11.07.2015 Views

Cournot Oligopoly and the Theory of Supermodular Games

Cournot Oligopoly and the Theory of Supermodular Games

Cournot Oligopoly and the Theory of Supermodular Games

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

120 RABAH AMIRHere, <strong>the</strong> upper bound on <strong>the</strong> possible values that Player i can get follows from<strong>the</strong> definition <strong>of</strong> pay<strong>of</strong>fs <strong>and</strong> Assumption A.3. It is also useful to define <strong>the</strong>closure <strong>of</strong> CM i under pointwise convergence:We are now ready forM i : {v: [0,+∞) → [0, +∞) such that 0 ≤ v ≤ u i (C i )1−δ i<strong>and</strong> v is nondecreasing}.PROPOSITION 1. The infinite-horizon game has a Nash equilibrium in stationarystrategies which are elements <strong>of</strong> LC M 1 × LCM 2 .It is convenient to break down <strong>the</strong> pro<strong>of</strong> <strong>of</strong> Proposition 1 into three distinctlemmas, labeled 1.1–1.3. We first define <strong>the</strong> associated best-response optimizationproblem.Suppose that Player II, say, uses a stationary strategy h ∈ LCM 2 . Then PlayerI’s value function for optimally responding to h (in <strong>the</strong> infinite-horizon game),to be denoted V h , is defined byV h (x) = sup E ∑ ∞t=0 δ 1u 1 (c 1 t )subject to x t+1 ∼ q(· |x t −c 1 t −h(x t )), t = 0, 1,...(3.2)with x 0 = x,where <strong>the</strong> expectation is over <strong>the</strong> unique probability measure induced by x, h<strong>and</strong> a stationary strategy by Player I (see Section 1), <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> supremum may betaken over <strong>the</strong> space <strong>of</strong> all stationary policies (see, e.g., Bertsekas <strong>and</strong> Shreve,1978, Stokey et al., 1989).LEMMA 1.1. In <strong>the</strong> optimization problem (3.2), assume that h ∈ LCM 2 .Then V h ∈ CM 1 <strong>and</strong> V h is <strong>the</strong> unique solution to <strong>the</strong> functional equation∫V h (x) = max{u 1 (c) + δ 1 V h (x ′ ) dF(x ′ | x −c−h(x)): c ∈ [0, K 1 (x)]}.(3.3)Pro<strong>of</strong>. Define <strong>the</strong> map T : CM 1 →CM 1 by∫T (v)(x) = sup{u 1 (c) + δ 1 v(x ′ ) dF(x ′ | x −c−h(x)): c ∈ [0, K 1 (x)]}.(3.4)First, we show that T indeed maps CM 1 into itself. To this end, we start by provingthat <strong>the</strong> suprem<strong>and</strong> in (3.4) is continuous in (c, x). Let c n → c <strong>and</strong> x n → x.Then, since h ∈ LCM 2 , x n − c n − h(x n ) → x − c − h(x). By Assumption A.2(see also (2.1)), we have F(· |x n −c n −h(x n )) → F(· |x−c−h(x)), <strong>and</strong>

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!