in</strong>gon the <strong>in</strong>formal economy, and professionals from developmentagencies <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy.<strong>WIEGO</strong> pursues its objectives by help<strong>in</strong>g to build andstrengthen networks of <strong>in</strong>formal worker organizations;undertak<strong>in</strong>g policy analysis, statistical research and dataanalysis on the <strong>in</strong>formal economy; provid<strong>in</strong>g policy adviceand conven<strong>in</strong>g policy dialogues on the <strong>in</strong>formal economy;and document<strong>in</strong>g and dissem<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g good practice <strong>in</strong>support of the <strong>in</strong>formal workforce. For more <strong>in</strong>formationvisit: www.wiego.org.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!