11.07.2015 Views

Doing Business in 2004 - Rapid Response - World Bank

Doing Business in 2004 - Rapid Response - World Bank

Doing Business in 2004 - Rapid Response - World Bank

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong>bus<strong>in</strong>ess<strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong>bus<strong>in</strong>ess<strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>iiiUnderstand<strong>in</strong>gRegulationA copublication of the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>,the International F<strong>in</strong>ance Corporation,and Oxford University Press


© <strong>2004</strong> The International <strong>Bank</strong> for Reconstruction and Development / The <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>1818 H Street NWWash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C. 20433Telephone 202-473-1000Internet www.worldbank.orgE-mail feedback@worldbank.orgAll rights reserved.1 2 3 4 05 04 03A copublication of the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> and Oxford University Press.The f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs, <strong>in</strong>terpretations, and conclusions expressed here are those of the author(s) and do not necessarilyreflect the views of the Board of Executive Directors of the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> or the governments they represent.The <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> cannot guarantee the accuracy of the data <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> this work. The boundaries, colors,denom<strong>in</strong>ations, and other <strong>in</strong>formation shown on any map <strong>in</strong> this work do not imply on the part of the <strong>World</strong><strong>Bank</strong> any judgment of the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries.Rights and PermissionsThe material <strong>in</strong> this work is copyrighted. No part of this work may be reproduced or transmitted <strong>in</strong> any form orby any means, electronic or mechanical, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g photocopy<strong>in</strong>g, record<strong>in</strong>g, or <strong>in</strong>clusion <strong>in</strong> any <strong>in</strong>formationstorage and retrieval system, without the prior written permission of the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>. The <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>encourages dissem<strong>in</strong>ation of its work and will normally grant permission promptly.For permission to photocopy or repr<strong>in</strong>t, please send a request with complete <strong>in</strong>formation to the CopyrightClearance Center, Inc., 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923, USA, telephone 978-750-8400, fax 978-750-4470, www.copyright.com.All other queries on rights and licenses, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g subsidiary rights, should be addressed to the Office of thePublisher, <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, 1818 H Street NW, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C. 20433, fax 202-522-2422, e-mailpubrights@worldbank.org.Additional copies of <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>: Understand<strong>in</strong>g Regulation may be purchased at http://publications.worldbank.org/ecommerce/catalog/product?item_id=1384804/.ISBN 0-8213-5341-1ISSN 1729–2638Library of Congress Catalog<strong>in</strong>g-<strong>in</strong>-Publication data has been applied for.


ContentsAcknowledgmentsPrefaceOverviewviiixivii1 Build<strong>in</strong>g New Indicators of<strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Regulation 1<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Methodology 2Other Indicators <strong>in</strong> a Crowded Field 7Notes 152 Start<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> 17How Easy Is <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Entry? 18Are Entry Regulations Good? Some, Yes—Many, No 22What to Reform? 24Notes 273 Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g Workers 29What Is Employment Regulation? 30Large Divergences <strong>in</strong> Practice 33What Are the Effects of Employment Regulation? 35What to Reform? 37Notes 384 Enforc<strong>in</strong>g Contracts 41Which Courts Are Socially Desirable? 46What Expla<strong>in</strong>s Differences <strong>in</strong> Court Efficiency? 48What to Reform? 49Notes 535 Gett<strong>in</strong>g Credit 55Shar<strong>in</strong>g Credit Information 56Legal Rights of Creditors 61Expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Patterns <strong>in</strong> Creditor Protections 64What Is the Impact on Credit Markets? 65What to Reform? 66Notes 696 Clos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> 71What Are the Goals of <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy? 72Effects of Good <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy Laws 78What to Reform? 79Notes 82v


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>7 The Practice of Regulation 83Regulation Varies Widely around the <strong>World</strong> 83Heavier Regulation Br<strong>in</strong>gs Bad Outcomes 87Rich Countries Regulate <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> aConsistent Manner 88What Do These F<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs Mean for Economic Theory? 90Pr<strong>in</strong>ciples of Good Regulation 92Notes 95References 97Data Notes 105<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Indicators 115Country Tables 133List of Contributors 179vi


Acknowledgments<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong> was prepared by a team led bySimeon Djankov. Caralee McLiesh co-manageddevelopment and production of the report. The workwas carried out under the general direction of MichaelKle<strong>in</strong>. Simeon Djankov coord<strong>in</strong>ated the work onstart<strong>in</strong>g a bus<strong>in</strong>ess and hir<strong>in</strong>g and fir<strong>in</strong>g workers.Caralee McLiesh led the work on gett<strong>in</strong>g f<strong>in</strong>ance.Tatiana Nenova designed and implemented the study onclos<strong>in</strong>g a bus<strong>in</strong>ess. Simeon Djankov and Stefka Slavovacoord<strong>in</strong>ated the work on enforc<strong>in</strong>g a contract. The teamalso comprised Ziad Azar, Geronimo Frigerio, JoannaKata-Blackman, and Lihong Wang and was assisted byBekhzod Abdurazzakov, Yanni Chen, Marcelo Lu, TotkaNaneva, and Tania Yancheva. Zai Fanai and GraceSorensen provided adm<strong>in</strong>istrative support.Andrei Shleifer co-authored the ma<strong>in</strong> backgroundstudies and provided valuable suggestions throughoutthe writ<strong>in</strong>g of the report. Florencio Lopez-de-Silanesand Rafael La Porta co-authored the backgroundstudies on start<strong>in</strong>g a bus<strong>in</strong>ess, hir<strong>in</strong>g and fir<strong>in</strong>gworkers, and enforc<strong>in</strong>g a contract. Oliver Hart coauthoredthe background study on clos<strong>in</strong>g a bus<strong>in</strong>ess.Bruce Ross-Larson edited the manuscript. NataliyaMylenko contributed to the research and chapter ongett<strong>in</strong>g credit. The survey of credit registries wasdeveloped <strong>in</strong> cooperation with the Credit Report<strong>in</strong>gSystems Project <strong>in</strong> the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, and the surveyon clos<strong>in</strong>g a bus<strong>in</strong>ess was developed with theassistance of Sel<strong>in</strong>da Melnik. Nicola Jentzsch andFredreich Schneider wrote background papers on theregulation of credit <strong>in</strong>formation and the <strong>in</strong>formaleconomy, respectively. Leszek Balcerowicz, Hernandode Soto, Bradford DeLong, and Andrei Shleifer contributedlectures on the scope of government.Preparation of the report was made possible by thecontributions of more than 2,000 judges, lawyers,accountants, credit registry representatives, bus<strong>in</strong>essconsultants, and government officials from aroundthe world. Many of the contributors are partners <strong>in</strong>Lex Mundi law firms or are members of the InternationalBar Association. Their names are listed <strong>in</strong>the Contributors’ section and their contact detailsare on the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> web site.Individual chapters were refereed by: ElizabethAdu, Asya Akhlaque, Gordon Betcherman, HarryBroadman, Gerard Byam, Gerard Caprio, AmandaCarlier, Jacquel<strong>in</strong>e Coolidge, Asli Demirguc-Kunt, JuliaDevl<strong>in</strong>, Michael Fuchs, Luke Haggarty, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, L<strong>in</strong>n Hammergren, Eric Haythorne, AartKraay, Peter Kyle, Katar<strong>in</strong>a Mathernova, RichardMessick, Margaret Miller, Claudio Montenegro, ReemaNayar, S. Ramachandran, Jan Rutkowski, StefanoScarpetta, Peer Ste<strong>in</strong>, Ahmet Soylemezoglu, AndrewStone, and Stoyan Tenev. A draft report was reviewedby David Dollar, Cheryl Gray, W. Paatii Ofosu-Amaah,Guy Pfeffermann, and Sanjay Pradhan. Axel Peuker,Neil Roger, and Suzanne Smith provided advice andcomments throughout the development of the report.Tercan Baysan, Najy Benhass<strong>in</strong>e, V<strong>in</strong>ay Bhargava,Harry Broadman, Gerard Caprio, Mierta Capaul,David Dollar, Qimiao Fan, Carol<strong>in</strong>e Freund, Alan Gelb,Indermit Gill, Frannie Leautier, Syed Mahmood,Andrei Michnev, John Page, Sanjay Pradhan,Mohammad Zia M. Qureshi, Stoyan Tenev, Corneliusvan der Meer, and Gerald West read the penultimatedraft and suggested changes. The onl<strong>in</strong>e service of the<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database is sponsored by the <strong>Rapid</strong><strong>Response</strong> Unit of the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> Group.vii


PrefaceviiiA vibrant private sector—with firms mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestments,creat<strong>in</strong>g jobs, and improv<strong>in</strong>g productivity—promotes growth and expands opportunities for poorpeople. To create one, governments around the worldhave implemented wide-rang<strong>in</strong>g reforms, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>gmacro-stabilization programs, price liberalization,privatization, and trade-barrier reductions. In manycountries, however, entrepreneurial activity rema<strong>in</strong>slimited, poverty high, and growth stagnant. Andother countries have spurned orthodox macroreforms and done well. How so?Although macro policies are unquestionablyimportant, there is a grow<strong>in</strong>g consensus that the qualityof bus<strong>in</strong>ess regulation and the <strong>in</strong>stitutions that enforceit are a major determ<strong>in</strong>ant of prosperity. Hong Kong(Ch<strong>in</strong>a)’s economic success, Botswana’s stellar growthperformance, and Hungary’s smooth transitionexperience have all been stimulated by a good regulatoryenvironment. But little research has measuredspecific aspects of regulation and analyzed theirimpact on economic outcomes such as productivity,<strong>in</strong>vestment, <strong>in</strong>formality, corruption, unemployment,and poverty. The lack of systematic knowledge preventspolicymakers from assess<strong>in</strong>g how good legal and regulatorysystems are and determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g what to reform.<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>: Understand<strong>in</strong>g Regulation isthe first <strong>in</strong> a series of annual reports <strong>in</strong>vestigat<strong>in</strong>g thescope and manner of regulations that enhancebus<strong>in</strong>ess activity and those that constra<strong>in</strong> it. Thepresent volume compares more than 130 countries—from Albania to Zimbabwe—on the basis of newquantitative <strong>in</strong>dicators of bus<strong>in</strong>ess regulations. The<strong>in</strong>dicators are used to analyze economic outcomes andidentify what reforms have worked, where, and why.What Is New?Many sources of data help expla<strong>in</strong> the bus<strong>in</strong>ess environment.More than a dozen organizations—such asFreedom House, the Heritage Foundation, and the<strong>World</strong> Economic Forum—produce and periodicallyupdate <strong>in</strong>dicators on country risk, economicfreedom, and <strong>in</strong>ternational competitiveness. Asgauges of general economic and policy conditions,these <strong>in</strong>dicators help identify broad priorities forreform. But few <strong>in</strong>dicators focus on the poorestcountries, and most of them are designed to <strong>in</strong>formforeign <strong>in</strong>vestors. Yet it is local firms, which areresponsible for most economic activity <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries, that could benefit the most from reforms.Moreover, many exist<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dicators rely on perceptions,notoriously difficult to compare acrosscountries or translate <strong>in</strong>to policy recommendations.Accord<strong>in</strong>g to one survey, Belarus and Uzbekistanrank ahead of France, Germany, and Sweden <strong>in</strong>firms’ satisfaction with the efficiency of government.Most important, no <strong>in</strong>dicators assess specific lawsand regulations regard<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity or thepublic <strong>in</strong>stitutions that enforce them. So these<strong>in</strong>dicators provide <strong>in</strong>sufficient detail to guidereform of the scope and efficiency of governmentregulation.The <strong>in</strong>dicators <strong>in</strong> the present volume represent anew approach to measurement. The focus is ondomestic, primarily smaller, companies. The analysisis based on assessments of laws and regulations, with<strong>in</strong>put from and verification by local experts who dealwith practical situations of the type covered <strong>in</strong> thereport.


PrefaceThis methodology offers several advantages. It isbased on factual <strong>in</strong>formation concern<strong>in</strong>g laws andregulations <strong>in</strong> force. It is transparent and easilyreplicable—allow<strong>in</strong>g broad country coverage, annualupdates, and ready extension to new locations. Itcovers regulatory outcomes, such as the time and costof meet<strong>in</strong>g regulatory requirements to register abus<strong>in</strong>ess, as well as measures of actual regulations,such as an <strong>in</strong>dex of the rigidity of employment law orthe procedures to enforce a contract. It also <strong>in</strong>vestigatesthe efficiency of government <strong>in</strong>stitutions,<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess registries, courts, and public creditregistries. Most important, the methodology buildson extensive and detailed <strong>in</strong>formation on regulations—<strong>in</strong>formationdirectly relevant to identify<strong>in</strong>gspecific problems and design<strong>in</strong>g reforms.The <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> series represents a collaborativeeffort. The <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> team works with lead<strong>in</strong>gscholars <strong>in</strong> the development of <strong>in</strong>dicators. This cooperationprovides academic rigor and l<strong>in</strong>ks theory topractice. For this year’s report, Professor AndreiShleifer (Harvard University) served as adviser on allprojects. Professor Oliver Hart (Harvard University)advised on the bankruptcy project, and ProfessorFlorencio Lopez-de-Silanes (International Institute ofCorporate Governance, Yale School of Management)and Professor Rafael La Porta (Dartmouth) advisedon the bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration, contract enforcement,and labor projects.Each project <strong>in</strong>volves a partnership with an associationof practitioners or an <strong>in</strong>ternational company.For example, the contract enforcement project wasconducted with Lex Mundi, the largest <strong>in</strong>ternationalassociation of private law firms. The project on creditmarket <strong>in</strong>stitutions benefited from collaboration withthe law firm of Baker and McKenzie, the InternationalBar Association Committee on International F<strong>in</strong>ancialLaw Reform, and Dun and Bradstreet. The bankruptcyproject was conducted with the help of the InsolvencyCommittee of the International Bar Association.The <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> project receives the <strong>in</strong>valuablecooperation of local partners—municipal officials,registrars, tax officers, labor lawyers and laborm<strong>in</strong>istry officials, credit registry managers, f<strong>in</strong>anciallawyers, <strong>in</strong>corporation lawyers <strong>in</strong> the case of bus<strong>in</strong>essstart-ups, bankruptcy lawyers, and judges. Only thosewith extensive professional knowledge andexperience provide data, and the <strong>in</strong>dicators build onlocal knowledge.Once the analysis is completed, the results aresubject to a peer-review process <strong>in</strong> lead<strong>in</strong>g academicjournals. Simultaneously, the background research ispresented at conferences and sem<strong>in</strong>ars organized withprivate-sector partners. For example, prelim<strong>in</strong>aryresults of the bankruptcy project were discussed withmembers of the International Bar Association at theassociation’s meet<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> Dubl<strong>in</strong> (Ireland), Durban(South Africa), Rome (Italy), and New York (UnitedStates). The data are posted on the web (http://rru.worldbank.org/do<strong>in</strong>gbus<strong>in</strong>ess), so anyone can checkand challenge their veracity. This cont<strong>in</strong>ual process ofref<strong>in</strong>ement produces <strong>in</strong>dicators that have been scrut<strong>in</strong>izedby the academic community, governmentofficials, and local professionals.What Does <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Aim to Achieve?Two years ago, the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> Group outl<strong>in</strong>ed a newstrategy for tapp<strong>in</strong>g private <strong>in</strong>itiative to reducepoverty. The <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> project aims to advancethe <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> Group’s private sector developmentagenda:• Motivat<strong>in</strong>g reforms through country benchmark<strong>in</strong>g.Around the world, <strong>in</strong>ternational and localbenchmark<strong>in</strong>g has proved to be a powerful forcefor mobiliz<strong>in</strong>g society to demand improved publicservices, enhanced political accountability, andbetter economic policy. Transparent scor<strong>in</strong>g onmacroeconomic and social <strong>in</strong>dicators has <strong>in</strong>tensifiedthe desire for change—witness the impact of thehuman development <strong>in</strong>dex, developed by theUnited Nations’ Development Programme, ongett<strong>in</strong>g countries to emphasize health andeducation <strong>in</strong> their development strategies. The<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> data provide reformers withcomparisons on a different dimension: theregulatory environment for bus<strong>in</strong>ess.• Inform<strong>in</strong>g the design of reforms. The data analyzed<strong>in</strong> <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> highlight specifically what needsix


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>xto be changed when reforms are designed, becausethe <strong>in</strong>dicators are backed by an extensivedescription of regulations. Reformers can alsobenefit from review<strong>in</strong>g the experience of countriesthat perform well accord<strong>in</strong>g to the <strong>in</strong>dicators.• Enrich<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>itiatives on developmenteffectiveness. Recogniz<strong>in</strong>g that aid works best <strong>in</strong> good<strong>in</strong>stitutional environments, <strong>in</strong>ternational donorsare mov<strong>in</strong>g toward more extensive monitor<strong>in</strong>g ofaid effectiveness and performance-based fund<strong>in</strong>g.The U.S. government’s Millennium ChallengeAccount and the International DevelopmentAssociation’s performance-based fund<strong>in</strong>g allocationsare two examples. It is essential that such efforts bebased on good-quality data that can be <strong>in</strong>fluenceddirectly by policy reform. This is exactly what<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong>dicators provide.• Inform<strong>in</strong>g theory. Regulatory economics is largelytheoretical. By produc<strong>in</strong>g new <strong>in</strong>dicators thatquantify various aspects of regulation, <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong><strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> facilitates tests of exist<strong>in</strong>g theories andcontributes to the empirical foundation for newtheoretical work on the relation between regulationand development.What to Expect NextThis report summarizes the results of the first year ofthe <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> project. The volume is only thefirst product of an ambitious study of the determ<strong>in</strong>antsof private sector development. About adozen topics <strong>in</strong> the bus<strong>in</strong>ess environment will bedeveloped over three years. This year, five topics areanalyzed. They cover the fundamental aspects of afirm’s life cycle: start<strong>in</strong>g a bus<strong>in</strong>ess, hir<strong>in</strong>g and fir<strong>in</strong>gworkers, enforc<strong>in</strong>g contracts, gett<strong>in</strong>g credit, and clos<strong>in</strong>ga bus<strong>in</strong>ess. Over the next two years, <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>will extend the coverage of topics. <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong>2005 will discuss three new topics—register<strong>in</strong>gproperty, deal<strong>in</strong>g with government licenses and<strong>in</strong>spections, and protect<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>vestors. <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong><strong>in</strong> 2006 will study three other topics: pay<strong>in</strong>g taxes,trad<strong>in</strong>g across borders, and improv<strong>in</strong>g law and order.The <strong>in</strong>dicators will be updated annually to providetime-series data on progress with reform. Currently the<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> project does not focus on the politicaleconomy of reform. As more data become available, theproject will <strong>in</strong>clude exploration of political economyissues and measurement of reform impact, as well asthe cross-section analysis that this report presents.The project will also create case studies of reform.It will document past experiences, the forces beh<strong>in</strong>dreform, and the features responsible for reforms’ultimate success or failure. This <strong>in</strong>formation will helppolicymakers design and manage reform.The impact of regulations is measured by theirrelationship to economic outcomes. Although dataon some outcomes such as <strong>in</strong>come growth andemployment are readily available, data on others arenot. The <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> project has begun to addressthis gap by support<strong>in</strong>g work on the size of the<strong>in</strong>formal bus<strong>in</strong>ess sector and the determ<strong>in</strong>ants ofentrepreneurship. In future years, other economicoutcome variables will be analyzed.The new data and analysis deepen our understand<strong>in</strong>gof productivity growth and the optimalscope for government <strong>in</strong> regulat<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity.Under the auspices of the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> project, Dr.Leszek Balcerowicz (National <strong>Bank</strong> of Poland),Professor Bradford DeLong (University of Californiaat Berkeley), Hernando de Soto (Institute of Libertyand Democracy <strong>in</strong> Lima, Peru), and Professor AndreiShleifer (Harvard University) have been <strong>in</strong>vited togive lectures on government regulation of bus<strong>in</strong>ess.In com<strong>in</strong>g years other outstand<strong>in</strong>g economic th<strong>in</strong>kerswill be <strong>in</strong>vited to give lectures on <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> topics.Updated <strong>in</strong>dicators and analysis of topics, as well asany revisions of or corrections to the pr<strong>in</strong>ted data, areavailable on the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Web site: http://rru.worldbank.org/do<strong>in</strong>gbus<strong>in</strong>ess.


OverviewTeuku, an entrepreneur <strong>in</strong> Jakarta, wants to open atextile factory. He has customers l<strong>in</strong>ed up, importedmach<strong>in</strong>ery, and a promis<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess plan. Teuku’sfirst encounter with the government is when register<strong>in</strong>ghis bus<strong>in</strong>ess. He gets the standard forms fromthe M<strong>in</strong>istry of Justice, and completes and notarizesthem. Teuku proves that he is a local resident anddoes not have a crim<strong>in</strong>al record. He obta<strong>in</strong>s a taxnumber, applies for a bus<strong>in</strong>ess license, and depositsthe m<strong>in</strong>imum capital (three times national <strong>in</strong>comeper capita) <strong>in</strong> the bank. He then publishes the articlesof association <strong>in</strong> the official gazette, pays a stamp fee,registers at the m<strong>in</strong>istry of justice, and waits 90 daysbefore fil<strong>in</strong>g for social security. One hundred sixtyeightdays after he commences the process, Teuku canlegally start operations. In the meantime, hiscustomers have contracted with another bus<strong>in</strong>ess.In Panama, another entrepreneur, Ina, registers herconstruction company <strong>in</strong> only 19 days. <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> isboom<strong>in</strong>g and Ina wants to hire someone for a twoyearappo<strong>in</strong>tment. But the employment law onlyallows fixed-term appo<strong>in</strong>tments for specific tasks,and even then requires a maximum term of one year.At the same time, one of her current workers oftenleaves early, with no excuse, and makes costlymistakes. To replace him, Ina needs to notify and getapproval from the union, and pay five months’severance pay. Ina rejects the more qualified applicantshe would like to hire and keeps the underperform<strong>in</strong>gworker on staff.Ali, a trader <strong>in</strong> the United Arab Emirates, can hireand fire with ease. But one of his customers refuses topay for equipment delivered three months earlier. Ittakes 27 procedures and more than 550 days to resolvethe payment dispute <strong>in</strong> court. Almost all proceduresmust be made <strong>in</strong> writ<strong>in</strong>g, and require extensive legaljustification and the use of lawyers. After thisexperience, Ali decides to deal only with customers heknows well.Timnit, a young entrepreneur <strong>in</strong> Ethiopia, wants toexpand her successful consult<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess by tak<strong>in</strong>g aloan. But she has no proof of good credit historybecause there are no credit <strong>in</strong>formation registries.Although her bus<strong>in</strong>ess has substantial assets <strong>in</strong>accounts receivable, laws restrict her bank from us<strong>in</strong>gthese as collateral. The bank knows it cannot recoverthe debt if Timnit defaults, because courts are <strong>in</strong>efficientand laws give creditors few powers. Credit isdenied. The bus<strong>in</strong>ess stays small.Hav<strong>in</strong>g registered, hired workers, enforcedcontracts, and obta<strong>in</strong>ed credit, Avik, a bus<strong>in</strong>essman <strong>in</strong>India, cannot make a profit and goes out of bus<strong>in</strong>ess.Faced with a 10-year-long process of go<strong>in</strong>g throughbankruptcy, Avik absconds, leav<strong>in</strong>g his workers, thebank, and the tax agency with noth<strong>in</strong>g.Does cumbersome bus<strong>in</strong>ess regulation matter? Yes,and particularly for poor people. In much of Africa,Lat<strong>in</strong> America, and the former Soviet Union, excessiveregulation stifles productive activity (figure 1). Andgovernment does not focus on what it should—def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and protect<strong>in</strong>g property rights. These arethe regions where growth stagnates, few new jobs arecreated, and poverty has risen. In Africa, poverty rateshave <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong> the last three decades, with morethan 40 percent of the population now liv<strong>in</strong>g on lessthan one dollar a day. Two decades of macroeconomicreform <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America have not slowedthe rise <strong>in</strong> poverty. And <strong>in</strong> most former Sovietxi


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>xiiFigure 1Cumbersome Regulation Is Associated with LowerProductivityLabor productivity, $1,000 per worker454035302520151050Less12 3 4MoreCountries ranked by procedures to start a bus<strong>in</strong>ess, quartilesSources: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database; <strong>World</strong> Development Indicators 2003.Figure 2Heavier Regulation Is Associated with Informality and CorruptionInformal economy, % <strong>in</strong>come per capitaHighCorruptionLowLow1 2 3 4 51 2 3 4 5Low High Less MoreCountries ranked by employment-law<strong>in</strong>dex, qu<strong>in</strong>tilesCountries ranked by procedures to registera bus<strong>in</strong>ess, qu<strong>in</strong>tilesNote: The correlations shown <strong>in</strong> these figures control for <strong>in</strong>come. Relationships are significant at the 1 percent level.HighSources: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database; Schneider 2002; Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi 2003.countries, poverty <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong> the decade prior tothe fall of communism, and even faster thereafter. In2003, the number of people earn<strong>in</strong>g less than adollar a day rema<strong>in</strong>s at 1.2 billion and the numberearn<strong>in</strong>g less than two dollars a day at 2.8 billion.“First, I would like to have work of any k<strong>in</strong>d,” saysan 18-year-old Ecuadorian. The quotation is fromVoices of the Poor, a <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> survey captur<strong>in</strong>g theperspectives of poor people around the world. Peopleknow how to escape poverty. What they need is tof<strong>in</strong>d a decent job. Studies us<strong>in</strong>g household surveydata confirm this—the vast majority of people whoescape from poverty do so by tak<strong>in</strong>g up new employmentopportunities.Not any job will lead out of poverty. If it weresimply a matter of creat<strong>in</strong>g jobs, hav<strong>in</strong>g the stateemploy everyone would do the trick. This has beentried <strong>in</strong> some parts of the world, notably <strong>in</strong> communistregimes. What is needed is to create productivejobs and new bus<strong>in</strong>esses that create wealth. Forthis, companies need to adjust to new market conditionsand seize opportunities for growth. But alltoo frequently this flexibility is taken away by cumbersomeregulation. Productive bus<strong>in</strong>esses thrivewhere government focuses on the def<strong>in</strong>ition andprotection of property rights. But where the governmentregulates every aspect of bus<strong>in</strong>ess activityheavily, bus<strong>in</strong>esses operate <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy.Regulatory <strong>in</strong>tervention isparticularly damag<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>countries where its enforcementis subject to abuseand corruption (figure 2).To document the regulationof bus<strong>in</strong>ess and <strong>in</strong>vestigatethe effect of regulationon such economic outcomesas productivity, unemployment,growth, poverty, and<strong>in</strong>formality, the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>team collected and analyzeddata on five topics—start<strong>in</strong>ga bus<strong>in</strong>ess, hir<strong>in</strong>g and fir<strong>in</strong>gworkers, enforc<strong>in</strong>g a contract,gett<strong>in</strong>g credit, andclos<strong>in</strong>g a bus<strong>in</strong>ess. The efficiency of the enforcement<strong>in</strong>stitutions—commercial registries; municipaloffices; tax, fire-and-safety, and labor <strong>in</strong>spectorates;credit and collateral registries; and courts—has alsobeen assessed.<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> starts by ask<strong>in</strong>g five questions. Arethere significant differences <strong>in</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess regulation acrosscountries? If so, what expla<strong>in</strong>s these differences?What types of regulation lead to improved economicand social outcomes? What are the most successful


Overviewregulatory models? And, more generally, what is thescope for government <strong>in</strong> facilitat<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity?As the coverage of topics expands <strong>in</strong> future editions of<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>, these questions will be furtherexplored. The analysis <strong>in</strong> this year’s report yieldssome prelim<strong>in</strong>ary answers.Poor Countries Regulate <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> the MostIt takes 2 days to start a bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong> Australia, but 203days <strong>in</strong> Haiti and 215 days <strong>in</strong> the DemocraticRepublic of Congo. There are no monetary costs tostart a new bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong> Denmark, but it costs morethan 5 times <strong>in</strong>come per capita <strong>in</strong> Cambodia and over13 times <strong>in</strong> Sierra Leone. Hong Kong (Ch<strong>in</strong>a),S<strong>in</strong>gapore, Thailand, and more than three dozenother economies require no m<strong>in</strong>imum capital fromstart-ups. In contrast, <strong>in</strong> Syria the capital requirementis equivalent to 56 times <strong>in</strong>come per capita, <strong>in</strong>Ethiopia and Yemen, 17 times, <strong>in</strong> Mali, 6 times.<strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>es <strong>in</strong> the Czech Republic and Denmark canhire workers on part-time or fixed-term contracts forany job, without specify<strong>in</strong>g maximum duration ofthe contract. Part-time work, exempt from someregulations, is less costly toterm<strong>in</strong>ate than full-timeemployment. In contrast,employment laws <strong>in</strong> ElSalvador allow fixed-termcontracts only for specificjobs, and set their duration tobe at most one year. Part-timeworkers receive the benefits offull-time workers, and aresubject to the same regulationon procedures for dismissal.A simple commercialcontract is enforced <strong>in</strong> 7 days<strong>in</strong> Tunisia and 39 days <strong>in</strong> theNetherlands, but takes almost1,500 days <strong>in</strong> Guatemala. Thecost of enforcement is lessthan 1 percent of the disputedamount <strong>in</strong> Austria, Canada,and the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom,Figure 3Poor Countries Regulate <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> the MostMoreregulationLessregulation661130Low-<strong>in</strong>come53but more than 100 percent <strong>in</strong> Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso, theDom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic, Indonesia, the Kyrgyz Republic,Madagascar, Malawi, and the Philipp<strong>in</strong>es.Credit bureaus conta<strong>in</strong> credit histories on almostevery adult <strong>in</strong> New Zealand, Norway, and the UnitedStates. But the credit registries <strong>in</strong> Cameroon, Ghana,Pakistan, Nigeria, and Serbia and Montenegro havecredit histories for less than 1 percent of adults. In theUnited K<strong>in</strong>gdom, laws on collateral and bankruptcygive creditors strong powers to recover their money ifa debtor defaults. In Colombia, the Republic ofCongo, Mexico, Oman, and Tunisia, a creditor has nosuch rights.It takes less than six months to go throughbankruptcy proceed<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> Ireland and Japan, butmore than 10 years <strong>in</strong> Brazil and India. It costs lessthan 1 percent of the value of the estate to resolve<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong> F<strong>in</strong>land, the Netherlands, Norway, andS<strong>in</strong>gapore—and nearly half the estate value <strong>in</strong> Chad,Panama, Macedonia, Venezuela, Serbia and Montenegro,and Sierra Leone.Regulation <strong>in</strong> poor countries is more cumbersome<strong>in</strong> all aspects of bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity (figure 3). Across allfive sets of <strong>in</strong>dicators, Bolivia, Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso, Chad,High-<strong>in</strong>comeNote: The <strong>in</strong>dicators for high-<strong>in</strong>come countries are used as benchmarks. The average value of the <strong>in</strong>dicator is shownabove each column.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.6312275556 102753Lower-middle<strong>in</strong>comeUpper-middle<strong>in</strong>comeCourt-powers-<strong>in</strong>bankruptcy<strong>in</strong>dexEntry proceduresContract proceduresEmployment-laws <strong>in</strong>dex437 18 43xiii


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>xivCosta Rica, Guatemala, Mali, Mozambique, Paraguay,the Philipp<strong>in</strong>es, and Venezuela regulate the most.Australia, Canada, Denmark, Hong Kong (Ch<strong>in</strong>a),Jamaica, the Netherlands, New Zealand, S<strong>in</strong>gapore,Sweden, and the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom regulate the least.There are exceptions. Among the least regulatedeconomies, Jamaica has aggressively adopted bestpracticeregulation over the last two decades.Contract enforcement, for example, has beenimproved <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the latest reforms <strong>in</strong> the UnitedK<strong>in</strong>gdom, and bankruptcy law has been revisedfollow<strong>in</strong>g the Australian reforms of 1992.Another important variable <strong>in</strong> expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g differentlevels of regulatory <strong>in</strong>tervention is legal orig<strong>in</strong>.Together, <strong>in</strong>come and legal orig<strong>in</strong> account for morethan 60 percent of the variation <strong>in</strong> regulation. Whilecountry wealth has long been recognized as adeterm<strong>in</strong>ant of the quality of <strong>in</strong>stitutions (forexample, <strong>in</strong> the writ<strong>in</strong>gs of Nobel laureate DouglassNorth), the importance of legal orig<strong>in</strong> has onlyrecently been <strong>in</strong>vestigated. The regulatory regimes ofmost develop<strong>in</strong>g countries are not <strong>in</strong>digenous—theyare shaped by their colonial heritage. When theEnglish, French, Spaniards, Dutch, Germans, andPortuguese colonized much of the world, theybrought with them their laws and <strong>in</strong>stitutions. After<strong>in</strong>dependence, many countries revised legislation,but <strong>in</strong> only a few cases have they strayed far from theorig<strong>in</strong>al. These channels of transplantation br<strong>in</strong>gabout systematic variations <strong>in</strong> regulation that are nota consequence of either domestic political choice orthe pressures toward regulatory efficiency. Commonlaw countries regulate the least. Countries <strong>in</strong> theFrench civil law tradition the most.However, heritage is not dest<strong>in</strong>y. Tunisia, forexample, is among the least regulated and mostefficient countries <strong>in</strong> the area of contract enforcement.Uruguay is among the least regulated economies <strong>in</strong> thehir<strong>in</strong>g and fir<strong>in</strong>g of workers. In contrast, Sierra Leone,a common law country, heavily regulates bus<strong>in</strong>essentry. India, another common law country, has one ofthe more regulated labor markets and most <strong>in</strong>efficient<strong>in</strong>solvency systems.Heavier Regulation Br<strong>in</strong>gs Bad OutcomesHeavier regulation is generally associated with more<strong>in</strong>efficiency <strong>in</strong> public <strong>in</strong>stitutions— longer delays andhigher cost (figure 4)—and more unemployedpeople, corruption, less productivity and <strong>in</strong>vestment,but not with better quality of private or public goods.The countries that regulate the most—poorFigure 4More Regulation Is Associated with Higher Costs and DelaysCost, % <strong>in</strong>come per capita160120Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency, years3.5803.04004 or less5 to 67 to 89 to 1011 to 1314 to 16Number of procedures to start a bus<strong>in</strong>ess16 or more2.5Score 0 Score 33 Score 67 Score 100LessMoreCourt-powers <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>solvencyNote: The correlations shown <strong>in</strong> these figures are significant at the 10 percent level.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.


OverviewFigure 5More Rigid Employment Regulation Is Associatedwith Higher Female UnemploymentFemale unemployment, %40353025201510500 20 40 60 80 100Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dexNote: The correlation shown <strong>in</strong> this figure rema<strong>in</strong>s statistically significant whencontroll<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>in</strong>come.Sources: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database; <strong>World</strong> Development Indicators 2003.countries—have the least enforcement capacity andthe fewest checks and balances <strong>in</strong> government toensure that regulatory discretion is not used to abusebus<strong>in</strong>esses and extract bribes.Excessive regulation has a perverse effect on the verypeople it is meant to protect. The rich and connectedmay be able to avoid cumbersome rules, or even beprotected by them. Others are the hardest hit. Forexample, rigid employment laws are associatedespecially strongly with fewer job opportunities forwomen (figure 5). And fewer regulatory restrictions onshar<strong>in</strong>g credit <strong>in</strong>formation benefits small firms’ accessto f<strong>in</strong>ance the most. Heavy regulation also encouragesentrepreneurs to operate <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy. InBolivia, one of the most heavily regulated economies <strong>in</strong>the world, an estimated 82 percent of bus<strong>in</strong>ess activitytakes place <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector. There, workers enjoyno social benefits and cannot use pension plans andschool funds for their children. <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>es do not paytaxes, reduc<strong>in</strong>g the resources for the delivery of basic<strong>in</strong>frastructure. There is no quality control for products.And entrepreneurs, fearful of <strong>in</strong>spectors and the police,keep operations below efficient production size.Critics argue that <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries regulationis rarely enforced and plays no role <strong>in</strong> theconduct of everyday bus<strong>in</strong>ess. Our analysis suggestsotherwise. And if it is the case that regulation isirrelevant <strong>in</strong> poor countries, why not just remove it? Adoctor can be hired <strong>in</strong> place of every governmentofficial regulat<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity or compliance withemployment laws. A textbook can be pr<strong>in</strong>ted <strong>in</strong> placeof every batch of paperwork required for this or thatlicense for runn<strong>in</strong>g a bus<strong>in</strong>ess.Good regulation does not mean zero regulation. Inall countries, the government is <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> variousaspects of control of bus<strong>in</strong>ess. The optimal level ofregulation is not none, but may be less than what iscurrently found <strong>in</strong> most countries, and especiallypoor ones. For bus<strong>in</strong>ess entry, two procedures—register<strong>in</strong>g for statistical purposes, and for tax andsocial security—are necessary to fulfill the socialfunctions of the process. Australia limits entry proceduresto these two. Sweden has three, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g registrationwith the labor office. New Zealand, the leastregulated economy <strong>in</strong> the world, has 19 procedures toenforce a contract. For employment regulation,Denmark regulates the work week to 37 hours, thepremium for overtime pay to 50 percent, the m<strong>in</strong>imumannual paid leave to 27 days, and the severance pay ofa worker with 20 or more years of experience to 10months’ wages. It also regulates other aspects ofhir<strong>in</strong>g and fir<strong>in</strong>g, and the conditions of employment.No one th<strong>in</strong>ks that Danish workers are discrim<strong>in</strong>atedaga<strong>in</strong>st. Yet Denmark is among the countries with themost flexible employment regulation. The Danishexample is also an illustration of the differencebetween rigidity of regulation and social protection.Cumbersome regulation is often an <strong>in</strong>appropriatetool for protect<strong>in</strong>g weak groups <strong>in</strong> society.Instead of spend<strong>in</strong>g resources on more regulation,governments are better off def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the propertyrights of their citizens and protect<strong>in</strong>g them aga<strong>in</strong>st<strong>in</strong>jury from other citizens and from the state. In <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong><strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>, two examples of such rights are creditorrights—the legal rights of lenders to recover their<strong>in</strong>vestment if the borrower defaults—and theefficiency of enforc<strong>in</strong>g property rights through thecourts. Countries that protect such rights—richxv


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>xvicountries like New Zealand and the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom,and poor countries like Botswana, Thailand, andSouth Africa—achieve better economic and socialoutcomes. In credit markets, assur<strong>in</strong>g lenders of fairreturns on <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong>creases the depth of creditmarkets and the productivity of <strong>in</strong>vestment, even aftercontroll<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>in</strong>come, <strong>in</strong>come growth, <strong>in</strong>flation, andcontract enforcement. Such assurance also <strong>in</strong>creasesaccess to these markets, s<strong>in</strong>ce lenders are will<strong>in</strong>g toextend credit beyond large and connected firms if theyknow that their rights to recover loans are secure.One Size Can Fit All—<strong>in</strong> the Manner of <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>RegulationMany times what works <strong>in</strong> developed countries workswell <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, too, defy<strong>in</strong>g the oftenusedsay<strong>in</strong>g, “one size doesn’t fit all.” In entry regulations,reduc<strong>in</strong>g the number of procedures to onlythose truly necessary—statistical registration, and taxand social security registration—and us<strong>in</strong>g the latesttechnology to make the registration process electronic,have produced excellent results <strong>in</strong> Canada andS<strong>in</strong>gapore, Latvia and Mexico—but also <strong>in</strong> Honduras,Vietnam, Moldova, and Pakistan. Similarly, design<strong>in</strong>gcredit <strong>in</strong>formation registries has democratized creditmarkets <strong>in</strong> Belgium and Taiwan (Ch<strong>in</strong>a), but also <strong>in</strong>Mozambique, Namibia, Nepal, Nicaragua, and Poland.Countries like Australia, Denmark, the Netherlands,and Sweden present best practices <strong>in</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess regulation,mean<strong>in</strong>g regulation that fulfills the task ofessential controls of bus<strong>in</strong>ess without impos<strong>in</strong>g anunnecessary burden. In these countries, high levels ofhuman capital <strong>in</strong> the public adm<strong>in</strong>istration, and theuse of modern technology, m<strong>in</strong>imize the regulatoryburden on bus<strong>in</strong>esses. And where private markets arefunction<strong>in</strong>g, competition is a substitute for regulation.By comb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g simple regulation with good def<strong>in</strong>itionand protection of property rights, they achieve whatmany others strive to do: hav<strong>in</strong>g government regulatorsserve as public servants, not public masters.Aside from how much and what they regulate,good practice countries share common elements <strong>in</strong>how they regulate. For example, countries with theleast time to register a bus<strong>in</strong>ess, such as Canada, haves<strong>in</strong>gle registration forms accessible over the Internet.Countries that take the least time to enforce a collateralagreement, Germany, Thailand, and the UnitedStates, for example, allow out-of-court enforcement.The design of regulation determ<strong>in</strong>es the efficiency ofeconomic and social outcomes.Good practice is not limited to rich countries orcountries where comprehensive regulatory reform hastaken place. In many <strong>in</strong>stances, reform <strong>in</strong> some areasof bus<strong>in</strong>ess regulation has been successful. Tunisia hasone of the best contract enforcement systems <strong>in</strong> theworld. Latvia is among the most efficient countries <strong>in</strong>entry regulation. In 2002, Pakistan electronicallyconnected all tax offices <strong>in</strong> the country, and streaml<strong>in</strong>edbus<strong>in</strong>ess registration. As a result, the time to start abus<strong>in</strong>ess was reduced from 53 to 22 days. The SlovakRepublic recently implemented best-practice laws oncollateral. Vietnam revised its Enterprise Law <strong>in</strong> 1999to enhance growth <strong>in</strong> private bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity.Such partial reforms may lead to a virtuous cyclewhere the success of one reform emboldens policymakersto pursue further reforms. The Russian Federationsimplified bus<strong>in</strong>ess entry <strong>in</strong> the past year,reduc<strong>in</strong>g the number of procedures from 19 to 12, andthe associated time from 51 days to 29 days (figure 6).The reforms led to the creation of a large number of newprivate bus<strong>in</strong>esses, which <strong>in</strong> turn became the constituencyfor improvements <strong>in</strong> other regulatorypractices. Employment law has s<strong>in</strong>ce been revised,result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> more flexibility <strong>in</strong> hir<strong>in</strong>g and fir<strong>in</strong>g workers.But reform options are not always the same acrossrich and poor countries. There are cases where goodpractices <strong>in</strong> developed countries are difficult totransplant to poor countries. <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy is oneexample where the establishment of a sophisticatedbankruptcy regime <strong>in</strong> a develop<strong>in</strong>g country generallyresults <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>efficiency and even corruption. Bothlenders and bus<strong>in</strong>esses suffer. In such <strong>in</strong>stances,develop<strong>in</strong>g countries could simplify the models used<strong>in</strong> rich countries to make them workable with lesscapacity and fewer resources. In the poorest countries,it is better not to develop a sophisticated bankruptcysystem and to rely <strong>in</strong>stead on exist<strong>in</strong>g contractenforcementmechanisms or negotiations betweenprivate parties. Similarly, specialized commercial courts


OverviewFigure 6Start<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> Russia, before and after ReformsCostPercentage of <strong>in</strong>come per capita20026 4ProceduresTimeDays8 2 0 0 10 20 30 40 50Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.1. Check name for uniqueness2. Obta<strong>in</strong> proof of funds3. Pay registration fee and duty4. Obta<strong>in</strong> approval of draft seal5. Obta<strong>in</strong> certificatefrom local registration chamber6. Prepare seal, obta<strong>in</strong>declaration of seal preparation7. Notarize bank card8. Register with StateCommittee on Statistics9. Register withtax <strong>in</strong>spectorate10. Register with medical fund11. Register withsocial <strong>in</strong>surance12. Register with pension fund13. Open companybank account14. Obta<strong>in</strong> tax ID15. Obta<strong>in</strong> registrationcertificate16. File with pension fund17. File with medical fund18. File with statistics committee19. File with social security fund2003Procedures1. Check name for uniqueness2. Obta<strong>in</strong> proof of funds3. Register with State TaxInspectorate4. Register with StateCommittee on Statistics5. Obta<strong>in</strong> approval of draft seal6. Register seal with localregistration chamber7. Register with pension fund8. Register with social <strong>in</strong>surance9. Register with medical fund10. Open companybank account11. Notarize bank card12. Obta<strong>in</strong> tax IDwork best <strong>in</strong> countries withmore resources and adm<strong>in</strong>istrativecapacity. Poor countriescan implement reformswith the same pr<strong>in</strong>ciple—specialization—but with specializedjudges or specializedsections with<strong>in</strong> general jurisdictioncourts.Reform PracticeRegulatory reform has beencont<strong>in</strong>uous <strong>in</strong> most developedcountries, improv<strong>in</strong>gthe environment for do<strong>in</strong>gbus<strong>in</strong>ess.• Australia has built <strong>in</strong> regulatoryreform by <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g“sunset” provisions <strong>in</strong> newregulations, with theregulation automaticallyexpir<strong>in</strong>g after a certa<strong>in</strong>period unless renewed byParliament. Also, theOffice of Regulation Reviewvets each proposed regulationus<strong>in</strong>g a “m<strong>in</strong>imumnecessary regulation” pr<strong>in</strong>ciple.In 1996, the officewas charged with cutt<strong>in</strong>gthe regulatory burden onsmall bus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>in</strong> half,with annual reviews ofprogress achieved.• Denmark revised itsbus<strong>in</strong>ess entry regulation<strong>in</strong> 1996 by remov<strong>in</strong>gseveral procedures, mak<strong>in</strong>gthe process electronic,and elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g all fees.S<strong>in</strong>ce then, a cost-benefitanalysis of proposed newregulation is conducted,xvii


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>xviiiresult<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> two of every five proposed regulationsbe<strong>in</strong>g shelved.• In the Netherlands, much of the work on reduc<strong>in</strong>gadm<strong>in</strong>istrative costs is done by an <strong>in</strong>dependentagency, ACTAL (Advisory Committee on the Test<strong>in</strong>gof Adm<strong>in</strong>istrative Burdens). Established <strong>in</strong> 2000,ACTAL has only n<strong>in</strong>e staff members and isempowered to advise on all proposed laws andregulations. To date, simplification of adm<strong>in</strong>istrativeprocedures has been achieved <strong>in</strong> the areas ofcorporate taxation, social security, environmentalregulation, and statistical requirements. The estimatedsav<strong>in</strong>gs are US$600 million from streaml<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g thetax requirements alone.• Sweden has a “guillot<strong>in</strong>e” approach for regulatoryreform, <strong>in</strong> which hundreds of obsolete regulationsare cancelled after the government periodicallyrequires regulatory agencies to register all essentialregulations.But there has been much less reform <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries, with the result that bus<strong>in</strong>esses aresometimes burdened by outdated regulation. Forexample, the company law regulat<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess entrydates back to 1884 <strong>in</strong> the Dom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic, to1901 <strong>in</strong> Angola, and to 1916 <strong>in</strong> Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso. ButOECD countries have all revised their laws <strong>in</strong> the lasttwo decades. Similarly, employment regulation <strong>in</strong>Africa often dates to colonial times or was revised justafter <strong>in</strong>dependence. On average, it is over threedecades old. This is evidence aga<strong>in</strong>st the “reformfatigue” <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, often attributed tothe work of <strong>in</strong>ternational aid agencies.With laws to meet the needs of bus<strong>in</strong>ess developeddecades or even a century earlier, it is hardly surpris<strong>in</strong>gthat those laws often impose unnecessaryburdens on bus<strong>in</strong>ess today. But this is also groundsfor optimism: outdated regulation is often the resultof <strong>in</strong>ertia or a lack of capacity to reform, not ofentrenched bus<strong>in</strong>ess or government <strong>in</strong>terests.There are many reforms where the regulatory burdenon bus<strong>in</strong>ess can be reduced, while the government canredirect much-needed resources toward the tasks thatreally count—such as provid<strong>in</strong>g basic social services.Indeed, some countries have recently modernizedmany aspects of their bus<strong>in</strong>ess regulation, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>gJamaica, the Republic of Korea, and Thailand. There isno reason why others should not follow. The benefitscan be enormous. So are the costs of not reform<strong>in</strong>g.Of course, reforms are not always easy. There are also<strong>in</strong>stances where powerful lobbies prevent or reverseregulatory reform. In 1996, the Peruvian governmenttried to reduce mandatory severance payments by 50percent. The uproar with unions made the governmentwithdraw the proposal quickly. Instead, severancepayments were <strong>in</strong>creased. The German government, <strong>in</strong>May 2003, proposed far-reach<strong>in</strong>g reforms aimed atmak<strong>in</strong>g labor markets more flexible. Such proposalshave previously been withdrawn after threats of workerstrikes. Another ill-fated reform comes from Croatia,where the private notaries’ profession has for yearsunderm<strong>in</strong>ed the government’s efforts to simplifybus<strong>in</strong>ess entry procedures and collateral enforcement.Simplification would mean more competition and aloss of profits for the private notaries. Although <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong><strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> does not address political economy of reform,the report gives other examples of reforms gone awrydue to oppos<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>terests.The analysis presented <strong>in</strong> this report suggests specificpolicy reforms (table 1) that illustrate two ma<strong>in</strong> themes:first, that poor countries have the furthest to go, andsecond, that when it comes to the manner of regulation,one size often fits all (<strong>in</strong> many cases there really is onebest practice). The list of reform examples is still<strong>in</strong>complete. Future reports aim to enlarge it.In bus<strong>in</strong>ess entry, reforms that are easy toimplement <strong>in</strong>clude the adoption of better <strong>in</strong>formationand <strong>in</strong>tragovernment communications technology—to <strong>in</strong>form prospective entrepreneurs and to serve asa virtual one-stop shop for bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration.The <strong>in</strong>troduction of a s<strong>in</strong>gle registration form andsilent consent <strong>in</strong> approv<strong>in</strong>g registration have hadenormous success. Reduc<strong>in</strong>g the number of proceduresto statistical and tax registration andabolish<strong>in</strong>g the m<strong>in</strong>imum capital requirementlighten the burden on entrepreneurs and have beenassociated with the creation of larger numbers ofnew bus<strong>in</strong>esses. Other reforms that require legislativechange <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g a generalobjectsclause <strong>in</strong> the articles of <strong>in</strong>corporation and


OverviewTable 1Examples of Good Reform PracticesPr<strong>in</strong>ciples of RegulationSome ExamplesStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>• Registration is an adm<strong>in</strong>istrative, not judicial, process • Ch<strong>in</strong>a, United States• Use of s<strong>in</strong>gle bus<strong>in</strong>ess identification number • Denmark, Turkey• Electronic application made possible • Latvia, Sweden, S<strong>in</strong>gapore• Statistical and tax registration sufficient to start operations • Australia, Canada, New Zealand• No m<strong>in</strong>imum capital requirement • Chile, Ireland, JamaicaHir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g Workers• Contracts “at will” between employers and employees • Denmark, Ireland, S<strong>in</strong>gapore• No limits on fixed-term contracts • Australia, Denmark, Israel• Apprentice wages for young workers • Chile, Colombia, Poland• Shift work between slow and peak periods • Hungary, PolandEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a Contract• Judiciary has a system for track<strong>in</strong>g cases • Slovak Republic, S<strong>in</strong>gapore• Summary procedure <strong>in</strong> the general court • Botswana, New Zealand, Netherlands• Simplified procedure <strong>in</strong> commercial courts • Australia, Ireland, Papua New Gu<strong>in</strong>ea• Attorney representation not mandatory • Lebanon, TunisiaGett<strong>in</strong>g Credit• Strong creditor protection <strong>in</strong> collateral and bankruptcy laws • New Zealand, United K<strong>in</strong>gdom• No restrictions on assets that may be used as collateral • Slovak Republic, Hong Kong (Ch<strong>in</strong>a)• Out of court or summary judgments for enforc<strong>in</strong>g collateral • Germany, Malaysia, Moldova• Regulations provide <strong>in</strong>centives for shar<strong>in</strong>g and proper use of credit <strong>in</strong>formation • Belgium, S<strong>in</strong>gapore, United StatesClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>• Limited court powers • Australia, F<strong>in</strong>land, United K<strong>in</strong>gdom• <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy adm<strong>in</strong>istrator files report with creditors • Botswana, Germany, Hungary• Cont<strong>in</strong>ued education for bankruptcy adm<strong>in</strong>istrators • Argent<strong>in</strong>a, France, NetherlandsxixFigure 7Courts and Notaries Are Bottlenecks to <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Start-UpWithout notary38With notary53Time, daysNote: Bars shown <strong>in</strong> these figures represent median values for countries with and without notary <strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>in</strong>bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration. Differences <strong>in</strong> medians are statistically significant at the 1 percent level for the time measuresbut significant only at the 13 percent level for the cost measure.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.With notary26Without notary19Cost, % of <strong>in</strong>come per capitaWithout court40With court56Time, daysremov<strong>in</strong>g notarial authorizations and court usefrom the registration process (figure 7). Suchreforms may be difficult to implement, as politicalWith court32Without court23will <strong>in</strong> government and theprivate sector may waver,but they have beneficial effectsbeyond bus<strong>in</strong>ess entry.In employment regulation,five types of reform ease theburden on bus<strong>in</strong>esses andprovide better job opportunitiesfor the poor.• First, <strong>in</strong> most develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries a general reformtoward reduction of thescope of employment regulationhas yielded positiveresults. The deregulationexperience <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America (Chile, Colombia,Guyana, and Uruguay) as well as <strong>in</strong> transitioneconomies (Estonia) provides many lessons.Cost, % of <strong>in</strong>come per capita


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>xx• Second, many OECD countries have focused on<strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g flexible part-time and fixed-termcontracts. These contracts br<strong>in</strong>g groups that areless likely to f<strong>in</strong>d jobs (women and youths) <strong>in</strong>to thelabor market. Germany has raised the duration offixed-term contracts to eight years, while Polanddoes not mandate any duration limit.• Third, several countries have either reduced them<strong>in</strong>imum wage (Colombia) or lowered them<strong>in</strong>imum wage limit for new entrants (Chile).• Fourth, some countries (Hungary) have made itpossible for employers to shift work time betweenperiods of slow demand and peak periods, withoutthe need for overtime payment.• Fifth, other countries have focused on eas<strong>in</strong>gregulation on fir<strong>in</strong>g. The most far-reach<strong>in</strong>g reformwas recently implemented <strong>in</strong> Serbia and Montenegro,where the severance payment for a worker with 20years’ tenure was reduced from 36 months to 4months.In contract enforcement, establish<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formationsystems on caseload and judicial statistics has had alarge payoff. Judiciaries that have established suchsystems, as <strong>in</strong> the Slovak Republic, can identify theirprimary users and the biggest bottlenecks. Simplify<strong>in</strong>gprocedures is also often warranted. Forexample, summary debt collection proceed<strong>in</strong>gs of thetype recently established <strong>in</strong> Mexico alleviate court congestionby reduc<strong>in</strong>g procedural complexity. Whendefault judgments—automatic judgments if thedefendant does not appear <strong>in</strong> court—are <strong>in</strong>troduced aswell, delays are cut significantly.The structure of the judiciary can also be modified toallow for small claims and specialized commercialcourts. Several countries that have small claims courts(Japan, New Zealand, the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom) haverecently <strong>in</strong>creased the maximum claim eligible forhear<strong>in</strong>g at the court. However, the manner of regulationof the judicial process <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries mayneed to be different. Where the judiciary is still <strong>in</strong> itsearly stages of development, as <strong>in</strong> Angola, Mozambique,or Nepal, specialized courts may be premature. There,reformers can establish a specialized section deal<strong>in</strong>gFigure 8Credit Bureaus Are Associated with More CreditPrivate credit, % GDPMoreLess1 2 3 4 5MoreCountries ranked by credit <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g, qu<strong>in</strong>tilesNote: The correlation between private credit to GDP and private credit bureausshown <strong>in</strong> this figure controls for national <strong>in</strong>come, <strong>in</strong>come growth, <strong>in</strong>flation, rule-oflaw<strong>in</strong>dex, creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex, the presence of a public registry, and legal orig<strong>in</strong>.The relationship is statistically significant at the 5 percent level.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.with commercial cases with<strong>in</strong> the general court or tra<strong>in</strong>specialized judges.Simplification of judicial procedures is associatedwith less time and cost. For example, <strong>in</strong> somecountries, such as Argent<strong>in</strong>a, Bolivia, Morocco, andSpa<strong>in</strong>, bus<strong>in</strong>esses are obliged to hire lawyers whenresolv<strong>in</strong>g commercial disputes. This <strong>in</strong>creases the costof enforc<strong>in</strong>g contracts, sometimes unnecessarily. Inmany <strong>in</strong>stances, the manager may simply present to thejudge proof of delivery of goods and require payment.Establish<strong>in</strong>g appropriate regulation and <strong>in</strong>centivesto facilitate private credit bureaus is an essential startto encourag<strong>in</strong>g access to credit (figure 8). In somecases—especially <strong>in</strong> poor countries where commercial<strong>in</strong>centives for private bureaus are low—sett<strong>in</strong>g up public credit registries has helped remedythe lack of private <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g, albeit secondbest to an effective private bureau. The design ofcredit <strong>in</strong>formation regulations <strong>in</strong>fluences the impactof bureaus: broader coverage of borrowers and goodregulations on collection, distribution, and quality of<strong>in</strong>formation (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g privacy and data protection)are associated with better function<strong>in</strong>g credit markets.


OverviewLegal creditor protections can be improved byreform<strong>in</strong>g collateral law: <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g out of court orsummary enforcement proceed<strong>in</strong>gs, elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>grestrictions on which assets may be used as securityfor loans, and improv<strong>in</strong>g the clarity of creditors’liens through collateral registries and clear laws onwho has priority <strong>in</strong> a disputed claim to collateral.Stronger powers for creditors to recover their claims<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>solvency are associated with more access tocredit.Three areas of bankruptcy reform give the mostpromise. The first is choos<strong>in</strong>g the appropriate<strong>in</strong>solvency law given a country’s <strong>in</strong>come and <strong>in</strong>stitutionalcapacity. Ill-function<strong>in</strong>g judiciaries are betteroff without pour<strong>in</strong>g resources <strong>in</strong>to sophisticatedbankruptcy systems. There is a general misperceptionthat bankruptcy laws are needed to enforce creditorrights. In practice, they often add to legal uncerta<strong>in</strong>tyand delays <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries. Private negotiationsof debt restructur<strong>in</strong>g under contract andsecured transactions law and the <strong>in</strong>troduction ofsummary judgments, like those for simple contractenforcement, will do. The second is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the<strong>in</strong>volvement of stakeholders <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>solvency processrather than rely<strong>in</strong>g on the court for mak<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>essdecisions. The third is tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g judges and bankruptcyadm<strong>in</strong>istrators <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>solvency law and practiceOf course, for governments to undertake reformthere needs to be a strong constituency <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong>change, so that <strong>in</strong>ertia and the lobby<strong>in</strong>g of entrenchedpolitical or bus<strong>in</strong>ess groups can be overcome. Bybr<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>g evidence to the debate, <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>motivates the need for change and <strong>in</strong>forms the designof new regulations and <strong>in</strong>stitutions.xxi


1Build<strong>in</strong>g New Indicatorsof <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> RegulationIn 1664, William Petty, an adviser to Cromwell’s governmentand to Charles II after the Restoration,compiled the first known national accounts. Hemade four entries. On the expense side, “food,hous<strong>in</strong>g, clothes and all other necessaries” wereestimated at £40 million. National <strong>in</strong>come was split<strong>in</strong>to £8 million from land, £7 million from otherpersonal estates, and £25 million from labor <strong>in</strong>come. 1In later centuries, estimates of country <strong>in</strong>come,expenditure, and material <strong>in</strong>puts and outputs becamemore abundant. However, it was not until the 1940sthat a systematic framework was developed formeasur<strong>in</strong>g national <strong>in</strong>come and expenditure, underthe direction of John Maynard Keynes. 2 It is hard tounderestimate the impact of this new methodology.Complicated transactions data were simplified <strong>in</strong>toan aggregate overview of the economy. Economic performanceand structure could be assessed with greaterprecision than ever before. As the methodology becamean <strong>in</strong>ternational standard, comparisons of countries’f<strong>in</strong>ancial positions became possible.Today the macroeconomic <strong>in</strong>dicators <strong>in</strong> nationalaccounts are standard <strong>in</strong> every country. Records ofoverall wealth, production, consumption, wages,trade, and <strong>in</strong>vestment across countries are taken forgranted. Empirical studies of those data have shedlight on new theories of macroeconomic development.But systems for measur<strong>in</strong>g the microeconomic and<strong>in</strong>stitutional factors that expla<strong>in</strong> the aggregates arestill nascent.<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> addresses the gap by construct<strong>in</strong>g newsets of <strong>in</strong>dicators on the regulatory environment forprivate sector development. The <strong>in</strong>dicators coverbus<strong>in</strong>ess entry, employment regulation, contractenforcement, creditor rights, credit <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>gsystems, and bankruptcy. This is only the beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g ofa large agenda of build<strong>in</strong>g similar <strong>in</strong>dicators of bus<strong>in</strong>esslicenses, property registries, corporate governance,trade <strong>in</strong>frastructure, law enforcement, and tax policy.More than a dozen organizations already produceand periodically update <strong>in</strong>dicators on country risk,economic freedom, and <strong>in</strong>ternational competitiveness;surveys of firms are now common. New methods arebe<strong>in</strong>g applied to aggregate <strong>in</strong>dicators, to produceuseful gauges of general economic and policy conditions.Surpris<strong>in</strong>gly, none assess the specific laws andregulations that enhance or h<strong>in</strong>der bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity.Nor do they evaluate the public <strong>in</strong>stitutions—courts,credit registries, the company register—that supportit. Reformers are left <strong>in</strong> the dark.The two types of <strong>in</strong>dicators <strong>in</strong> <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> focuson government regulation and its effect on bus<strong>in</strong>esses—especially on small and medium-size domesticbus<strong>in</strong>esses (which make up the majority of firms,<strong>in</strong>vestment, and employment <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries).First are measures of actual regulation––such as thenumber of procedures to register a bus<strong>in</strong>ess or an <strong>in</strong>dexof employment law rigidity. Second are measures ofregulatory outcomes, such as the time and cost toregister a bus<strong>in</strong>ess, enforce a contract, or go throughbankruptcy.Based on read<strong>in</strong>gs of laws and regulations, withverification and <strong>in</strong>put from local government officials,lawyers, bus<strong>in</strong>ess consultants, and other professionalsadm<strong>in</strong>ister<strong>in</strong>g or advis<strong>in</strong>g on legal and regulatoryrequirements, this methodology has several advantages.It uses factual <strong>in</strong>formation and allows multiple <strong>in</strong>teractionswith local respondents, ensur<strong>in</strong>g accuracy by1


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>2Figure 1.1Costs of <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Entry <strong>in</strong> Ethiopia400Percentage of <strong>in</strong>come per capita Procedure300 200 100 0Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.1. Check company name2. Sign documentsbefore a notary3. Deposit documents4. Pay stamp duty5. File with the regionalTrade Office6. Publish a public notice7. Make a company seal8. Register with InlandRevenue Authorityclarify<strong>in</strong>g possible mis<strong>in</strong>terpretations of questions. Itis <strong>in</strong>expensive, so the data can be collected <strong>in</strong> a largesample of countries. And because the same standardassumptions are applied <strong>in</strong> data collection, which istransparent and easily replicable, comparisons andbenchmarks are valid across countries.Most important, the analysis has direct relevance forpolicy reform, which it facilitates <strong>in</strong> three ways. First,the analysis reveals the relationship between <strong>in</strong>dicatorsand economic and social outcomes, allow<strong>in</strong>g policymakersto see how particular laws and regulations areassociated with poverty, corruption, employment,access to credit, the size of the <strong>in</strong>formal economy, andthe entry of new firms. Putt<strong>in</strong>g higher adm<strong>in</strong>istrativeburdens on entrepreneurs dim<strong>in</strong>ishes bus<strong>in</strong>essactivity—but it also creates more corruption and alarger <strong>in</strong>formal economy, with fewer jobs for the poor.Second, beyond highlight<strong>in</strong>g the areas for policyreform, the analysis provides guidance on the designof reforms. The data offer a wealth of detail on thespecific regulations and <strong>in</strong>stitutions that enhance orh<strong>in</strong>der bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity, the biggest bottlenecks caus<strong>in</strong>gbureaucratic delay, and the cost of comply<strong>in</strong>g withregulation. A library of current laws, also specify<strong>in</strong>g theregulatory reforms under way, support each <strong>in</strong>dicatorset. Governments can thus identify, after review<strong>in</strong>gtheir country’s <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong>dicators, where theylag beh<strong>in</strong>d and will know what to reform.For example, <strong>in</strong> January 2003, Ethiopia was one ofthe most expensive countries <strong>in</strong> which to start a newbus<strong>in</strong>ess. The breakdown of the bus<strong>in</strong>ess entry processshows that the cost of entry—more than four timesgross national <strong>in</strong>come per capita—is driven ma<strong>in</strong>lyby the requirement to publish an official notice <strong>in</strong> thenewspapers (figure 1.1). If the government elim<strong>in</strong>atesthe publication fee, the cost plummets to about 50percent of <strong>in</strong>come per capita, plac<strong>in</strong>g Ethiopia belowthe average <strong>in</strong> the sample of more than 130 countries.(In June 2003, the Ethiopian government reduced thecost of publish<strong>in</strong>g the notice by 30 percent.)Another example of how the <strong>in</strong>dicators shed lighton policy reforms is the time it takes to enforce acontract <strong>in</strong> court. Countries that have specializedcommercial judges or specialized commercial courtstend to have faster dispute resolution. In countrieswhere commercial sections <strong>in</strong> general courts or commercialcourts were recently established, as <strong>in</strong> Portugaland Tanzania, the time to recover a debt has been significantlyreduced. A reformer can <strong>in</strong>fer that specializationimproves efficiency.F<strong>in</strong>ally, analyses across sets of <strong>in</strong>dicators build theagenda for comprehensive regulatory reform. Forexample, exam<strong>in</strong>ation of both entry and labor regulationreveals that a venue to challenge <strong>in</strong>efficient,unfair, or corrupt regulatory practices is needed. Anombudsman’s office or adm<strong>in</strong>istrative courts <strong>in</strong>countries with well-function<strong>in</strong>g public adm<strong>in</strong>istration,or statutory time limits and a “silence isconsent” rule <strong>in</strong> countries with less adm<strong>in</strong>istrativecapacity would improve entry and labor regulation.<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> MethodologyFeatures and AssumptionsThe methodology followed for each of the topics <strong>in</strong><strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> has six standard features:1. The team, with academic advisers, collects andanalyzes the laws and regulations <strong>in</strong> force.2. The analysis yields an assessment <strong>in</strong>strument orquestionnaire that is designed for local professionals


Build<strong>in</strong>g New Indicators of <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Regulationexperienced <strong>in</strong> their fields, such as <strong>in</strong>corporationlawyers and consultants for bus<strong>in</strong>ess entry orlitigation lawyers and judges for contractenforcement.3. The questionnaire is structured around ahypothetical case to ensure comparability acrosscountries and over time.4. The local experts engage <strong>in</strong> several rounds of<strong>in</strong>teraction—typically four—with the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong><strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> team.5. The prelim<strong>in</strong>ary results are presented to bothacademics and practitioners, prior to ref<strong>in</strong>ements<strong>in</strong> the questionnaire and further rounds of datacollection.6. The data are subjected to numerous tests forrobustness, which frequently lead to revisions orexpansions of the collected <strong>in</strong>formation. Forexample, follow<strong>in</strong>g collection and analysis of dataon bus<strong>in</strong>ess entry regulation, <strong>in</strong>corporation lawyers<strong>in</strong> several countries suggested that the m<strong>in</strong>imumcapital requirement be <strong>in</strong>cluded, because itsometimes constitutes a very large start-up cost.The requirement was <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> a follow-upquestionnaire. (For another example, the contractenforcement project collected and analyzed data onthe recovery of debt <strong>in</strong> the amount of 50 percent of<strong>in</strong>come per capita, as well as on two other cases—the eviction of nonpay<strong>in</strong>g tenants and the recoveryof a smaller debt claim [5 percent of <strong>in</strong>come percapita], which served as robustness checks). 3The result is a set of <strong>in</strong>dicators whose constructionis easy to replicate. And extend<strong>in</strong>g the dataset to obta<strong>in</strong>other benchmarks is straightforward. For example,<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> studies a certa<strong>in</strong> type of bus<strong>in</strong>ess—usually a domestic limited-liability company. Analystscan follow the methodology and construct the samemeasures as benchmarks for sole proprietorships andforeign companies.The methodology of one project—bus<strong>in</strong>ess entryregulation—is presented <strong>in</strong> detail below as an illustrationof the general approach used <strong>in</strong> <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong><strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>, before the methodology for the other foursets of <strong>in</strong>dicators is summarized. The data for all setsof <strong>in</strong>dicators are for January 2003.Start<strong>in</strong>g a bus<strong>in</strong>ess. The project on start<strong>in</strong>g abus<strong>in</strong>ess records all procedures officially required foran entrepreneur to operate an <strong>in</strong>dustrial or commercialbus<strong>in</strong>ess legally. They <strong>in</strong>clude obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g necessarypermits and licenses—and complet<strong>in</strong>g the required<strong>in</strong>scriptions, verifications, and notifications—to startoperation. 4 The questionnaire calculates the costand time of fulfill<strong>in</strong>g each procedure under normalcircumstances, as well as the m<strong>in</strong>imum capital requirementsto operate. The assumption is that such<strong>in</strong>formation is readily available to the entrepreneurand that all government and nongovernmententities <strong>in</strong> the process function efficiently andwithout corruption.To make the bus<strong>in</strong>ess comparable across countries,10 assumptions are employed. The bus<strong>in</strong>ess• is a limited-liability company (If there is more thanone type of limited-liability company <strong>in</strong> thecountry, the type most popular among domesticfirms is chosen.);• operates <strong>in</strong> the country’s most populous city;• is 100 percent domestically owned and has fivefounders, none of whom is a legal entity;• has start-up capital of 10 times <strong>in</strong>come per capita,paid <strong>in</strong> cash;• performs general <strong>in</strong>dustrial or commercial activities,such as the production and sale of products orservices to the public;• leases the commercial plant and offices;• does not qualify for <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong>centives or anyspecial benefits;• has up to 50 employees one month after the start ofoperations, all of them nationals;• has turnover of at least 100 times <strong>in</strong>come percapita; and• has a company deed 10 pages long.Obviously, the assumptions enhance comparabilityat the expense of generality. For example, <strong>in</strong>many countries, both bus<strong>in</strong>ess regulation and itsenforcement are different across different locationswith<strong>in</strong> a country. <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> covers bus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>in</strong>the largest city. However, one also must be m<strong>in</strong>dfulthat <strong>in</strong> many develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, <strong>in</strong>flation data—3


Build<strong>in</strong>g New Indicators of <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> RegulationFigure 1.2Start<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> BoliviaCostPercentage of <strong>in</strong>come per capitaTimeDays160 120 80 40 0 Procedure 0 20 40 60Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.1. Check uniquenessof name2. Have attorney prepare deedand application3. Notarize articlesof <strong>in</strong>corporation4. Publish deed5. Prepare Open<strong>in</strong>g Statementof Accounts (OSA)6. Seal the OSA7. Get unified taxregistration card8. Have lawyer requestcommercial registration9. Get evidence of depositof capital10. Obta<strong>in</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess license11. Register deedat Registro Commercial12. Register at Chamberof Commerce13. Register at CajaNacional de Salud14. Get evidence of depositof payroll15. Register at INFOCAL16. Register at the M<strong>in</strong>istryof Labor17. Register with pensionsystem, Futuro18. Register with pensionsystem, Previsionobta<strong>in</strong> a company registration number, as specified <strong>in</strong>the company law or commercial code.The data collection results <strong>in</strong> a file that describes thesequence of procedures—and their time and cost—tostart legal operation. Consider the data for Bolivia(figure 1.2). The data represent a good-case scenariobecause the assumptions necessary to standardizeresponses across countries remove many possible bottlenecks,such as the entrepreneur’s not hav<strong>in</strong>g correct<strong>in</strong>formation about where to go and what documentsto submit.In practice, entrepreneurs may avoid some legallyrequired procedures altogether—say, by not register<strong>in</strong>gfor social security or not register<strong>in</strong>g with thechamber of commerce—or they can pay a facilitatorfor assistance. In both cases, the time would bereduced. So the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> time <strong>in</strong>dicator maybe either smaller or largerthan the average start-uptime documented <strong>in</strong> enterprisesurveys. For example,Mozambique’s average startuptime <strong>in</strong> the January 2003<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> data was 153days, but a survey of recentlystarted bus<strong>in</strong>esses reported138 days on average <strong>in</strong> July2002. <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> reported88 days <strong>in</strong> India <strong>in</strong> January2003, but an enterprisesurvey conducted <strong>in</strong> 2002reported 90 days. 6Other TopicsHir<strong>in</strong>g and fir<strong>in</strong>g. The <strong>in</strong>dicatorsfor employment regulationare based on adetailed study of employmentlaws. Data are alsogathered on the specific constitutionalprovisions relatedto labor. In most cases, boththe actual laws and a secondarysource are used toensure accuracy. Conflict<strong>in</strong>ganswers are checked <strong>in</strong> twoadditional sources, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g a local legal treatise onemployment regulation. Legal advice from lead<strong>in</strong>glocal law firms is solicited to confirm accuracy <strong>in</strong> allcases.To make the data comparable across countries,several assumptions about the worker and thecompany are applied. The worker is a nonexecutive,full-time employee who has worked <strong>in</strong> the samecompany for 20 years, has a nonwork<strong>in</strong>g wife and twochildren, and is not a member of a labor union(unless membership is mandatory). The bus<strong>in</strong>ess, alimited-liability manufactur<strong>in</strong>g company that operates<strong>in</strong> the country’s most populous city, is 100 percentdomestically owned and has 201 employees.Three <strong>in</strong>dices of the regulation of labor marketsare constructed by exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g detailed provisions <strong>in</strong>5


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>6the employment laws—flexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex,conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex, and flexibilityof-fir<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>dex, with values between 0 and 100,where a higher value means more regulation. Anemployment-regulation <strong>in</strong>dex averages the values ofthe three <strong>in</strong>dices. 7Enforc<strong>in</strong>g contracts. The <strong>in</strong>dicators on contractenforcement are also constructed by assum<strong>in</strong>g a hypotheticalcase—a payment dispute of 50 percent of<strong>in</strong>come per capita <strong>in</strong> the country’s most populous city.The data track the procedures to recover debt throughthe courts. The pla<strong>in</strong>tiff has fully complied with thecontract (and is thus 100 percent <strong>in</strong> the right) and filesa lawsuit to recover the debt. The debtor attempts todelay and opposes the compla<strong>in</strong>t. The judge decidesevery motion for the pla<strong>in</strong>tiff. There are no appeals orpostjudgment motions.The data come from read<strong>in</strong>gs of the codes of civilprocedures and other court regulations, as well asfrom adm<strong>in</strong>ister<strong>in</strong>g surveys to local litigationattorneys. Most of the respondents are members of theLex Mundi association of law firms. At least two associationlawyers <strong>in</strong> each country participated <strong>in</strong> thesurvey. The questionnaires were designed with thehelp of scholars from Harvard and Yale universitiesand with the advice of practic<strong>in</strong>g attorneys. 8On the basis of questionnaire responses, four<strong>in</strong>dicators of the efficiency of commercial contractenforcement are developed:1. the number of procedures, mandated by law orcourt regulation, that demand <strong>in</strong>teraction betweenthe parties or between them and the judge or acourt officer;2. the time needed for dispute resolution <strong>in</strong> calendardays, counted from the moment the pla<strong>in</strong>tiff filesthe lawsuit <strong>in</strong> court until the moment of settlementor, when appropriate, payment (this measure<strong>in</strong>cludes the days when actions take place and thewait<strong>in</strong>g periods between actions);3. the official cost of go<strong>in</strong>g through court procedures,<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g court costs and attorney fees; and4. the procedural complexity of contractenforcement—an <strong>in</strong>dex that scores countries onhow heavily dispute resolution is regulated.Figure 1.3Is the Time to Enforce a Contract IndicatorRepresentative? YesDays6004002000<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Court recordsMexicoEcuadorDom<strong>in</strong>icanRepublicBrazilSources: Hammergren 2003, <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2001, <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.Are the <strong>in</strong>dicators from a hypothetical case representativeof debt recovery practices? Yes. Few countrieshave done studies on commercial dispute resolution bylook<strong>in</strong>g at actual court cases. Where data are available—from Brazil, the Dom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic, Ecuador, Mexico,and Peru—the median times are very similar to thosereported <strong>in</strong> <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> (figure 1.3). 9 For example, asurvey of about 500 debt recovery cases <strong>in</strong> Mexico f<strong>in</strong>dsthat the median time from fil<strong>in</strong>g to service of process is53 days; from service of process to judgment, 111 days;and from judgment to enforcement, 182 days—a total of346 days. 10 The respective numbers <strong>in</strong> <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> are55 days, 119 days, and 151 days—a total of 325 days. Astudy on the Dom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic, us<strong>in</strong>g more than2,000 cases, f<strong>in</strong>ds that the median duration from fil<strong>in</strong>gto judgment is 431 days. <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> arrives at 405days. And a study of more than 300 cases <strong>in</strong> Ecuadorf<strong>in</strong>ds the duration from fil<strong>in</strong>g to resolution to be 369days. 11 <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ds 333 days. Consistent withthe good-case scenario of the hypothetical case, ournumbers are somewhat lower.Gett<strong>in</strong>g credit. <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> constructs two sets ofmeasures on gett<strong>in</strong>g f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g: shar<strong>in</strong>g credit <strong>in</strong>formationand legally protect<strong>in</strong>g creditor rights. Theassessment of credit <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong>stitutions beg<strong>in</strong>swith a survey of bank<strong>in</strong>g supervisors. It confirms thepresence or absence of public credit registries andprivate credit bureaus. The survey also collectsPeru


Build<strong>in</strong>g New Indicators of <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Regulationdescriptive data on credit market outcomes and<strong>in</strong>formation on related rules <strong>in</strong> credit markets (collateral,<strong>in</strong>terest rate controls, laws on credit<strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g).In countries that confirmed the presence of a publicregistry or a major private bureau, a second survey,on registry structure, laws, and associated rules wasconducted. The survey was developed <strong>in</strong> cooperationwith the Credit Report<strong>in</strong>g Systems Project of the<strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> Group and was reviewed by academicexperts on the topic from the University of Salerno.From the responses, measures are constructed for thecoverage of the market for credit <strong>in</strong>formation, thescope of credit <strong>in</strong>formation collected and distributed,the accessibility of the data <strong>in</strong> the public creditregistry, and the quality of <strong>in</strong>formation available <strong>in</strong>the registry. 12 A separate questionnaire on the regulatoryframework for shar<strong>in</strong>g credit <strong>in</strong>formation isconducted. 13The creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dicator measures four powersof secured creditors <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy: 141. whether there are restrictions, such as creditors’consent, on enter<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to reorganizationproceed<strong>in</strong>gs;2. whether there is no automatic stay (or “assetfreeze”) on realiz<strong>in</strong>g collateral upon bankruptcy;3. whether secured creditors are satisfied first onliquidation; and4. whether management is replaced by a court- orcreditor-appo<strong>in</strong>ted receiver <strong>in</strong> reorganization.A value of 1 is assigned to each variable when acountry’s laws and regulations provide those powers forsecured creditors. The creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex sums thetotal score across all four variables. A m<strong>in</strong>imum of 0represents weak creditor rights; a maximum of 4 representsstrong creditor rights. Data for the variables areobta<strong>in</strong>ed by read<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>solvency laws and legalsummaries, then verified by means of a questionnairesubmitted to f<strong>in</strong>ancial lawyers, and then cross-checkedaga<strong>in</strong>st data gathered for the bankruptcy project.Clos<strong>in</strong>g a bus<strong>in</strong>ess. The <strong>in</strong>dicators are derived fromquestionnaires answered by bankruptcy judges andattorneys at private law firms. The questionnaires weredesigned with the assistance of scholars from HarvardUniversity and with the advice of practic<strong>in</strong>g attorneys.Most respondents are members of the InternationalBar Association.The data track the procedures for a hypotheticalbus<strong>in</strong>ess go<strong>in</strong>g through bankruptcy. The bus<strong>in</strong>ess is adomestically owned limited-liability company operat<strong>in</strong>ga hotel <strong>in</strong> the most populous city. It has 201employees, 1 ma<strong>in</strong> secured creditor, and 50 unsecuredcreditors. On the basis of detailed assumptions aboutthe debt structure and future cash flows, it is assumedthat the company becomes <strong>in</strong>solvent on January 1.The case is designed so that the bus<strong>in</strong>ess has a highervalue as a go<strong>in</strong>g concern—that is, the efficientoutcome is either reorganization or sale as a go<strong>in</strong>gconcern, not piecemeal liquidation.Six <strong>in</strong>dicators for the bankruptcy process are constructedfrom responses to the questionnaire: 151. the time to go through bankruptcy;2. the cost of go<strong>in</strong>g through bankruptcy;3. whether absolute priority for secured lenders ispreserved throughout the process;4. whether the efficient outcome is achieved;5. an aggregate-goals-of-bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>dex, createdby averag<strong>in</strong>g the scores for time, cost, priority, andreach<strong>in</strong>g the efficient outcome;6. an <strong>in</strong>dex for court powers <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy.Other Indicators <strong>in</strong> a Crowded Field<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> enters a crowded field of <strong>in</strong>dicatorsand rat<strong>in</strong>gs on various aspects of the environment fordo<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess (box 1.1). Eight organizations periodicallycollect such <strong>in</strong>dicators, with a focus on <strong>in</strong>ternationalportfolio <strong>in</strong>vestors, global lenders, andexecutives of mult<strong>in</strong>ational companies:• <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Environment Risk Intelligence (BERI),• Euromoney Institutional Investor (EII),• International Country Risk Guide (ICRG), PoliticalRisk Services group,• Country Risk Review (CRR), Global Insight,• The Economist Intelligence Unit (EIU),• The Heritage Foundation,• <strong>World</strong> Markets Research Center, and• A. T. Kearney.7


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>Box 1.1Cross-Country Indicators of the <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Environment<strong>World</strong> Competitiveness Yearbook• Published s<strong>in</strong>ce 1987 by the Institute for Management Development <strong>in</strong> Lausanne, Switzerland. Until 1996, a jo<strong>in</strong>t publicationwith the <strong>World</strong> Economic Forum.• Analyzes the <strong>in</strong>ternational competitiveness of 49 countries, on the basis of hard data from <strong>in</strong>ternational organizations andperception surveys of enterprise managers.• In the 2002 survey, there were 3,532 respondents, or 72 per country on average.• Hard data cover economic performance, <strong>in</strong>ternational trade and <strong>in</strong>vestment, public f<strong>in</strong>ance and fiscal policy, education,productivity, and <strong>in</strong>frastructure quality. Survey questions cover <strong>in</strong>stitutional framework (government efficiency, justice, andsecurity), bus<strong>in</strong>ess legislation (openness, competition regulations, labor regulations, and capital market regulations),management practices, and the impact of globalization.Source: www.imd.ch.Global Competitiveness Report8• Published s<strong>in</strong>ce 1996 by the <strong>World</strong> Economic Forum <strong>in</strong> Geneva, Switzerland.• Analyzes the <strong>in</strong>ternational competitiveness of 80 countries, on the basis of hard data from <strong>in</strong>ternational organizations andperception surveys of enterprise managers.• In the 2002 survey, there were 4,601 respondents, or 58 per country on average.• Survey questions cover access to credit, public <strong>in</strong>stitutions for contract and law enforcement, corruption, domesticcompetition, labor regulations, corporate governance, environmental policy, and cluster development. Hard data covereconomic performance, <strong>in</strong>ternational trade and <strong>in</strong>vestment, public f<strong>in</strong>ance and fiscal policy, education, technological<strong>in</strong>novation, <strong>in</strong>formation and communications technology, and <strong>in</strong>frastructure quality. Start<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> 2003, the analysis uses six<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong>dicators on start<strong>in</strong>g a bus<strong>in</strong>ess and enforc<strong>in</strong>g a contract.Source: www.weforum.org.<strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Environment and Enterprise Performance Survey• Published <strong>in</strong> 1999 and 2002 by the EBRD and the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>.• Analyzes government effectiveness, regulatory quality, rule of law, and corruption <strong>in</strong> 27 transition economies.• Based on surveys of 6,000 firms <strong>in</strong> 1999 and 7,500 firms <strong>in</strong> 2002, with hard data as well as perceptions questions.Source: www.<strong>in</strong>fo.worldbank.org/governance/beeps2002.Index of Economic Freedom• Published s<strong>in</strong>ce 1995 by the Heritage Foundation and the Wall Street Journal.• Analyzes economic freedom <strong>in</strong> 161 countries.• Based on assessments by <strong>in</strong>-house experts, draw<strong>in</strong>g on many public and private sources.• The <strong>in</strong>dex covers 10 areas: trade policy, fiscal burden, government <strong>in</strong>tervention, monetary policy, foreign <strong>in</strong>vestment, bank<strong>in</strong>gand f<strong>in</strong>ance, wages and prices, property rights, bus<strong>in</strong>ess regulation, and black markets.Source: www.heritage.org.<strong>World</strong> Markets Research Center• Published s<strong>in</strong>ce 1996 by the <strong>World</strong> Markets Research Center <strong>in</strong> London.• Analyzes the <strong>in</strong>vestment climate <strong>in</strong> 186 countries.• Based on assessments by 180 <strong>in</strong>-house experts, draw<strong>in</strong>g on many public and private sources.Source: www.worldmarketsanalysis.com.(contd.)


Build<strong>in</strong>g New Indicators of <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> RegulationBox 1.1Cross-Country Indicators of the <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Environment (cont<strong>in</strong>ued)Economic Freedom of the <strong>World</strong>• Published s<strong>in</strong>ce 1997 by the Fraser Institute.• Analyzes economic freedom <strong>in</strong> 123 countries.• Based on assessments by <strong>in</strong>-house experts, draw<strong>in</strong>g on many public and private sources. The rat<strong>in</strong>gs on the bus<strong>in</strong>essenvironment are derivative, based on the Global Competitiveness Report.• The <strong>in</strong>dex covers eight areas: size of government, legal structure, security of property rights, access to sound money, freedom toexchange with foreigners, regulation of credit, regulation of labor, and other bus<strong>in</strong>ess regulation.Source: www.freetheworld.com.Country Risk Service• Published quarterly s<strong>in</strong>ce 1997 by The Economist Intelligence Unit.• Provides <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>vestors with risk rat<strong>in</strong>gs for 100 countries.• Based on assessments by <strong>in</strong>-house experts, draw<strong>in</strong>g on previous rat<strong>in</strong>gs.• The <strong>in</strong>dex covers seven areas of country risk: political, economic policy, economic structure, liquidity, currency, sovereign debt,and bank<strong>in</strong>g sector.Source: www.eiu.com.International Country Risk Guide• Published monthly s<strong>in</strong>ce 1982 by Political Risk Services <strong>in</strong> Arl<strong>in</strong>gton, Virg<strong>in</strong>ia.• Provides <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>vestors with risk rat<strong>in</strong>gs for 140 countries.• Based on assessments by <strong>in</strong>-house experts, draw<strong>in</strong>g on previous rat<strong>in</strong>gs and outside experts.• The <strong>in</strong>dex covers three areas of country risk: political, f<strong>in</strong>ancial, and economic. Political risk covers law and order, <strong>in</strong>vestmentprofile, and bureaucratic quality.9Source: www.prsgroup.com.<strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Environment Risk Intelligence• Published by <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Environment Risk Intelligence three times a year s<strong>in</strong>ce 1966, <strong>in</strong> Geneva, Switzerland.• Provides <strong>in</strong>ternational <strong>in</strong>vestors with risk rat<strong>in</strong>gs for 50 countries.• Based on assessments by <strong>in</strong>-house experts, draw<strong>in</strong>g on previous rat<strong>in</strong>gs and outside experts. Their assessments are evaluated bya panel of about 100 external experts.• The <strong>in</strong>dex covers two areas of country risk: political and operational. Operational risk covers the enforceability of contracts,labor costs, bureaucratic delays, short-term credit, and long-term loans.Source: www.beri.com.Country Risk Reports• Published by a U.S. consult<strong>in</strong>g and <strong>in</strong>formation company, Global Insight (formerly DRI), s<strong>in</strong>ce 1996.• Provides quarterly country risk reviews for 117 countries.• Based on desk research of 80 <strong>in</strong>-house experts.• The <strong>in</strong>dex covers 33 immediate risk events and 18 secondary risk events, further classified <strong>in</strong>to policy (tax and nontax) risksand outcome (price and nonprice) risks. Secondary risk events are classified <strong>in</strong>to domestic political, external political, andeconomic risk.Source: www.global<strong>in</strong>sight.com.(contd.)


Build<strong>in</strong>g New Indicators of <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> RegulationFigure 1.4Access to <strong>Bank</strong> F<strong>in</strong>ance and Lend<strong>in</strong>g RatesAccess to f<strong>in</strong>anceHighRich countriesAccess to f<strong>in</strong>anceHighPoor countriesLow1 2 3 4 5LowestHighestCountries ranked by lend<strong>in</strong>g rates, qu<strong>in</strong>tileLow1 2 34 5LowestHighestCountries ranked by lend<strong>in</strong>g rates, qu<strong>in</strong>tileSource: EII (access-to-f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong>dicator), International F<strong>in</strong>ancial Statistics (June 2003 CD-ROM, lend<strong>in</strong>g rates).sometimes difficult environments rarely have thatchoice. Indeed, recent research shows that the<strong>in</strong>dicators generated by experts expla<strong>in</strong> the flow offoreign <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong>to an economy but not the flowof domestic private <strong>in</strong>vestment. 17Because foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors’ <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>in</strong> manycountries is lack<strong>in</strong>g, the experts assess<strong>in</strong>g the lessanalyzedcountries may not be as well <strong>in</strong>formed aboutthe environment for do<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess there. Considerthe view of the EII expert panel on access to bankcredit. The first graph <strong>in</strong> figure 1.4 shows a negativerelationship between access to bank credit and actuallend<strong>in</strong>g rates <strong>in</strong> the richer half of the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>sample. The second graph shows, contrary to expectations,a positive relationship between the two dataseries <strong>in</strong> poor countries.Another example is from a recent study thatcompares various expert poll rat<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> developedand develop<strong>in</strong>g countries. 18 The rat<strong>in</strong>gs across pollsare consistent <strong>in</strong> developed countries, but not <strong>in</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g countries (figure 1.5). One conclusion:pollsters pay less attention to countries that do notpresent large <strong>in</strong>vestment opportunities.The generality required for mak<strong>in</strong>g monthly orquarterly updates is adequate for mak<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formedchoices about whether to move money <strong>in</strong> or out ofcountries but not for guid<strong>in</strong>g policy reform. Take theregulatory component of the Index of EconomicFreedom, which comb<strong>in</strong>es “licens<strong>in</strong>g requirements toFigure 1.5Polls <strong>in</strong> Poor Countries Do Not AgreeRat<strong>in</strong>g1086420France S<strong>in</strong>gapore Belgium India Cameroon NigeriaNote: The rat<strong>in</strong>gs are normalized between 0 and 10, with higher values forbetter <strong>in</strong>vestment climates.Source: Batra 2003.BERIEIUICRGEIIoperate a bus<strong>in</strong>ess, the ease of obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g a bus<strong>in</strong>esslicense, corruption with<strong>in</strong> the bureaucracy, labor regulations,such as established work weeks, paidvacations, and parental leave, as well as selected laborregulations; environmental, consumer safety, andworker health regulations, and regulations thatimpose a burden on bus<strong>in</strong>ess.” 19 What reforms shouldthe government consider if its country is perform<strong>in</strong>gpoorly on this <strong>in</strong>dicator? Perhaps reform is needed <strong>in</strong>all aspects of bus<strong>in</strong>ess regulation, but perhaps it isnot.11


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>12Figure 1.6Regulation and the Informal EconomyInformal economyHigherLowerLessBelarusBosnia-Herzegov<strong>in</strong>aVietnamGeorgiaIran, IslamicRep. ofBoliviaPeruAzerbaijanYemenSyriaMongoliaCh<strong>in</strong>aNote: The correlation shown <strong>in</strong> this figure is controlled for <strong>in</strong>come.Sources: The Heritage Foundation 2002; Schneider 2002.AlbaniaPanamaUruguayThailandJordanRegulation <strong>in</strong>dexSri LankaSloveniaThe difficulty <strong>in</strong> us<strong>in</strong>g expert polls for policyreform is seen <strong>in</strong> the relationship of the burden ofregulation to the size of the <strong>in</strong>formal economy. Forexample, if the measures are adjusted for differentcountry <strong>in</strong>comes, there is no discernible relationshipbetween the Heritage Foundation’s regulatory <strong>in</strong>dexand an estimate of <strong>in</strong>formal output (figure 1.6). But alarge body of other research shows that excessivebus<strong>in</strong>ess-entry regulation and labor regulation arestrong determ<strong>in</strong>ants of <strong>in</strong>formality. 20Enterprise SurveysThe Global Competitiveness Report and the <strong>World</strong>Competitiveness Yearbook report a comb<strong>in</strong>ation ofhard data and perceptions data. The perceptions datacome from enterprise surveys on various aspects ofthe bus<strong>in</strong>ess environment. Managers answer questionson the difficulty of register<strong>in</strong>g a new firm, enforc<strong>in</strong>gcontracts through the courts, deal<strong>in</strong>g with laborissues, and so on. A. T. Kearney, <strong>in</strong> its FDI ConfidenceIndex,surveys bus<strong>in</strong>ess executives <strong>in</strong> the 1,000 largestmult<strong>in</strong>ational companies, ask<strong>in</strong>g respondents toshare their perceptions about the best countriesF<strong>in</strong>landUnited Arab EmiratesNew ZealandHong KongS<strong>in</strong>gaporeMorefor <strong>in</strong>vestment. The EBRD–<strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Environmentand Enterprise PerformanceSurvey uses a mixtureof perception and harddataquestions <strong>in</strong> transitioneconomies.Enterprise surveys are<strong>in</strong>formative if used appropriately.In many areas, perceptionsaffect bus<strong>in</strong>essdecisions and thus economicactivity. If managers considerthe courts to be corrupt and<strong>in</strong>efficient, they are unlikelyto use them. And if managersbelieve that there is notenough available <strong>in</strong>formationon what documents arenecessary to apply for abus<strong>in</strong>ess license, it does notmatter that the documentsare posted on a government Web site. The <strong>in</strong>formationis not easily accessible even if it is available.As regulatory reform takes place, its effect can beobserved <strong>in</strong> well-designed enterprise surveys. The surveydone by the Center for Economic and F<strong>in</strong>ancialResearch, an <strong>in</strong>dependent th<strong>in</strong>k tank, covers 2,000firms <strong>in</strong> 20 regions of the Russian Federation and asksabout actual costs of do<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess and general perceptionsof the bus<strong>in</strong>ess climate. 21 In August 2001, theRussian Parliament passed a new law limit<strong>in</strong>g thenumber of <strong>in</strong>spections of bus<strong>in</strong>esses to one per regulatoryagency every two years. Before the law tookforce, many bus<strong>in</strong>esses experienced multiple <strong>in</strong>spectionsby agencies. With the new law, the average number of<strong>in</strong>spections <strong>in</strong> the first half of 2002, compared withthe first half of 2001, fell 21 percent. Clearly, there wasimmediate impact. Such <strong>in</strong>-depth country surveyscan complement the cross-country <strong>in</strong>dicators of thebus<strong>in</strong>ess environment.But a large body of evidence shows that surveyquestions on perceptions do not always elicitmean<strong>in</strong>gful responses. 22 Reasons abound—forexample, biases <strong>in</strong> survey design, scal<strong>in</strong>g of responses,


Build<strong>in</strong>g New Indicators of <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Regulationunwill<strong>in</strong>gness of respondents to admit their lack ofknowledge or views, lack of a reference po<strong>in</strong>t foranswer<strong>in</strong>g, and sample selection.Design biases. Simple manipulations of survey designaffect the way respondents <strong>in</strong>terpret questions. One biascomes from the order<strong>in</strong>g of questions. People attempt toprovide answers consistent with the answers they havepreviously given <strong>in</strong> the survey. In one sociological survey,respondents were asked two questions: “How happy areyou with your life <strong>in</strong> general?” and “How happy are youwith your marriage?” When the marriage question camefirst, the answers to both were highly correlated, butwhen it came second, they were uncorrelated. 23If the survey is long, respondents may exert littleeffort <strong>in</strong> answer<strong>in</strong>g questions. As a consequence, theorder<strong>in</strong>g of multiple-choice options is importantbecause survey respondents may simply pick the firstor last available alternative. Two identical questions <strong>in</strong>the Global Competitiveness Report and the <strong>World</strong>Competitiveness Yearbook ask about the impedimentsto hir<strong>in</strong>g and fir<strong>in</strong>g workers and the ease of creat<strong>in</strong>g anew bus<strong>in</strong>ess. Strik<strong>in</strong>gly, the answers to the twoquestions are highly correlated <strong>in</strong> the former andunrelated <strong>in</strong> the latter, <strong>in</strong> part as a result of theorder<strong>in</strong>g and phras<strong>in</strong>g of questions.<strong>Response</strong> scales. <strong>Response</strong>s also change accord<strong>in</strong>gto the scales presented to respondents. In oneexperiment, some German households were asked howmany hours of television they watched each day. Half ofthe respondents were given a scale that began with ahalf-hour, then an hour, and proceeded <strong>in</strong> half-hour<strong>in</strong>crements, end<strong>in</strong>g with four-and-a-half hours. Theother respondents were given the same scale, but the firstfive answers were compressed so that it began with twoand-a-halfhours. Twice as many respondents <strong>in</strong> thesecond set reported watch<strong>in</strong>g television more than twoand-a-halfhours a day (37 percent versus 16 percent). 24Un<strong>in</strong>formed answers. Respondents want to avoidembarrassment. In one well-known example, roughly25 percent of nonvoters report hav<strong>in</strong>g voted whensurveyed immediately after an election. In anotherexample, survey experiments show that respondentsanswer questions on fictitious issues, such as provid<strong>in</strong>gop<strong>in</strong>ions on countries that do not exist, to avoidadmitt<strong>in</strong>g lack of knowledge. 25Figure 1.7Perceptions Bear No Relation to Actual Tax RatesStatutory corporate tax, %5040302010LowGeorgiaPakistanBangladeshCameroon Burk<strong>in</strong>a FasoBosnia-Herzegov<strong>in</strong>aChilePerceptions of taxes as an obstacleSources: Ernst and Young 2003; Batra and others 2003.Ch<strong>in</strong>aTunisiaPortugalS<strong>in</strong>gaporeBotswanaHighLack of a reference po<strong>in</strong>t. One example of this defectcomes from the United States, where nearly 85 percentof people who need to renew their driver’s licensereport be<strong>in</strong>g “better-than-average” drivers. Thisproblem is compounded <strong>in</strong> cross-country comparisons.One survey asks managers, “Are high taxes amajor obstacle to do<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong> your country?”When the answers are plotted aga<strong>in</strong>st the corporatetax rate, the two display no relationship whatsoever(figure 1.7). Managers <strong>in</strong> every country th<strong>in</strong>k tax ratesare high.Sample selection. Nationally representativeenterprise surveys are expensive to adm<strong>in</strong>ister. As aresult, almost all firm surveys sample from selectedsectors or subsectors with<strong>in</strong> an economy, and manydo not cover enough respondents to be statisticallyrepresentative. Different approaches to sampl<strong>in</strong>g canlead to significantly different results, a phenomenonthat suggests users should be cautious <strong>in</strong> generaliz<strong>in</strong>gfrom f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs based on a limited pool of firms.F<strong>in</strong>ally, perceptions measures are often driven bygeneral sentiment but do not provide useful <strong>in</strong>dicatorsof specific features of the bus<strong>in</strong>ess environment.Consider the 2003 Global Competitiveness Report. Inthe <strong>in</strong>dex of the quality of the national bus<strong>in</strong>ess environment,Turkey experiences a dramatic fall <strong>in</strong>rank<strong>in</strong>gs, from 33rd to 52nd (of 75 countries). Thereport reasons, “Turkey’s drop … is driven by arelative decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> factor quality (university-<strong>in</strong>dustry13


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>14Figure 1.8Regulatory Quality Rat<strong>in</strong>gsRegulatory qualityHighLowZIMBABWEBANGLADESHNIGERIAGEORGIAECUADORUKRAINEINDONESIASource: Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi 2003.20 40 6080100Percentileresearch collaboration, quality of managementschools, adm<strong>in</strong>istrative burden of start-ups, andothers) and context for strategy and rivalry (effectivenessof antitrust policy).” 26 It is hard to imag<strong>in</strong>ehow the university-<strong>in</strong>dustry research collaboration orthe quality of management schools could decl<strong>in</strong>e soprecipitously <strong>in</strong> a s<strong>in</strong>gle year. Also, <strong>in</strong> 2003, theTurkish government reformed bus<strong>in</strong>ess start-up regulations.27 Most likely, the change <strong>in</strong> surveyrespondents’ perceptions was <strong>in</strong>fluenced by thef<strong>in</strong>ancial crisis that started the previous year—that is,it changed the po<strong>in</strong>t of reference. Not co<strong>in</strong>cidentally,Argent<strong>in</strong>a, another country <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>ancial crisis <strong>in</strong> early2002, also experienced a dramatic fall <strong>in</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>essenvironment rank<strong>in</strong>gs.Aggregate Indicators Are More RobustThe robustness of perceptions <strong>in</strong>dicators is greatlyenhanced if they are aggregated. Aggregation br<strong>in</strong>gsthree benefits: it improves the precision of estimat<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>dicators; it quantifies the explanatory power, giv<strong>in</strong>gpolicymakers the ability to choose which <strong>in</strong>dicatorsand analyses to rely on; and it <strong>in</strong>creases coverage becausesome surveys study countries that other surveysTHAILANDBOTSWANACOSTA RICAGREECECHILEBELGIUMDENMARKdo not. However, despite thebenefits, aggregated <strong>in</strong>dicatorscannot provide detail on thedesign of underly<strong>in</strong>g regulationsand how to reformthem.Us<strong>in</strong>g aggregation methodologyto study regulatoryquality, the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>Institute’s 2002 regulatoryquality <strong>in</strong>dicator measuresthe <strong>in</strong>cidence of marketunfriendlypolicies, such asprice controls, and perceptionsof the regulatory burden onbus<strong>in</strong>esses. 28 It uses 60<strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>in</strong>dicators fromabout a dozen sources.Countries are ranked by us<strong>in</strong>gpo<strong>in</strong>t estimates, with standarddeviations <strong>in</strong>form<strong>in</strong>g usersabout the precision of the rank<strong>in</strong>g (figure 1.8).The benefits are readily apparent. First, the po<strong>in</strong>testimates have better explanatory power than<strong>in</strong>dividual perception surveys do. For example, theaggregate <strong>in</strong>dicators have much greater power <strong>in</strong> predict<strong>in</strong>gthe share of <strong>in</strong>formal activity across countriesthan the <strong>in</strong>dividual <strong>in</strong>dicators do (compare figure 1.9with figure 1.6). Second, the aggregates also showwhich of the underly<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dicators are most closelyrelated to the composite measure: for example, theregulatory-quality <strong>in</strong>dex shows that the <strong>World</strong>Markets Research Center and the EIU <strong>in</strong>dicators areclosest to the underly<strong>in</strong>g aggregate measure thatrelates more closely to government policies andeconomic outcomes. Third, almost every country canbe covered (the regulatory-quality <strong>in</strong>dex covers 199countries).An aggregate <strong>in</strong>dex of the <strong>in</strong>vestment climate—which <strong>in</strong>cludes regulatory quality, <strong>in</strong>frastructurequality, competition, and macroeconomic stability—has recently been constructed at the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>Group, by us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dicators from 21 databases. 29As with the previous example, an unobservedcomponentsapproach is used to capture the <strong>in</strong>formation


Build<strong>in</strong>g New Indicators of <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> RegulationFigure 1.9Regulatory Quality Is Associated with Less InformalActivityInformal economy, % <strong>in</strong>come per capita706050403020100common to a set of <strong>in</strong>dicators and elim<strong>in</strong>ate theidiosyncratic part of each <strong>in</strong>dicator. The <strong>in</strong>dex ratesthe United States, S<strong>in</strong>gapore, Switzerland, Canada,and the Netherlands as the top five economies fordo<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess. Bangladesh, Haiti, and Mozambiquevie for the lowest rat<strong>in</strong>g.NotesLowRegulatory qualityNote: The correlation shown <strong>in</strong> this figure is statistically significant at the5 percent level when controlled for <strong>in</strong>come per capita.Sources: Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi 2003; Schneider 2002.High1. Petty 1691.2. Meade and Stone 1941. Although presented to theBritish Parliament as a one-off measure, the nationalaccounts quickly became an annual production.3. For <strong>in</strong>stance, one question is whether the numberof procedures <strong>in</strong> debt recovery is correlated acrosscountries with the number of procedures <strong>in</strong> resolv<strong>in</strong>ga (commercial) tenancy dispute. The answer is yes. Forthe countries <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> sample, the simplecorrelation is 0.86. The simple correlation between thenumber of procedures <strong>in</strong> debt recovery equivalent to 5percent and 50 percent of <strong>in</strong>come per capita is 0.94.The high correlations imply that the specific case thatwas chosen is generally representative for other typesof commercial resolution.4. The methodology was developed by Djankov andothers (2002) and adopted with m<strong>in</strong>or changeshere.5. Informal payments are subject to greater measurementerror. Moreover, theoretical models <strong>in</strong> publiceconomics show that bribes are proportional to theseverity of regulatory burden—that is, <strong>in</strong>formalpayments are an outcome of cumbersome regulationsrather than a regulatory obstacle <strong>in</strong> their own right.6. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2002a.7. The methodology was developed by Botero and others(2003) and adopted with m<strong>in</strong>or changes <strong>in</strong> this report.8. The methodology was developed by Djankov andothers (2003) and adopted with m<strong>in</strong>or changes <strong>in</strong> thisreport. The orig<strong>in</strong>al study used two cases: a bouncedcheck of 5 percent of GNI per capita, and a landlordtenantdispute.9. The work on Lat<strong>in</strong> America is summarized <strong>in</strong>Hammergren (2003).10. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2002b, p. 40.11. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2003.12. Djankov, McLiesh, and Shleifer 2003.13. Jentzsch 2003.14. The methodology was developed by La Porta and others(1998) and was adopted with m<strong>in</strong>or changes here.15. Djankov, Hart, and others 2003.16. BERI 2002. User Guide,p.1.17. Batra 2003.18. Batra 2003.19. The Heritage Foundation 2002, p. 74.20. Schneider 2002; Friedman and others 2000; Djankovand others 2002.21. The survey results are available at www.cefir.ru.22. Bertrand and Mulla<strong>in</strong>athan 2002.23. Schwarz, Strack, and Mai 1991.24. Schwarz and others 1985.25. Bishop, Oldendick, and Tuchfarber 1986.26. Cornelius, Porter, and Schwab 2003, p. 38.27. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2002c.28. Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi (2003) use theunobserved-component methodology, which expressessurvey data as a l<strong>in</strong>ear function of the unobservedcommon component, and a disturbance termcaptur<strong>in</strong>g perception errors. The assumptions of themodel ensure that the distribution of the aggregate<strong>in</strong>dicator is normal and that the means and standarddeviations for each country have a natural<strong>in</strong>terpretation. In particular, one can construct a90 percent probability range around the po<strong>in</strong>t estimatewhere the “true” level of the <strong>in</strong>dicator lies.29. See Batra 2003 for a detailed description.15


2Start<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>In The Other Path, Hernando de Soto shows thatthe prohibitively high cost of establish<strong>in</strong>g a bus<strong>in</strong>ess<strong>in</strong> Peru denies economic opportunity to thepoor. In 1983, de Soto’s research team followed allnecessary bureaucratic procedures <strong>in</strong> sett<strong>in</strong>g up aone-employee garment factory <strong>in</strong> the outskirts ofLima. Two hundred and eighty-n<strong>in</strong>e days and $1,231later, the factory could legally start operation. 1 Thecost amounted to three years of wages—not the k<strong>in</strong>dof money the average Peruvian entrepreneur has at hisor her disposal. “When legality is a privilege availableonly to those with political and economic power,those excluded—the poor—have no alternative butillegality,” writes Mario Vargas Llosa <strong>in</strong> the foreword tode Soto’s book.This sentiment is not new. Well <strong>in</strong>to the 19th century,European companies required a state charter or aconcession from the state to be registered, and only therich could afford such. 2 In France, free registration forprivate companies was proclaimed <strong>in</strong> 1791, <strong>in</strong> theaftermath of the revolution. In England, free <strong>in</strong>corporationwas allowed <strong>in</strong> 1844, a consequence ofexpand<strong>in</strong>g the franchise to the middle classes. 3When European corporate law was transplanted toother parts of the world, whether through will<strong>in</strong>gappropriation or through colonization, it affected theformation of bus<strong>in</strong>ess entities. The 1865 CommercialCode <strong>in</strong> Chile, follow<strong>in</strong>g the 1848 Spanish Code,required two separate presidential decrees for company<strong>in</strong>corporation. In contrast, the first Commercial Codeof Colombia, adopted <strong>in</strong> 1853, did not conta<strong>in</strong> therequirement to obta<strong>in</strong> a concession from the state.This departure from the Spanish Code was made <strong>in</strong>the belief that free bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong>corporation is a right. 4The 19th century saw a boom <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>corporation <strong>in</strong> theUnited States, with the passage of general corporatelaws—<strong>in</strong> 1811 <strong>in</strong> New York, 1839 <strong>in</strong> Massachusetts,1844 <strong>in</strong> England, 1849 <strong>in</strong> California, and 1883 <strong>in</strong>Delaware. The ma<strong>in</strong> reasons for the rapid expansionwere the competition among states <strong>in</strong> liberaliz<strong>in</strong>g theircorporate laws and the advent of the railroads. By thelate 19th century, the United States had more limitedliabilitycompanies than all of Europe. 5The <strong>in</strong>corporation of bus<strong>in</strong>ess is beneficial for fourreasons. First, legal entities can outlive their founders.Second, resources are pulled together, as shareholdersjo<strong>in</strong> forces <strong>in</strong> establish<strong>in</strong>g the company’s capital. Third,the formal <strong>in</strong>troduction of limited liability—start<strong>in</strong>gwith the enactment of the Code de Commerce <strong>in</strong>France <strong>in</strong> 1807—reduces the risks of do<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess.In The Wealth of Nations, Adam Smith notes: “These[<strong>in</strong>corporated] companies have been useful for thefirst <strong>in</strong>troduction of some branches of commerce bymak<strong>in</strong>g, at their own expense, an experiment whichthe state might not th<strong>in</strong>k it prudent to make.” 6 Limitedliability gives one the freedom to <strong>in</strong>novate andexperiment without large negative consequences.Fourth, registered bus<strong>in</strong>esses have access to services—provided by public courts or private commercialbanks—that are not available to unregistered firms.In short, the establishment of a legal entity makes everybus<strong>in</strong>ess venture less risky and <strong>in</strong>creases its longevityand its likelihood of success.Two procedures—notification of existence and taxand social security registration—are sufficient forbus<strong>in</strong>ess registration. In reality, all countries imposeadditional requirements. Further, the regulation ofbus<strong>in</strong>ess entry varies systematically across countries.17


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>18Richer countries regulate less. So do countries <strong>in</strong> thecommon-law tradition.In poorer countries, market failures may be moresevere, and therefore may <strong>in</strong>crease the desire tocorrect the failures by regulat<strong>in</strong>g entry. The temptationshould be resisted, for the costs of government <strong>in</strong>efficiencymay outweigh the benefits of stricter regulation.Cumbersome entry regulation is associatedwith less private <strong>in</strong>vestment, higher consumer prices,greater adm<strong>in</strong>istrative corruption, and a larger<strong>in</strong>formal economy. There are no discernible benefits <strong>in</strong>improv<strong>in</strong>g product quality or <strong>in</strong> reduc<strong>in</strong>g undesirableexternalities such as pollution.Governments can go a long way with simplereforms. These <strong>in</strong>clude adopt<strong>in</strong>g better <strong>in</strong>formationand <strong>in</strong>tragovernment communications technology—to <strong>in</strong>form prospective entrepreneurs and to serve as avirtual one-stop shop for bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration.Cutt<strong>in</strong>g unnecessary steps from the entry process,such as notarial certification of all <strong>in</strong>corporationdocuments or registration with the local chamber ofcommerce, <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g s<strong>in</strong>gle registration forms, as<strong>in</strong>gle company identification number, and silentconsent <strong>in</strong> approv<strong>in</strong>g registration (a nonresponseimplies approval) have had enormous success. In theRussian Federation, a 2002 reform transferred all registrationpowers to the State Tax Inspectorate, therebycutt<strong>in</strong>g the number of bus<strong>in</strong>ess entry proceduresfrom 19 to 12. Thanks to a s<strong>in</strong>gle registration form,separate notification to the local registrationchamber, the pension fund, the health fund, the statisticalcommittee, and the social security fund, andapplication of mak<strong>in</strong>g a seal are no longer necessary.Moreover, the registration of the new legal entity andtax registration are merged <strong>in</strong>to one procedure.Reforms that require new legislation <strong>in</strong>clude<strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g a general-objects clause <strong>in</strong> the articles of<strong>in</strong>corporation (which allows a firm to change l<strong>in</strong>es ofbus<strong>in</strong>ess without reregister<strong>in</strong>g), elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g thecapital requirement, and remov<strong>in</strong>g notarial authorizationsand court use from the registration process.Such reforms may be difficult to implement, as theymay face stiff opposition from both judges and thelegal and notarial professions, but their beneficialeffects go far beyond bus<strong>in</strong>ess entry.How Easy Is <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Entry?It takes two procedures, two days, and less than 1percent ofannual <strong>in</strong>come per capita to register aprivate limited-liability company <strong>in</strong> Australia. Itcosts noth<strong>in</strong>g to do the same <strong>in</strong> Denmark, andalmost noth<strong>in</strong>g (about 1 percent of annual <strong>in</strong>comeper capita) <strong>in</strong> Canada, New Zealand, S<strong>in</strong>gapore,Sweden, the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, and the United States.But it takes 18 procedures to start a bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong>Algeria, Bolivia, and Paraguay, and 19 procedures <strong>in</strong>Belarus, Chad, and Colombia. It takes 152 days to doso <strong>in</strong> Brazil, 168 days <strong>in</strong> Indonesia, 198 days <strong>in</strong> theLao PDR, 215 days <strong>in</strong> the Democratic Republic ofCongo, and 203 days <strong>in</strong> Haiti. And it costs more thanthree times per capita <strong>in</strong>come to start a bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong>Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso and Nicaragua, four times <strong>in</strong> Ethiopiaand Niger, and more than five times <strong>in</strong> Cambodia.(In June 2003, the Ethiopian government reducedthe cost of bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration by a quarter.)<strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> entry costs $5,531 <strong>in</strong> Angola (838 percent ofper capita <strong>in</strong>come), $785 <strong>in</strong> the Democratic Republicof Congo (872 percent of per capita <strong>in</strong>come), and$1,817 <strong>in</strong> Sierra Leone (13 times per capita <strong>in</strong>come).Contrast this with $28 <strong>in</strong> New Zealand, $210 <strong>in</strong> theUnited States, $264 <strong>in</strong> the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, and $249<strong>in</strong> S<strong>in</strong>gapore.In Mexico—a country with an <strong>in</strong>come per capita of$5,910—the entrepreneur needs to deposit at least$5,180 to start registration. High capital requirementsare the norm <strong>in</strong> the Middle East—at 17 times the<strong>in</strong>come per capita <strong>in</strong> Yemen, 16 times <strong>in</strong> Saudi Arabia,and 24 times <strong>in</strong> Jordan. Some African countries alsohave high capital requirements: 7 times <strong>in</strong>come percapita <strong>in</strong> Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso, 8 times <strong>in</strong> Niger, 9 times <strong>in</strong>Mauritania, and 18 times <strong>in</strong> Ethiopia. In a third of thesample, there are no capital requirements at all.These numbers show the vast differences <strong>in</strong> thetreatment of new firms across countries. Fourmeasures—the necessary procedures, the associatedtime and cost, and the m<strong>in</strong>imum capitalrequirements—capture various aspects of the registrationprocess.• The number of procedures describes the externalparties that the would-be entrepreneur faces. One can


Start<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>th<strong>in</strong>k of them as tollbooths—at each procedure,the entrepreneur may be stopped. In many countries,at each procedure <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g government officials, abribe may change hands.• The number of days and the official costsassociated with each procedure are easy to<strong>in</strong>terpret: the higher those numbers, the morecumbersome and costly the registration processand the less likely it is that many entrepreneurs willregister bus<strong>in</strong>esses.• The m<strong>in</strong>imum capital requirement is the amount ofcapital that the entrepreneur needs to put <strong>in</strong>to abank account before registration starts. The accountis frozen dur<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess entry and <strong>in</strong> manycountries rema<strong>in</strong>s so until the dissolution of thelegal entity.All entry <strong>in</strong>dicators constructed <strong>in</strong> this chapterdescribe a limited-liability company—not a sole proprietorship,a partnership, a cooperative, a jo<strong>in</strong>t stockcompany, or a corporation. Why? Because privatelimited-liability companies are the most prevalentbus<strong>in</strong>ess form around the world. They are also desirablefor economic reasons. Investors are encouraged toventure <strong>in</strong>to bus<strong>in</strong>ess when the potential losses arelimited to their capital participation. 7Indeed, evidence from 19th-century England,Ireland, and the United States suggests that the <strong>in</strong>troductionof limited liability dramatically <strong>in</strong>creasedthe number of companies seek<strong>in</strong>g registration. 8 Astudy of German companies also shows that limitedliability is associated with larger firm size. 9 Today,limited-liability companies account for more than 55percent of registered bus<strong>in</strong>esses and 90 percent ofoutput <strong>in</strong> OECD countries. 10 Even <strong>in</strong> a transitioneconomy, such as Latvia’s, limited-liability companiesaccount for 62 percent of all registered bus<strong>in</strong>essesand 93 percent of output. 11 Similarly, limited-liabilitycompanies account for 57 percent of privateenterprises <strong>in</strong> Vietnam and more than 70 percent ofoutput.Sometimes, as part of registration, new bus<strong>in</strong>esseshave to acquire zon<strong>in</strong>g permits or licenses, so they are<strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the entry procedures list of the respectivecountries.• In Indonesia, every bus<strong>in</strong>ess needs to apply for atrad<strong>in</strong>g license, a procedure that takes two weeks and,<strong>in</strong> the event the entrepreneur has moved from out oftown,requires a “good conduct” note from the police.• In Ghana, companies are required to obta<strong>in</strong> anenvironmental certificate. The company submitsan application describ<strong>in</strong>g the location, currentzon<strong>in</strong>g classification, processes to be used, andlikely environmental impact. Environmental officialsvisit the site once the application is submitted andfile a detailed report. It takes at least 90 days tofulfill this procedure.• In Jordan, all entrepreneurs must apply for amunicipal vocational license. The application needsto be accompanied by the certificate of companyregistration, the membership certificate <strong>in</strong> thechamber of commerce, an activity approval by theappropriate m<strong>in</strong>istry, a notarized rental contract orownership title of facilities, and a location map.On top of these procedures, some bus<strong>in</strong>esses needpermits and construction approvals, utility connections,and product and process licenses beforethey can commence operations. Although these proceduresare not covered <strong>in</strong> the data here (because theyare not general requirements), they can be significantobstacles for entrepreneurs. In Tanzania, it takes 25separate procedures to acquire all of the necessarypermits and licenses for land and factory use. In thebest case, these procedures take 795 days to fulfill, andthe official cost is $508, or about twice the <strong>in</strong>come percapita. In Mozambique, it takes 34 procedures, 625days, and $11,045, or about 50 times the <strong>in</strong>come percapita, to fulfill all requirements for entry of a newmanufactur<strong>in</strong>g firm. 12Enterprise surveys reveal that entrepreneurs’ perceptionsof the efficiency of the registration processdiffer across regions <strong>in</strong> a country, sometimes dramatically.One reason is that local regulations canaffect start<strong>in</strong>g a bus<strong>in</strong>ess, as <strong>in</strong> Botswana, Brazil, Chile,Colombia, Ecuador, Jordan, Kenya, Malawi, Philipp<strong>in</strong>es,Romania, Tanzania, Uganda, Venezuela, and Zimbabwe.The local enforcement of the national company lawand regulations expla<strong>in</strong>s most differences, as <strong>in</strong> Vietnam,Russia, and Bulgaria. 13 In Vietnam, the 2000 Enterprise19


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>20Figure 2.1Start<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> BelarusCostPercentage of <strong>in</strong>come per capita30 20 10 Procedure 0Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.0 20 1001. Get approval of companyname2. Open temporarybank account3. Notarize documentsand pay registration fee4. Register the bus<strong>in</strong>ess5. Get approval of seal byregistry6. Get approval of seal bypolice7. Prepare a bus<strong>in</strong>ess seal8. Obta<strong>in</strong> a managementcertificate9. Notarize all documents10. Register with Tax Office11. Obta<strong>in</strong> a statistical number12. Obta<strong>in</strong> a company ID13. Register with SocialSecurity Office14. Notarize applicationfor a bank account15. Open regular bank account16. Schedule sanitary <strong>in</strong>spection17. Get standards andmetrology <strong>in</strong>spection18. Get fire <strong>in</strong>spection19. Apply for a bus<strong>in</strong>ess licenseLaw stipulated statutory time limits for all procedures<strong>in</strong> the bus<strong>in</strong>ess entry process, but <strong>in</strong> the spr<strong>in</strong>g of2001 a company <strong>in</strong> Dong Nai prov<strong>in</strong>ce obta<strong>in</strong>ed itsregistration certificate <strong>in</strong> one day, while a company <strong>in</strong>Hanoi took 123 days. At the same time, it took eightdays on average to acquire a company seal <strong>in</strong> Ho ChiM<strong>in</strong>h City but 14 days <strong>in</strong> Hanoi.No government <strong>in</strong> the world lets an entrepreneurregister a new bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong> a s<strong>in</strong>gle procedure, but somecome close. In Canada, the entrepreneur submits thefederal registration form through the onl<strong>in</strong>e ElectronicFil<strong>in</strong>g Center and receives a bus<strong>in</strong>ess number with<strong>in</strong>the hour. With this number, the entrepreneur applieswith the Canadian Customs and Revenue Agency fortax numbers, payroll deductions, and import and exportlicenses. The process isidentical <strong>in</strong> Australia. InDenmark, the entrepreneurTimeDaysalso needs to register the40 60 80 120 m<strong>in</strong>imum capital with abank, while <strong>in</strong> Ireland theentrepreneur needs to order acompany seal.In other countries theprocess is more convoluted(figure 2.1). In Belarus, theentrepreneur needs approvalof the company name fromthe M<strong>in</strong>istry of Justice. Withthis document <strong>in</strong> hand, theentrepreneur opens a temporarybank account <strong>in</strong> thename of the company to beregistered. With the newbank statement, the entrepreneurneeds to visit anotary public, who authorizesall the documents. Thenotarized documents aresubmitted to the state registry.The process doesn’t stopthere. The entrepreneurrequests an <strong>in</strong>spection ofbus<strong>in</strong>ess premises from thelabor m<strong>in</strong>istry—and whilewait<strong>in</strong>g for the <strong>in</strong>spectors to come, prepares acompany seal and takes a course to obta<strong>in</strong> a managementcertificate. The certificate is notarized andregistered with the local police department. When allthe documents are notarized, the entrepreneur visitsthe tax office and the social security office, leavescopies with them, and obta<strong>in</strong>s receipts. He or she isf<strong>in</strong>ally ready to apply for a company identificationnumber and a statistical number.The end of bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration is <strong>in</strong> sight. Theentrepreneur can now notarize the application of aregular bank account, and obta<strong>in</strong> the bank account—then schedule a sanitary <strong>in</strong>spection, a standards andmetrology <strong>in</strong>spection, and a fire <strong>in</strong>spection. When thebus<strong>in</strong>ess passes all <strong>in</strong>spections, the entrepreneur can


Start<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Table 2.1Frequency of Entry Procedures across CountriesPurpose of ProcedurePercent of CountriesTax registration 93Labor registration 87Adm<strong>in</strong>istrative registration 76<strong>Bank</strong> deposit 68Notarization 63Health benefits 62Notice <strong>in</strong> newspaper 36Company seal 38Court registration 32Chamber of Commerce 27Statistical Office 17Environment 12Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.obta<strong>in</strong> a bus<strong>in</strong>ess license. The bus<strong>in</strong>ess can startoperations after 19 procedures, 118 days, and $369 <strong>in</strong>official payments.As mentioned at the outset, two procedures—thenotification of existence and the tax and socialsecurity registration—are sufficient for bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration.Other procedures, such as register<strong>in</strong>g withthe statistical office, obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g environmentalpermits, or register<strong>in</strong>g workers for health benefits(table 2.1), seem to be socially desirable. And stillothers, such as hav<strong>in</strong>g local chambers of commerceapprove the applicant, can limit competition.The purpose of still other procedures is dubious,and economies with heavy regulations of entry displaya bewilder<strong>in</strong>g variety. In Vietnam, founders needed toobta<strong>in</strong> a seal-mak<strong>in</strong>g license from the M<strong>in</strong>istry ofPublic Security and have the seal made by theauthorized seal makers. In the Russian Federation,founders needed (until recently) to visit the SocialPension Fund, the State Fund of Compulsory MedicalInsurance, the State Committee on Statistics, and theSocial Security Fund before obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the commercialregistration certificate. They needed to revisit each ofthose agencies to file a copy of the certificate to get acompany ID from each of them. The procedures wereradically reformed <strong>in</strong> late 2002.Which countries regulate bus<strong>in</strong>ess entry the most?When the countries are divided <strong>in</strong>to groups accord<strong>in</strong>g totheir <strong>in</strong>come per capita, the high-<strong>in</strong>come countries havethe smallest number of procedures, with a median of 7.They are followed by the upper-middle-<strong>in</strong>come group,with a median of 10 procedures. The lower-middle<strong>in</strong>comecountries have the highest number of procedures,around 12, while the poorest countries have amedian of 11 procedures. The time to register acompany is, aga<strong>in</strong>, the shortest <strong>in</strong> the richest countries,at less than one month. Although the registrationprocess takes around the same amount of time—50days—<strong>in</strong> upper-middle- and lower-middle-<strong>in</strong>comecountries, it is significantly higher <strong>in</strong> the poorestcountries, where the median number of days is 63. Incontrast, the cost of start<strong>in</strong>g a bus<strong>in</strong>ess grows monotonicallyfor companies <strong>in</strong> rich countries versus poorcountries. It accounts for less than 10 percent of <strong>in</strong>comeper capita <strong>in</strong> the high-<strong>in</strong>come group, and for an amaz<strong>in</strong>g120 percent <strong>in</strong> low-<strong>in</strong>come countries (figure 2.2).Regional differences are also significant (figure 2.3).Lat<strong>in</strong> American governments regulate bus<strong>in</strong>ess entrythe most <strong>in</strong> terms of procedures and time; they arefollowed by African and Middle Eastern governments.OECD governments regulate the least. The cost of registrationis extremely high <strong>in</strong> African countries—ataround 190 percent of per capita <strong>in</strong>come. Similarly, them<strong>in</strong>imum capital requirements—with a median ofmore than 700 percent of per capita <strong>in</strong>come—aremuch higher <strong>in</strong> the Middle East and North Africa than<strong>in</strong> any other region.Strong patterns emerge by legal orig<strong>in</strong>. 14 Nordiccountries have the smallest number of procedures—amedian of 5—the shortest time, at 21 days, and thelowest cost, at less than 1 percent of per capita <strong>in</strong>come(figure 2.4). Countries <strong>in</strong> the French civil law traditiontake the longest time and have the most procedures andhighest cost. But France itself is a top performer amongFrench-orig<strong>in</strong> countries. Countries <strong>in</strong> the Germantradition have the largest capital requirement, more than100 percent of <strong>in</strong>come per capita, whereas the mediancapital requirement for English-orig<strong>in</strong> countries is zero.How do the entry <strong>in</strong>dicators <strong>in</strong>terrelate? Do governmentschoose one type of entry barrier overanother? For example, very fast bus<strong>in</strong>ess registrationmight be more costly, so that entrepreneurs are <strong>in</strong>effect pay<strong>in</strong>g for better public adm<strong>in</strong>istration. Orgovernments could reduce obstacles by requir<strong>in</strong>g few21


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>22Figure 2.2Rich Countries Have Less Burdensome Entry RegulationsTime, days6040200Figure 2.3OECD Countries Regulate Entry the LeastTime, days806040OECD: High-IncomeSouth AsiaEast Asia& PacificEurope &Central AsiaMiddle East& North AfricaSub-SaharanAfricaLat<strong>in</strong> America& Caribbean200TimeCostRichTimeCostCost, % of <strong>in</strong>come per capitaregistration procedures but allow only the wealthyand well-connected to register, by impos<strong>in</strong>g largem<strong>in</strong>imum capital requirements. This is not the case.Some governments appear to regulate start<strong>in</strong>g abus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong> every way possible—the number of procedures,time, cost, and m<strong>in</strong>imum capital requirementsare highly correlated.Are Entry Regulations Good? Some,Yes—Many, NoM<strong>in</strong>imum capital,% of <strong>in</strong>come per capitaNote: Bars shown <strong>in</strong> these figures represent the median values by regional group.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.Cost, % of <strong>in</strong>come per capitaPoorDo entry regulations, even when seem<strong>in</strong>gly desirable,lead to better outcomes? Unregulated markets exhibit12080400200150100500M<strong>in</strong>imum capital,% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita120804008006004002000RichNote: Bars shown <strong>in</strong> these figures represent the median values by <strong>in</strong>come group.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.OECD: High-IncomeM<strong>in</strong>imum capitalProceduresM<strong>in</strong>imum capitalProceduresSouth AsiaEast Asia& PacificEurope &Central AsiaUppermiddleLowermiddleUppermiddlefrequent failures, rang<strong>in</strong>gfrom monopoly power toexternalities. A governmentNumber ofprocedures that pursues social efficiencymight try to address these1284failures through regulation.The government screens newentrants to ensure thatconsumers buy high-qualityproducts from desirableLowermiddle0Poorsellers and to reduce suchexternalities as pollution.By be<strong>in</strong>g registered, newcompanies acquire a type ofofficial approval, whichmakes them reputable enoughto engage <strong>in</strong> transactionswith the general public andNumber ofprocedures129630other bus<strong>in</strong>esses. If so, stricterregulation of entry shouldbe associated with superiorsocial outcomes.It isn’t. Compliance with<strong>in</strong>ternational quality standardsdecl<strong>in</strong>es as the numberof entry procedures rises,and pollution levels <strong>in</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g countries do notfall with the <strong>in</strong>troductionof environmental permits.Measures of food poison<strong>in</strong>gand job-related accidents arenot lower <strong>in</strong> countries with a higher number ofsanitary and health and safety regulations. 15Entry regulations do have real effects—mostlyunwanted. Cumbersome entry procedures pushentrepreneurs <strong>in</strong>to the <strong>in</strong>formal economy, even aftercontroll<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>in</strong>come per capita (figure 2.5). 16There, workers lack health <strong>in</strong>surance and pensionMiddle East &North AfricaSub-SaharanAfricaLat<strong>in</strong> America& Caribbeanbenefits. Products are not subject to qualitystandards. It is impossible for bus<strong>in</strong>esses to obta<strong>in</strong>bank credit or use courts to resolve disputes. Andemployers cannot use state-provided tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gbudgets for employees and school support for theirchildren.


Start<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Figure 2.4Nordic-Orig<strong>in</strong> Countries Regulate Entry the LeastTime, days6040200Figure 2.5Heavy Entry Regulation Is Associated withInformalityInformal economy, % <strong>in</strong>come per capita5040302010FrenchEnglishGermanCost, % of <strong>in</strong>come per capitaSocialistNordic0Less1 2 3 4 5 MoreCountries ranked by procedures to register a bus<strong>in</strong>ess, qu<strong>in</strong>tilesNote: The correlation shown <strong>in</strong> this figure is statistically significant at the1 percent level when controlled for <strong>in</strong>come per capita.Sources: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database; Schneider 2002.Some developed economies also suffer from excessiveregulation and pay the price. In France, the M<strong>in</strong>istryof Industry adopted the Loi d’Orientation duCommerce et de l’Artisanat <strong>in</strong> 1974, to protect smallshopkeepers and craftsmen aga<strong>in</strong>st competition fromlarger retail stores. The legislation created a zon<strong>in</strong>gpermit requirement, at the discretion of the localmunicipal council. These entry requirements weakenedemployment growth <strong>in</strong> the formal retail sector. If theregulations had not been <strong>in</strong>troduced, the analysis6040200M<strong>in</strong>imum capital,% of <strong>in</strong>come per capitaNote: Bars shown <strong>in</strong> these figures represent the median values by legal-orig<strong>in</strong> group.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.TimeCost12080400FrenchEnglishM<strong>in</strong>imum capitalGermanSocialistNumber ofproceduresProceduresNordic12840implies that employment <strong>in</strong>the French retail sectorwould have been 10 percenthigher today. 17 Anotherstudy suggests that if Italywere to adopt U.S. entryregulations, private <strong>in</strong>vestmentas a share of manufactur<strong>in</strong>goutput wouldrise by an estimated 40percent. 18 Although similarstudies have yet to beconducted <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries, the effects ofentry regulation are thoughtto be of similar magnitude—for two reasons. Distortions are larger (as the datashow), so the deregulation effect is more significant.But regulatory enforcement is not as strong andtherefore this effect is mitigated.Consumers face higher prices <strong>in</strong> developed anddevelop<strong>in</strong>g countries with relatively heavy entry regulations.19 Field studies <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries showthat foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors avoid <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> countrieswith more burdensome regulation, thereby reduc<strong>in</strong>gthe potential welfare benefits to consumers <strong>in</strong> thecountry. 20The unwanted effects go on. Controll<strong>in</strong>g for<strong>in</strong>come per capita, cumbersome entry procedures areassociated with higher corruption <strong>in</strong> the governmentoffices that handle the procedures, particularly <strong>in</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g countries (figure 2.6). Each procedure isa po<strong>in</strong>t of contact—an opportunity to extract abribe. Llosa writes: “Such a regulatory system is notonly immoral but <strong>in</strong>efficient. With<strong>in</strong> it, success doesnot depend on <strong>in</strong>ventiveness and hard work but onthe entrepreneur’s ability to ga<strong>in</strong> sympathy ofpresidents, m<strong>in</strong>isters, and other public functionaries(which usually means his ability to corrupt them).” 21Whether entry regulation is socially desirable canalso be addressed from a different perspective. Ifdemocratic countries regulated more, and if politicians<strong>in</strong> such countries responded to their constituencies, onecould hypothesize that such regulations are beneficialby design. By contrast, authoritarian governments may23


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>24Figure 2.6Cumbersome Entry Regulation Is Associated withCorruptionCorruptionHighLowLess1 2 3 4 5 MoreCountries ranked by procedures to register a bus<strong>in</strong>ess, qu<strong>in</strong>tilesNote: The correlation shown <strong>in</strong> this figure is statistically significant at the1 percent level when controlled for <strong>in</strong>come per capita.Sources: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database; Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi 2003.be more likely to be captured by <strong>in</strong>cumbent firms andto have regulatory systems aimed at maximiz<strong>in</strong>gbribes rather than address<strong>in</strong>g market failures. 22 Thatis why more-representative and more-limited governmentswould regulate entry less. Indeed, a studyon bus<strong>in</strong>ess entry regulations <strong>in</strong> 85 countries f<strong>in</strong>ds,hold<strong>in</strong>g per capita <strong>in</strong>come constant, that countrieswith more-limited governments and greater politicalrights have lighter entry regulation. 23 This result iseven stronger when the analysis is repeated with the<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> sample of 133 countries.In sum, cumbersome entry regulations do not<strong>in</strong>crease the quality of products, make work safer, orreduce pollution. They hold back private <strong>in</strong>vestment.They push more people <strong>in</strong>to the <strong>in</strong>formal economy.They <strong>in</strong>crease consumer prices. And they fuel corruption.Governments that regulate more are lessaccountable to their citizens.What to Reform?With so many examples of successful reform <strong>in</strong> regulat<strong>in</strong>gbus<strong>in</strong>ess entry, there is no better time to act.Indeed, even jurisdictions with efficient bus<strong>in</strong>essregistration procedures have recently updated theirregulations—Denmark <strong>in</strong> 1996, Australia <strong>in</strong> 2001,Norway <strong>in</strong> 1997, New Zealand <strong>in</strong> 1998. As have someothers: Vietnam <strong>in</strong> 1999, Pakistan and the RussianFederation <strong>in</strong> 2002, and Turkey <strong>in</strong> 2003. In contrast,the laws regulat<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration <strong>in</strong> theDom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic date to 1884, <strong>in</strong> Mozambique to1888, <strong>in</strong> Angola to 1901, and <strong>in</strong> Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso to 1916.However, antiquated laws are not always to blame: <strong>in</strong>Sierra Leone, the Legal Practitioners Act of 2000 mademandatory the use of attorneys <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>corporation.This requirement <strong>in</strong> effect doubled the cost ofbus<strong>in</strong>ess registration.Adm<strong>in</strong>istrative ReformOne can start by provid<strong>in</strong>g prospective entrepreneurswith all necessary <strong>in</strong>formation, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the numberand sequence of procedures, their time, and theircost. This will m<strong>in</strong>imize the time lost due to notunderstand<strong>in</strong>g procedures and will reduce thelikelihood of bribes or unofficial padd<strong>in</strong>g of fees. InVenezuela, the relevant <strong>in</strong>formation is available onthe Web, with a graphic presentation of the sequence(http://economia.eluniversal.com/guiad<strong>in</strong>ero/micro3.shtml#). In Spa<strong>in</strong>, s<strong>in</strong>ce 1999, the m<strong>in</strong>istries ofeconomy, f<strong>in</strong>ance, labor, public adm<strong>in</strong>istration, andthe chamber of commerce have an <strong>in</strong>formational Website (www.ipyme.org) for entrepreneurs, show<strong>in</strong>gexactly where and when to go, and what documentsto br<strong>in</strong>g. The site describes the documentation forcomplet<strong>in</strong>g the registration process, and theadditional requirements to start a bus<strong>in</strong>ess. Theassociated fees, stamp duties, and notary costs are alsolisted. Many other countries provide such services,such as Ireland, Latvia, and S<strong>in</strong>gapore. Where Internetusage is still low, the <strong>in</strong>formation can be provided <strong>in</strong>leaflets or posted on the wall of the registry office, asit is <strong>in</strong> Mongolia, South Africa, and Thailand.Other countries have recently adopted new technologiesto improve communication and to share<strong>in</strong>formation among government offices. In 2002, taxoffices around Pakistan were l<strong>in</strong>ked electronically.While it previously took a week for an entrepreneur<strong>in</strong> Karachi to receive a tax registration number, it nowtakes a few hours.Next, regulators can move to a s<strong>in</strong>gle registrationform and a s<strong>in</strong>gle registration number. France moved


Start<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>to a s<strong>in</strong>gle form <strong>in</strong> 1994, F<strong>in</strong>land <strong>in</strong> 2001. 24 Manycountries—such as Croatia, Madagascar, Portugal,Serbia, and Montenegro—require several types offorms to be filed, which can be confus<strong>in</strong>g andsometimes expensive. Countries also require multipleregistration numbers, issued by various governmentagencies. In Ecuador, a new bus<strong>in</strong>ess needs fiveseparate registration numbers: from the super<strong>in</strong>tendentof companies, from the mercantile registry,from the tax office, from the social security <strong>in</strong>stitute,and from the m<strong>in</strong>istry of labor. In contrast, SouthAfrica moved to a s<strong>in</strong>gle company identificationnumber <strong>in</strong> 1998, Belgium <strong>in</strong> 2000, Italy <strong>in</strong> 2001, andMoldova <strong>in</strong> 2002.Adm<strong>in</strong>istrative rules can be revised to allow forstatutory response times, for post<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation onfee schedules, and for silent-consent rules. Fewer thana third of the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> countries have statutoryresponse times. But a recent study of the 2000Enterprise Law <strong>in</strong> Vietnam shows their effectiveness.After the maximum was set at 15 days, the averageresponse time fell from 45 days to 19 days, <strong>in</strong> about ayear. 25 Post<strong>in</strong>g fee schedules helped fight adm<strong>in</strong>istrativecorruption <strong>in</strong> India. Silent consent means thatif entrepreneurs have not heard from the governmentagency with<strong>in</strong> a given number of days, approval isautomatic and they may cont<strong>in</strong>ue to the nextprocedure. A silent-consent rule was just adopted <strong>in</strong>Bulgaria.A more comprehensive reform is to establish a onestopshop for company registration. In 1994, Franceestablished the Centre de Formalite des Entreprises(CFE), a s<strong>in</strong>gle office where entrepreneurs can file allthe declarations and documents needed to set up anew enterprise. The CFE then forwards thedocuments and declarations to the governmentdepartments and courts that must approve or registerthe new bus<strong>in</strong>ess. Similar one-stop shops have beenestablished <strong>in</strong> Thailand (<strong>in</strong> 1997), <strong>in</strong> the Dakahliaregion of Egypt (<strong>in</strong> 1999), and <strong>in</strong> El Salvador (<strong>in</strong>2000). In establish<strong>in</strong>g them, however, governmentsneed to ensure that they dismantle other steps forbus<strong>in</strong>ess registration, to avoid creat<strong>in</strong>g “one-more-stopshops.” In the Philipp<strong>in</strong>es, where a One Stop ActionCenter was established <strong>in</strong> 1987, <strong>in</strong>vestors cont<strong>in</strong>uedto compla<strong>in</strong> about cumbersome procedures anddelays. For some adm<strong>in</strong>istrative requirements, adouble licens<strong>in</strong>g procedure was <strong>in</strong> effect imposed,with the <strong>in</strong>vestors hav<strong>in</strong>g to apply to both the OneStop Action Center and the licens<strong>in</strong>g body. 26 Onesolution is to use an already-exist<strong>in</strong>g governmentagency to process the application for bus<strong>in</strong>ess registrationand forward the <strong>in</strong>formation to otheragencies. Just this k<strong>in</strong>d of reform was adopted <strong>in</strong>Turkey recently. Instead of go<strong>in</strong>g to eight governmentagencies for approvals, the entrepreneursubmits a s<strong>in</strong>gle application to the Trade Registrar.The registration is issued <strong>in</strong> one day.As Internet technology becomes widespread, registrationcan become electronic, through a virtual onestopshop. Several countries already use onl<strong>in</strong>ebus<strong>in</strong>ess or tax registration—Australia, Austria,Canada, Denmark, Hungary, Latvia, New Zealand,and S<strong>in</strong>gapore. Ho Chi M<strong>in</strong>h City <strong>in</strong> Vietnamrecently <strong>in</strong>troduced it as well. In 2001, Italy passed alaw on electronic signatures, allow<strong>in</strong>g entrepreneursto submit documents by e-mail. The trade registraroffice is establish<strong>in</strong>g data transmission l<strong>in</strong>ks withcompanies, notaries, chambers of commerce, andtrade associations. When <strong>in</strong> place, the process willradically reduce the time and cost of register<strong>in</strong>g a newbus<strong>in</strong>ess. Israel, Peru, and Thailand are <strong>in</strong> the midst ofsimilar reforms.Onl<strong>in</strong>e bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration has other benefits. InKorea, Hong Kong (Ch<strong>in</strong>a), Taiwan (Ch<strong>in</strong>a), and theUnited K<strong>in</strong>gdom, anyone may view the register ofcompany names over the Web and confirm that theproposed company name is unique. Entrepreneurs <strong>in</strong>Bolivia can do the same through touch-tone phone,sav<strong>in</strong>g time <strong>in</strong> a potentially long procedure.Legal ReformSeveral legal reforms have produced good results.One is the adoption of a general-objects clause <strong>in</strong> registration,so that entrepreneurs do not need to specifythe precise nature of their bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity. Companylaws <strong>in</strong> all Nordic and common-law countries allowfor such a clause. This not only elim<strong>in</strong>ates the need forcourt <strong>in</strong>volvement—it allows for the <strong>in</strong>stantaneous, ifexpensive, purchase of off-the-shelf companies to25


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>26create a new one. 27 The entrepreneur needs only to goto a lawyer, buy the shell company, and change itsname. The general-objects clause also makes it easierfor companies to reregister. Recent legislation <strong>in</strong>Belarus and Uzbekistan made it necessary for tens ofthousands of companies to reregister, at great cost totheir owners. The process would be automatic if theentrepreneur needed only to confirm cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>gexistence, under a general-objects clause.Comprehensive reform of bus<strong>in</strong>ess entry regulationswould elim<strong>in</strong>ate the capital requirement. Inthe early days of <strong>in</strong>corporat<strong>in</strong>g a bus<strong>in</strong>ess, m<strong>in</strong>imumcapital was required for the privilege of obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>glimited liability. 28 And shareholders paid dearly. The1855 Limited Liability Act <strong>in</strong> England mandated am<strong>in</strong>imum value of shares at £10 and a m<strong>in</strong>imumnumber of shareholders at seven. In today’s money,this would have amounted to $5,265.Some countries still justify capital requirements—as protect<strong>in</strong>g creditors, as protect<strong>in</strong>g the companyaga<strong>in</strong>st <strong>in</strong>solvency, and as protect<strong>in</strong>g the public fromactivities that could reduce social welfare. But thismakes little sense. Why would a highly leveragedcompany that transports radioactive waste have thesame capital requirement as a company that designssoftware? If capital requirements were commensuratewith risks of creditors, shouldn’t they differ acrosssectors? When <strong>in</strong>-k<strong>in</strong>d contributions becomeacceptable, as they are <strong>in</strong> almost all countries, what isthe actual value of m<strong>in</strong>imum capital <strong>in</strong> the event of<strong>in</strong>solvency?In about a dozen countries <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>sample, the capital requirement is a major obstacle tostart<strong>in</strong>g a bus<strong>in</strong>ess (table 2.2). In Japan, more thanhalf of the potential bus<strong>in</strong>ess start-ups are thwarted forlack of m<strong>in</strong>imum capital. 29 Not surpris<strong>in</strong>g, with paid<strong>in</strong>capital at registration amount<strong>in</strong>g to 71 percent of<strong>in</strong>come per capita.The desired direction of reform is to let privatecontracts between debtors and creditors substitute forcapital rules. This is exactly what the 1982 corporatelaw reforms <strong>in</strong> Canada and the 1984 reforms <strong>in</strong> SouthAfrica did. 30The use of notaries for the authorization ofdocuments related to bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration can also beTable 2.2Some Countries Have Prohibitive Capital RequirementsM<strong>in</strong>imum M<strong>in</strong>imum capitalcapitalrequirementrequirement (% of <strong>in</strong>comeCountry (US$) per capita)El Salvador 11,429 549Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso 1,435 652Egypt, Arab Rep. 11,593 789Niger 1,435 844Mali 2,152 897Yemen 8,413 1,717Ethiopia 1,756 1,756Cambodia 5,112 1,826Mongolia 9,006 2,047Jordan 42,313 2,404Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.Figure 2.7Notaries—An Unnecessary BurdenWithout notary38With notary53Time, daysCost, % of <strong>in</strong>come per capitaNote: Bars shown <strong>in</strong> these figures represent median values for countries withand without notary <strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>in</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration. Differences <strong>in</strong> mediansare statistically significant at the 1 percent level for the time measures butsignificant only at the 13 percent level for the cost measure.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.Without notary19With notary26elim<strong>in</strong>ated. Notaries are not part of the registrationprocess <strong>in</strong> Nordic countries, and seldom are <strong>in</strong>common-law countries (only <strong>in</strong> Ethiopia, Sri Lanka,and the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom). In contrast, notaries arealmost always used <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America, French-speak<strong>in</strong>gAfrica, and transition countries (figure 2.7).Where notaries are needed to authorize documents,this is frequently the most expensive part of thecompany registration. In Mexico, notary costs are $875,


Start<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>almost 80 percent of the total costs. In Turkey, notarizationcosts $780, 84 percent of the registration cost.In Guatemala it costs $850, 73 percent; <strong>in</strong> Slovenia,$920, 67 percent; and <strong>in</strong> Angola, $2,800, 51 percent.Why do some countries still have notaries <strong>in</strong>volved<strong>in</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration? It is hard to tell, but historyis replete with examples of <strong>in</strong>stitutions that haveoutlived their usefulness. Notaries were a large part ofItalian trad<strong>in</strong>g relations with foreign partners <strong>in</strong> thetwelfth through fifteenth centuries, particularly <strong>in</strong> theLevant. The Papacy saw a good source of <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>notarial services and made notaries papal adm<strong>in</strong>istrators.Notaries quickly lost their importance <strong>in</strong>England <strong>in</strong> 1534, when Henry VIII broke from theRoman Catholic Church and made it a crim<strong>in</strong>aloffense to apply to the Vatican for a notarialappo<strong>in</strong>tment. In contrast, notaries reta<strong>in</strong>ed their role<strong>in</strong> France, Spa<strong>in</strong>, and Italy. Colonization ensured theirexistence <strong>in</strong> many countries around the world.The service a notary provides—check<strong>in</strong>g the identityof company founders and company officers—isrout<strong>in</strong>ely performed by public adm<strong>in</strong>istrators for manyother services. And clerks at the bus<strong>in</strong>ess registry areas able as notaries to confirm identity.In many developed countries, bus<strong>in</strong>ess registrationis an adm<strong>in</strong>istrative process and the courts take nopart <strong>in</strong> it. But <strong>in</strong> almost all French-speak<strong>in</strong>g Africancountries and <strong>in</strong> most transition countries, bus<strong>in</strong>essentry is a judicial process and court approval isnecessary (figure 2.8). Judicial approval tends to be avery long procedure. In Bulgaria the bus<strong>in</strong>ess registrationprocess takes 30 days, 21 of them spent at thecourt. In Slovenia the court process takes 37 days, and<strong>in</strong> the Czech Republic it takes 45 days.Slovakia is draft<strong>in</strong>g legislation to convert to anadm<strong>in</strong>istrative process. So is Serbia and Montenegro.Reform is not expensive, because the fees from registrationservices cover costs. Evidence of the costeffectivenessof such adm<strong>in</strong>istrative registration isavailable from the 2001 reform <strong>in</strong> Italy and theongo<strong>in</strong>g reform <strong>in</strong> Serbia and Montenegro. The costof sett<strong>in</strong>g up a system of adm<strong>in</strong>istrative registration<strong>in</strong> Serbia and Montenegro is estimated at $1.5million, with annual operat<strong>in</strong>g costs of about $1.1million. Compare this with projected annualFigure 2.8Courts Are Bottlenecksrevenues of $1.8 million from register<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>esses.So the <strong>in</strong>vestment would be paid off fully <strong>in</strong> less thanthree years. 31Legal reforms <strong>in</strong>volve rewrit<strong>in</strong>g the company law,but they would significantly speed up bus<strong>in</strong>ess entryand reduce its costs. They would also free commercialcourts from the large number of registrationand reregistration cases. Instead, commercial judgescould focus on their primary role—resolv<strong>in</strong>gdisputes.The adoption of some or all of these adm<strong>in</strong>istrativeand legal reforms will generate additional entrepreneurialactivity, as <strong>in</strong> Austria after the adoption of the1999 Young Enterprise Law. The law elim<strong>in</strong>ated allregistration-related costs and removed some proceduralburdens. The number of new registrationsshot up from 19,000 a year before 1999 to about26,000 a year after that. In Vietnam, the EnterpriseLaw of January 2000 spurred the creation of 50,000new private enterprises, almost 75 percent of the total.NotesWith court56Without court40 With court32Time, daysNote: Bars shown <strong>in</strong> these figures represent median values for countries withand without court <strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>in</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration. Differences <strong>in</strong> medians arestatistically significant at the 1 percent level for both the time and cost measures.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.Without court23Cost, % of <strong>in</strong>come per capita1. De Soto 1989.2. The first corporations were Egyptian burial societies.Their <strong>in</strong>dependence was founded <strong>in</strong> primeval rights of27


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>28association and respect for the sacred. In Europe thefirst corporations were monastic orders, led by theorder of St. Benedict (480–547). As Benedict<strong>in</strong>emonasteries swept north <strong>in</strong>to Europe from Italy andEast from Ireland, sell<strong>in</strong>g w<strong>in</strong>e, cheeses, brandies, andbreads, they also became the first transnationalcorporations. The proceeds were used to establish andlater <strong>in</strong>corporate universities and libraries. Soon,medieval towns around Northern Europe startedadopt<strong>in</strong>g corporate charters. Corporations took off <strong>in</strong>16th-century England, chartered by the Crown for thepursuit of mercantilist policies, with a designated publicpurpose: to establish ferries, canals, water systems, tollroads, bridges, banks, colleges, and colonial enterprises,such as the East India Trad<strong>in</strong>g Company of 1601 andthe Massachusetts Bay Company of 1628.3. In particular, the 1832 Reform Act gave vot<strong>in</strong>g rights toall men of households with annual revenue of £10.4. Pistor and Berkowitz 2003.5. Berle and Means 1932.6. Adam Smith, The Wealth of Nations, 1776, p. 100,referr<strong>in</strong>g to companies <strong>in</strong>corporated by Royal Charter.7. Diamond 1982.8. Shannon 1931, Blumberg 1996.9. Horvath and Woywode 2003.10. Jacobs 2002. There are three economic arguments forlimited liability: it encourages <strong>in</strong>vestors to take risks, itfacilitates the distribution of risk among corporationsand creditors, and it avoids high litigation costs <strong>in</strong> caseof debt recovery.11. FIAS 2003.12. These numbers are reported <strong>in</strong> table 2.1 <strong>in</strong> Morissetand Neso 2002.13. Trang and others 2001, Zhuravskaya 2003, and FIAS2003.14. The classification of legal orig<strong>in</strong> follows La Porta andothers 1999.15. Djankov and others 2002.16. Friedman and others 2000; Djankov and others 2002;Batra, Kaufmann, and Stone 2003.17. Bertrand and Kramarz 2002.18. Ales<strong>in</strong>a and others 2003.19. Hoekman, Kee, and Olarreaga 2001 f<strong>in</strong>d that a 10 percent<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the number of procedures is associatedwith a 5.8 percent <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> prices <strong>in</strong> countrieswithout liberal trade regimes. Also see Djankov andothers 2002.20. FIAS 2003.21. De Soto 1989, p. XVII.22. Olson 1991, DeLong and Shleifer 1993.23. Djankov and others 2002.24. European Commission 2002.25. Trang and others 2001.26. Sader 2002.27. Buy<strong>in</strong>g an off-the-shelf company is a long-stand<strong>in</strong>gpractice: it had become common to buy chartersfrom moribund companies dur<strong>in</strong>g the economicboom that followed the Revolution <strong>in</strong> 1688 <strong>in</strong>England.28. Corporate capital was regarded as a trust fund toprotect creditors. In the United States, this view wasformulated <strong>in</strong> Wood vs. Dummer <strong>in</strong> 1824 (Wood vs.Dummer, 3 Mason 308, Fed. Case No. 17,944, 1924).29. Japanese Association of Small <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>es 1999.30. Jordan 1996.31. Jacobs 2002.


3 Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersDur<strong>in</strong>g the Industrial Revolution <strong>in</strong> Brita<strong>in</strong>,women received one-third to one-half thewage of men. One scholar of that periodwrites: “Employers did not offer a liv<strong>in</strong>gwage to the female s<strong>in</strong>ce they assumed that she wasdependent upon a household headed by a male andtherefore did not depend only on her wages for subsistence.”1 About one hundred years later, <strong>in</strong> 1882, afactory <strong>in</strong>spector describes employment relations <strong>in</strong>Russia: “The owner is an absolute sovereign. He is nottied by any law, and often applies and <strong>in</strong>terpretsexist<strong>in</strong>g legal regulations at his own discretion. Theworkers must obey him.” 2 A third example comesfrom Zimbabwe, where, before <strong>in</strong>dependence <strong>in</strong> 1980,Africans did not benefit from m<strong>in</strong>imum-wage legislation,were discrim<strong>in</strong>ated aga<strong>in</strong>st <strong>in</strong> appo<strong>in</strong>tments toskilled jobs, and were barred from tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g programs. 3Regulation can change that.Employment law protects workers from arbitrary,unfair, or discrim<strong>in</strong>atory actions by their employers.Regulations—from mandatory m<strong>in</strong>imum wage topremiums for overtime work to grounds for dismissalto severance pay—have been <strong>in</strong>troduced as a responseto apparent market failures. The failures range fromthe exploitation of workers <strong>in</strong> one-company towns todiscrim<strong>in</strong>ation on the basis of gender, race, or age tothe suffer<strong>in</strong>g of the unemployed <strong>in</strong> the GreatDepression and <strong>in</strong> the transition of formerly socialisteconomies.More recent concern for social justice, particularly <strong>in</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, led the International Labor Organizationto establish a set of fundamental pr<strong>in</strong>ciples andrights at work. They <strong>in</strong>clude the freedom of association,the right to collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g, the elim<strong>in</strong>ation offorced labor, the abolition of child labor, and the elim<strong>in</strong>ationof discrim<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>in</strong> hir<strong>in</strong>g and work practices. 4They constitute the m<strong>in</strong>imum regulation necessary forthe effective function<strong>in</strong>g of labor markets. 5 Every countryneeds to adopt and enforce them.However, if regulation <strong>in</strong> other aspects of theemployment relation is too rigid, it lowers labor forceparticipation, <strong>in</strong>creases unemployment, and forcesworkers <strong>in</strong>to the <strong>in</strong>formal economy. Economicanalysis shows that if the average Lat<strong>in</strong> Americancountry were to reduce its employment protection tothe level found <strong>in</strong> the United States, estimated totalemployment would rise by almost six percentagepo<strong>in</strong>ts. 6 In some countries, the negative effects of rigidemployment regulation are even larger. A 10 percent<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> dismissal costs <strong>in</strong> Peru is associated withan estimated <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> long-term unemployment of11 percent, 7 and <strong>in</strong> India and Zimbabwe of about20 percent. 8Disadvantaged groups are hurt the most. Evidencefrom Argent<strong>in</strong>a, Chile, Colombia, France, the RussianFederation, Spa<strong>in</strong>, and Tunisia shows that newentrants <strong>in</strong>to the labor market—women andyouths—suffer disproportionately the consequencesof reduced employment opportunities. 9 As a result,many women and teenagers either rema<strong>in</strong>unemployed or f<strong>in</strong>d employment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formaleconomy. In Côte d’Ivoire, 73.3 percent of <strong>in</strong>formalemployees are women; <strong>in</strong> Uganda, 80.5 percent; <strong>in</strong>Peru, 57.5 percent. 10 Cross-country analyses suggestthat if Mozambique were to reduce its labor regulationsto the level found <strong>in</strong> Zambia, the share of<strong>in</strong>formal employment might drop by as much as 13.5percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts, and the share of <strong>in</strong>formal29


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>30employment of women might drop by 18 percentagepo<strong>in</strong>ts. 11Rigid employment regulation is associated withmore poverty <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries. A study ofIndia suggests that, between 1958 and 1990, poverty <strong>in</strong>West Bengal, the Indian state with the highest labor protection,<strong>in</strong>creased by 10 percent as employment opportunitieswere denied to poor people. 12 Almost 2 millionurban poor people would have found jobs <strong>in</strong> WestBengal if the state government had not passed stricterregulation on dismissals and work hours. In contrast,the government of Andra Pradesh, another Indianstate, made employment regulation more flexible <strong>in</strong>the 1980s: 1.8 million urban poor found jobs <strong>in</strong> manufactur<strong>in</strong>gand service companies <strong>in</strong> the next decade.Improv<strong>in</strong>g the flexibility of employment lawwhile ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g fundamental workers’ rightsrequires several reforms. Among them, <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>gpart-time and fixed-term employment contracts,reduc<strong>in</strong>g the m<strong>in</strong>imum wage for young workers, andallow<strong>in</strong>g for shift<strong>in</strong>g the work time between periodsof slow demand and peak times have proven successful<strong>in</strong> several countries. Other possible reformsfor countries with greater adm<strong>in</strong>istrative capacity<strong>in</strong>clude provid<strong>in</strong>g unemployment benefits to workers<strong>in</strong> times of low demand (short-time compensation)and us<strong>in</strong>g a negative <strong>in</strong>come tax <strong>in</strong> place of am<strong>in</strong>imum wage.What Is Employment Regulation?Employment regulation is one of four bodies of laborlaw:• Employment regulation• Social security laws• Industrial relations• Workplace safety.This chapter is limited to employment regulation.Next year’s report will provide analysis of socialsecurity laws, and the report <strong>in</strong> the year after will study<strong>in</strong>dustrial relations and workplace safety regulation.Employment regulation governs the <strong>in</strong>dividualemployment contract, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g flexibility of hir<strong>in</strong>gthrough part-time and fixed-term contracts; andconditions of employment, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g maximumnumber of hours <strong>in</strong> a work week, premiums forovertime work, paid annual leave, and a m<strong>in</strong>imumwage. It also governs flexibility of fir<strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>ggrounds for dismissal, notification rules for dismissal,priority rules for dismissal, and severance pay.Social security laws govern the social response toneeds and conditions that have a significant impacton workers’ quality of life, such as old age, disability,death, unemployment, and maternity. Social securitylaws are present <strong>in</strong> developed countries but stillnascent elsewhere. 13Industrial-relations laws regulate the barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g,adoption, and enforcement of collective agreements;the organization of trade unions; and <strong>in</strong>dustrial actionby workers and employers.Workplace safety covers the work<strong>in</strong>g environmentand tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g of workers for the use of mach<strong>in</strong>ery andequipment, as well as the regulation of productionprocesses or materials that are hazardous to workers’health. Workplace safety regulation has beneficialeffects for both workers and bus<strong>in</strong>esses. 14Employment regulation is fairly new, establishedafter <strong>World</strong> War II <strong>in</strong> many advanced economies. Inthe aftermath of the 1973 oil shock, many developedcountries tightened employment laws, especially <strong>in</strong>the area of collective dismissals. S<strong>in</strong>ce then, regulationhas been cont<strong>in</strong>ually undergo<strong>in</strong>g reform—everydeveloped country except the United States has mademajor revisions to its labor regulation s<strong>in</strong>ce 1990. InMay 2003, the German government announcedreforms to reduce unemployment. The ma<strong>in</strong> proposalswould make dismissals easier and reduce the timeunemployed people are allowed to receive benefits.The reform will also make fixed-term contracts moreattractive to small-bus<strong>in</strong>ess owners.Flexibility of Hir<strong>in</strong>gThe first area of employment regulation addressed <strong>in</strong>this chapter is hir<strong>in</strong>g by means of part-time andfixed-term contracts. Part-time contracts haveproven popular <strong>in</strong> recent reforms. Employees whovalue flexible work schedules—especially youngerpeople cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g their education, women withchildren, and older people who work to supplement


Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersFigure 3.1Use of Fixed-Term Labor Contracts% of fixed-term <strong>in</strong> total contracts2520151050IrelandAustriaSource: OECD 1999.NorwaySwedenF<strong>in</strong>landPortugalAustraliatheir <strong>in</strong>come—have been the ma<strong>in</strong> beneficiaries. Bymid-2003 every country <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> sampleallowed part-time contracts. Some countries—<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g France, Japan, Namibia, and Romania—exempt part-time employment from carry<strong>in</strong>g themandatory benefits of full-time workers. Part-timecontracts are also easier to term<strong>in</strong>ate. These twofeatures make it attractive for bus<strong>in</strong>esses to hire parttimeworkers. In many OECD countries, where dataon labor contracts are available, roughly a quarter ofthe workforce has part-time jobs: the Netherlands(30 percent), Australia (27 percent), Norway (27percent), Switzerland (26 percent), New Zealand (24percent), and the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom (23 percent). 15 InAustralia, teenagers make up a large share of thepart-time workforce, work<strong>in</strong>g under so-called casualcontracts.Fixed-term contracts ease the entry for newemployees. They were established <strong>in</strong> France <strong>in</strong> 1979,to be used for the replacement of employees on leave,temporary <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> activity, and seasonal activities,as well as <strong>in</strong> contracts for disadvantaged groups suchas youths and women. 16 By 1999, 10 percent of theworkforce <strong>in</strong> France had such contracts. Spa<strong>in</strong>adopted revisions to its labor code <strong>in</strong> the mid-1980sto allow for part-time and fixed-term contracts; by 1999,almost 30 percent of workers, primarily first-timeentrants <strong>in</strong> the labor market, had such contracts.The 1996 revision of the labor code <strong>in</strong> Tunisia<strong>in</strong>troduced fixed-term contracts, and by 2001 about15 percent of the labor force had them. 17 Othercountries with high rates of fixed-term contracts areAustralia, F<strong>in</strong>land, Portugal, and Sweden (figure 3.1).Many countries allow fixed-term contracts only forspecific tasks. This is true for most Lat<strong>in</strong> Americancountries—such as Argent<strong>in</strong>a, Bolivia, Brazil, Guatemala,Mexico, Panama, Uruguay, and Venezuela—and forsouthern Europe—France, Greece, Italy, Portugal,and Spa<strong>in</strong>. Chile, Japan, Mexico, and Sweden limit theduration of fixed-term contracts to one year, butmany former socialist countries allow fixed-termcontracts of up to five years. Poland does not regulatethe duration of fixed-term contracts. Nor doAustralia, New Zealand, South Africa, the UnitedK<strong>in</strong>gdom, or Zambia.Conditions of EmploymentThe legal provisions for conditions of employmentcover flexibility <strong>in</strong> work<strong>in</strong>g time requirements,mandatory payment for non–work<strong>in</strong>g days (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>gpaid annual leave and holidays), and m<strong>in</strong>imum-wagelegislation. In countries with a common-law tradition,substantial aspects of the employment relation areleft to the <strong>in</strong>dividual agreement between the workerand manager.Kenya, Oman, S<strong>in</strong>gapore, Slovenia, Thailand, andthe United States, among others, impose no regulationregard<strong>in</strong>g daily rest. However, it is legislatedat a m<strong>in</strong>imum of 14 hours <strong>in</strong> Chile, Colombia,Ethiopia, Panama, and Syria. With the exception ofNew Zealand, all countries regulate the number ofwork hours. Botswana, Chile, Costa Rica, Ireland,Malaysia, Morocco, and Vietnam all allow a 48-hourworkweek. France has the shortest workweek, at 35hours, followed by Denmark, with 37 hours. Nightwork is generally allowed <strong>in</strong> most countries, exceptAlbania, Belarus, Mozambique, Norway, Turkey, andUruguay. Work on holidays is not subject to any regulation<strong>in</strong> Denmark, Hong Kong (Ch<strong>in</strong>a), Latvia,Malaysia, S<strong>in</strong>gapore, and Tunisia. However, holidaywork is strictly regulated <strong>in</strong> countries with a Germanlegal tradition, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g Austria, Germany, andSwitzerland.31


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>Figure 3.2Premiums for Overtime Work—from Noth<strong>in</strong>gto DoubleOvertime premium, %10080604020Figure 3.3How High Is the M<strong>in</strong>imum WageRatio of m<strong>in</strong>imum to average wage10.80.60.40.20New ZealandGhanaAlbaniaSloveniaBoliviaTunisiaBelarusNicaragua0VenezuelaEl SalvadorHondurasPortugalSpa<strong>in</strong>BoliviaRussianFederationSource: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.Source: Maloney and Nunez 2000.32In cyclical or seasonal <strong>in</strong>dustries, overtime work isoften used. Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso, Cameroon, Jamaica, HongKong (Ch<strong>in</strong>a), New Zealand, Spa<strong>in</strong>, and the UnitedK<strong>in</strong>gdom do not have regulations on a premium forovertime work. Chad, Italy, and Mali require a 10percent premium over wages paid for work <strong>in</strong> normalhours. Bangladesh, Belarus, India, Mexico, Nicaragua,Pakistan, Uruguay, and Uzbekistan mandate up todouble pay for overtime work (figure 3.2). SomeCentral European countries recently revisedemployment regulation to allow managers to shift worktime from periods of slow demand to peak periods. InPoland, such shifts must balance out with<strong>in</strong> six months;<strong>in</strong> Hungary, with<strong>in</strong> a year. Such reforms elim<strong>in</strong>ate theuncerta<strong>in</strong>ty of spend<strong>in</strong>g longer hours at work foremployees, while reduc<strong>in</strong>g the costs of unpredictable orcyclical demand—and overtime pay—for bus<strong>in</strong>esses.The United States leaves it to <strong>in</strong>dividual or collectiveworker contracts to agree on the number ofdays of paid annual leave. In all other countries, theduration of annual leave is subject to regulation. Themost generous annual leave is mandated <strong>in</strong> SierraLeone (39 days), followed by Congo Republic (35days); Ethiopia (33 days); Chad, Côte d’Ivoire, andNiger (32 days); and Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso, Egypt, F<strong>in</strong>land,Nicaragua, and Yemen (30 days).Several OECD countries—Austria, Denmark,F<strong>in</strong>land, Italy, Norway, Sweden, and Switzerland—haveno mandatory m<strong>in</strong>imum wage. In some countries,like Austria, this is the result of a long social partnershipamong labor unions, bus<strong>in</strong>ess associations,and the government. Regulation would be redundant.In countries that regulate m<strong>in</strong>imum wages, the ratioof m<strong>in</strong>imum to average wages varies from 0.82 <strong>in</strong>Venezuela to 0.05 <strong>in</strong> the Russian Federation (figure 3.3).If this ratio is high, bus<strong>in</strong>esses are unwill<strong>in</strong>g to hireless experienced workers, discrim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g aga<strong>in</strong>st youthsor mothers return<strong>in</strong>g after maternity leave, who havebeen out of the workforce for some time. Onepromis<strong>in</strong>g reform is to enforce a lower m<strong>in</strong>imumwage for younger workers, as established <strong>in</strong> Chile <strong>in</strong>1989, generat<strong>in</strong>g a significant <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> job opportunitiesfor recent graduates. The <strong>in</strong>troduction ofsimilar apprentice wage laws was a common reform<strong>in</strong> other Lat<strong>in</strong> American countries <strong>in</strong> the 1990s. 18Flexibility of Fir<strong>in</strong>gFlexibility of fir<strong>in</strong>g encompasses grounds fordismissal, procedures for dismissal, notice periods,and severance payments. The rules on grounds fordismissal vary from “contract at will”—as <strong>in</strong> Ghana,Israel, and the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, where theemployment relation may be term<strong>in</strong>ated by eitherparty at any time—to allow<strong>in</strong>g term<strong>in</strong>ation ofcontracts under a narrow list of “fair” causes such asredundancy—as <strong>in</strong> France—to not consider<strong>in</strong>g


Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g Workersredundancy as a fair cause for dismissal—as <strong>in</strong> Bolivia,the Republic of Korea (before 1998), and Portugal.The 1998 reforms of employment regulation <strong>in</strong> theRepublic of Korea allowed for dismissal on thegrounds of redundancy or economic restructur<strong>in</strong>g.The procedures for dismissal often require notificationor even approval by unions, workers councils,the public employment service, a labor <strong>in</strong>spector, or ajudge. Some countries also mandate retra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g andreassignment to another job <strong>in</strong> the enterprise—andestablish priority rules for dismissal or re-employmentof redundant workers. In Tunisia, companies mustnotify the labor <strong>in</strong>spector of planned dismissals <strong>in</strong>writ<strong>in</strong>g one month ahead, <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g the reasons andthe workers affected. The <strong>in</strong>spector may propose alternativesto layoffs. If these proposals are not acceptedby the employer, the case goes to the regional tripartitecommittee comprised of the labor <strong>in</strong>spector, theemployer organization, and the labor union. Thecommittee decides by a majority vote (if the <strong>in</strong>spectorand union reject the proposal, no dismissal is possible).It may also suggest retra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g, reduced hours, or earlyretirement. Only 14 percent of dismissals end upbe<strong>in</strong>g accepted. As a result, annual layoffs are less than1 percent of the workforce, compared with more than10 percent <strong>in</strong> the average OECD country.Even if employers are permitted to dismiss workers,regulations may impose notice periods and severancepayments (figure 3.4). In Croatia, employers need toFigure 3.4Severance Payments—from Noth<strong>in</strong>g to 20Months’ PayNumber of months of full salary paid20151050AustraliaDenmarkArmeniaSource: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.VietnamIndonesiaSaudi ArabiaBoliviaGuatemalagive workers three months’ advance notice and paysix monthly salaries <strong>in</strong> severance for employees withtenure <strong>in</strong> the bus<strong>in</strong>ess of more than 20 years.Often workers feel unjustly dismissed or may notreceive sufficient compensation. One recourse is tofile a lawsuit aga<strong>in</strong>st their employers. In manycountries, such disputes are handled by specializedlabor courts or tribunals. Until recently, representativesof employee and employer organizations frequentlysat on the jury, alongside professionaljudges. This practice has often led to protractedjudicial procedures and difficulties <strong>in</strong> reach<strong>in</strong>g compromise.In Brazil, prior to 1999, an equal numberof representatives from labor unions and bus<strong>in</strong>essassociations served as judges on the Labor ConciliationBoard, the regional labor courts, and thesupreme labor court. The average labor dispute tookalmost three years. 19 In 1999 this practice wasabolished and only professional lawyers couldbecome labor judges. Also, judges were givenlifelong tenure, which reduced their susceptibility topolitical pressure. By 2001, the time needed toresolve disputes was halved.Large Divergences <strong>in</strong> PracticeEmployment regulation is an area of great divergenceamong developed countries. A comparison of NewZealand and Portugal, two OECD members withsimilar <strong>in</strong>come per capita, illustrates the differences <strong>in</strong>regulatory scope.• Fixed-term contracts may be entered <strong>in</strong>to <strong>in</strong> NewZealand for any reason, and no maximum durationis prescribed by law. In Portugal, such contracts areallowed only for specific tasks, such as substitutionfor another worker or seasonal activity, and aretemporary.• Work<strong>in</strong>g times and leave times <strong>in</strong> New Zealand areregulated by collective barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and <strong>in</strong>dividualemployment contracts. In Portugal, the constitutionregulates work and leave times, remuneration, andwork<strong>in</strong>g conditions.• New Zealand mandates no premium for overtimework. There are no restrictions on night work, andpaid annual leave is 15 days. In Portugal, the33


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>34premium for overtime work ranges from 50percent to 75 percent. There are restrictions onnight work, and paid annual leave is 24 days.• New Zealand allows “contracts at will,” which canbe term<strong>in</strong>ated with notice by either party. Portugalhas a public policy list of fair grounds for dismissal,mandatory early notice, and priority rules for reemploymentof redundant workers.• In New Zealand “reasonable notice,” usually oneweek, is required to dismiss a worker, and there isno regulation on the amount of severance pay. InPortugal, the standard dismissal notice is 60 days,and the severance pay for workers with 20 years oftenure is mandated by the law to be 20 months ofwages.The transplantation of employment laws dur<strong>in</strong>gcolonial days created stark differences betweendevelop<strong>in</strong>g countries as well.• In Ghana, a common-law jurisdiction, fixed-termcontracts are allowed for any reason, and there isno maximum duration. In Mozambique, a formerPortuguese colony with a similar <strong>in</strong>come percapita, fixed-term contracts are allowed only forseasonal activities.• In Ghana, leave and remuneration are negotiated<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dividual employment contracts. InMozambique, the constitution regulates them, withm<strong>in</strong>imum annual leave of 22 days.• Ghana allows contracts at will. Mozambique’s laborcode lists fair grounds for dismissal and imposesstr<strong>in</strong>gent procedural limitations, such as mandatorynotification of the government and priority rules forre-employment of redundant workers.• Labor regulation <strong>in</strong> Ghana imposes no severancepayment for dismissal. In Mozambique, the lengthof notice is regulated at 12 weeks, and the severancepayment for a worker with 20 years of experience is30 months of wages.To document the systematic differences <strong>in</strong>employment regulation across countries, three <strong>in</strong>diceswere constructed by study<strong>in</strong>g the letter of the lawand conduct<strong>in</strong>g surveys of labor lawyers <strong>in</strong> eachcountry (table 3.1). The methodology is simple: if theregulation restricts the ability of managers andworkers to negotiate the employment contract, avalue of 100 is entered, zero otherwise. For example,fixed-term contracts are allowed <strong>in</strong> Venezuela onlyfor temporary tasks, while <strong>in</strong> Vietnam they areallowed for any task. On this component of the hir<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>dex, Venezuela gets a 100, Vietnam a 0. Similarly,managers have to give fair cause for dismissal <strong>in</strong>Cameroon, but not <strong>in</strong> Jamaica. On this component ofthe flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex, Cameroon gets a 100,Jamaica a 0. The scores are averaged across the componentsof each <strong>in</strong>dex to get the value of the <strong>in</strong>dexitself. 20 Table 3.1 details the components of each <strong>in</strong>dex(flexibility of hir<strong>in</strong>g, conditions of employment, andflexibility of fir<strong>in</strong>g). Averag<strong>in</strong>g across these three<strong>in</strong>dices yields the <strong>in</strong>dex of employment regulation,where higher values represent more rigidity <strong>in</strong>employment regulation.Employment regulation is more flexible <strong>in</strong>developed countries. Austria, Denmark, Hong Kong(Ch<strong>in</strong>a), New Zealand, S<strong>in</strong>gapore, the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom,the United States, and New Zealand are among the 10countries with the most flexible employment protection(table 3.2). Malaysia, Papua New Gu<strong>in</strong>ea, andZimbabwe are also <strong>in</strong> this group. The countries withthe most rigid employment regulation <strong>in</strong>clude sixLat<strong>in</strong> American countries (Brazil, Mexico, Panama,Paraguay, Peru, and Venezuela), and Angola, Belarus,Mozambique, and Portugal.Some countries have very strong protection <strong>in</strong> oneof the <strong>in</strong>dices but not <strong>in</strong> others. Greece, Taiwan(Ch<strong>in</strong>a), and Tunisia restrict the use of fixed-termcontracts. Hungary and Poland are among thecountries with the most regulation on conditions ofemployment. Belarus, Mexico, and Peru have strictregulations on fir<strong>in</strong>g. In general, however, the <strong>in</strong>dicatorsof labor regulation tend to move together: restrictionson hir<strong>in</strong>g go with restrictions on fir<strong>in</strong>g (figure 3.5),as well as with more rigid conditions of employment.Which groups of countries have the most flexibleregulation? Rich countries have the lowest averagescores on all <strong>in</strong>dices (figure 3.5). Nordic-orig<strong>in</strong> countriesregulate employment relations the least <strong>in</strong> conditionsof employment but less so <strong>in</strong> dismissals, <strong>in</strong> which


Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersTable 3.1Rigidities <strong>in</strong> Employment RegulationHir<strong>in</strong>gConditions ofemploymentFir<strong>in</strong>gPart-time contractsFixed-term contractsHours of workLeavesM<strong>in</strong>imum wageGrounds for fir<strong>in</strong>gFir<strong>in</strong>g proceduresNotice and severancepaymentJob securityIs part-time employment prohibited?Are part-time workers exempt from mandatory benefits of full-time workers?Is it easier or less costly to term<strong>in</strong>ate part-time workers than full-time workers?Are fixed-term contracts allowed only for fixed-term tasks?What is the maximum duration of fixed-term contracts (<strong>in</strong> months)?What is the mandatory m<strong>in</strong>imum daily rest?What is the maximum number of hours <strong>in</strong> a workweek?What is the premium for overtime work?Are there restrictions on night work?Are there restrictions on weekly holiday work?What is the number of legally mandated days of annual leave with pay <strong>in</strong> manufactur<strong>in</strong>g?Is paid time off for holidays mandatory?Is there a mandatory m<strong>in</strong>imum wage?Are conditions of employment specified <strong>in</strong> the constitution?Is it unfair to term<strong>in</strong>ate the employment contract without cause?Does the law establish a public policy list of “fair” grounds for dismissal?Is redundancy considered a fair ground for dismissal?Must the employer notify a third party before dismiss<strong>in</strong>g one redundant employee?Does the employer need the approval of a third party to dismiss one redundant worker?Must the employer notify a third party before a collective dismissal?Does the employer need the approval of a third party before a collective dismissal?Does the law mandate retra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g or replacement prior to dismissal?Are there priority rules apply<strong>in</strong>g to dismissal or layoffs?Are there priority rules apply<strong>in</strong>g to re-employment?What is the legally mandated notice period (<strong>in</strong> weeks) after 20 years?What is the severance pay as a number of months for which full wages are payable aftercovered employment of 20 years?Is the right to job security specified <strong>in</strong> the constitution?35Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.English-orig<strong>in</strong> countries have the lightest regulation.Across regions, East Asian economies regulate the leastand Lat<strong>in</strong> American countries the most, even after thesignificant labor reforms <strong>in</strong> the 1990s. This result isconsistent with previous studies. For example, <strong>in</strong> 1999the cost of fir<strong>in</strong>g a full-time worker was equivalent to93 days of wages <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America, twice the 45 days <strong>in</strong>the OECD. 21 Countries <strong>in</strong> the socialist legal traditionhave the second-strictest labor regulation.What Are the Effects of Employment Regulation?The fact that employment regulation arose <strong>in</strong> responseto market failures does not mean that today’s regulationsare optimal. Their design may have been poorto beg<strong>in</strong> with. And what was appropriate <strong>in</strong>, say, 1933,when Portugal adopted its constitutional protectionsof workers, may not be appropriate today, becausecircumstances, technology, and bus<strong>in</strong>ess organizationhave changed.Indeed, although employment regulation generally<strong>in</strong>creases the tenure and wages of <strong>in</strong>cumbent workers,strict regulatory <strong>in</strong>tervention has many undesirableside effects. The first is to limit job creation. Quarterlyjob creation <strong>in</strong> Portugal, the most heavily regulatedlabor market <strong>in</strong> the sample, is 59 percent of that <strong>in</strong> theUnited States, one of the ten least regulated labormarkets. With fewer new jobs available, Portugueseworkers stay <strong>in</strong> jobs they do not like. 22 Conversely, therelaxation of labor regulation <strong>in</strong> the United States


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>Table 3.2Indexes on Employment RegulationFlexibility of hir<strong>in</strong>g Conditions of employment Flexibility of fir<strong>in</strong>g Employment lawsMost-flexible regulationCh<strong>in</strong>a 17 Hong Kong (Ch<strong>in</strong>a) 22 Hong Kong (Ch<strong>in</strong>a) 1 S<strong>in</strong>gapore 20Czech Republic 17 Zimbabwe 22 S<strong>in</strong>gapore 1 United States 22Namibia 17 Denmark 25 Uruguay 3 Malaysia 25Nigeria 17 Malaysia 26 Papua New Gu<strong>in</strong>ea 4 Denmark 25Papua New Gu<strong>in</strong>ea 17 S<strong>in</strong>gapore 26 United States 5 Papua New Gu<strong>in</strong>ea 26Australia 33 United States 29 Japan 9 Hong Kong (Ch<strong>in</strong>a) 27Canada 33 South Africa 36 United K<strong>in</strong>gdom 9 Zimbabwe 27Denmark 33 Sweden 39 Australia 13 United K<strong>in</strong>gdom 28Poland 33 Norway 39 Austria 14 Austria 30Uganda 33 Kuwait 40 Malaysia 15 New Zealand 32Least-flexible regulation36Brazil 78 Nicaragua 90 Brazil 68 Paraguay 73Chad 78 Mongolia 90 Panama 68 Peru 73Greece 78 Paraguay 90 Peru 69 Mozambique 74Gu<strong>in</strong>ea 78 Turkey 91 Ukra<strong>in</strong>e 69 Venezuela, RB 75Thailand 78 Poland 92 Mexico 70 Belarus 77Venezuela, RB 78 Hungary 92 Belarus 71 Mexico 77El Salvador 81 Ukra<strong>in</strong>e 93 Russian Federation 71 Angola 78Mexico 81 Chad 93 Paraguay 71 Brazil 78Panama 81 Rwanda 94 Portugal 73 Portugal 79Taiwan (Ch<strong>in</strong>a) 81 Bolivia 95 Angola 74 Panama 79Note: Indexes range from 0 to 100, with higher values <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g more-rigid regulation.The employment-laws <strong>in</strong>dex is the average of the flexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g, conditions-of-employment,and flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dexes.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.s<strong>in</strong>ce the 1950s has helped <strong>in</strong>crease new employmentopportunities by as much as 150 percent. 23 When aPortuguese bus<strong>in</strong>ess decreases employment, it is 40percent less likely to <strong>in</strong>crease it when the economypicks up than a U.S. company is. This result is corroboratedby other studies that show jobless recoveries<strong>in</strong> economies with heavily regulated labor markets. 24It means that some workers rema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> perennialunemployment.A second effect is to reduce the flexibility of theworkforce: workers who have endured long unemploymentspells tend to have obsolete skills. Unemploymentduration is three times higher <strong>in</strong> Portugalthan it is <strong>in</strong> the United States, and more than twice ashigh <strong>in</strong> Brazil and Spa<strong>in</strong>, two other heavily regulatedmarkets.Third, flexible labor regulation is associated withhigher R&D <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> technologies. In particular,bus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>in</strong> low-employment-protection countries<strong>in</strong> the OECD have almost 30 percent higher<strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> R&D than bus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>in</strong> OECDeconomies with rigid employment laws. 25 Why?Because organized labor frequently resists attemptsto acquire new technology, particularly if it isperceived to displace workers. In addition, str<strong>in</strong>gentregulations on fir<strong>in</strong>g may push managers <strong>in</strong>to reorganiz<strong>in</strong>gthe production process <strong>in</strong> ways that provideemployment for displaced workers, which <strong>in</strong> turnreduces <strong>in</strong>centives to buy the latest technology.Fourth, restrictions on hir<strong>in</strong>g and fir<strong>in</strong>g have beenshown to result <strong>in</strong> smaller firm size, and to leaveeconomies of scale unexploited <strong>in</strong> manufactur<strong>in</strong>g andsome services (the evidence is primarily from OECDeconomies). 26All of these effects—less job creation, longer unemploymentspells and the related skill obsolescence of


Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersFigure 3.5Who Regulates the Employment Relation?Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex60504030Income group averageRegional averageLegal-orig<strong>in</strong> averageSouth AsiaEnglish-orig<strong>in</strong>Middle East2035 40 45 50 55Flexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dexSource: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.Socialist-orig<strong>in</strong>Lat<strong>in</strong> AmericaLower-middle-<strong>in</strong>come French-orig<strong>in</strong>East. EuropeAfricaLow-<strong>in</strong>come Upper-middle-<strong>in</strong>comeGerman-orig<strong>in</strong>Nordic-orig<strong>in</strong>OECD High-<strong>in</strong>comeEast AsiaHigh-<strong>in</strong>comeworkers, less R&D <strong>in</strong>vestment, and smaller companysize—may serve to reduce productivity growth. 27Surveys of managers also show that employmentregulation is a burden on bus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>in</strong> many develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries. One survey asks managers to rank eightareas with regard to the burdens regulations impose onthe operation and growth of their bus<strong>in</strong>esses: bus<strong>in</strong>esslicens<strong>in</strong>g, customs and foreign trade restrictions, foreigncurrency and exchange regulations, employment regulations,environmental regulations, fire and safety regulations,tax regulations and their adm<strong>in</strong>istration, andhigh effective tax rates. 28 Employment regulations wereseen to be the major obstacle to improv<strong>in</strong>g productivity<strong>in</strong> Bangladesh, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, India,Panama, Portugal, Thailand, Tunisia, and Venezuela.And they were rated the second-most-importantobstacle to productivity growth <strong>in</strong> Argent<strong>in</strong>a, Bolivia,Ecuador, Mexico, and Uruguay. 29More worry<strong>in</strong>g, employment regulation limits theopportunities of disadvantaged groups to come outof poverty. Excessive regulation is associated withhigher unemployment, 30 especially for youths andwomen (figure 3.6). Cross-country analyses suggestthat if France were to make its labor regulations asflexible as those <strong>in</strong> the United States, the employmentrate might <strong>in</strong>crease by up to 1.6 percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts.The effect is even larger for Spa<strong>in</strong>, at 2.3 percentagepo<strong>in</strong>ts. Women would benefit the most, with morethan 70 percent of the new jobs. Us<strong>in</strong>g the employmentregulation <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>in</strong> this chapter, a reduction<strong>in</strong> the value by a third would be associated with a10-percentage-po<strong>in</strong>t fall <strong>in</strong> the unemployment rate ofyoung women.Without job opportunities <strong>in</strong> the formal economy,many people jo<strong>in</strong> the unofficial sector (figure 3.7).There, workers have no social protection whatsoever.Cross-country studies show that a reduction of theemployment regulation <strong>in</strong>dex by a third is associatedwith a 14-percentage-po<strong>in</strong>t decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formalemployment and a 6.7-percentage-po<strong>in</strong>t fall <strong>in</strong> outputproduced <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy.What to Reform?Reform is tak<strong>in</strong>g place, but it is often hotly contestedby labor unions and frequently falls short or isreversed. 31 In the early 1980s, Spa<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>troducedmore-flexible legislation on fixed-term contracts,only to roll it back <strong>in</strong> the latter part of the decade. In1996, the Peruvian government tried to reduceseverance payments by 50 percent. The ensur<strong>in</strong>gFigure 3.6Rigid Employment Regulation Is Associated withHigher Female UnemploymentFemale unemployment, %4030201000 20 40 60 80 100Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dexNote: The correlation shown <strong>in</strong> this figure rema<strong>in</strong>s statistically significant whencontroll<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>in</strong>come.Sources: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database; <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2003.37


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>38Figure 3.7Labor Regulation and InformalityInformal sector, % <strong>in</strong>come per capitaHighLowLow1 2 3 4 5 HighCountries ranked by employment-laws <strong>in</strong>dex, qu<strong>in</strong>tilesNote: The correlation shown <strong>in</strong> this figure is controlled for <strong>in</strong>come per capita. Therelationship is statistically significant at the 1 percent level.Sources: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database; Schneider 2002.uproar caused the government to <strong>in</strong>stead <strong>in</strong>creaseseverance payments. In 1998 Argent<strong>in</strong>a revokedtemporary employment contracts—which had been<strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong> 1995 as the ma<strong>in</strong> component of thelabor reform.A general reform oriented toward less regulationof labor markets has yielded positive results <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong>America and <strong>in</strong> some transition economies. Six Lat<strong>in</strong>American countries have reformed their employmentlegislation <strong>in</strong> the last decade: Argent<strong>in</strong>a, Brazil,Colombia, Guatemala, Panama, and Peru. With theexception of Panama, all of those countries <strong>in</strong>troducedtemporary contracts. The contracts have lowerdismissal costs, and employers usually pay lowerpayroll taxes. Among transition economies, theCzech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Poland, theRussian Federation, and the Slovak Republic made thehir<strong>in</strong>g of workers more flexible and reduced regulationon conditions of employment. Estonia’sreform is the most far-reach<strong>in</strong>g: it reduced regulationon both the hir<strong>in</strong>g and the fir<strong>in</strong>g of workers. Therehas been little reform of employment regulation <strong>in</strong>Africa and South Asia.Several other types of reforms of employment regulationhave eased the burden on bus<strong>in</strong>esses andprovided better job opportunities for poor people:• Many OECD countries have <strong>in</strong>troduced flexiblepart-time and fixed-term contracts. Thesecontracts br<strong>in</strong>g groups less likely to f<strong>in</strong>d jobs,such as women and youths, <strong>in</strong>to the labor market.Germany <strong>in</strong>creased the duration of fixed-termcontracts to eight years, whereas Poland haselim<strong>in</strong>ated the time limit.• Several countries have either <strong>in</strong>troducedapprentice wages (Colombia) or lowered them<strong>in</strong>imum wage for new entrants (Chile).• Some countries (Hungary, Poland) have made itpossible for employers to shift work time betweenperiods of slow demand and peak periods withoutthe need for overtime payment.• Other countries have eased regulations on fir<strong>in</strong>g.Serbia and Montenegro reduced the severancepayment for a worker with 20 years of tenure from36 months to 4.As countries adopt better technology for monitor<strong>in</strong>gthe labor market and build up their adm<strong>in</strong>istrativecapacity, they will be able to undertake moresophisticatedreforms. Several OECD countries haveimplemented legislation on short-term compensation,which provides employees with job security at times oflow demand. If an employer cannot ga<strong>in</strong>fully occupy aworker dur<strong>in</strong>g slack times, a government fund coversthe payment for such periods. Belgium, Italy, andSweden have good experience manag<strong>in</strong>g such funds. 32This <strong>in</strong>novation reduces employee turnover and shiftsthe burden away from the bus<strong>in</strong>ess. Further reform may<strong>in</strong>clude a negative <strong>in</strong>come tax <strong>in</strong> place of a mandatorym<strong>in</strong>imum wage. Such a tax would give people an<strong>in</strong>centive to jo<strong>in</strong> the workforce <strong>in</strong> entry-level jobs whilealleviat<strong>in</strong>g the burden on unemployment <strong>in</strong>surance. 33Notes1. Valenze 1985, p. 36.2. Tur<strong>in</strong> 1934, p. 34.3. Fallon and Lucas 1991.4. ILO 1998, 2000, 2001, 2002, 2003.5. Becker 1971. Economic studies show that the presenceof such fundamental rights improves productivity.6. Heckman and Pages 2000.7. Saavedra and Torero 2000.


Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g Workers8. Fallon and Lucas 1991. The negative effects of rigidlabor regulations are not limited to develop<strong>in</strong>g countries.The <strong>in</strong>troduction of high severance payments <strong>in</strong>France after <strong>World</strong> War II is estimated to have<strong>in</strong>creased long-term unemployment by 4.4 percentagepo<strong>in</strong>ts (Lazear 1990).9. Hopenhayn 2001 for Argent<strong>in</strong>a; Montenegro and Pages2003 for Chile; Kugler 2000 for Colombia; Dolado andothers 1997 for Spa<strong>in</strong>; <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2002a for the RussianFederation; Abowd and others 1999 for France.10. Betcherman 2002.11. Botero and others 2003.12. Besley and Burgess 2003.13. Mulligan and Sala-i-Mart<strong>in</strong> 2000; Botero and others2003.14. Fishback 1998.15. OECD 1999. All figures are for 1999.16. Blanchard and Landier 2000.17. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2003.18. Gill, Montenegro, and Domeland 2002.19. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2002b.20. The rank<strong>in</strong>gs generated by this <strong>in</strong>dex are consistentwith the rank<strong>in</strong>gs on regulation on dismissals <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong>American countries (Heckman and Pages 2000) andthe rank<strong>in</strong>gs on employment protection <strong>in</strong> the OECD(OECD 1999). The correlations are highly significant,at 0.63 and 0.73, respectively. These provide supportfor the robustness of the methodology.21. Heckman and Pages 2000.22. Blanchard and Portugal 2001.23. Holmes 1998.24. Betcherman and others 2001.25. Nicoletti and others 2001.26. Nicoletti and Scarpetta 2003.27. Scarpetta and Verdier 2002; Montenegro and Pages2003.28. Batra and others 2003.29. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2003. Two other surveys, by the chamber ofcommerce <strong>in</strong> 2000 and 2001, also show that 52 percentof managers of private manufactur<strong>in</strong>g enterprisesperceived labor regulations to be excessive, especially <strong>in</strong>the textiles, chemicals, and construction <strong>in</strong>dustries.30. Scarpetta 1996 for the OECD; Fields and Wan 1989 forSouth Asia; Aidt and Tzannatos 2003 for a recentsurvey of country studies.31. Gill, Montenegro, and Domeland 2002.32. Van Audenrode 1994.33. Blanchard 2002.39


4Enforc<strong>in</strong>g ContractsImag<strong>in</strong>e that a new client comes to a textile companyand orders shirts. The client and the companymanager sign a contract for payment on delivery.But at delivery, the client refuses to pay <strong>in</strong> full.What happens next? In New Zealand, the companymanager will show the client the contract and ask forpayment. The client is likely to pay. In Poland, thecompany manager will show the contract to the clientand ask for payment. The client is likely to refuse topay. In Côte d’Ivoire, the company manager wouldprobably not deal with the new client unless the clientcould provide references from other textile companiesor from companies that operated <strong>in</strong> the same region. 1In Vietnam, the client might not bother go<strong>in</strong>g to thecompany without hav<strong>in</strong>g at least half of the moneyavailable for an advance payment.Why the differences? The answer lies <strong>in</strong> the efficiencyof courts—the ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>stitution enforc<strong>in</strong>g contracts.New Zealand has a very efficient court system. Polishcourts take a long time to resolve disputes. Courts<strong>in</strong> Vietnam and Côte d’Ivoire are considered <strong>in</strong>efficient.In the words of a Vietnamese enterprisemanager <strong>in</strong>terviewed <strong>in</strong> 1999: “The court is weak, andno entrepreneurs use it.” 2 Weaknesses <strong>in</strong> the legal systemspan countries and centuries. Go<strong>in</strong>g back 400 years,Shakespeare’s Hamlet lists court delays among thecalamities of life: “The oppressor’s wrong, the proudman’s contumely, the pangs of despised love, the law’sdelay.” 3 In the absence of efficient courts, fewer transactionstake place, and those transactions <strong>in</strong>volve onlya small group of people l<strong>in</strong>ked through k<strong>in</strong>ship,ethnic orig<strong>in</strong>, and previous deal<strong>in</strong>gs.Courts have four important functions. Theyencourage new bus<strong>in</strong>ess relationships, because partnersdo not fear be<strong>in</strong>g cheated. They generate confidence<strong>in</strong> more complex bus<strong>in</strong>ess transactions by clarify<strong>in</strong>gthreat po<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong> the contract and enforc<strong>in</strong>g suchthreats <strong>in</strong> the event of default. They enable moresophisticated goods and services to be rendered byencourag<strong>in</strong>g asset-specific <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> their production.And they serve a social objective by limit<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>justice and secur<strong>in</strong>g social peace. Without courts,commercial disputes often end up <strong>in</strong> feuds, to thedetriment of everyone <strong>in</strong>volved.Companies that have little or no access to courtsmust rely on other mechanisms, both formal and<strong>in</strong>formal—such as trade associations, social networks,credit bureaus, and private <strong>in</strong>formation channels—to decide with whom to do bus<strong>in</strong>ess. Companiesmay also adopt conservative bus<strong>in</strong>ess practices anddeal only with repeat customers. Transactions arethen structured to forestall disputes. Whateveralternative is chosen, economic and social value maybe lost. 4Four types of reform of contract enforcement haveproven successful:• Establish<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation systems on caseload andjudicial statistics has delivered a large payoff.Judiciaries with such systems (for example, <strong>in</strong> theSlovak Republic) can identify their primary usersand the biggest bottlenecks.• Tak<strong>in</strong>g out of the courts transactions that arenot disputes—such as the register<strong>in</strong>g of newbus<strong>in</strong>ess entities—can free up resources forcommercial litigation. Because such reform mayrequire new laws, governments can <strong>in</strong> the meantimereorganize the workflow <strong>in</strong> the courts so that41


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>42clerks, not judges, are responsible for companyregistration.• Simplify<strong>in</strong>g the procedures is often warranted forcommercial disputes, especially <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries. For example, summary debt collectionproceed<strong>in</strong>gs of the type recently established <strong>in</strong>Mexico alleviate court congestion by reduc<strong>in</strong>gprocedural formalism. When default judgments—automatic if the defendant does not appear <strong>in</strong>court—are <strong>in</strong>troduced as well, delays are cutsignificantly.• Modify<strong>in</strong>g the structure of the judiciary may allowfor small-claims courts and specialized commercialcourts. Several countries with small-claimscourts—such as Japan, the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, andNew Zealand—recently <strong>in</strong>creased the maximumclaim eligible for hear<strong>in</strong>g at the court. In othercountries, such as Botswana and India, localcourts deal with small cases and pass disputesconcern<strong>in</strong>g larger amounts to the higher courts.Where the judiciary is least developed, as <strong>in</strong>Angola, Mozambique, and Nepal, specializedcourts are premature. Instead, reformers areallowed to <strong>in</strong>troduce summary proceed<strong>in</strong>gswith<strong>in</strong> general-jurisdiction courts or havespecialized judges <strong>in</strong> the general court, with afocus on the execution of judgments.Ease of Contract EnforcementUs<strong>in</strong>g a hypothetical bus<strong>in</strong>ess transaction, lawyers<strong>in</strong> 133 countries were asked to describe how acompany would go through the courts to recover itsoverdue payment. The survey covers the procedureby-procedureevolution of a commercial casebefore courts <strong>in</strong> the country’s most populous city.Respondents were given the amount of the claim(half of <strong>in</strong>come per capita), the location and ma<strong>in</strong>characteristics of the litigants, the presence of cityregulations, the nature of the remedy requested by thepla<strong>in</strong>tiff, the merit of the pla<strong>in</strong>tiff’s and defendant’sclaims, and the social implications of the judicialoutcome. 5 These standardized details enabled therespondent law firms to describe the proceduresexplicitly—and to determ<strong>in</strong>e the duration and cost ofeach procedure.On the basis of their responses, three <strong>in</strong>dicators ofthe efficiency of contract enforcement were constructed:• The number of procedures, mandated by law orcourt rules, that demand <strong>in</strong>teraction between theparties to the dispute or between them and thejudge or court officer.• The cost, as a share of <strong>in</strong>come per capita, <strong>in</strong>curreddur<strong>in</strong>g dispute resolution—compris<strong>in</strong>g court fees,attorney fees, and payments to other professionals.• The estimated time to resolve a dispute, measuredas the number of days from the moment thepla<strong>in</strong>tiff files the lawsuit <strong>in</strong> court until the momentof settlement or actual payment. Separate estimatesare made for the average time until the completionof process, trial, and enforcement. Comparisonswith studies of actual court practices <strong>in</strong> severalLat<strong>in</strong> American countries show remarkableconsistency <strong>in</strong> the length of time between fil<strong>in</strong>g andsettlement (see figure 1.3). 6Three examples illustrate the strik<strong>in</strong>g differences <strong>in</strong>the efficiency of contract enforcement across countries.In Slovenia, the creditor must complete 22 proceduresand spend 1,003 days to get paid (figure 4.1). It will costmore than $360, or 7.2 percent of the claim amount(3.6 percent of <strong>in</strong>come per capita), <strong>in</strong> attorney andcourt fees. In Tunisia, it takes only 14 procedures and 7days to take a debt recovery case from fil<strong>in</strong>g toenforcement of judgment. There are no requirementsto appo<strong>in</strong>t a lawyer or <strong>in</strong>itiate a protest procedurebefore a public notary. The creditor files a claim <strong>in</strong>court, and the court issues a summons to the debtor.The cost is 8 percent of the claim (4 percent of <strong>in</strong>comeper capita). In Guatemala, it takes 19 procedures and1,460 days to enforce the contract, with 40 percent ofthe claim amount go<strong>in</strong>g to attorney and court fees.What procedures are common <strong>in</strong> resolv<strong>in</strong>g commercialdisputes? In 61 percent of the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>sample, the case is handled by a general-jurisdictioncourt (table 4.1). In some other countries <strong>in</strong> thesample—<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g Canada, Denmark, France, Italy,Japan, the Netherlands, Norway, and S<strong>in</strong>gapore—it ishandled by a specialized court. Almost all countries useprofessional judges, but <strong>in</strong> a few countries, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g


Enforc<strong>in</strong>g ContractsFigure 4.1Enforc<strong>in</strong>g a Contract <strong>in</strong> SloveniaProcedure 0 200 400 600 800 1,0001. Pla<strong>in</strong>tiff files the lawsuit <strong>in</strong> writ<strong>in</strong>g and pays court fee2. Lawsuit is registered and receives a reference number3. Case is assigned to a judge4. Court scrut<strong>in</strong>izes the compla<strong>in</strong>t5. First attempt at delivery of notification is made6. Second attempt at delivery of notification is made7. Notification is sent by registered mail8. Defendant answers the compla<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong> writ<strong>in</strong>g9. Defendent‘s answer is delivered to the pla<strong>in</strong>tiff with<strong>in</strong> 30 daysof its receipt by the court10. Pla<strong>in</strong>tiff files answer to statements of the opposition11. Defendent files answer to preparative submission of pla<strong>in</strong>tiff12. Hear<strong>in</strong>g is held and notification of judgment is madeimmediately afterward13. Written judgment is issued14. Defendant is sought at his or her residence or a note isleft with household or neighbor and a notice is left on the door15. Pla<strong>in</strong>tiff is sought at his or her residence or a note is leftwith household or neighbor and a notice is left on the door16. Pla<strong>in</strong>tiff requests enforcement clause from the court17. An enforcement motion is filed18. Enforcement order or writ of execution is made19. Attachment of debtor‘s property is made20. A call for auction is issued21. Sale through auction is made22. Payment is made to creditorSource: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.Australia, Turkey, and Zambia, lay judges preside overthe case. Few countries make the use of lawyers forlegal representation mandatory, but many pla<strong>in</strong>tiffshire lawyers anyhow. Mandatory representation is thenorm <strong>in</strong> Argent<strong>in</strong>a, Bolivia, Italy, Morocco, Spa<strong>in</strong>, andsome other Lat<strong>in</strong> American and Middle Easterncountries. More generally, mandatory legal representationis a feature of French-civil-law countries.Rich countries tend to have specialized courts, rely<strong>in</strong>gless on professional judges and legal representation.Small-claims courts, which tend to follow simplerprocedures than general courts, are sometimes usedTimeDaysfor resolv<strong>in</strong>g commercialdisputes, as <strong>in</strong> Brazil,Zambia, and Zimbabwe. InUganda it takes only 16 proceduresand about threemonths to resolve a dispute.Several other countries—Belgium, Hong Kong (Ch<strong>in</strong>a),NewZealand, and the UnitedStates—have small-claimscourts, but the maximumclaim amount is smaller thanthe one specified <strong>in</strong> thehypothetical experiment here.For example, <strong>in</strong> New York thejurisdictional limit for smallclaimscourts is $3,000. InNew Zealand, the limit of thedisputes tribunal is NZ$7,500,or $3,125. If the amount is lessthan NZ$12,000 and bothparties agree, the disputestribunal still determ<strong>in</strong>es theclaim. Similar arrangementsare available <strong>in</strong> the smallclaimscourts of most Australianstates.Countries also differ <strong>in</strong> theuse of written arguments <strong>in</strong>court proceed<strong>in</strong>gs. Almostevery one has writtenrequirements for the fil<strong>in</strong>g,process, judgment, andenforcement-of-judgment stages. But only about athird require that all the evidence be written and thatf<strong>in</strong>al arguments be submitted <strong>in</strong> written form. Onlyhalf require written notification of judgment. MostLat<strong>in</strong> American countries (such as Colombia,Ecuador, Honduras, and Venezuela) and someMiddle Eastern countries (such as Morocco) requirewritten documentation for every procedure.In just over half the sample, the compla<strong>in</strong>t must bejustified by cit<strong>in</strong>g relevant parts of the law <strong>in</strong>stead ofpresent<strong>in</strong>g the compla<strong>in</strong>t on equity grounds andlett<strong>in</strong>g a judge determ<strong>in</strong>e its admissibility <strong>in</strong> court.43


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>44Table 4.1Frequency of Procedures <strong>in</strong> Contract EnforcementProcedureFrequencyUse of professionalsGeneral-jurisdiction court 61%Professional judge tries the case 94%Use of an attorney is mandatory 20%Written arguments are required for—Fil<strong>in</strong>g 92%Service of process 94%Opposition 72%Evidence 40%F<strong>in</strong>al arguments 30%Judgment 86%Notification of judgment 55%Enforcement of judgment 98%Legal justificationCompla<strong>in</strong>t must be legally justified 55%Judgment must be legally justified 87%Judgment must be on law (not on equity) 63%Statutory regulation of evidenceJudge cannot <strong>in</strong>troduce evidence 39%Judge cannot reject irrelevant evidence 11%Out-of-court statements are <strong>in</strong>admissible 69%Mandatory prequalification of questions 23%Oral <strong>in</strong>terrogation only by judge 15%Only orig<strong>in</strong>al documents and certified copies 50%are admissibleAuthenticity and weight of evidence def<strong>in</strong>ed by law 30%Mandatory record<strong>in</strong>g of evidence 69%Control of superior reviewEnforcement is suspended until resolution of appeal 56%Comprehensive review <strong>in</strong> appeal 85%Interlocutory appeals are allowed 80%Other statutory <strong>in</strong>terventionsMandatory pretrial conciliation 13%Service of process by judicial officer required 51%Notification of judgment by judicial officer required 28%Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.This presents another hurdle for bus<strong>in</strong>esses, becauseit forces them to seek legal advice. Only a fifth ofcommon-law countries require legal justification of thecompla<strong>in</strong>t, four-fifths of civil-law countries, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>gAustria, France, Germany, and Spa<strong>in</strong>. Denmark is theonly civil-law country that does not require reference toa specific law at any stage of the proceed<strong>in</strong>gs. Canada,Ghana, Malaysia, New Zealand, and S<strong>in</strong>gapore areother countries that do not require legal justification.The requirements for who may <strong>in</strong>troduce evidenceand how they may do so are frequently responsible forcaus<strong>in</strong>g delays <strong>in</strong> contract enforcement. More thantwo-thirds of the sample countries have statutory regulationson out-of-court statements and the record<strong>in</strong>gof evidence, but fewer than a fifth have regulations onthe admissibility of irrelevant evidence, the prequalificationof questions, and oral <strong>in</strong>terrogations. Thoseare primarily Lat<strong>in</strong> American countries (such asGuatemala and Honduras). But Portugal, Mozambique,and the Nordic countries (Denmark, F<strong>in</strong>land, Norway,and Sweden) have few statutory regulations of evidence.Italy imposes no regulations whatsoever.In 56 percent of the countries, enforcement issuspended if an appeal is filed, and the suspensionlasts until the appeal is resolved. Nearly all countries,particularly those with a German legal tradition andMiddle Eastern countries other than Egypt and Jordan,allow for comprehensive review <strong>in</strong> appeal and forappeals dur<strong>in</strong>g trial. Pretrial mediation is mandatory<strong>in</strong> Albania, Bolivia, Cameroon, Madagascar, Malawi,Mali, Nicaragua, the Philipp<strong>in</strong>es, and Uzbekistan. Lat<strong>in</strong>American countries and former French and Portuguesecolonies <strong>in</strong> Africa have the most str<strong>in</strong>gent mediationrequirements.Richer countries tend to have fewer proceduresto resolve disputes—especially common-law countries(Australia and the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom), but alsoDenmark, Norway, and Switzerland (table 4.2). Severalpoorer countries, like Jamaica, Tanzania, Tunisia, andZimbabwe, also have few procedures. African countriesimpose the greatest number of procedures, withAngola, Burundi, Cameroon, Chad, the DemocraticRepublic of Congo, and Sierra Leone among the 10countries with the largest number. Those are jo<strong>in</strong>ed bythree Lat<strong>in</strong> American countries—Mexico, Paraguay,and Puerto Rico—and the Kyrgyz Republic and Oman.Complex legal procedures frequently cause longdelays. One example is described <strong>in</strong> the autobiographyof Goethe, Germany’s poet. 7 On tak<strong>in</strong>g his law degree<strong>in</strong> 1771, the young Goethe began practic<strong>in</strong>g before theReichskammer Court <strong>in</strong> Wetzlar. Here is a descriptionof what he found at the courthouse: “A monstrous


Enforc<strong>in</strong>g ContractsTable 4.2Number of Procedures to Enforce a ContractThe fewest …… and the mostAustralia 11 Angola 46Norway 12 Paraguay 46United K<strong>in</strong>gdom 12 Cameroon 46Zimbabwe 13 Mexico 47Denmark 14 Sierra Leone 48Jamaica 14 Chad 50Switzerland 14 Oman 54Tanzania 14 Puerto Rico 55Tunisia 14 Congo, Dem. Rep. 55Taiwan, Ch<strong>in</strong>a 15 Burundi 62Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.chaos of papers lay swelled up and <strong>in</strong>creased every year.Twenty thousand cases had been heaped up, anddouble that number was brought forward.” It was notunusual for a case to rema<strong>in</strong> on the docket for morethan 100 years. One case, filed <strong>in</strong> 1459, was stillawait<strong>in</strong>g a decision <strong>in</strong> 1734.Conditions have greatly improved s<strong>in</strong>ce Goethe’stime. Countries with very different characteristics havemanaged to achieve quick dispute resolution (table 4.3).Among them are common-law countries such asBotswana, S<strong>in</strong>gapore, and New Zealand, which takeless than two months. Japan, the Republic of Korea, andLithuania, all <strong>in</strong> the German legal tradition, also haveexpeditious procedures, as do the Netherlands,Nicaragua, and Tunisia, three French-legal-orig<strong>in</strong>countries.Tunisia, the world’s leader <strong>in</strong> speedy resolution ofcommercial disputes, is perhaps the most surpris<strong>in</strong>g. Itscurrent procedures were put <strong>in</strong> place only <strong>in</strong> 1996. Thecourts employ a special proceed<strong>in</strong>g, called <strong>in</strong>junction topay, for recover<strong>in</strong>g a debt claim. The process lasts oneweek and <strong>in</strong>cludes 14 procedures, from the moment offil<strong>in</strong>g the claim with the tribunal cantonal <strong>in</strong> Tunis untilthe moment the creditor receives payment. On thepla<strong>in</strong>tiff’s application, the judge will order payment ifthe debt claim is well justified.Botswana uses an expedited court proceed<strong>in</strong>g thatdoes not require a trial. Such summary procedures areavailable mostly <strong>in</strong> common-law countries, althoughsome civil-law countries also have them. In Botswana,the creditor would apply for a summary procedure <strong>in</strong>Table 4.3Days to Enforce a ContractThe fastest …… and the slowestTunisia 7 Bosnia and Herzegov<strong>in</strong>a 630Netherlands 39 Italy 645New Zealand 50 Lebanon 721S<strong>in</strong>gapore 50 Nigeria 730Botswana 56 Angola 865Japan 60 Ethiopia 895Armenia 65 Poland 1000Nicaragua 65 Slovenia 1003Lithuania 74 Serbia and Montenegro 1028Korea, Republic of 75 Guatemala 1460Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.cases where the defendant is unable to raise any credibleopposition to the pla<strong>in</strong>tiff’s compla<strong>in</strong>t. The debtormay request leave to defend, but the request will bedenied by the court. The whole process requires 22procedures and lasts 56 days.Four transition economies (Bosnia and Herzegov<strong>in</strong>a,Poland, Serbia and Montenegro, and Slovenia) jo<strong>in</strong>three African countries (Angola, Ethiopia, and Nigeria),as well as Guatemala, Italy, and Lebanon, as countrieswith the longest delays. For Italy, the explanation lies<strong>in</strong> the country’s lax appeals process, which allowsdisruption of the proceed<strong>in</strong>gs at any po<strong>in</strong>t dur<strong>in</strong>g thetrial. Guatemala takes the longest time to enforce asimple commercial contract—four years, on average.The greatest differences across countries are <strong>in</strong> thecosts of proceed<strong>in</strong>gs (table 4.4). Several economies,both developed (Austria, the Netherlands, the UnitedK<strong>in</strong>gdom, the United States, and Taiwan [Ch<strong>in</strong>a])and develop<strong>in</strong>g (Brazil, Jordan, Mongolia,Uzbekistan, and the Republic of Yemen) impose negligiblecosts. But <strong>in</strong> several countries—the DemocraticRepublic of Congo, Côte d’Ivoire, India, and thePhilipp<strong>in</strong>es—the costs are almost equal to <strong>in</strong>come percapital or double the claim amount. In Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso,the Dom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic, Indonesia, the KyrgyzRepublic, and Malawi, the costs are two or more times<strong>in</strong>come per capita. Why, then, would bus<strong>in</strong>esses takedisputes to court?Another important factor <strong>in</strong> decid<strong>in</strong>g whether touse the courts is the predictability of resolv<strong>in</strong>g a dispute.Lawyers were asked the m<strong>in</strong>imum and maximum45


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>46Table 4.4Cost of Dispute ResolutionThe cheapest …US$expected number of days for enforc<strong>in</strong>g a contract <strong>in</strong>the hypothetical case. The range can be large. InNigeria, for example, it takes 730 days on average toresolve a dispute, but it can take as much as 1,643 days;<strong>in</strong> Slovenia the range is 480 to 1,825 days, and <strong>in</strong> theUnited Arab Emirates, 300 to 1,800 (figure 4.2).Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty is positively correlated with the averagetime to resolve disputes: countries with <strong>in</strong>efficientcourts are also likely to have uncerta<strong>in</strong> outcomes.Analysis shows that the effect of uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty is onlyabout a third as significant as the effect of averagetime <strong>in</strong> expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the use of courts by bus<strong>in</strong>esses. Inother words, focus<strong>in</strong>g reform on reduc<strong>in</strong>g the lengthof judicial process has a high value.Which Courts Are Socially Desirable?% of <strong>in</strong>comeper capitaJordan 5 0.3United States 120 0.4Yemen, Rep. of 2 0.5Netherlands 120 0.5United K<strong>in</strong>gdom 120 0.5Taiwan, Ch<strong>in</strong>a 68 0.5Austria 240 1.0Mongolia 7 1.8Uzbekistan 13 2.1Brazil 83 2.4… and the most expensiveCôte d’Ivoire 572 83.3Congo, Dem. Rep. 800 92.3India 444 95.0Philipp<strong>in</strong>es 1086 103.7Madagascar 304 120.2Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso 375 172.8Kyrgyz Republic 730 254.7Indonesia 1754 269.0Dom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic 9250 440.5Malawi 920 520.6Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.Courts should be fast, fair, and affordable. Legalexperts argue that the three attributes are difficult toFigure 4.2Uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty <strong>in</strong> Contract EnforcementDays2,0001,5001,0005000TunisiaNetherlandsS<strong>in</strong>gaporeBoliviaMozambiqueNote: Bars <strong>in</strong> this figure represent the average time to enforce a contract;l<strong>in</strong>es represent the range between the m<strong>in</strong>imum and maximum expected timeto enforce a contract.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.United ArabEmiratesSyriaNigeriaPolandSloveniabalance. The ma<strong>in</strong> reason to regulate procedures <strong>in</strong>commercial dispute resolution is that <strong>in</strong>formal justiceis vulnerable to subversion by the rich and powerful. Ifone of the disputants is more economically orpolitically powerful than the other, he can encouragethe judge to favor him, us<strong>in</strong>g either bribes or threats.In practice, fewer procedures are associated with bothreduced time and cost, and with perceptions ofimproved fairness. Analysis of data from a <strong>World</strong><strong>Bank</strong> survey of more than 10,000 enterprises <strong>in</strong> 82countries establishes that a lower number of proceduresis associated with more fairness and impartiality<strong>in</strong> the legal system (figure 4.3). It is alsoassociated with more honesty, more consistency, andmore public confidence <strong>in</strong> courts.History supports these f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs. In 17th-centuryEngland, debt disputes were decided by lay courts,presided over by the local mayor and a clerk. 8 Procedureswere simple—the pla<strong>in</strong>tiff wish<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>in</strong>itiatea lawsuit needed only to go to the town hall on a courtday and enter a compla<strong>in</strong>t with the clerk. Proceed<strong>in</strong>gswere oral, and rul<strong>in</strong>gs were not subject to appeal.Courts were accessible to everyone—rich and poor.Another example of the attractiveness of fast andaffordable resolution of commercial disputes comesfrom the Spanish consulados of the Middle Ages.


Enforc<strong>in</strong>g ContractsFigure 4.3A Small Number of Procedures Is Associated withPerceived FairnessJudges are unfair and partial6Figure 4.4Procedural Complexity Is Associated with GreaterCorruptionJudges are corrupt655443322110 20 30 40 50Number of proceduresNote: The correlation shown <strong>in</strong> this figure is statistically significant at the 1percent level. The result rema<strong>in</strong>s significant controll<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>in</strong>come per capita.Sources: Batra and others 2003; <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.110 20 30 40 50Number of proceduresNote: The correlation shown <strong>in</strong> this figure is statistically significant at the 1percent level. The result rema<strong>in</strong>s significant after controll<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>in</strong>come per capita.Sources: Batra and others 2003; <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.Orig<strong>in</strong>ally used as maritime courts, these private commercialcourts spread <strong>in</strong> Spa<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> the late thirteenthand fourteenth centuries, start<strong>in</strong>g with Valencia <strong>in</strong> 1283.In 1592, a consulado was established <strong>in</strong> Mexico City toserve the needs of Spanish merchants <strong>in</strong> the New <strong>World</strong>.In the request for a royal charter, the Mexico Citymerchants guild asserted that “every day there arise manylawsuits and disputes, disagreements and differencesover company accounts, consignments, freights and<strong>in</strong>surance, risks, damages, leakage and spillage, losses,failures, and defalcations. The settlement of suchmatters <strong>in</strong> ord<strong>in</strong>ary courts proves costly and timeconsum<strong>in</strong>g.”9 Staffed by merchants, the consuladosused oral proceed<strong>in</strong>gs to resolve disputes.In addition to lead<strong>in</strong>g to other poor outcomes,legal complexity facilitates corruption. In surveysconducted <strong>in</strong> the Slovak Republic <strong>in</strong> 2000, more than80 percent of entrepreneurs <strong>in</strong>dicated the slowness ofthe courts to be among the three ma<strong>in</strong> obstacles todo<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess—and that giv<strong>in</strong>g “someth<strong>in</strong>g special”to a court clerk or judge was necessary to speed theprocess along. 10 Between a third and a half of therespondents found Slovak commercial judges to becorrupt. More generally, a higher number of proceduresis associated with more opportunities <strong>in</strong> thejudicial system for extract<strong>in</strong>g bribes (figure 4.4).If the efficiency and fairness of dispute resolution <strong>in</strong>court are questionable, companies use other ways tostructure transactions so that disputes do not occur. A1996 enterprise survey of six African countries—Burundi, Cameroon, Côte d’Ivoire, Kenya, Zambia, andZimbabwe—studied perceptions of court <strong>in</strong>efficiency.In Burundi only 15.4 percent of respondents saidcourts were effective for dispute resolution. InCameroon, Côte d’Ivoire, Kenya, and Zambia, onlyabout 20 percent of respondents thought that courtscould be used for recover<strong>in</strong>g unpaid debt. More than70 percent of supplies were procured from a s<strong>in</strong>glesupplier. The average supplier/customer relationshipwas 10 years, and <strong>in</strong>frequent orders accounted for lessthan a fifth of total orders. 11 In these and some othercountries, <strong>in</strong>formation from private credit bureaus orpublic credit registries is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly be<strong>in</strong>g used bylenders to compensate for poor enforcement systems.Another survey, of small entrepreneurs <strong>in</strong> Vietnam<strong>in</strong> 1999, found that only 9 percent of respondentswould consider us<strong>in</strong>g courts to resolve disputes. 12 Oneentrepreneur said, “They normally create problems. InVietnam no one believes we have a good legal system.”Instead, entrepreneurs rely on social networks for<strong>in</strong>formation about new customers. 13 In 40 percent oftransactions, payment is made <strong>in</strong> advance.47


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>48What Expla<strong>in</strong>s Differences <strong>in</strong> Court Efficiency?Richer countries have more-developed judicialsystems—and more resources to establish specializedcourts, to tra<strong>in</strong> judges and support staff, and to br<strong>in</strong>gthe latest technology to the courtroom. Compar<strong>in</strong>gcountries by <strong>in</strong>come quartiles, the richest jurisdictionshave the lowest median cost, at 6.6 percent of<strong>in</strong>come per capita (figure 4.5); the shortest mediantime, at 210 days; and the lowest number of procedures,18. Upper-middle-<strong>in</strong>come countries have thelongest time, with a median of 270 days, followed bythe poorest countries at 248 days and lower-middle<strong>in</strong>comecountries at 225 days. The poorest countrieshave the highest costs, at 31 percent of <strong>in</strong>come percapita, and have the largest number of procedures, 30.Legal tradition is also associated with the efficiencyof contract enforcement. Nordic countries have thefewest procedures (17), the shortest time (139 days),and the second-lowest (after Germanic countries) cost,at 9 percent. Countries <strong>in</strong> the French legal traditionhave the most procedures (31), and the second-longesttime and cost (300 days and 13.7 percent). Germaniccountries have low costs but a long duration (amedian of 348 days). They have the third-fewestnumber of procedures, 22 (figure 4.6). Legal tradition isnot dest<strong>in</strong>y, however. Tunisia—a relatively poorMiddle Eastern jurisdiction <strong>in</strong> the French legaltradition—is a premier example of efficiency.Among civil-law countries, Lat<strong>in</strong> American jurisdictionshave the most onerous contract enforcement,<strong>in</strong> the number of procedures and time. It takes a medianof one year, 30 procedures, and 17 percent of <strong>in</strong>comeper capita to resolve a dispute. Only Sub-Saharan Africahas higher median costs—at 46 percent. OECD (high<strong>in</strong>come) countries take the shortest time (median of200 days), have the lowest cost (6.2 percent of <strong>in</strong>comeper capita) and the fewest procedures (18).The complexity of judicial processes is the ma<strong>in</strong>channel for the <strong>in</strong>come and legal tradition of countriesto affect the efficiency of contract enforcement.Common-law countries, ma<strong>in</strong>ly wealthier ones, havethe lowest procedural complexity. Seven of them—Australia, Canada, Ghana, Jamaica, New Zealand, theUnited K<strong>in</strong>gdom, and Zambia—make the top-10 list.Figure 4.5Contract Enforcement Is Cheaper <strong>in</strong> Rich CountriesLow-<strong>in</strong>comeUpper-middle<strong>in</strong>comeLower-middle<strong>in</strong>comeHigh-<strong>in</strong>come($1,508)0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35Cost, % of claimNote: Bars shown <strong>in</strong> this figure represent the median cost as a percent of theclaim by <strong>in</strong>come group. Numbers <strong>in</strong> parentheses are the median cost <strong>in</strong> U.S.dollars. The correlation between <strong>in</strong>come per capita and the cost of enforc<strong>in</strong>g acontract is statistically significant at the 1 percent level.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.($621)($239)Figure 4.6Nordic Countries Have the Fewest Procedures1720Nordic English German Socialist FrenchNote: Bars shown <strong>in</strong> this figure represent the median number ofprocedures by legal-orig<strong>in</strong> group.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.22($83)Japan, Taiwan (Ch<strong>in</strong>a), and Turkey are the other three.In contrast, Lat<strong>in</strong> American countries have the highestprocedural complexity, with Argent<strong>in</strong>a, Costa Rica,El Salvador, Guatemala, Nicaragua, Panama, Peru, andVenezuela among the 10 countries with the mostcomplex procedures. They are jo<strong>in</strong>ed by France andSpa<strong>in</strong>. The complexity of procedures is associated withhigher cost and longer duration (figure 4.7).2731


Enforc<strong>in</strong>g ContractsFigure 4.7Procedural Complexity Means DelaysComplexity of procedureMostcomplexity(top third)Averagecomplexity(middle third)Leastcomplexity(lowest third)These results are <strong>in</strong>dicative beyond the debtrecovery case amount<strong>in</strong>g to half of <strong>in</strong>come percapita. The procedures described here would besimilar <strong>in</strong> other types of commercial disputes—delivery of faulty goods, breach of confidentialityagreements, illegal use of <strong>in</strong>tellectual property, use ofshared public resources, failure to deliver on time,and so forth. Also, the background study 14 tested forrobustness by vary<strong>in</strong>g the contract amount to 5percent of <strong>in</strong>come per capita and the nature of thecommercial dispute by us<strong>in</strong>g a landlord/tenantdispute. The f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs rema<strong>in</strong> essentially the same.What to Reform?Days to enforce a contractNote: A measure of procedural complexity is compiled as the sum of the sixsub<strong>in</strong>dices reported <strong>in</strong> table 4.1. Each sub<strong>in</strong>dex is the simple average of itsconstitut<strong>in</strong>g variables, and the aggregate <strong>in</strong>dex varies between 0 and 100.The correlation between procedural complexity and days to enforce a contractis significant at the 1 percent level, after controll<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>in</strong>come.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.Four types of reform have proven successful <strong>in</strong>improv<strong>in</strong>g the efficiency of contract enforcement:establish<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation systems and judicial statistics,tak<strong>in</strong>g nondispute cases out of courts, simplify<strong>in</strong>gjudicial procedure, and creat<strong>in</strong>g specialized courts andspecialized procedures with<strong>in</strong> courts.Establish<strong>in</strong>g Information Systems andJudicial StatisticsLack of reliable <strong>in</strong>formation systems and workflowstatistics limits the ability of judicial reformers to204327397identify bottlenecks. It also h<strong>in</strong>ders the monitor<strong>in</strong>g ofreform progress and the accountability of courtadm<strong>in</strong>istrators. Judicial statistics should <strong>in</strong>clude dataon the number of petitions and cases at various stagesof the judicial process—as well as court users’ characteristics,the nature of disputed cases, the amount ofthe dispute, and the use of appeals, all fundamentalfor court management. Such data could also be madepublic, to <strong>in</strong>crease transparency and accountability.Such countries as Brazil, the Dom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic,and Mexico have recently piloted management<strong>in</strong>formation systems <strong>in</strong> the courts. The results areencourag<strong>in</strong>g, especially when bolstered by otherreforms. For example, the pilot <strong>in</strong> Mexico revealedthat more than 60 percent of the cases do not gobeyond the <strong>in</strong>itial fil<strong>in</strong>g of claim. This gave the governmenta more accurate picture about the actualcaseload of judges—who, like judges everywhere else,claimed an ever-<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g workload. In the Dom<strong>in</strong>icanRepublic, the pilot established that almost a third ofthe cases <strong>in</strong> civil courts are not disputes but arecompany registrations and consensual divorce fil<strong>in</strong>gs.These cases can be handled by court clerks, which will<strong>in</strong>crease the productivity of judges. The pilot <strong>in</strong> Brazildocumented the need for simplification of debt collectionprocedures—even with summary judgments,payments took years to collect. As a result, defaultjudgments have been suggested.New technology and <strong>in</strong>formation systems can alsohave a very direct impact on court efficiency. When asystem of automatic case assignment was implemented<strong>in</strong> the Slovak Republic, the time between fil<strong>in</strong>g and thefirst hear<strong>in</strong>g was reduced from 73 to 27 days, and thenumber of procedures between fil<strong>in</strong>g and first hear<strong>in</strong>gwent from 23 to 5. 15 What was previously done bysend<strong>in</strong>g a paper file from one office to another is nowdone electronically, with several court officers able toview the file simultaneously, thereby further reduc<strong>in</strong>gdelay. Automatic case assignment is also an anticorruptiondevice, elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g the possibility of litigants“pay<strong>in</strong>g” to have certa<strong>in</strong> judges assigned.Tak<strong>in</strong>g Nondispute Cases Out of CourtsIn many countries, particularly those with a civil-lawtradition, courts are tied up with cases such as the49


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>50creation or voluntary dissolution of a company, wherethere is no dispute. S<strong>in</strong>ce such cases are usually numerous,they demand considerable court resources. At theSofia District Court, Bulgaria’s largest, 23 judges handleall types of cases, with eight judges deal<strong>in</strong>g exclusivelywith bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration and re-registration. Remov<strong>in</strong>gcourt approvals from the bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration processand adopt<strong>in</strong>g an equivalent adm<strong>in</strong>istrative procedurewould <strong>in</strong>crease judges’ time by half.Another example comes from the courts <strong>in</strong>neighbor<strong>in</strong>g Serbia and Montenegro. In Belgrade, 18 ofthe 95 commercial judges work exclusively on registrationand re-registration cases. If these cases werehanded to an adm<strong>in</strong>istrative agency, as is currentlyproposed <strong>in</strong> the draft law, the judiciary would haveabout 25 percent more time to spend on disputes.Company registration has recently been taken out ofthe courts <strong>in</strong> Honduras, result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> reduc<strong>in</strong>g the casesthat courts need to deal with every year by 8,000.Tak<strong>in</strong>g nondispute cases out of the judiciary oftenrequires new legislation, which may take time. In themeantime, the judicial process can be reorganized togive more responsibility to court clerks <strong>in</strong> handl<strong>in</strong>gsuch cases.Simplify<strong>in</strong>g Judicial ProceduresSeveral areas of reform to simplify procedures havebeen explored: <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g oral procedures, simplify<strong>in</strong>gthe notification process, limit<strong>in</strong>g thenumber and tim<strong>in</strong>g of appeals, reduc<strong>in</strong>g or elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>gthe need for legal justification, and simplify<strong>in</strong>gthe regulation on evidence. Such simplificationis associated with less time and cost to resolvedisputes (figure 4.8).In countries where written elements dom<strong>in</strong>ate,judges do not have direct contact with witnesses andother sources of evidence. This absence of directcontact, together with piecemeal rather than cont<strong>in</strong>uoustrials, causes delays. Reforms targeted at<strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g oral procedures <strong>in</strong> dispute resolution<strong>in</strong>creased court efficiency <strong>in</strong> 18th-century Prussia,and more recently <strong>in</strong> Italy, Paraguay, and Uruguay. 16In pilot reforms <strong>in</strong> Argent<strong>in</strong>a, new oral proceduresreduced the average time of cases from three years toless than six months. 17In some countries, the defendant is notified directlyby the pla<strong>in</strong>tiff or the pla<strong>in</strong>tiff’s attorney, or simply byletter. In others, the defendant cannot be heldaccountable unless an appo<strong>in</strong>ted court officer servesthe claim. In Bulgaria, notification of defendants wasidentified as the major factor <strong>in</strong> caus<strong>in</strong>g long delays <strong>in</strong>commercial cases. The court was obliged to notify thedefendant <strong>in</strong> person before the case could commence.With a creative defendant, this process could—anddid—take years. So the code of judicial procedure wasrevised <strong>in</strong> 2000. Now, after the first notification fails, itis enough to post a second notification on the court’sannouncement board and <strong>in</strong> the official gazette.Mexico reformed its notification procedure evenfurther, allow<strong>in</strong>g for default judgment if the defendantdoes not appear on the first hear<strong>in</strong>g.In most countries, the enforcement of judgment isautomatically suspended until resolution of theappeal; this suspended judgment substantiallyreduces the value of the first-<strong>in</strong>stance judgment. Inothers, the suspension of enforcement is either notautomatic or even not allowed, which is associatedwith less time to resolve disputes (figure 4.8). Onesolution <strong>in</strong> the former case is to charge <strong>in</strong>terest ondelayed judgment to allow the w<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g party torecoup the cost of delay.In Tanzania, one of the ma<strong>in</strong> procedural changeswith the establishment of the specialized commercialsection of the high court was to bar appeals dur<strong>in</strong>gFigure 4.8Simple Rules Are Associated with Less Time andLower Cost342Enforcementsuspendedon appealDays220Enforcementnot suspendedon appealCost, % of <strong>in</strong>come per capita58Compla<strong>in</strong>t andjudgment mustbe legally justifiedNote: Differences are statistically significant at the 1 percent level.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.16Neither compla<strong>in</strong>tnor judgmentmust be legallyjustified


Enforc<strong>in</strong>g Contractstrial. Parties must wait until the court reaches a f<strong>in</strong>aljudgment before mak<strong>in</strong>g an appeal. This prohibitionhas elim<strong>in</strong>ated an average of n<strong>in</strong>e months <strong>in</strong> appealtime. 18 However, the problem arises aga<strong>in</strong> when a f<strong>in</strong>alappeal is launched. Even countries with specializedcourts typically do not have a separate appeals court.Appeals on judgments by specialized courts are pulledtogether with all other cases, as <strong>in</strong> Tanzania, and takea long time to resolve; consequently, much of thevalue of specialized courts is lost.Establish<strong>in</strong>g Specialized CourtsSpecialized courts generally entail procedural simplificationaimed at “mass production” <strong>in</strong> small-claimscourts, commercial courts, or adm<strong>in</strong>istrative tribunals.Creat<strong>in</strong>g small-claims courts or expand<strong>in</strong>g their jurisdictionhas been popular <strong>in</strong> the last two decades. Smallclaimscourts have substantially reduced time todisposition and are typically much cheaper thanregular courts.Specialized commercial courts are associated withfaster and cheaper contract enforcement <strong>in</strong> wealthycountries such as Germany, Japan, and theNetherlands—but also <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries suchas Ecuador, India, and Tanzania. One reason for thegreater efficiency is that judges become expert <strong>in</strong>handl<strong>in</strong>g commercial disputes. Perhaps moreimportant, commercial courts often have less formalprocedures: the use of oral arguments is oftenpermitted even <strong>in</strong> countries where the general courtsrequire written procedures. Countries with specializedcourts or specialized commercial sections <strong>in</strong>the general courts are about 50 percent faster <strong>in</strong>resolv<strong>in</strong>g commercial disputes—218 days versus 349days, on average.Specialized commercial courts are much less prevalent<strong>in</strong> civil-law countries, although this was not the casehistorically. 19 In many civil-law countries, specializedcommercial courts were established and laterabandoned. In Spa<strong>in</strong>, the commercial courts wereabolished <strong>in</strong> 1868, after the revolution. In Portugal,commercial courts were abolished <strong>in</strong> 1932, with theprocedure unified under the Code of Civil Procedure<strong>in</strong> 1939. Commercial courts suffered the same fate <strong>in</strong>Brazil, aga<strong>in</strong> with a new Code of Civil Procedure.In contrast, commercial courts reta<strong>in</strong>ed theirimportance <strong>in</strong> France. Born out of the merchant courts<strong>in</strong> medieval fairs, they were established as permanentcourts <strong>in</strong> 1563, dur<strong>in</strong>g the reign of Charles IX. Theenactment of the Commercial Code <strong>in</strong> 1806 enlargedtheir jurisdiction considerably by broaden<strong>in</strong>g the legaldef<strong>in</strong>ition of commercial transactions. Later judicialreforms, such as those <strong>in</strong> 1958, did not dim<strong>in</strong>ish theirimportance.Some Lat<strong>in</strong> American countries have re<strong>in</strong>troducedspecialized courts. In 1996, for example, specializeddebt collection was established <strong>in</strong> the four major citiesof Colombia: Bogota, Medell<strong>in</strong>, Cali, and Barranquilla.The judge is responsible for the seizure, attachment,appraisal, and auction<strong>in</strong>g of property to repay debt. Bythe year 2000, 75 percent of cases were be<strong>in</strong>g resolvedwith<strong>in</strong> a year, and the number of pend<strong>in</strong>g commercialcases fell by 5,000. Also, the number of filed cases<strong>in</strong>creased, from about 4,000 a year to 11,000 a year.Several other countries are follow<strong>in</strong>g suit. In India,the first Debt Recovery Tribunals were established <strong>in</strong>1994. By 2003, 30 such tribunals had started operat<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong> various cities around the country. Only f<strong>in</strong>ancial<strong>in</strong>stitutions may file cases for claims greater than onemillion rupees. A recent evaluation f<strong>in</strong>ds, “DebtRecovery Tribunals are seen as a vast improvement overtraditional courts as regards time and appropriateprocedure.” 20 In 2001, Ghana <strong>in</strong>stituted a fast-trackcourt, a specialized section <strong>in</strong> the high court. It hasbetter technology, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g a computerized system forcase management, automated transcripts, and randomassignment of cases. Judicial process is also eased. Thecourt’s success has prompted plans to establish fasttracksections <strong>in</strong> all regional capital courts.Some countries that already have small-claimscourts—such as Japan, the Netherlands, and the UnitedK<strong>in</strong>gdom—have recently <strong>in</strong>creased the permissibleamount that may be tried <strong>in</strong> such courts, a reformvastly popular among litigants. 21 Other countries—such as Australia and New Zealand—have allowedlitigants to agree on rais<strong>in</strong>g the disputed claim’s limitif they consent to try it <strong>in</strong> the small-claims court. Suchreforms are likely to result <strong>in</strong> further efficiency ga<strong>in</strong>s.In 1999 a commercial court was established <strong>in</strong> Dares-Salaam,Tanzania, as a specialized division of the51


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>52high court. It has jurisdiction over larger commercialdisputes, with claims amount<strong>in</strong>g to more than 10 millionTanzanian shill<strong>in</strong>gs, about $12,500. 22 It also has a higherfee, about 4 percent of the claim, but it handles cases<strong>in</strong> three to four months on average, much shorter thanthe two to three years needed for an average commercialdispute <strong>in</strong> the high court. Assess<strong>in</strong>g itsfairness and efficiency, one local lawyer says: “Thecommercial court has proven its efficiency. It has builtmuch-needed public confidence <strong>in</strong> the commercialcommunity, so much that many companies now<strong>in</strong>sist on a dispute clause <strong>in</strong> their contracts. This clauseprovides that any disputes not resolved amicably by theparties will be referred to the commercial court.” 23By mid-2003 the specialized court <strong>in</strong> Dar-es-Salaamwas hav<strong>in</strong>g grow<strong>in</strong>g pa<strong>in</strong>s. Countries plann<strong>in</strong>g to<strong>in</strong>troduce specialized commercial courts can learnmuch from its experience. After two years of success,it became <strong>in</strong>undated with cases. Pla<strong>in</strong>tiffs were will<strong>in</strong>gto pay the 4 percent fee to see their case resolved with<strong>in</strong>six months or less. The greater demand was not metby putt<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> more judges, clerks, and stenographers.A special court of appeals was also needed.In countries where the judiciary is still develop<strong>in</strong>g,specialized courts are likely to be premature. Instead,hav<strong>in</strong>g specialized judges or establish<strong>in</strong>g specializedcommercial procedures with<strong>in</strong> the general courtsand focus<strong>in</strong>g them on execution, as was recentlyproposed <strong>in</strong> Mozambique, is likely to pay higherdividends. A specialized commercial court mayquickly become a victim of its own success, as <strong>in</strong>Tanzania. Or it may stretch judicial resources beyondthe capacity of some poorer countries. The lesson:enact<strong>in</strong>g new procedures, tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g judges <strong>in</strong> thesubject matter, educat<strong>in</strong>g lawyers about the newcourt, and giv<strong>in</strong>g it wide publicity yield susta<strong>in</strong>ableresults only if those steps are matched by committ<strong>in</strong>gmore resources as the demand expands. In Tanzania,a second commercial court is be<strong>in</strong>g planned <strong>in</strong>Arusha, which will take some of the burden off theone <strong>in</strong> Dar-es-Salaam.Out-of-court resolution mechanisms are a bettershort-term solution <strong>in</strong> countries with only a rudimentaryjudiciary; they are also important <strong>in</strong> otherdevelop<strong>in</strong>g countries. One example illustrates theirbenefits. The M<strong>in</strong>istry of Justice <strong>in</strong> Argent<strong>in</strong>a,troubled by the long delays <strong>in</strong> commercial litigation,implemented a pilot project <strong>in</strong> 20 civil courts,requir<strong>in</strong>g them to send commercial cases tomediation. Both the m<strong>in</strong>istry and Fundación Libra,an NGO, tra<strong>in</strong>ed mediation staff. 24 The resultsexceeded expectations. Of more than 32,000 casesthat went through mediation between April 1996 andApril 1997, only a third were returned to the courts.Mediation took only two months on average—a farcry from the three to four years that it generally takesto resolve commercial disputes. Voluntary mediationhas enjoyed tremendous success <strong>in</strong> several othercountries—among them Albania, Bangladesh, Bolivia,Ecuador, and the Russian Federation. 25Legal reform experts have come forward withfurther lists of recommended changes. Their lists<strong>in</strong>clude hir<strong>in</strong>g more judges, improv<strong>in</strong>g the selectionof judges, manag<strong>in</strong>g judicial careers, improv<strong>in</strong>gjudicial adm<strong>in</strong>istration and entrance <strong>in</strong>to the legalprofession, ensur<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>dependence of thejudiciary, and meet<strong>in</strong>g resource needs. 26 Some reformswork admirably, such as the tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g of judges <strong>in</strong>Malawi, Sri Lanka, and Uganda. But tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g can beexpensive. In many rich countries it requires substantialresources—France spends more than $23 million ayear on judicial tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g; the Netherlands, $20million; and the United States, $17 million. 27Furthermore, not everyth<strong>in</strong>g that looks good as areform succeeds. Increas<strong>in</strong>g the number of judges todeal with case overload is often recommended, eventhough the evidence shows that it does not <strong>in</strong>creaseefficiency. 28 Why? Because it treats the manifestation(overworked judges), not the cause (procedural complexity),of judicial <strong>in</strong>efficiency.One needs only to look at history. In the sixteenthcentury, France and England had economies ofroughly equal size, probably generat<strong>in</strong>g similarnumbers of commercial disputes. But the extensivecomplexity of the judicial process <strong>in</strong> France requiredmore judges. One legal historian writes, “The totalnumber of royal judges <strong>in</strong> France must certa<strong>in</strong>ly haveexceeded 5,000. In contrast, from 1300 to 1800 thejudges of the English central court of common lawand Chancery rarely exceeded 15.” 29 The stagger<strong>in</strong>g


Enforc<strong>in</strong>g Contractsdifference <strong>in</strong> the number of state-employed judges isdue to the fact that English courts depended on thelocal adm<strong>in</strong>istrators (municipal councils) to serve asjurors.Beyond enhanc<strong>in</strong>g—or at least not prevent<strong>in</strong>g—out-of-court resolution mechanisms, there is littlegovernments <strong>in</strong> poor countries can do <strong>in</strong> the shortterm.Private parties will f<strong>in</strong>d ways to do transactions—by writ<strong>in</strong>g contracts that are easier to monitor andenforce (such contracts might specify the use ofleas<strong>in</strong>g agreements or give title to assets <strong>in</strong> exchangefor loans) and by rely<strong>in</strong>g on reputation mechanismsfor enforc<strong>in</strong>g contracts. <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> takes place <strong>in</strong>societies with courts as dysfunctional as those <strong>in</strong>Angola or Congo. Though far from efficient, suchcontracts may be the best way of do<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess giventhe circumstances. In such countries, other <strong>in</strong>stitutionsthat facilitate contract enforcement, such as credit<strong>in</strong>formation registries, take on great importance.Notes1. Bigsten and others 2000.2. McMillan and Woodruff 1999.3. Shakespeare, Hamlet: Pr<strong>in</strong>ce of Denmark,act III, scene 1.4. Informal substitutes for courts are usually expensive toma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>. One study <strong>in</strong>vestigates the contractualarrangements <strong>in</strong> the Indian software <strong>in</strong>dustry andf<strong>in</strong>ds that the lack of court enforcement results <strong>in</strong>15–20 percent higher transaction costs (Banerjee andDuflo 2000). Similar costs of <strong>in</strong>efficient contractenforcement are reported <strong>in</strong> transactions amongRomanian firms (Murrell 2003). The true cost ishigher and is reflected <strong>in</strong> the foregone opportunities <strong>in</strong>new transactions.5. For further description, see the data notes <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong><strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Indicators tables.6. Studies of actual court files provide the best method ofaccurately document<strong>in</strong>g the duration of judicialprocedure. In addition, such studies show wholitigates, what the ma<strong>in</strong> types of disputes are, whatamounts are claimed, how litigation ends, and howoften judgments are appealed. See Hammergren(2003) for a survey of exist<strong>in</strong>g studies.7. Goethe 1969.8. Muldrew 1993.9. Cedula Reales 448, Archivo Municipal de Mexico, 1590.10. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2001a.11. Bigsten and others 2000.12. McMillan and Woodruff 1999.13. Informal networks that use collective action as a meansto enforce contracts have been known for centuries;they <strong>in</strong>clude the Maghribi traders (Greif 1993), themerchant courts <strong>in</strong> the Champagne fairs (Milgrom,North, and We<strong>in</strong>gast 1990), and the German Hansa(Doll<strong>in</strong>ger 1970). But <strong>in</strong>formal mechanisms breakdown when the opportunity cost of deviation isreduced, as occurs with <strong>in</strong>creased competition(Woodruff 1998) or costly substitution (Clay 1997).14. Djankov and others 2003.15. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2001b.16. Botero and others 2003.17. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2001b.18. F<strong>in</strong>negan 2001.19. Zweigert 1983.20. PriceWaterhouseCoopers 2001, p. 5.21. Botero and others 2003.22. F<strong>in</strong>negan 2001.23. S<strong>in</strong>are 2000, p. 4.24. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2001b.25. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2002a.26. Hammergren 2000.27. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2002b.28. See Dakolias 1999. For evidence to the contrary, seeDjankov and others 2003.29. Dawson 1960, p. 71.53


5Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditAn entrepreneur with a promis<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>essidea can obta<strong>in</strong> credit as easily <strong>in</strong> Maputoor Jakarta as <strong>in</strong> London or New York. In1996, a real estate developer <strong>in</strong> Maputodecided to build a luxury homes complex. He <strong>in</strong>vitedthe head of a local large bank, a fellow golf clubmember, for lunch, and described his idea. For $10million, 50 homes could be built to house the middleclass. Other than the land, the entrepreneur could offerno collateral or monetary contribution. No matter.With<strong>in</strong> a week, he received $4 million to start thework.The same year, a young entrepreneur <strong>in</strong> Jakartaproposed an even grander idea to the second-largestIndonesian bank. With a population near<strong>in</strong>g 200million, the country needed its own national car—and he could produce it. He would need $800 millionto secure the participation of a foreign partner whowould br<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the technology. The entrepreneurcould not offer collateral. But the banker needednone. The name of the entrepreneur: HutomoMandala Purta, son of (then) President Suharto.Credit is as easily obta<strong>in</strong>able <strong>in</strong> Maputo or Jakartaas <strong>in</strong> London or New York. By the right people. Foreveryone else, obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g credit <strong>in</strong> most develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries <strong>in</strong>volves a lot of frustration and likelyrejection. Few bother.In most countries, banks will not extend creditwithout assurances that borrowers are creditworthyand that it will be possible to recover the debt if thereis a default. As a consequence, entrepreneurs withpromis<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess opportunities cannot obta<strong>in</strong>loans if the bank does not have enough <strong>in</strong>formationon the value of the property and the credit history ofthe borrower—and if the legal system does notprotect creditors.Two types of <strong>in</strong>stitutions expand access to creditand improve its allocation: credit <strong>in</strong>formation registriesor bureaus, and creditor rights <strong>in</strong> the country’ssecured-transactions and bankruptcy laws. 1 Theyoperate best together—<strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g allowscreditors to dist<strong>in</strong>guish good from bad clients, whilelegal rights to enforce claims help <strong>in</strong> the event ofdefault. Sometimes, <strong>in</strong>formation-shar<strong>in</strong>g mechanismsremedy poor legal protection. Public credit registriescan also help remedy the lack of private creditbureaus <strong>in</strong> poor countries. What is often termed“credit culture” is <strong>in</strong> fact an outcome of theunderly<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions.From the excommunication of usurers <strong>in</strong> themedieval church to the homestead protections <strong>in</strong> theUnited States, regulations protect borrowers fromunscrupulous creditors. But well-<strong>in</strong>tended shield<strong>in</strong>gof borrowers is often misguided—<strong>in</strong> the words of onedist<strong>in</strong>guished lawyer, “<strong>in</strong> its zeal to protect debtors[the law] precludes them from becom<strong>in</strong>gborrowers.” 2 Good credit <strong>in</strong>stitutions def<strong>in</strong>e propertyrights for both creditors and debtors, mak<strong>in</strong>geveryone better off. Collateral and <strong>in</strong>solvency regulationsdef<strong>in</strong>e the rights of creditors to recover theirloans. In addition, collateral regulation helps debtorsby extend<strong>in</strong>g the right of property title to the right touse property as security for f<strong>in</strong>ance. Informationshar<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>stitutions enable debtors to build reputationalcollateral.Countries have chosen different paths to expandaccess to credit. Poor countries are as likely to havepublic credit registries and strong creditor rights as55


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>56developed countries, although their enforcement ofregulation is weaker than that of developed countries.But private credit bureaus are much more prevalent<strong>in</strong> developed f<strong>in</strong>ancial markets. Countries <strong>in</strong> thecommon-law tradition rely more on creditor protections<strong>in</strong> the law. Civil-law countries, especially <strong>in</strong>the French tradition, use public credit registries morefrequently.What can governments do to help creditors believethey will be repaid? Establish<strong>in</strong>g appropriate regulationsfor the operation of private credit bureaus is acritical start. Remov<strong>in</strong>g legal restrictions to exchang<strong>in</strong>gcredit <strong>in</strong>formation, unambiguous endorsement ofcredit bureaus by central banks, and well-designedconsumer protection and privacy laws will create<strong>in</strong>centives for the shar<strong>in</strong>g and proper use of goodqualitycredit <strong>in</strong>formation. In some cases—especially <strong>in</strong>poor countries where commercial <strong>in</strong>centives for privatebureaus are low—establish<strong>in</strong>g public credit registrieshas helped remedy the lack of private <strong>in</strong>formationshar<strong>in</strong>g, or complemented private bureaus by focus<strong>in</strong>gon bank<strong>in</strong>g supervision. The design of the registries<strong>in</strong>fluences their impact: broader coverage of the creditmarket and regulations on collection, distribution, andquality of <strong>in</strong>formation are associated with larger creditmarkets.Legal creditor protections can be improved byreform<strong>in</strong>g collateral law: <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g summaryenforcement proceed<strong>in</strong>gs, elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g restrictions onwhich assets may be used as security for loans, andimprov<strong>in</strong>g the clarity of creditors’ liens through collateralregistries and clear laws on who has priority <strong>in</strong>a disputed claim to collateral. More-efficient courtsare crucial for the legal protections to take effect.Reforms of <strong>in</strong>solvency laws are sometimes necessary—as discussed <strong>in</strong> the next chapter.Shar<strong>in</strong>g Credit InformationEvery lender gathers <strong>in</strong>formation on the creditworth<strong>in</strong>essof potential borrowers. A debtor’s history witha bank is also an important way to build a good trackrecord. 3 Credit registries make borrowers’ reputationsaccessible to other creditors. By facilitat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formationexchanges among lenders, registries help creditors sortgood borrowers from bad, price loans correctly, andreduce the costs of screen<strong>in</strong>g. When borrowers knowthat their reputation will be shared among lenders,they have additional <strong>in</strong>centives to repay. And becausecredit histories are available, borrowers benefit fromlower <strong>in</strong>terest rates, as banks compete for good clients. 4Informal reputation mechanisms have helpedlenders allocate credit for centuries. 5 But they areappropriate only for small-scale bus<strong>in</strong>ess activities oramong a close-knit group of merchants and lenders.As formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>termediaries developed, so havethe <strong>in</strong>stitutions to help them allocate credit. Formal<strong>in</strong>stitutions for credit <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g emerged<strong>in</strong> the 17th century <strong>in</strong> Paris, where notaries exchangeddata on debtors’ creditworth<strong>in</strong>ess—and <strong>in</strong> Amsterdam,where the municipality <strong>in</strong>itiated a precursor to themodern public credit <strong>in</strong>formation registry. 6 In the18th century, private credit report<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>essesemerged <strong>in</strong> the United States, evolv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to today’sDun & Bradstreet (D&B). Back then, D&B deliveredits reference books to subscribers under lock and key.In the 19th century, mutual-protection societiesdeveloped <strong>in</strong> Germany. 7The credit <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong>dustry has grown at anastonish<strong>in</strong>g pace, facilitated by rapid technologicaladvances and f<strong>in</strong>ancial deepen<strong>in</strong>g. 8 Today D&Btransmits credit <strong>in</strong>formation on more than 60 millionbus<strong>in</strong>esses worldwide. Yet credit-<strong>in</strong>formation-shar<strong>in</strong>gorganizations differ greatly. Some concentrate onbus<strong>in</strong>ess or trade credit. Those are typically “<strong>in</strong>quirydriven,” and rely ma<strong>in</strong>ly on <strong>in</strong>formation availablethrough public sources, direct <strong>in</strong>vestigations, andtrade creditors. Others focus on consumer credit andfacilitate direct exchange among f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions.9 Although many such registries (also knownas bureaus) operate nationally, there is grow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>ternationalconsolidation. The largest, Experian, hasmore than 40,000 clients <strong>in</strong> 50 countries, with annualsales <strong>in</strong> excess of $1.7 billion.Institutions shar<strong>in</strong>g credit <strong>in</strong>formation also differ<strong>in</strong> ownership structure. The first publicly ownedcredit <strong>in</strong>formation registry was established <strong>in</strong>Germany <strong>in</strong> 1934 after the bank<strong>in</strong>g crises of the GreatDepression. S<strong>in</strong>ce then, many governments havefollowed suit, with dist<strong>in</strong>ct waves <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America


Gett<strong>in</strong>g Creditafter the macroeconomic <strong>in</strong>stability of the 1980s—and more recently <strong>in</strong> transition countries. Somepublic credit registries, such as those <strong>in</strong> Germany andTurkey, were started to monitor systemic risk andbegan distribut<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation to lenders only later.Others—<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g those <strong>in</strong> Bangladesh, Bulgaria,France, Mozambique, and Taiwan (Ch<strong>in</strong>a)—wereestablished to help lenders allocate credit effectively.How prevalent are credit <strong>in</strong>formation registries?Surveys conducted for this report show that privatebureaus that facilitate exchange of <strong>in</strong>formation amongf<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions operate <strong>in</strong> 57 countries and <strong>in</strong>every developed country but France. 10 Public credit registriesoperate <strong>in</strong> 68 countries, and are be<strong>in</strong>g established<strong>in</strong> Albania, Armenia, and Panama (figure 5.1). 11What is the coverage of <strong>in</strong>stitutions shar<strong>in</strong>g credit<strong>in</strong>formation? On average, private bureaus cover 321borrowers per 1,000 people, rang<strong>in</strong>g from more than800 borrowers per 1,000 people <strong>in</strong> Canada, NewZealand, Norway, and the United States to less than 1<strong>in</strong> newly established registries <strong>in</strong> Ghana and Pakistan(table 5.1).Public credit registries cover much less <strong>in</strong>formation.The average registry conta<strong>in</strong>s records on 40borrowers per 1,000 <strong>in</strong>habitants and 44 percent of thevalue of credits to gross national <strong>in</strong>come (GNI). Butthere is significant variation, from the extensive scaleof Portugal’s, with 496 borrowers per 1,000<strong>in</strong>habitants and 130 percent of credit to GNI, toNigeria’s and Serbia and Montenegro’s, with less thanone borrower per 1,000 people and credit to GNIbelow 1 percent.Rules and Regulations on PublicCredit-Information Shar<strong>in</strong>gPublic credit registries vary greatly <strong>in</strong> the extent towhich their design supports lend<strong>in</strong>g transactions. Thefirst difference is <strong>in</strong> the rules on collection of<strong>in</strong>formation. More than two-thirds of registriesrecord only loans above a m<strong>in</strong>imum size. M<strong>in</strong>imumloan cutoffs average $87,000 but can be more than $1million, as <strong>in</strong> Germany and Saudi Arabia, <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g afocus on monitor<strong>in</strong>g systemic risk. Other regulationson collection mandate whether nonbank lenders maysubmit data, as <strong>in</strong> Belgium, Bolivia, France, Taiwan(Ch<strong>in</strong>a), and Vietnam, and whether defaults must beerased when loans are repaid. The duration of historicaldata collected also varies: for Venezuela it istwo years; for Honduras, three years; and forMozambique and Tunisia, 10 years.Second is the scope of <strong>in</strong>formation distribution.Some public registries distribute data only on the total<strong>in</strong>debtedness of the borrower, as <strong>in</strong> Austria, Germany,Saudi Arabia, and the United Arab Emirates. Othersprovide demographic data, court judgments, loanrepayment patterns, utility payments, credit <strong>in</strong>quiries,57Table 5.1How Much Credit Information Is Available?Number of borrowers (firms/<strong>in</strong>dividuals) per 1,000 peoplePrivate BureausPublic Credit RegistriesTop 10 Bottom 10 Top 10 Bottom 10Norway 945 Spa<strong>in</strong> 48 Portugal 496 Niger 0.6New Zealand 818 Israel 47 Spa<strong>in</strong> 305 Mozambique 0.6United States 810 Belgium 42 Chile 209 Central African Republic 0.5Canada 806 Guatemala 35 Argent<strong>in</strong>a 149 Rwanda 0.4Japan 777 Portugal 24 El Salvador 130 Cameroon 0.4Ireland 730 Philipp<strong>in</strong>es 22 Malaysia 105 Saudi Arabia 0.3Australia 722 Hungary 15 Venezuela 97 Nigeria 0.2Germany 693 Sri Lanka 9 Peru 92 Congo, Rep. of 0.2United K<strong>in</strong>gdom 652 Pakistan 0.5 Ecuador 82 Chad 0.2Poland 543 Ghana 0.2 Belgium 68 Serbia and Montenegro 0.1Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>IBRD 32438*Note: Data for T aiwan, Hong Kong,and Puer to Rico have been broken outfrom the national dataset.58NorwaySweden F<strong>in</strong>landNetherlandsDenmark Russian LatviaFed. LithuaniaUnitedK<strong>in</strong>gdom Germany Poland BelarusBelgiumUkra<strong>in</strong>eSwitzerlandMoldovaFrance ItalyRomaniaIrelandKazakhstanKyrgyzRep.Georgia UzbekistanArmenia AzerbaijanBulgariaTurkeySpa<strong>in</strong>PortugalGreeceSyrianArabRep. Islamic Rep.of IranJordanKuwaitLebanonTunisiaIsraelMoroccoPakistanNepalAlgeriaArab Rep.of EgyptBangladeshSaudiArabiaIndiaUnited ArabEmiratesOmanNigerMaliThailandRep. of Y emenVietnamSenegalBurk<strong>in</strong>aFasoSriLankaEthiopiaNigeriaBen<strong>in</strong>Côted’Ivoire GhanaMalaysiaCameroonUgandaRep.ofKoreaPhilipp<strong>in</strong>esIndonesiaJapanAustraliaNewZealandRussian FederationMongoliaCh<strong>in</strong>aLaoP.D.R.MauritaniaChadCambodiaGu<strong>in</strong>eaCentralAfrican Rep.KenyaS<strong>in</strong>gaporeCongoBurundiDem. Rep.of CongoTanzaniaAngolaMalawiZambiaPapuaNew Gu<strong>in</strong>eaMozambiqueZimbabweMadagascarNamibiaBotswanaHong Kong*Sierra LeoneRwandaTaiwan*TogoLesothoSouthAfricaUkra<strong>in</strong>eGermanyPolandCzech RepublicSlovak RepublicAustriaHungar yBoth private bureau and public credit registry existOnly private bureau existsOnly public credit registry existsNo private bureau or public credit registry existsNot <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> sampleSloveniaRomaniaCroatiaBosnia andHerzegov<strong>in</strong>a SerbiaandMontenegroBulgariaFYRMacedoniaItalyAlbaniaGreeceFigure 5.1Which Countries Have Credit Registries?CanadaUnited StatesDom<strong>in</strong>ican Rep.PuertoRico*MexicoHaitiJamaicaHondurasGuatemalaNicaraguaEl SalvadorPanamaCosta RicaR.B. deVenezuelaColombiaEcuadorPeru BrazilBoliviaParaguayUruguayChileArgent<strong>in</strong>aThis map was produced by the MapDesign Unit of The <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>.The boundaries, colors,denom<strong>in</strong>ationsand any other <strong>in</strong>formation shown onthis map do not imply, on the part ofThe <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> Group, any judgmenton the legal status of any territory, orany endorsement or acceptance ofsuch boundaries.SEPTEMBER 2003Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.


Gett<strong>in</strong>g Creditand rat<strong>in</strong>gs—for example, Belgium, Ecuador, Romania,Taiwan (Ch<strong>in</strong>a), Venezuela, and Vietnam distribute atleast two such types of detailed <strong>in</strong>formation. Anotherdist<strong>in</strong>ction is whether registries distribute positive ornegative <strong>in</strong>formation, or both. Positive data <strong>in</strong>cludetotal loans outstand<strong>in</strong>g, assets, and personal<strong>in</strong>formation, which helps <strong>in</strong> identify<strong>in</strong>g total<strong>in</strong>debtedness and assess<strong>in</strong>g capacity to repay a loan.Negative data reveal past defaults and arrears, andprovide more <strong>in</strong>formation on will<strong>in</strong>gness to repaycommitments. About 70 percent of public registriesdistribute both negative and positive data, 25 percentonly positive, and the rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g 5 percent onlynegative <strong>in</strong>formation (Belgium [before mid-2003], theDom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic, and Turkey).Third is the access to <strong>in</strong>formation, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g whomay use the registry and whether data are availablefor distribution with<strong>in</strong> a day, electronically, and freeof charge. In 39 percent of countries, only banksupervisors and <strong>in</strong>stitutions that submit data haveaccess. In 41 percent, <strong>in</strong>formation is available only onthe creditor’s own customers. Lenders <strong>in</strong> countries ofthe West African Monetary Union wait almost threemonths to receive paper copies of the data. Publicregistries charge no fees, except <strong>in</strong> Belgium, Brazil,Bulgaria, Ecuador, Egypt, Italy, Mozambique,Pakistan, Romania, Taiwan (Ch<strong>in</strong>a), and Vietnam. 12Fourth is the quality of <strong>in</strong>formation, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g howcurrent the data are, and the safeguards <strong>in</strong> place toensure that <strong>in</strong>formation is accurate. Two-thirds ofcountries impose legal penalties for report<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>accurate data and conduct statistical checks forerrors. One-third are required by law to respond toborrower compla<strong>in</strong>ts.To gauge the ability of registries to support credittransactions, the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> team constructed an<strong>in</strong>dex of the rules and regulations concern<strong>in</strong>g the collection,distribution, accessibility, and quality ofpublic registries (table 5.2), measured on a scale of 0to 100.The results quantify the variation <strong>in</strong> design and<strong>in</strong>dicate whether a public registry is oriented more toserv<strong>in</strong>g lenders or to supervis<strong>in</strong>g banks. The Taiwan(Ch<strong>in</strong>a) registry <strong>in</strong>cludes an extensive range of<strong>in</strong>formation on borrowers and their loans regardlessTable 5.2Public Registries Differ <strong>in</strong> DesignTop 10 Bottom 10Country Score Country ScoreTaiwan (Ch<strong>in</strong>a) 70 Yemen, Rep. of 38Mongolia 68 Morocco 33Vietnam 67 Serbia and Montenegro 33Austria 66 Niger 22Spa<strong>in</strong> 64 Mali 22Lithuania 63 Ben<strong>in</strong> 22Belgium 63 Côte d’Ivoire 22Argent<strong>in</strong>a 61 Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso 22Italy 61 Senegal 22Portugal 61 Togo 22Note: Scores range from 0 to 100, with higher values <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g that the structure of thepublic registry is designed to serve lenders.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.of the loan size, and was designed with the ma<strong>in</strong>purpose of serv<strong>in</strong>g lenders. It also has the highestscore, 70. The recently established public credit registries<strong>in</strong> Mongolia and Vietnam are designed toprovide an extensive range of <strong>in</strong>formation and score68 and 67, respectively. In contrast, the registries <strong>in</strong>most West African countries—Ben<strong>in</strong>, Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso,Côte d’Ivoire, Mali, Niger, and Senegal—provide little<strong>in</strong>formation to facilitate credit markets.Regulations on Private CreditInformation Shar<strong>in</strong>gPrivate bureaus are generally better designed for facilitat<strong>in</strong>gcredit transactions than public registries are(figure 5.2). They are also far more likely to report thatlenders are their primary clients. In addition, they tendto be specialized <strong>in</strong> list<strong>in</strong>g either firms or <strong>in</strong>dividuals,while almost all public credit registries cover both.Private bureaus collect <strong>in</strong>formation from a moreextensive range of sources, such as trade creditors,retailers, courts, and other public records. They distributelonger historical data and more types of data,have fewer restrictions on access, and provide such otherservices as credit scor<strong>in</strong>g, monitor<strong>in</strong>g of borrowers,fraud detection, and sometimes even debt collection.Because fewer private bureaus have m<strong>in</strong>imum loan sizerequirements, they may be better placed to coverconsumers, entrepreneurs, and small bus<strong>in</strong>esses.59


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>60Figure 5.2Private Registries Are Oriented More to Serv<strong>in</strong>gLenders% of public registries% of private registries11%0%Specialize <strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>dividuals14%42%30%Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.84%22%55%14%80%28%75%Specialize<strong>in</strong> firmsNo m<strong>in</strong>imumloan sizeNonbank creditorsprovide dataF<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutionsand firms are theprimary usersDistribute morethan 2 yrs of dataPrivate bureaus are formed <strong>in</strong> response to commercialopportunities and market conditions, 13 butgovernment regulation also plays a part. 14 <strong>Bank</strong>secrecy, privacy, and data protection regulationsmandate what <strong>in</strong>formation may be shared, whileregulations on <strong>in</strong>formation disclosure and access affectthe availability of data.Countries differ significantly <strong>in</strong> their approach toregulat<strong>in</strong>g credit <strong>in</strong>formation. 15 Some governmentshelp create a market for credit registries by requir<strong>in</strong>gthat lenders obta<strong>in</strong> credit reports before grant<strong>in</strong>gloans, as <strong>in</strong> Bangladesh, Belgium, Colombia, Ecuador,Malaysia, Nicaragua, and Pakistan. The absence of<strong>in</strong>terest-rate restrictions on commercial lend<strong>in</strong>g (as<strong>in</strong> 70 percent of surveyed countries) also helps createdemand. Countries that require unique identifiers—such as national ID or social security numbers—greatly facilitate bureau activity by allow<strong>in</strong>g payment<strong>in</strong>formation from different sources to be attributed toone borrower. At the other extreme, some governmentseither do not permit private registries tooperate, such as those <strong>in</strong> Azerbaijan, the IslamicRepublic of Iran, and Mongolia—or they limitlicenses for credit registries, as <strong>in</strong> F<strong>in</strong>land and (afterrecent changes) <strong>in</strong> Thailand. Some countries have fewrelevant laws or none at all, thereby restrict<strong>in</strong>g registriesbecause there is no clear legal basis foroperat<strong>in</strong>g. In Uzbekistan, a credit registry hasobta<strong>in</strong>ed its bus<strong>in</strong>ess registration but cannot operatebecause it does not have the legal foundation tocollect and distribute data.Three other areas of regulation <strong>in</strong>fluence credit<strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g: the content of credit <strong>in</strong>formationthat may be shared legally, the rules on access to<strong>in</strong>formation sources and disclosure, and the rights ofthe borrower to obta<strong>in</strong> credit <strong>in</strong>formation.The extent of credit <strong>in</strong>formation that f<strong>in</strong>ancial<strong>in</strong>stitutions may share with private bureaus istypically proscribed by secrecy provisions <strong>in</strong> bank<strong>in</strong>glaws and by data protection or privacy laws. In somecountries, shar<strong>in</strong>g positive data is restricted, as <strong>in</strong>Australia, Nicaragua, and Portugal. In others, shar<strong>in</strong>gis forbidden except <strong>in</strong> cases of crim<strong>in</strong>al prosecution,tax evasion, or money launder<strong>in</strong>g. Consent clauses <strong>in</strong>lend<strong>in</strong>g contracts can circumvent bans on shar<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>some countries. But <strong>in</strong>terviews with bureaus andbanks <strong>in</strong>dicate that such circumvention is <strong>in</strong>sufficient,because lenders usually want official governmentendorsement before shar<strong>in</strong>g. In the majorityof countries, <strong>in</strong>formation may be shared only if theborrower authorizes do<strong>in</strong>g so or if there is “permissiblepurpose.” Many countries regulate theamount of historical <strong>in</strong>formation that may be shared,with almost half requir<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>in</strong>formation ondefaults be elim<strong>in</strong>ated after the default is repaid, thusprevent<strong>in</strong>g a banker from acquir<strong>in</strong>g a full picture ofthe loan applicant’s history (table 5.3).Table 5.3Regulat<strong>in</strong>g Private Information Shar<strong>in</strong>g—CountryExamplesRemediedLimits onNegative Defaults Must Reta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gInformation Only Be Erased Historical DataAustralia Czech Rep. BrazilChile Chile GermanyF<strong>in</strong>land Hong Kong (Ch<strong>in</strong>a) ItalyHong Kong (Ch<strong>in</strong>a) Portugal NicaraguaNew Zealand Switzerland PanamaNicaragua South Africa PeruPortugal Thailand South AfricaSources: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database, Jentzsch 2003a.


Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditOpen access to public <strong>in</strong>formation sources—suchas databases, court judgments, notary records, traderegistries, and f<strong>in</strong>ancial statements—facilitates thecreation and operation of private bureaus. In somecountries the sources exist but various regulationsconstra<strong>in</strong> access to them, as <strong>in</strong> Ch<strong>in</strong>a, the Dom<strong>in</strong>icanRepublic, Egypt, Jordan, Nigeria, the Russian Federation,Syria, Uzbekistan, and the Republic ofYemen. The degree of centralization of the <strong>in</strong>formationsources also matters. In Argent<strong>in</strong>a and Morocco,court judgments are publicly available but can be seenonly at the local level, greatly <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the costs ofgather<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation. Regulations requir<strong>in</strong>g firms todisclose <strong>in</strong>formation publicly and account<strong>in</strong>gstandards ensur<strong>in</strong>g standardization of <strong>in</strong>formationcan also enhance <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g. Although allcountries require that publicly traded companiesdisclose f<strong>in</strong>ancial statements, only around halfrequire private companies to do so. Such regulationshelp compensate for other restrictions. For example,although laws <strong>in</strong> F<strong>in</strong>land restrict <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>gamong banks, public records are open—so the privatebureau gathers comprehensive data on borrowerdefaults from court records.Countries also apply a range of measures to protectborrowers’ rights to <strong>in</strong>formation on their creditworth<strong>in</strong>ess.The measures affect bus<strong>in</strong>esses as well asconsumers, because credit scor<strong>in</strong>g for smallbus<strong>in</strong>esses is based largely on personal profiles oftheir owners. Regulatory protections <strong>in</strong>clude the rightof borrowers to see their own <strong>in</strong>formation, to correcterrors, to be notified <strong>in</strong> the event of an adverse action,to stop its disclosure <strong>in</strong> case of dispute, and to knowto whom it was disclosed. Those measures ensure theproper use of <strong>in</strong>formation and enhance the quality ofdata, because they establish <strong>in</strong>centives for credit registriesto ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> accurate <strong>in</strong>formation. Such provisionsare be<strong>in</strong>g adopted at an <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g rate <strong>in</strong>North America and Europe. 16Legal Rights of CreditorsIn decid<strong>in</strong>g whether to extend credit and at what<strong>in</strong>terest rate, lenders need to know what share of debtthey can recover if a borrower defaults. S<strong>in</strong>cesecured-transaction laws were first codified <strong>in</strong>ancient Rome, one of the ma<strong>in</strong> ways for creditors torecover bad debt has been with collateral. 17 Collaterallaws enable firms to use their assets as security togenerate capital—from the farmer <strong>in</strong> Boliviapledg<strong>in</strong>g his cows as collateral for a tractor loan tothe securitization of loan portfolios that drivesmortgage f<strong>in</strong>ance markets <strong>in</strong> the United States. 18Collateral strengthens the <strong>in</strong>centives of debtors torepay their loans. By provid<strong>in</strong>g creditors with theright to an asset on default, collateral also reduces alender’s costs of screen<strong>in</strong>g loan applicants. And welldesignedcollateral agreements can facilitate theefficient sale or liquidation of bankrupt firms.For those reasons, collateral is a major determ<strong>in</strong>ant<strong>in</strong> lend<strong>in</strong>g decisions across countries. Patterns <strong>in</strong> theuse of collateral show it to be especially importantfor small firms <strong>in</strong> obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g loans. 19 It is alsoimportant <strong>in</strong> poorer countries. In some develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries, overcollateralization <strong>in</strong>dicates poorenforcement—collateral is necessary, but lessvaluable than <strong>in</strong> rich countries, because the prospectsof recover<strong>in</strong>g it are dim. For example, banks <strong>in</strong>Malawi, Moldova, and Mozambique typically securemore than 150 percent of a loan’s value. Interviewswith lenders <strong>in</strong>dicate that they will always firstattempt to negotiate repayment on default. But collateralprovides <strong>in</strong>surance for recover<strong>in</strong>g bad loanswhen negotiation fails.The value of collateral depends largely on the easeof creat<strong>in</strong>g and enforc<strong>in</strong>g security agreements, whichare far from equal across countries. In the Dom<strong>in</strong>icanRepublic and Peru, stamp duties and taxes to create asecurity agreement can add up to 4 percent of thetotal debt; <strong>in</strong> Nigeria, 2 percent; and <strong>in</strong> Tunisia, 1.9percent. In contrast, costs are negligible <strong>in</strong> France,Japan, the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, and the United States.And what happens if a borrower defaults? Lawyers<strong>in</strong> more than 130 countries were surveyed for a hypotheticalcase of collect<strong>in</strong>g on a bad loan secured bybus<strong>in</strong>ess equipment. It takes a week for a creditor toseize and sell collateral <strong>in</strong> Germany, Ireland, Tunisia,and the United States. But it can take five years <strong>in</strong>Bosnia and Herzegov<strong>in</strong>a, Brazil, and Chile. InAlbania, recent reforms allow creditors to seize and61


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>62Figure 5.3Enforc<strong>in</strong>g Collateral <strong>in</strong> Argent<strong>in</strong>aCostPercentage of <strong>in</strong>come per capita30 20Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.sell collateral without court <strong>in</strong>volvement. The processtakes a week. Such “private” mechanisms exist <strong>in</strong> aquarter of the sample countries. In Chile, the creditorfiles a claim with the court, and the court must declaredefault and order a bailiff to seize assets, before thereis public auction. The debtor may appeal the processat every stage. In Argent<strong>in</strong>a, enforc<strong>in</strong>g collateral <strong>in</strong> thehypothetical good-case scenario takes 148 days andcosts 42 percent of <strong>in</strong>come per capita (figure 5.3).The value of collateral also depends on theefficiency of the <strong>in</strong>solvency regime; creditors areconcerned about recover<strong>in</strong>g collateral if a debtorfirm goes bankrupt. 20 <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy laws def<strong>in</strong>e whocontrols the <strong>in</strong>solvency process, who has rights toTimeDays40 10 0 Procedure 0 25 50 75 100 125 1501. File compla<strong>in</strong>t2. Court decision to proceed3. File writ of payment4. Debtor opposes certa<strong>in</strong>defenses5. Court orders to notifycreditor of the defenses6. Creditor notified7. Creditor answers defenses8. Court renders judgment9. Debtor appeals(proceed<strong>in</strong>gs do not stop)10. Attachment of collateral registeredbefore Public Registry11. Auctioneer designated12. Auctioneer notified13. Auctioneer accepts14. Auctioneer’s Associationschedules public auction15. Auctioneer publishes legalnotices for potential buyers16. Period for fil<strong>in</strong>g oppositionsto defective publications17. Public sale18. Auctioneer files liquidation,<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g expenses19. Obta<strong>in</strong> court orderapprov<strong>in</strong>g auction20. Transfer of title to purchaser21. Creditor requests the courtissue payment of net proceedsthe property of a bankruptfirm and with what priority,and the efficiency ofrealiz<strong>in</strong>g the rights. Withoutlegal protections along eachof those dimensions, creditorswill either <strong>in</strong>crease theprice of loans to adjust forthe additional risk—possiblybeyond the reach of someentrepreneurs—or not makeloans at all. The overalleffect is to reduce access tocredit.Four powers of securedcreditors <strong>in</strong> reorganizationand liquidation procedureshave been shown to enhancecredit: 21• Whether there are restrictions,such as creditorconsent, when a debtorfiles for reorganization, asopposed to cases wheredebtors can seek unilateralprotection from creditors’claims by fil<strong>in</strong>g for rehabilitation(as <strong>in</strong> the UnitedStates <strong>in</strong> Chapter 11 of thebankruptcy code).• Whether secured creditors can seize their collateralafter the decision for reorganization is approved—<strong>in</strong> other words, whether there is no “automaticstay” or “asset freeze” imposed by the court.• Whether secured creditors are paid first out of theproceeds from liquidat<strong>in</strong>g a bankrupt firm.• Whether creditors or an adm<strong>in</strong>istrator are responsiblefor manag<strong>in</strong>g the bus<strong>in</strong>ess dur<strong>in</strong>g the resolutionof reorganization, rather than hav<strong>in</strong>g abankrupt debtor cont<strong>in</strong>ue to run the bus<strong>in</strong>ess.Of the four, priority payment for secured creditors<strong>in</strong> liquidation is the most widespread—<strong>in</strong> 62 percentof countries (figure 5.4). Countries that do not rank


Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditFigure 5.4Priority Payment Is Common% of countries6259Figure 5.5Legal Rights—From None to All Four% of countries372733382187Restrictions ondebtor fil<strong>in</strong>g forreorganizationNo automaticstay on collectionof securitySecuredcreditors arepaid firstManagementdoes not stay <strong>in</strong>reorganizationScore 0 Score 1 Score 2 Score 3 Score 4Creditor rightsSource: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.secured creditors first usually favor employee and taxclaims. In Turkey, government claims have priorityover secured creditors. In France, Hungary, Poland,Peru, and the Russian Federation, labor claims gethigher priority, usually <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g wages, benefits, andseverance payments, as well as other labor claimsaccumulated dur<strong>in</strong>g the period of <strong>in</strong>solvency. Brazil,Greece, India, Mexico, Romania, and West Africancountries give priority to both labor and governmentclaims over secured creditors.Around 60 percent of countries require that anadm<strong>in</strong>istrator run the bus<strong>in</strong>ess dur<strong>in</strong>g the reorganization.In the rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g jurisdictions, the bankruptdebtor reta<strong>in</strong>s the ma<strong>in</strong> responsibility for decisions onord<strong>in</strong>ary bus<strong>in</strong>ess, as <strong>in</strong> Argent<strong>in</strong>a, Austria, Brazil, Chile,Ch<strong>in</strong>a, Greece, Italy, the Philipp<strong>in</strong>es, Sweden, Turkey,and the United States.Restrictions on enter<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to reorganization andon a creditor’s seiz<strong>in</strong>g and sell<strong>in</strong>g of collateral after areorganization petition has been approved are lesscommon; they exist <strong>in</strong> around every third country. Inn<strong>in</strong>e countries, laws do not provide for any reorganizationprocedure at all (Bosnia and Herzegov<strong>in</strong>a,Egypt, Jordan, Kenya, Nepal, Panama, Syria, Uganda,and Zambia). In others, fil<strong>in</strong>g for reorganizationprovides automatic safe harbor from creditors’claims by means of an automatic stay. The type ofautomatic stay also varies significantly. In Indonesia,creditors must wait 90 days before they may enforcetheir security, and <strong>in</strong> Canada, 30 days. But <strong>in</strong> Ben<strong>in</strong>,creditors may not enforce security until after the<strong>in</strong>solvency process, which takes 40 months onaverage—a duration that <strong>in</strong>creases the cost anduncerta<strong>in</strong>ty of enforcement.Eight percent of countries, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g poorcountries such as Colombia, Tunisia, and Yemen, butalso France, provide none of the legal protectionsmeasured <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dex. Only n<strong>in</strong>e jurisdictionsprovide all four legal rights to creditors: Hong Kong(Ch<strong>in</strong>a), Kenya, Lebanon, New Zealand, Nicaragua,Nigeria, Panama, the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, and Zimbabwe(figure 5.5). In the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, a secured lenderhas the power to immediately appo<strong>in</strong>t an adm<strong>in</strong>istratorto take over the management of a bankruptcompany and enforce security, thereby effectivelyblock<strong>in</strong>g the possibility of a debtor’s enter<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to areorganization proceed<strong>in</strong>g without creditor consent.The adm<strong>in</strong>istrator is given wide powers, therebyprovid<strong>in</strong>g the secured lender with complete control ofthe process and a first priority of payment.Other aspects of secured lend<strong>in</strong>g regulationsfacilitate credit. Broaden<strong>in</strong>g the scope of security—the type of assets, debt, borrowers, and lenders thatmay be part of a security agreement—is one example.63


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>64Figure 5.6French-Legal-Orig<strong>in</strong> Countries Have Fewer Creditor Rights and More PublicRegistriesCreditor-rights score% with public registry1.5French1.8Nordic2.1SocialistSource: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.The clarity of property rights—through propertyregistries and laws that provide creditors withpriority access to the collateral <strong>in</strong> disputes outside<strong>in</strong>solvency—is also critical for giv<strong>in</strong>g lenders morecerta<strong>in</strong>ty of what can be recovered on default. Andthe levels of <strong>in</strong>tervention by courts and other publicofficials <strong>in</strong> creat<strong>in</strong>g and enforc<strong>in</strong>g security maypresent significant obstacles to borrowers and lendersalike. (Quantitative measures of those and otheraspects of laws on secured lend<strong>in</strong>g will be presented<strong>in</strong> <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> 2005.)Expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Patterns <strong>in</strong> Creditor Protections2.3GermanDo governments <strong>in</strong> rich countries “buy” good <strong>in</strong>stitutions?Not always. Surpris<strong>in</strong>gly, poor countries are aslikely as rich countries to have laws protect<strong>in</strong>g creditorrights. Poor countries are also as likely to establishpublic credit registries. 22 Those <strong>in</strong> developed countriescollect more credit <strong>in</strong>formation and have broader regulationson the quality of <strong>in</strong>formation. But they do notprovide more access or distribute more types of<strong>in</strong>formation than the ones <strong>in</strong> poorer countries. For thisreason, public credit registries <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countriesare more likely to report f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions asprimary users. But the cost and time needed to createand enforce security is higher <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries.And they have weaker regulatory environments for<strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g as well as weaker enforcement oflaws.2.4English0Nordic18Socialist22English56German72FrenchDo countries “<strong>in</strong>herit”good <strong>in</strong>stitutions? Yes. Legaltradition is the key determ<strong>in</strong>antof creditor protections.Creditor-rights scores average2.4 (out of a maximum of 4)<strong>in</strong> common-law countries,but only 1.5 for countrieswith French legal heritage(figure 5.6). Lenders alsoface more delays and highercosts of enforc<strong>in</strong>g collateral<strong>in</strong> French-orig<strong>in</strong> countries.But perhaps as a remedyfor poor creditor rights,French-legal-orig<strong>in</strong> countries are more likely toestablish public credit registries. Three-quarters ofthem have public registries, compared with a quarterof common-law countries and no Nordic countries.Do countries copy their neighbors’ <strong>in</strong>stitutions?Look<strong>in</strong>g across regions, Lat<strong>in</strong> American countries aremore likely to have public credit registries—71 percent,compared with only a third of OECD economies. Theyalso have the fewest creditor rights—1.7 on average.Transition countries have an average score of 2.3. Thereare no other important differences across regions.Public agencies are sometimes built to compensatefor the lack of private <strong>in</strong>stitutions. In almost 80 percentof countries, there was no private bureau when thepublic credit registry was established. Countrieswithout private bureaus are a third more likely to havepublic registries than countries with private bureaus(59 percent, compared with 39 percent), and those registriesare more likely to report that they serve lendersrather than bank<strong>in</strong>g supervisors.The presence of private bureaus is stronglyassociated with country wealth, although the regulatoryframework for <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g is also important.Highly concentrated lend<strong>in</strong>g markets—<strong>in</strong> which lendershave less <strong>in</strong>centive to share <strong>in</strong>formation because theycould lose the rents they extract from know<strong>in</strong>g theircustomers—reduce the likelihood of a private registry.Governments establish public registries as aremedy for poor protection of legal creditor rights.Countries with a public registry have significant lower


Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditFigure 5.7Creditor Rights, Information Shar<strong>in</strong>g, and Efficient Enforcement Expand Access to CreditPrivate credit, % of GDPMorePrivate credit, % of GDPMorePrivate credit, % of GDPMoreLessCountries ranked by creditor rights,decilesMoreLessCountries ranked by credit <strong>in</strong>formationshar<strong>in</strong>g, decilesMoreLessMoreCountries ranked by days to enforce acontract, decilesNote: The correlations shown <strong>in</strong> these figures control for national <strong>in</strong>come, <strong>in</strong>come growth, <strong>in</strong>flation, contract enforcement, the creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex, and a measure ofcredit-<strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g (equals 0 with no registries, 1 if public or private registries operate, and 2 if both operate), and legal orig<strong>in</strong>. All relationships shown arestatistically significant at the 5 percent level.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.creditor-rights scores—1.6—compared with othercountries—at 2.3. By provid<strong>in</strong>g more <strong>in</strong>formation forcreditors to use <strong>in</strong> assess<strong>in</strong>g risk, governments maycompensate for creditors’ weaker rights to enforcesecurity on default. The result is consistent withbanks’ use of creditor protection. In Lat<strong>in</strong> America—the region with the weakest legal protections—banksreport that they give twice as much weight to<strong>in</strong>formation from credit registries as on collateralwhen mak<strong>in</strong>g loan decisions. 23A similar substitution is evident between the easeof contract enforcement and the presence of publicregistries. Countries that score lower on rule of lawand have more bureaucratic contract enforcement aremuch more likely to have a registry, a relationship suggest<strong>in</strong>gthat registries help remedy poor enforcementthrough courts. Because the reputational effectprovides an <strong>in</strong>centive for borrower repayment,creditors can rely on registries as a form of contractenforcement before the fact rather than go through thecourts on default. That reliance is also important wherelenders face social pressure not to enforce claims. 24What Is the Impact on Credit Markets?Institutions shar<strong>in</strong>g credit <strong>in</strong>formation (public registriesand private bureaus), stronger creditor rights,and better enforcement systems are associated withdeeper credit markets across countries (figure 5.7). 25The fact that the impact of <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g isgreater when controll<strong>in</strong>g for creditor rights suggeststhat <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g compensates for poor legalprotection. The effect of creditor rights is much strongerwhen controll<strong>in</strong>g for measures of enforcement, af<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g suggest<strong>in</strong>g that without enforcement, laws onthe books are not enough to protect creditors.What protections work best <strong>in</strong> which circumstances?Although both <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g andcreditor rights are good for credit market depth, therelative importance of the various creditor protectionsdepends on country wealth. For the poorer half of thesample, <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g has greater impact thancreditor rights. But <strong>in</strong> the richer countries, the effect ofcredit <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g is less significant than thatof creditor rights. Legal protections—importanteverywhere—have more impact <strong>in</strong> rich countries.Country wealth is an important factor for understand<strong>in</strong>gwhether <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g is betterorganized publicly or privately. When the impact ofpublic and private registries is analyzed separately, theeffect of private bureaus on credit depth is positiveand significant. The effect of hav<strong>in</strong>g a public registry,though positive, is statistically <strong>in</strong>significant. But thisresult masks important differences by <strong>in</strong>come group.In the poorer half of the sample, both private bureausand public registries are associated with more private65


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>66credit, although the effect of private bureaus is larger.In poor countries, public registries help compensatefor weak creditor rights, poor enforcement, and thelack of private registries. The effect of a publicregistry on credit-market depth <strong>in</strong> poor countries iseven greater when it has achieved high coverage andhigh scores on the public registry rules <strong>in</strong>dex—that is,with broader rules on collection, distribution, access,and quality. 26In developed countries, public credit registrieshave a positive but <strong>in</strong>significant association withprivate credit. This analysis does not capture their<strong>in</strong>direct impact. Registries perform supervisoryfunctions as well as serv<strong>in</strong>g lenders (especially <strong>in</strong>wealthier countries), and such functions may havebenefits not analyzed here.Who benefits the most? Well-connected and largefirms may f<strong>in</strong>d it easy to get loans without credithistories, especially <strong>in</strong> rich countries. Smaller firms <strong>in</strong>poor countries, for which <strong>in</strong>formation is scarce or ofpoor quality, ga<strong>in</strong> the most. The relationship betweenthe presence of <strong>in</strong>formation-shar<strong>in</strong>g registries and afirm’s access to formal sources of f<strong>in</strong>ance is significantand positive, more so <strong>in</strong> poor countries and the mostfor small firms <strong>in</strong> poor countries (figure 5.8).The presence of private bureaus and public registriesis also associated with a lower spread betweenlend<strong>in</strong>g and deposit rates. 27 Other studies have shownthat stronger creditor rights and more <strong>in</strong>formationshar<strong>in</strong>g are associated with lower default rates. 28Firms <strong>in</strong> countries with <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g are lesslikely to report obstacles to obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g f<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g andshow evidence of credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts. 29 Countries withstronger legal creditor protections have larger debtmarkets, and higher rates of capital <strong>in</strong>vestment andproductivity growth. 30 The overall l<strong>in</strong>k between thedevelopment of f<strong>in</strong>ancial markets and growth is wellestablished. 31Country case studies show that <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g improves credit markets. InChile, the establishment of a credit registry <strong>in</strong>creasedlend<strong>in</strong>g. 32 Studies of the U.S. market show that morecredit <strong>in</strong>formation provides more power to predictdefaults. 33 Simulations <strong>in</strong> European countries showthat mov<strong>in</strong>g from no <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g, to shar<strong>in</strong>gFigure 5.8Information Shar<strong>in</strong>g Is Associated with a Firm'sAccess to Formal F<strong>in</strong>anceAll countries,all firmsPoor countries,all firmsPoor countries,small firmsNote: Figure shows the predicted impact of <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g on the percentof firm f<strong>in</strong>ance from formal sources, based on regressions with more than 6,000firm-level observations, and controll<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>in</strong>come, rule of law, firm ownership,age, sector, and size. The effect of <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g is significant at the1 percent level <strong>in</strong> each case, and the effect on small firms <strong>in</strong> poor countries issignificantly different from the effect on the full sample.Sources: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database; Batra and others 2003.negative data only, to shar<strong>in</strong>g both positive andnegative <strong>in</strong>formation, reduces bad loans dramatically.Lenders agree. In a survey of banks <strong>in</strong> 34 countries,more than half reported that shar<strong>in</strong>g credit<strong>in</strong>formation reduces default rates and loan process<strong>in</strong>gtime and costs by 25 percent or more (figure 5.9).What to Reform?Increase with <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g, %3 4 5 6Facilitat<strong>in</strong>g Information Shar<strong>in</strong>gEstablish<strong>in</strong>g regulations to facilitate the shar<strong>in</strong>g ofcredit <strong>in</strong>formation through private bureaus is thecritical first step for poor countries and rich countries.Other steps <strong>in</strong>clude permitt<strong>in</strong>g and provid<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>centives for the shar<strong>in</strong>g of both positive andnegative <strong>in</strong>formation (as Hong Kong and Belgiumdid <strong>in</strong> mid-2003) and keep<strong>in</strong>g past defaults onrecord. Separately, the scope of disclosure laws onf<strong>in</strong>ancial statements can be expanded <strong>in</strong> manycountries. Elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g restrictions on access to publicrecords can be accelerated by better technology andstorage of <strong>in</strong>formation. Ensur<strong>in</strong>g strong borrower


Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditFigure 5.9Shar<strong>in</strong>g Credit Information Reduces Defaults and Improves <strong>Bank</strong> EfficiencyImpact of <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g ondefault rates% Bad loans % Respondent banks1086420No <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>gNegative <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>gPositive and negative <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>gPersonalChequeaccountsCreditrights to access and correct <strong>in</strong>formation protectsborrowers and improves the quality of <strong>in</strong>formation.The impact of restrictions on <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g—or of ambiguity <strong>in</strong> its regulation—can be severe. InThailand, two credit bureaus have operated for severalyears. But <strong>in</strong> 2003 a new law imposed large f<strong>in</strong>es andcrim<strong>in</strong>al liabilities on participat<strong>in</strong>g f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutionsfor m<strong>in</strong>or violations <strong>in</strong> shar<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation,even though there are no procedures to ensure that dataare shared accord<strong>in</strong>g to the law. Both credit bureausshut down their operations when the law was passedand reopened only five months later, when clarify<strong>in</strong>gregulations were issued.In the past few years, almost every country <strong>in</strong> theformer Soviet Union has tried to set up a privatecredit bureau. A major impediment is the secrecyprovision <strong>in</strong> the bank<strong>in</strong>g or data protection laws. InArmenia, Georgia, Kazakhstan, and the Russian Federation,there is a debate about whether requir<strong>in</strong>g theborrower’s authorization would be sufficient. Somebelieve so, but others th<strong>in</strong>k the potential liability forcredit bureaus is too high. No private bureaus operate<strong>in</strong> those countries.Laws on credit report<strong>in</strong>g help overcome lenders’unwill<strong>in</strong>gness to share <strong>in</strong>formation—from fear oflos<strong>in</strong>g good borrowers to competitors, unfamiliarity,or concern over liability related to privacy or banksecrecy. But laws are rigid and must be designed <strong>in</strong>sufficiently general terms toreflect a rapidly chang<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>dustry. Laws also taketime to be approved. Alternativegovernment andcentral bank support hasproven effective <strong>in</strong> manycountries. Such support hastaken the form of centralbank directives, standards,penalties for noncompliance(as <strong>in</strong> Mexico, where theDecrease <strong>in</strong> Decrease <strong>in</strong> central bank imposes 100costs defaultspercent provision<strong>in</strong>g requirementswhen data are notsubmitted to the bureau), oreven letters of endorsementto banks (as <strong>in</strong> India and the Dom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic).Bureau codes of conduct, as <strong>in</strong> S<strong>in</strong>gapore and underdevelopment <strong>in</strong> Saudi Arabia, are another moreflexible way to set standards and build consensusamong lenders, government, and borrowers. Theextensive consultative process to develop a codeof conduct not only facilitates lender compliancebut also improves data quality by allow<strong>in</strong>g partiesto reach agreement on feasible standards andformats.Entry of one of the major <strong>in</strong>ternational creditreport<strong>in</strong>g firms can accelerate the process of establish<strong>in</strong>ga private credit registry. In the Czech Republic,Guatemala, India, and Mexico, private bureaus arebe<strong>in</strong>g formed <strong>in</strong> jo<strong>in</strong>t ventures with foreign firms,which provide technical assistance and expertise.Countries need to ensure that there are no legalobstacles to such foreign <strong>in</strong>vestment.Especially <strong>in</strong> poor countries and those with highlyconcentrated lend<strong>in</strong>g markets, such measures may be<strong>in</strong>sufficient to attract private <strong>in</strong>vestment. Establishmentof a public registry may offer the advantageof rapid setup because it uses central bank regulationrather than new laws. Direct enforcement by banksupervisors can counter lenders’ unwill<strong>in</strong>gness tocomply. And establish<strong>in</strong>g a public registry is cheap.The one <strong>in</strong> Mozambique cost only a few hundredthousand dollars to establish.<strong>Bank</strong>‘s assessment of the impact of<strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>gSource: Hadlow 2003. Authors’ calculations based on a 2001–02 survey of banks <strong>in</strong> 34 countries, with responses regard<strong>in</strong>gprocess<strong>in</strong>g time (69 banks), costs (68), and defaults (67).6040200Change of 25% or moreNo changeDecrease <strong>in</strong>process<strong>in</strong>g time67


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>68The design of registries is important for expand<strong>in</strong>gaccess to credit <strong>in</strong> poor countries. Broader rules onthe collection, distribution, and quality of <strong>in</strong>formationcan expand coverage, with help from new technology.In Malaysia, a new onl<strong>in</strong>e real-time system was<strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong> the public registry <strong>in</strong> 2001. It providescoverage of all loans, <strong>in</strong>stant responses to requests,and more frequent updates of credit <strong>in</strong>formationamong f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions. Almost half of the registriessurveyed reported the <strong>in</strong>tention to upgradetheir technology.In establish<strong>in</strong>g public registries, care must be takennot to stifle private <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g. As the creditmarket matures, or as private <strong>in</strong>itiatives materialize,public registries can be restructured to complementthem by focus<strong>in</strong>g on overall supervision and shar<strong>in</strong>gdata with the private registries, as happened recently<strong>in</strong> Mexico. The registries <strong>in</strong> Argent<strong>in</strong>a, the Dom<strong>in</strong>icanRepublic, and Peru share data with private bureaus(Bolivia will soon follow suit). Some successfulstrategies entail more extensive private-public partnership.Sri Lanka’s credit registry was set up <strong>in</strong> 1990,with 51 percent of the capital held by the centralbank, the rest shared among commercial f<strong>in</strong>ancial<strong>in</strong>stitutions. The government’s sharehold<strong>in</strong>g decl<strong>in</strong>esas more <strong>in</strong>stitutions jo<strong>in</strong> the registry. In S<strong>in</strong>gaporeand Thailand, the government <strong>in</strong>itiated the establishmentof private bureaus.Legal Rights To Create andEnforce SecurityEfficient courts are essential for enforc<strong>in</strong>g the rightsof creditors, especially unsecured lenders. For securedlend<strong>in</strong>g, reforms beyond the courts are necessary,simplify<strong>in</strong>g the steps and reduc<strong>in</strong>g the costs ofcreat<strong>in</strong>g and enforc<strong>in</strong>g security. Elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g thestamp duties and taxes for creat<strong>in</strong>g collateralagreements—as well as the requirements to notarizedocuments—can substantially reduce costs.Introduc<strong>in</strong>g out-of-court enforcement enhances thepowers for secured creditors to recover debt, as <strong>in</strong>Albania, Germany, Thailand, and the United States.Summary enforcement proceed<strong>in</strong>gs through thecourts are another effective reform. Moldova’sreforms <strong>in</strong> 2001 <strong>in</strong>troduced a fast-track enforcementprocedure. Ten days after notify<strong>in</strong>g the debtor, theother creditors, and the collateral registry of a default,creditors may file an enforcement order with thecourt. All that is required is evidence of the notifications,the default, and the security agreement.With<strong>in</strong> three days, the judge reviews the documentationand issues an enforcement judgment.There is no judicial analysis of the cause of dispute.Such measures <strong>in</strong>crease the importance of wellwrittensecurity contracts, to avoid problems <strong>in</strong> thejudicial review of valid documentation. And theyradically change the debtor’s <strong>in</strong>centives to appeal anddelay the enforcement process. In Moldova, appeals arepossible but must be undertaken <strong>in</strong> a separate trial. If thedebtor loses, he will bear all costs. So appeals are likelyonly if the debtor has a genu<strong>in</strong>e dispute or grievance.S<strong>in</strong>ce the reform, the time to seize and sell security hasfallen from more than three years to around 70 days.More-comprehensive reforms also address thescope and clarity of rights <strong>in</strong> security agreements. Tobeg<strong>in</strong> with, countries must allow the debtor to reta<strong>in</strong>possession and use collateral. <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> so is stillimpossible <strong>in</strong> Serbia and Montenegro, where thelender must take possession of assets to have a validcharge—hardly a practical solution for borrowerswho pledge bus<strong>in</strong>ess equipment. Also important,especially for small firms, is <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>strumentsthat allow security for a chang<strong>in</strong>g pool of assets suchas <strong>in</strong>ventory, receivables, property that will be realized<strong>in</strong> the future (e.g., crops), or a whole enterpriseespecially for small firms.Clear rules that anticipate and resolve priorityconflicts are essential <strong>in</strong> def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the property rightsof secured creditors. Registries of collateral agreements,where lenders can check for exist<strong>in</strong>g liens, alsosupport the clarity of property rights. In the UnitedStates, a lender can check by search<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> anelectronic registry of almost all collateral agreements.Not so <strong>in</strong> three-quarters of the world, where registriesare limited to certa<strong>in</strong> types of property, such as land(<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g many rich countries such as Germany andFrance). New technology makes such registries <strong>in</strong>expensive.In a few countries, such as New Zealand, thecollateral registry <strong>in</strong>terface is operated by the creditbureau. That is a w<strong>in</strong>-w<strong>in</strong> reform. The bureau benefits


Gett<strong>in</strong>g Creditfrom additional <strong>in</strong>formation on borrowers, and thegovernment benefits by hav<strong>in</strong>g a sophisticatedelectronic registry adm<strong>in</strong>istered by experts <strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>formation technology systems.F<strong>in</strong>ally, effective reforms of secured lend<strong>in</strong>g requireattention to <strong>in</strong>solvency as well as collateral laws. Thepowers allocated to secured creditors <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>solvencyprocess are a crucial determ<strong>in</strong>ant of access to credit.Good collateral <strong>in</strong>struments facilitate other goals ofbankruptcy also—by provid<strong>in</strong>g the right <strong>in</strong>centivesfor liquidat<strong>in</strong>g unviable companies and rescu<strong>in</strong>gviable firms. For example, liquidation is more efficientwhen collateral is concentrated <strong>in</strong> the hands of onema<strong>in</strong> creditor, and sale as a go<strong>in</strong>g concern is morelikely if the whole enterprise is pledged as security fora loan. 34Notes1. Other related factors, such as macroeconomicconditions, bank<strong>in</strong>g supervision, and ownership, arenot discussed here.2. Garro 1998.3. Campbell and Kracaw 1980; Diamond 1984, 1991;Stiglitz and Weiss 1988.4. Jappelli and Pagano 1993; Miller 2003.5. Greif, Milgrom, and We<strong>in</strong>gast 1994; Besley 1995.6. Hoffman, Poste-V<strong>in</strong>ay, and Rosenthal 1998.7. Olegario 2003.8. Miller 2003.9. The dist<strong>in</strong>ction between bus<strong>in</strong>ess and consumerreport<strong>in</strong>g is not as clear as it may seem. Some registriescover both consumers and firms. Also, bus<strong>in</strong>ess loansare often made on the basis of personal credit histories,especially for small firms and entrepreneurs. Thischapter covers both.10. Apply<strong>in</strong>g a broader def<strong>in</strong>ition of private credit registriesthat do not directly exchange <strong>in</strong>formation amongf<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions (which <strong>in</strong>cludes <strong>in</strong>vestigative-stylecredit report<strong>in</strong>g firms), private registries operate <strong>in</strong>approximately 70 percent of sample countries.11. The survey of public and private credit registries wasdeveloped with the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>’s Credit Report<strong>in</strong>gSystems Project (http://econ.worldbank.org/programs/2245).12. Although fees might restrict access, they may also<strong>in</strong>dicate orientation toward serv<strong>in</strong>g lenders. This variableis therefore not <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dex of public creditregistries.13. Jappelli and Pagano (1993) build a theoretical modelshow<strong>in</strong>g how <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g depends on marketconditions such as competition and heterogeneity andmobility of borrowers.14. Jappelli and Pagano 2000; Jentzsch 2003a.15. Surveys were conducted of the legal departments ofprivate and public credit registries, as well as bank<strong>in</strong>gsupervisors. <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> project and Jentzsch2003a.16. Jentzsch 2003b.17. Ke<strong>in</strong>an 2001.18. In the strict sense; <strong>in</strong> a secured transaction, theownership title of the asset rema<strong>in</strong>s with the debtor.But <strong>in</strong> many countries there are common functionalequivalents known as “title f<strong>in</strong>ance”—for example,leas<strong>in</strong>g and conditional sales—whereby the creditortakes title of the asset.19. Mann 1997; Hill 2002.20. Survey estimates from secured transactions lawyers<strong>in</strong>dicate that (on average) around 30 percent ofcollateral enforcement is <strong>in</strong>side <strong>in</strong>solvency proceed<strong>in</strong>gs.However, <strong>in</strong> many countries, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g Nigeria,Albania, Bolivia, and the Russian Federation, expertsestimate that the rate is under 10 percent.21. This four-po<strong>in</strong>t measure of creditor rights wasdeveloped by La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, andVishny (1998) and orig<strong>in</strong>ally covered 49 countries as of1995.22. Except that those <strong>in</strong> the richest quartile are less likelythan those <strong>in</strong> the upper-middle quartile to have apublic credit registry.23. Miller 2003.24. See, for example, Besley 1995.25. <strong>Bank</strong>s and nondepository f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions(IFS l<strong>in</strong>e 22d).26. Djankov, McLiesh, and Shleifer 2003.27. The analysis excludes three outliers with extremelyhigh spreads (Brazil, Uruguay, and Bolivia).28. Jappelli and Pagano 2002.29. Love and Mylenko 2003; Gal<strong>in</strong>do and Miller 2001.30. La Porta and others 1998; Lev<strong>in</strong>e 1998.31. K<strong>in</strong>g and Lev<strong>in</strong>e 1993; Lev<strong>in</strong>e 1997; Rajan andZ<strong>in</strong>gales 1998; Demirguc-Kunt and Maksimovic 1998.32. Fuentes and Maquieira 2001.33. Barron and Staten 2003.34. Bolton and Scharfste<strong>in</strong> 1996; Hill 2002.69


6Clos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>The penalty for declar<strong>in</strong>g bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>Ancient Rome was slavery or be<strong>in</strong>g cut topieces. The choice was left to the creditor. Bythe Middle Ages, the treatment of <strong>in</strong>solventdebtors had softened considerably. In Northern Italy,bankrupt debtors hit their naked backside aga<strong>in</strong>st arock three times before a jeer<strong>in</strong>g crowd and cried out,“I declare bankruptcy.” 1 In French medieval cities,bankrupts were required to wear a green cap at alltimes, and anyone could throw stones at them. InEngland, bankrupt debtors were thrown <strong>in</strong>to prison,were often pilloried, and occasionally had one ear cutoff. 2The English bankruptcy law of 1732 was the firstmodern bankruptcy law. The United States <strong>in</strong>troducedits first bankruptcy law <strong>in</strong> 1800, copy<strong>in</strong>g the Englishlaw. 3 France, Germany, and Spa<strong>in</strong> adopted their firstbankruptcy laws <strong>in</strong> the early n<strong>in</strong>eteenth century.Imprisonment still featured as a common punishment,and bankruptcy was seen a means to liquidate f<strong>in</strong>anciallydistressed companies and distribute their rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gassets among creditors. A rudimentary rehabilitationprocedure—designed to reorganize the debt of abankrupt firm so that it could cont<strong>in</strong>ue operat<strong>in</strong>g—was developed <strong>in</strong> Austria <strong>in</strong> 1914 but was rarely used.Similar procedures were <strong>in</strong>troduced <strong>in</strong> Spa<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> 1922, <strong>in</strong>South Africa <strong>in</strong> 1926, and <strong>in</strong> Belgium, France, Germany,Netherlands, and the United States <strong>in</strong> the 1930s. 4A modern reorganization procedure did not appearuntil 1978, when Chapter 11 was adopted <strong>in</strong> the UnitedStates. In the next 25 years a wave of bankruptcyreforms brought reorganization procedures to Italy <strong>in</strong>1979, France <strong>in</strong> 1985, the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom <strong>in</strong> 1986,New Zealand <strong>in</strong> 1989, Australia and Canada <strong>in</strong> 1992,Germany <strong>in</strong> 1994 and 1999, Sweden <strong>in</strong> 1996, andJapan and Mexico <strong>in</strong> 2000, to name a few. By mid-2003 every country <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> sample, withthe exception of Cambodia, had bankruptcy laws.Today’s bankruptcy regimes differ enormously <strong>in</strong>their efficiency and use. Canada, Ireland, Japan,Norway, and S<strong>in</strong>gapore take less than a year toresolve bankruptcy. Brazil, Chad, and India takemore than a decade. In Norway and S<strong>in</strong>gapore itcosts about 1 percent of the value of the estate toresolve <strong>in</strong>solvency. In the Czech Republic, thePhilipp<strong>in</strong>es, Thailand, Uganda, and Venezuela, itmay cost as much as half the estate to go throughformal bankruptcy. Angola, Bangladesh, Burundi,Mozambique, and Togo have bankruptcy laws on thebooks, but they are almost never used. In Belarusand Uzbekistan, bankruptcy is used mostly toliquidate dormant enterprises.<strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy is still <strong>in</strong> its <strong>in</strong>fancy <strong>in</strong> many countries,and reform cont<strong>in</strong>ues even <strong>in</strong> the best-perform<strong>in</strong>gjurisdictions. The average age of the bankruptcy law<strong>in</strong> the 10 best-practice countries—Belgium, Canada,F<strong>in</strong>land, Ireland, Japan, the Republic of Korea, Latvia,the Netherlands, Norway, and S<strong>in</strong>gapore—is six years.Some countries, such as Egypt and Pakistan, are <strong>in</strong> theprocess of revis<strong>in</strong>g their bankruptcy laws. Brazil andSpa<strong>in</strong> just did.Three areas of reform hold the most promise. Oneis choos<strong>in</strong>g the appropriate way of deal<strong>in</strong>g with<strong>in</strong>solvency given a country’s <strong>in</strong>come and <strong>in</strong>stitutionalcapacity. Poor countries are generally better off witheffective debt enforcement outside of <strong>in</strong>solvency thanwith complicated bankruptcy laws and specializedcourts. The second is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>volvement of71


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>72stakeholders <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>solvency process rather thanrely<strong>in</strong>g on a court to make bus<strong>in</strong>ess decisions. Thethird is tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g judges and bankruptcy adm<strong>in</strong>istrators<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>solvency law and practice.Some countries, such as Latvia and Mexico, haverecently taken steps <strong>in</strong> all those areas, with significantimprovements <strong>in</strong> the efficiency of bankruptcy procedures.Others, such as Germany and Japan, havereformed their bankruptcy law to make it moreattractive to debtors. A third group of countries,<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g Argent<strong>in</strong>a and Moldova, focuses on thetra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g of judges. Still other countries, such asTanzania and Thailand, have reformed their judicialstructure to allow for specialized courts or specializedsections with<strong>in</strong> courts.Countries with ill-function<strong>in</strong>g judiciaries are betteroff without sophisticated bankruptcy systems. Thereis a general misperception that bankruptcy laws areneeded to enforce creditors’ rights. In practice, thelaws usually exacerbate legal uncerta<strong>in</strong>ty and delays <strong>in</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g countries. Private negotiation of debtrestructur<strong>in</strong>g under contract law—and as discussed<strong>in</strong> the previous chapter, the efficient enforcement ofsecured-debt contracts outside <strong>in</strong>solvency under collaterallaw—will succeed better.What Are the Goals of <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy?The goals of bankruptcy are universal. The first goalis to maximize the total value of proceeds received bycreditors, shareholders, employees, and other stakeholders.<strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>es should be rehabilitated, sold as ago<strong>in</strong>g concern, or liquidated—whichever generatesthe greatest total value. The second goal is to rehabilitateviable bus<strong>in</strong>esses and liquidate unviable ones.In other words, bankruptcy law should be neitherhard on good bus<strong>in</strong>esses nor soft on bad ones. Thethird goal is a smooth, predictable transition <strong>in</strong>claims priority between good and bad f<strong>in</strong>ancialstates of the company—to reduce <strong>in</strong>vestors’ risk. Thatgoal is achieved by ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the absolute priorityof claims <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy. Good bankruptcy lawsgenerally achieve the three goals. Bad ones do not. Asa result, they make everyone worse off—both debtorsand creditors.Goal #1: Maximiz<strong>in</strong>g ValueThe value of a bankrupt bus<strong>in</strong>ess is maximized whenless of it is dissipated <strong>in</strong> the direct and <strong>in</strong>direct costsof bankruptcy—and the debtor is liquidated, sold, orrehabilitated quickly. If bankruptcy is expensive anddrawn out, both the distressed companies and theircreditors will avoid it. Even if resolution is successful,large costs are likely to dra<strong>in</strong> the resources of alreadydistressedcompany. Similarly, if the bankruptcy processlasts too long, the focus of management will be onimmediate, process-related tasks rather than on strategicissues. And suppliers and customers will be likely tof<strong>in</strong>d a way to cease deal<strong>in</strong>g with the bankruptbus<strong>in</strong>ess. 5 For example, the bankruptcy process <strong>in</strong>Brazil takes 10 years and as a result is seldom used.A survey of bankruptcy lawyers and judges,conducted <strong>in</strong> cooperation with the International BarAssociation, estimated the time it takes to completethe <strong>in</strong>solvency procedure and its cost, as a share oftotal estate value. 6 The estimates refer to the <strong>in</strong>solvencyof a domestic company runn<strong>in</strong>g a hotel <strong>in</strong> thedowntown area of a country’s most populous city.The ma<strong>in</strong> features of hypothetical case are as follows. 7The company’s only significant asset is the real estateon which the hotel operates. The hotel is mortgagedto a domestic commercial bank, its ma<strong>in</strong> creditor. Thecompany has 201 employees and 50 suppliers, and itsrevenues are fixed as a multiple (1,000 times) of theper capita <strong>in</strong>come of each country. That amounts to$34 million <strong>in</strong> annual revenues <strong>in</strong> the United States,or $240,000 <strong>in</strong> Madagascar. The revenues were calibratedto match the bus<strong>in</strong>ess volume of a mediumsizehotel bus<strong>in</strong>ess.The company is controlled by a majority shareholderand is not publicly traded. It defaults on its bank loanafter a difficult f<strong>in</strong>ancial year but cont<strong>in</strong>ues to operateand make payments to unsecured creditors. The bankprefers to liquidate its security <strong>in</strong> the fastest andcheapest way, while management and the ma<strong>in</strong> ownertry to keep the company <strong>in</strong> operation. The unsecuredcreditors—hold<strong>in</strong>g 99 percent of the claims by numberbut only 26 percent by value—support the rescueeffort. The company is assumed to be worth more asa go<strong>in</strong>g concern than it would be <strong>in</strong> a piecemealliquidation.


Clos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Figure 6.1Clos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> Serbia and MontenegroProcedure 0 500 1,000 1,500 2,000 2,5001. The company defaults2. The ma<strong>in</strong> creditor files for an executive decision to enforcewith the municipal court3. The company’s management appeals4. Unsecured creditors sue the company to collect their claims5.The court issues a decision to enforce and ordersan assessment of the estate value6. The judge announces a liquidation auction and sets a date7. Judge establishes a deadl<strong>in</strong>e for deposit of purchase price8. The National <strong>Bank</strong> alerts the court that it has blocked thecompany’s account due to unsatisfied f<strong>in</strong>ancial commitments9. A liquidation order is published, and adm<strong>in</strong>istrator isappo<strong>in</strong>ted10. The adm<strong>in</strong>istrator takes his post11. Management appeals the liquidation order aga<strong>in</strong>, butthe appeal does not postpone the order‘s enforcement12. Creditors report their claims to the <strong>in</strong>solvency council13. The bankruptcy estate is assessed and claims are approved14. A period for disputes over the claims is allowed15. The bankruptcy estate is sold off and the judge issuesa f<strong>in</strong>al liquidation resolution16. The rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g funds are disbursed to unsecured creditors17. The adm<strong>in</strong>istrator prepares the f<strong>in</strong>al reportSource: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.On the basis of this hypothetical case, lawyers andjudges <strong>in</strong> all countries completed a survey on thesequence of procedures and their tim<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>solvencyprocess. Time is measured <strong>in</strong> days, as therespondent attorneys answer questions about theduration of each bankruptcy procedure. Cost isdef<strong>in</strong>ed as the cost of the entire bankruptcy process,<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g court costs, <strong>in</strong>solvency practitioners’ costs,and the costs of <strong>in</strong>dependent assessors, lawyers, andaccountants. For a hypothetical f<strong>in</strong>ancially distressedcompany <strong>in</strong> Argent<strong>in</strong>a, from the moment it files forbankruptcy to the actual resolution, the <strong>in</strong>solvencyprocess lasts two years and n<strong>in</strong>e months and costsTimeDays18 percent of the value ofthe bankruptcy estate. Theoutcome is <strong>in</strong>efficient, becausethe assets are sold piecemeal,even though the bus<strong>in</strong>esswould be worth more as ago<strong>in</strong>g concern. In Serbiaand Montenegro, the liquidationprocedure takesmore than seven years andcosts about 38 percent ofthe value of the bankruptcyestate (figure 6.1). In practice,creditors can and do appealthe f<strong>in</strong>al distribution ofproceeds, so the processcould take another sixmonths to one year.Canada, F<strong>in</strong>land, Japan,Norway, and S<strong>in</strong>gapore areamong the top 10 countries<strong>in</strong> both shortest time andlowest cost (table 6.1).The Czech Republic, thePhilipp<strong>in</strong>es, and Serbia andMontenegro are amongthe bottom 10. Developedcountries have more-efficientbankruptcy procedures,especially <strong>in</strong> their duration.All 10 of the jurisdictionswith the fastest proceduresare high-<strong>in</strong>come countries. N<strong>in</strong>e of the 10 countrieswith the cheapest bankruptcy procedures are high<strong>in</strong>comecountries.Across regions, South Asian jurisdictions have themost time-consum<strong>in</strong>g bankruptcy procedures. Theiraverage duration is more than five years, and theaverage cost is 9 percent of the bankruptcy estate(figure 6.2). The most expensive bankruptcy proceduresare <strong>in</strong> East Asian countries, averag<strong>in</strong>g 20percent of the estate. Other regions where bankruptcyis costly are Africa, Europe and Central Asia, and Lat<strong>in</strong>America. Countries <strong>in</strong> those regions also have fairlylong procedures, 3 to 4 years. In contrast, OECD73


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>74Table 6.1Time and Cost of <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy ProceduresFastestIrelandJapanS<strong>in</strong>gaporeCanadaTaiwan (Ch<strong>in</strong>a)BelgiumF<strong>in</strong>landNorwayAustraliaHong Kong (Ch<strong>in</strong>a)CheapestS<strong>in</strong>gaporeF<strong>in</strong>landNorwayNetherlandsColombiaGeorgiaKuwaitJapanCanadaNew ZealandSource: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.SlowestIndiaChadBrazilCzech RepublicMauritaniaSerbia and MontenegroPanamaIndonesiaChilePhilipp<strong>in</strong>esMost ExpensiveMacedonia, FYRIsraelVenezuela, RBUnited Arab EmiratesUgandaChadCzech RepublicSerbia and MontenegroPanamaPhilipp<strong>in</strong>escountries have procedures that are cheap (less than 8percent of the estate value) and short (less than twoyears on average). With the exception of developedcountries, <strong>in</strong>solvency is a long and expensive process allaround the world. In develop<strong>in</strong>g countries it takes threeor more years and costs 15 percent of the estate value.Some other f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs on time and cost:• Nordic proceed<strong>in</strong>gs are the fastest, at around twoyears on average, and also the cheapest, at 4.5 percentof the estate value. F<strong>in</strong>land and Norway are amongthe world’s top countries on time and cost.• English-legal-orig<strong>in</strong> countries are the secondfastestlegal-orig<strong>in</strong> group <strong>in</strong> resolv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>solvency, at2.7 years.• In French-civil-law countries, <strong>in</strong>solvency lasts onaverage 3.7 years, and it costs 15 percent of theestate value.• In transition countries, the process lasts aroundthree years and costs 7 percent of the estate value.• Some of the poorest countries seem more efficientthan many of the middle-<strong>in</strong>come countries. Thisf<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g is <strong>in</strong> part a product of the low use of thejudicial system <strong>in</strong> poor countries. For example,<strong>in</strong>terviews <strong>in</strong> Bangladesh reveal that bankruptcy isalmost never used as a mechanism for resolv<strong>in</strong>gdistress. The only cases that go through the bankruptcysystem deal with state-owned enterprises;those cases typically <strong>in</strong>volve the write-off of debt.In the United States, there are more than 55,000corporate bankruptcy cases each year, 20 per 100,000population. 8 In the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, there aresome 40,000 a year, about 75 per 100,000 population.In contrast, about 500 bankruptcy cases were started<strong>in</strong> Spa<strong>in</strong>, about 1 per 100,000 population. In somedevelop<strong>in</strong>g countries, bankruptcy is often used: morethan 1,000 bankruptcy petitions were filed <strong>in</strong> Malaysia<strong>in</strong> 2002, about 17 per 100,000 people. In Belarus,Egypt, and Uzbekistan, nearly 1,000 cases are filedeach year. But most of them are requests for the liquidationof dormant enterprises (as <strong>in</strong> Belarus) orserve merely as a threat po<strong>in</strong>t for private negotiationsof debt restructur<strong>in</strong>g (as <strong>in</strong> Egypt, where fewer than 5percent of fil<strong>in</strong>gs result <strong>in</strong> true bankruptcy proceed<strong>in</strong>gs).In Albania, the Democratic Republic ofCongo, Burundi, Ghana, Haiti, Honduras, Laos,Figure 6.2Time and Cost to Resolve <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcyCost, % of estate2520151050German-orig<strong>in</strong> AfricaLat<strong>in</strong> AmericaEnglish-orig<strong>in</strong> East. EuropeLower-middle-<strong>in</strong>come French-orig<strong>in</strong>Middle East Low-<strong>in</strong>comeHigh-<strong>in</strong>comeOECD high-<strong>in</strong>comeNordic-orig<strong>in</strong>2 3 4 5Time, yearsSource: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.Upper-middle-<strong>in</strong>comeEast AsiaSocialist-orig<strong>in</strong>South AsiaIncome group averageRegional averageLegal-orig<strong>in</strong> average


Clos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Madagascar, and Vietnam, bankruptcy is almost neverused by private companies or banks. (In suchcountries, the cost documented <strong>in</strong> the survey refers tobankruptcy of state-owned enterprises or subsidiariesof foreign firms.)Goal #2: Rescu<strong>in</strong>g a Viable <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong><strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy law is often oriented to clos<strong>in</strong>g downunviable companies. But sometimes the bias towarddiscont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess leads to the premature liquidationof companies <strong>in</strong> temporary distress—andthus a loss of value to society.The hypothetical case <strong>in</strong> the survey allows an <strong>in</strong>vestigationof whether viable companies will be rescued.It is a rescue case, s<strong>in</strong>ce the company is more valuableas a go<strong>in</strong>g concern than closed down and sold offpiecemeal. 9 The efficient outcome is def<strong>in</strong>ed as anybankruptcy procedure (rehabilitation, foreclosure, orliquidation) that results <strong>in</strong> a go<strong>in</strong>g-concern salewithout an <strong>in</strong>terruption <strong>in</strong> operations, or a successfulrehabilitation with management dismissed. The saleof the hotel to a real-estate developer who will convertit <strong>in</strong>to office space is less efficient than a sale toanother hotel operator would be, and value will belost even if the firm is sold to a hotel operator ifoperations are <strong>in</strong>terrupted. The company may alsorema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> the hotel bus<strong>in</strong>ess with its present ownerTable 6.2Jurisdictions with Efficient <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy Outcomesand management. That would not be efficient, though,because the management was <strong>in</strong> part responsible forthe poor f<strong>in</strong>ancial situation of the company.Several countries liquidate the <strong>in</strong>debted companyimmediately and auction it as a go<strong>in</strong>g concern. Thistask may be accomplished by means of liquidationprocedures, as <strong>in</strong> Austria, the Netherlands, andPoland—or by foreclosure of the secured debtoutside of <strong>in</strong>solvency, as <strong>in</strong> El Salvador, Jamaica, NewZealand, and S<strong>in</strong>gapore (table 6.2). Nordic countries,such as Denmark and Sweden, have bankruptcyregimes oriented toward quick liquidation. F<strong>in</strong>landallows the fail<strong>in</strong>g company to propose a rehabilitationplan—but the process h<strong>in</strong>ges on creditors’approval, and swift liquidation typically follows.Several other jurisdictions—Belgium, Canada,Colombia, the Islamic Republic of Iran, theRepublic of Korea, Peru, Portugal, Thailand, and theUnited States—allow rehabilitation proposals, butthey are typically followed by liquidation as a go<strong>in</strong>gconcernsale. Japan, Spa<strong>in</strong>, Taiwan (Ch<strong>in</strong>a), andVietnam successfully adopt a rehabilitation planwhere<strong>in</strong> management is replaced. (Here it should benoted that some countries achieve the efficientoutcome but do not reach other goals of<strong>in</strong>solvency—for example, <strong>in</strong> Poland a firm would besold as a go<strong>in</strong>g concern <strong>in</strong> liquidation but at a high75Unsuccessful Rehabilitation SuccessfulLiquidation Foreclosure Followed by Liquidation Rehabilitation with(go<strong>in</strong>g-concern sale) (go<strong>in</strong>g-concern sale) (go<strong>in</strong>g-concern sale) Management ReplacedAustria Australia Belgium AlbaniaBotswana El Salvador Canada IrelandDenmark Ethiopia Colombia JapanNetherlands Haiti F<strong>in</strong>land KazakhstanPoland Hong Kong (Ch<strong>in</strong>a) Iran, Islamic Rep. of LatviaSlovak Republic Israel Korea, Rep. of NorwaySweden Jamaica Mexico SenegalUganda Kuwait Peru Spa<strong>in</strong>Venezuela New Zealand Portugal TanzaniaSerbia and Montenegro Thailand Taiwan (Ch<strong>in</strong>a)S<strong>in</strong>gapore United States VietnamNote: In Ireland the efficient outcome is achieved through successful adoption of a plan whereby the firm is sold as a go<strong>in</strong>g concern.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>76Figure 6.3Nordic-Orig<strong>in</strong> and High-Income Countries Have Efficient <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcyOutcomesCountries achiev<strong>in</strong>g the efficient outcome77%42%35%Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.24% 23%OECD high<strong>in</strong>comeEast Asia& PacificLat<strong>in</strong> America& CaribbeanEurope &Central AsiaMiddle East &North AfricaRegion17%Sub- SaharanAfricacost—18 percent of the estate—and withoutpriority payment for the secured lender.)Almost all high-<strong>in</strong>come countries achieve the efficientoutcome. It is always achieved <strong>in</strong> Nordic countries,and <strong>in</strong> about half of common-law and German-legaltraditionjurisdictions (figure 6.3). Empirical studiesof Swedish bankruptcy show that liquidation leads tosuccessful sale as a go<strong>in</strong>g concern <strong>in</strong> more than threequartersof the cases. 10 The probability of achiev<strong>in</strong>g anefficient outcome is 42 percent <strong>in</strong> East Asia, 23 percent<strong>in</strong> French-legal-tradition jurisdictions, and only 9percent <strong>in</strong> socialist-legal-tradition jurisdictions. SouthAsia is the least efficient, with no country achiev<strong>in</strong>gthe efficient outcome. One <strong>in</strong> three countries <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong>America achieves the efficient <strong>in</strong>solvency outcome,compared with one <strong>in</strong> four <strong>in</strong> Eastern Europe andCentral Asia and one <strong>in</strong> five <strong>in</strong> Africa.0%South AsiaCountries achiev<strong>in</strong>g the efficient outcome100%Nordic48%English44%GermanLegal orig<strong>in</strong>23%French9%Socialistwast<strong>in</strong>g resources to <strong>in</strong>ducemanagement either to forestallor to precipitate bankruptcy.<strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy laws favorsecured creditors, employees’claims, or taxes. 11 In thehypothetical case, two-fifthsof the countries, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>gArmenia, Botswana, Panama,and Uruguay, favor securedcreditors over employees’ andtax claims (table 6.3). Themajority of them give priorityto labor over tax claims.Canada, France, Hungary,Portugal, and Spa<strong>in</strong> givepriority to employees’ claims,at the expense of secured claims and taxes. Onaverage, common-law countries favor secured creditors,whereas countries <strong>in</strong> the French and socialist legaltraditions favor taxes and labor. Lower-<strong>in</strong>comecountries are less likely to give priority to securedlenders.Countries that give secured lenders top priority arealso more likely to have efficient <strong>in</strong>solvency systemsthat save viable bus<strong>in</strong>esses and liquidate bad ones(figure 6.4). Priority creates <strong>in</strong>centives for all partiesto work toward an efficient outcome. Without theassurance that their claims will be paid first, seniorTable 6.3Priority of Claims—Country ExamplesSecured Claims Labor Has Taxes HaveHave Top Priority Top Priority Top PriorityGoal #3: Keep<strong>in</strong>g the Order of Claims StableThe bankruptcy system ensures the stability ofcreditors’ claims between normal times and times off<strong>in</strong>ancial distress. Senior claims need to be paid offbefore any others. Stability of priority is important fortwo reasons. First, senior creditors will be reluctant tolend if they do not have a predictable priority to theirclaim after a company is <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy. Second, hav<strong>in</strong>gdifferent priorities <strong>in</strong>side and outside of bankruptcycan result <strong>in</strong> perverse <strong>in</strong>centives, with some creditorsBolivia Brazil BosniaBelgium France ChileBulgaria Greece EgyptCambodia India JamaicaCanada Niger LebanonCh<strong>in</strong>a Poland Taiwan (Ch<strong>in</strong>a)F<strong>in</strong>land Russia TanzaniaGermany Thailand TurkeyIran, Islamic Rep. of Vietnam UgandaKenya Yemen UzbekistanSource: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.


Clos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>creditors are likely to blocka company’s entry <strong>in</strong>tobankruptcy procedures,even if it would lead to anefficient outcome. Once thecompany is <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>solvency,creditors are encouraged tomove the process towardthe efficient outcome—ifthey are confident of thepriority of their claim.Who Achieves the Goalsof <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy?Insolvency proceed<strong>in</strong>gs thusdiffer <strong>in</strong> their length andcost, achievement of anefficient outcome, and preservationof a stable order<strong>in</strong>gof claims. Which countriesEfficiency of outcomemanage to achieve all those goals best? Developedcountries generally achieve the goals of <strong>in</strong>solvency,with Canada, Japan, the Netherlands, New Zealand,and S<strong>in</strong>gapore among the top 10 (table 6.4). Irelandand the United States (not shown <strong>in</strong> the table) are tiedfor eleventh. The least effective bankruptcy regimes<strong>in</strong>clude ma<strong>in</strong>ly African countries—Angola, Burundi,Chad, the Democratic Republic of Congo, Ghana,Gu<strong>in</strong>ea, Rwanda, and Togo—along with Lao PDR <strong>in</strong>East Asia, and Honduras <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America.Latvia is perhaps the biggest surprise. A transitioneconomy that only recently revised its bankruptcy laws,Latvia is now among the top ten countries wherebankruptcy is effective <strong>in</strong> achiev<strong>in</strong>g the goals of <strong>in</strong>solvency.Indeed, Latvia adopted its first postsocialist lawonly <strong>in</strong> 1996. Subsequent amendments <strong>in</strong> 2001 def<strong>in</strong>edthe power of the <strong>in</strong>solvency adm<strong>in</strong>istrator. Lithuania,Moldova, and the Russian Federation have alsoimproved their bankruptcy laws <strong>in</strong> the past five years.Transition economies are not the only reformers.With the exception of Norway, all 10 of the bestpracticejurisdictions have revised their bankruptcylaw s<strong>in</strong>ce 1990. On average, their current laws are sixyears old. In the least effective countries, the averagebankruptcy law is more than 40 years old. 12Figure 6.4Priority of Secured Claims Is Associated with Efficient Outcomes1008060English-orig<strong>in</strong>40Lat<strong>in</strong> America East Asia German-orig<strong>in</strong>Upper-middle-<strong>in</strong>comeLower-middle-<strong>in</strong>come20Middle EastEast EuropeIncome group averageFrench-orig<strong>in</strong>Low-<strong>in</strong>comeRegional averageAfricaSocialist-orig<strong>in</strong>South AsiaLegal-orig<strong>in</strong> average050 60 70 80 90 100Priority of claimsNote: The variables are scaled so that higher values represent stricter observance of priority and higher probabilityof reach<strong>in</strong>g efficient outcomes.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.Nordic-orig<strong>in</strong>OECD high-<strong>in</strong>comeHigh-<strong>in</strong>comeTable 6.4Where Is <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy Most Effective <strong>in</strong> Achiev<strong>in</strong>g theGoals of Insolvency—And Where Least?MostS<strong>in</strong>gaporeF<strong>in</strong>landNorwayNetherlandsJapanCanadaBelgiumLatviaKorea, Rep. ofNew ZealandSource: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.LeastAngolaBurundiCongo, Dem. Rep.Gu<strong>in</strong>eaRwandaTogoChadLao PDRGhanaHondurasReform to improve bankruptcy is not about be<strong>in</strong>gfriendly to creditors or to debtors. S<strong>in</strong>gapore isextremely creditor-friendly, closely followed by Ireland.Germany, Japan, the Netherlands, and Norway arethought to balance the <strong>in</strong>te-rests of debtors andcreditors. Belgium is very debtor-friendly. 13 Yet allthose jurisdictions have quick and cheap bank-ruptcyprocedures, reach the efficient outcome, and ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>the absolute priority of claims.77


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>78Some countries—especially French-legal-orig<strong>in</strong>jurisdictions <strong>in</strong> Africa—have attempted to reach thegoals of <strong>in</strong>solvency by giv<strong>in</strong>g broader powers to thecourt. Three powers are especially important. First isthe <strong>in</strong>volvement of stakeholders <strong>in</strong> the appo<strong>in</strong>tmentand replacement of the <strong>in</strong>solvency adm<strong>in</strong>istrator.Second is access to <strong>in</strong>formation throughout the<strong>in</strong>solvency process—specifically, whether the lawsrequire that the bankruptcy adm<strong>in</strong>istrator submitreports only to the court or also to other stakeholders.Third, <strong>in</strong> some countries the court adopts aplan for rehabilitat<strong>in</strong>g a bankrupt debtor—<strong>in</strong> others,creditors and other stakeholders are required toaccept the plan before it can be implemented.Expand<strong>in</strong>g court powers <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy proceed<strong>in</strong>gson those dimensions has not had the desired effects(figure 6.5). Countries with more court power are lesslikely to achieve the goals of <strong>in</strong>solvency, even controll<strong>in</strong>gfor <strong>in</strong>come. Moreover, higher levels of courtpower are associated with more corruption—aga<strong>in</strong>,even controll<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>in</strong>come. In such jurisdictions,less court <strong>in</strong>volvement is needed, not more. Involv<strong>in</strong>gcreditors and other stakeholders <strong>in</strong> the bankruptcyprocess is important.Effects of Good <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy LawsThe ma<strong>in</strong> test of whether bankruptcy laws andjudicial procedures are good is whether f<strong>in</strong>anciallydistressed companies and their stakeholders usethem. If companies do not see <strong>in</strong>centives to enterbankruptcy, for example when no rehabilitationprocedure exists or when management gets firedautomatically, few bankruptcies will take place.Similarly, if creditors f<strong>in</strong>d bankruptcy unattractive—for example, if they are left out of the formulation oradoption of a rehabilitation plan, or if there is aprolonged stay on assets—they will f<strong>in</strong>d other meansof resolv<strong>in</strong>g their claims. The result: less chance ofmaximiz<strong>in</strong>g the value of the estate, of achiev<strong>in</strong>g theefficient outcome and stability of claims.That is precisely what happens <strong>in</strong> many countrieswith an obsolete bankruptcy regime or with <strong>in</strong>efficientjudicial processes. Interviews with the five largest banks<strong>in</strong> Mozambique, which account for about 90 percent ofFigure 6.5More Court Power—Less Likely to Achieve theGoals of InsolvencyGoals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex806040207961Score 0 Score 33 Score 67 Score 100Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dexNote: The correlation between the court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex and the goals-of<strong>in</strong>solvency<strong>in</strong>dex is statistically significant at the 10 percent level, controll<strong>in</strong>g for<strong>in</strong>come per capita. The variables are scaled so that higher scores represent morecourt powers and a higher likelihood that <strong>in</strong>solvency goals will be achieved.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.bank loans to enterprises, reveal that they never useformal bankruptcy. Instead, each bank has a large debtrecovery department that negotiates defaulted loansdirectly with the customers. Similarly, private bankshave very rarely used bankruptcy <strong>in</strong> Bangladesh, Ben<strong>in</strong>,Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso, Cameroon, Nepal, Niger, Mali, andMongolia. When the bankruptcy law is used <strong>in</strong> thosecountries, it is generally only to clear a state-ownedcompany from debt—or to liquidate a subsidiary of aforeign company. Though exist<strong>in</strong>g on paper, the law isnot used <strong>in</strong> the course of do<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess. By contrast, <strong>in</strong>countries where bankruptcy procedures are efficient,many cases are filed. Belgium, Denmark, F<strong>in</strong>land,Norway, Sweden, and Switzerland have the highest<strong>in</strong>cidence of fil<strong>in</strong>gs—on average, 50 companies forevery 100,000 citizens each year (figure 6.6).In countries without efficient bankruptcy procedures,out-of-court negotiations (workouts) are thema<strong>in</strong> mechanism for reorganiz<strong>in</strong>g debt (table 6.5). 14Workouts are usually faster, cheaper, and more predictablethan formal bankruptcy. Contracts can bewritten so as to avoid reference to the bankruptcylaw—by us<strong>in</strong>g blank promissory notes, writ<strong>in</strong>g leas<strong>in</strong>gcontracts, or giv<strong>in</strong>g power of attorney to creditors. 15But the contracts may be difficult to enforce <strong>in</strong>countries where either party has strong rights <strong>in</strong>5342


Clos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Figure 6.6Inefficient <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy Systems—Not Used<strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy cases per 100,000 people35251551Worst2 3 4 5Countries ranked by goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex, qu<strong>in</strong>tilesSource: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database and national judicial statistics.Best<strong>in</strong>stitutions for deal<strong>in</strong>g with bankruptcy, given acountry’s <strong>in</strong>come. A second <strong>in</strong>gredient is the<strong>in</strong>volvement of stakeholders rather than the court<strong>in</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess decisions. A third is the availability ofwell-tra<strong>in</strong>ed judges and bankruptcy trustees,supported by well-function<strong>in</strong>g clerical and adm<strong>in</strong>istrativestaff. Some developed countries, such asItaly, are known to have less-than-efficient legalprovisions <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy but a very efficientjudicial process. In contrast, many develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries—such as Côte d’Ivoire, Georgia, and thePhilipp<strong>in</strong>es—have good bankruptcy laws on thebooks but an <strong>in</strong>efficient judicial process. In eithercase, creditors perceive the bankruptcy system as<strong>in</strong>efficient and seldom use it.Table 6.5Private Workouts—the Norm <strong>in</strong> Countries withInefficient <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcyBangladesh Ghana MauritaniaBelarus Guatemala MozambiqueBolivia Indonesia PakistanBrazil Iran, Islamic Rep. of PanamaCosta Rica Jamaica PortugalEgypt Malaysia TurkeyGeorgia Mali UruguaySource: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.formal bankruptcy, because that party will hold outand cause delays.Where the process of bankruptcy is efficient, accessto external credit is both easier and cheaper. 16 That isso because creditors can be reasonably sure of collect<strong>in</strong>gon their loans when a firm fails. The enforcementof such rights <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy is also shown to beassociated with deeper private credit markets andsmaller <strong>in</strong>terest-rate spreads <strong>in</strong> developed countries(figure 6.7). Such is not the case <strong>in</strong> poor countries,suggest<strong>in</strong>g aga<strong>in</strong> that f<strong>in</strong>ancial distress would be betteraddressed by private negotiations under contractlaw, without us<strong>in</strong>g the bankruptcy law.What to Reform?There are several <strong>in</strong>gredients <strong>in</strong> an efficientbankruptcy system. 17 One is the choice of appropriateChoos<strong>in</strong>g Appropriate InstitutionsWhat constitutes good bankruptcy law? The answerdepends on the capacity of the judiciary to deal withsophisticated commercial cases. Where judges are welltra<strong>in</strong>ed and have the support of clerks to do researchand manage the workflow, where account<strong>in</strong>g practicesare reliable and the legal profession is experienced <strong>in</strong>handl<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>ess litigation, the law can provide amenu of options—<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g liquidation and rehabilitationunder bankruptcy provisions, as well asenforcement of collateral agreements outside of<strong>in</strong>solvency under secured-transactions and contractslaw. Only high-<strong>in</strong>come countries and a few uppermiddle-<strong>in</strong>comecountries (Republic of Korea, Latvia)meet those criteria. In lower-middle-<strong>in</strong>come countries,the best bankruptcy law is the one that allows forsimple liquidation procedures. Enforcement outside ofbankruptcy, under secured-transactions law or privateworkouts, is another option.In poor and lower-middle-<strong>in</strong>come countries,ensur<strong>in</strong>g the efficient enforcement of collateralthrough private mechanisms or summary judgmentstakes priority. To the extent that they already exist,more-sophisticated bankruptcy procedures mayrema<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> force. But the emphasis for reform should beon creation ofsimple debt-enforcement mechanismsthrough improvements <strong>in</strong> secured-transactions law,commercial codes, and cost reductions. The reason: thejudiciary would not have the capacity to adm<strong>in</strong>ister79


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>Figure 6.7Achiev<strong>in</strong>g the Goals of Insolvency Is Associated with Better Credit Outcomes <strong>in</strong> Wealthy Countries . . .Private credit, % of GDP1.8Interest-rate spread35801.61.41.21.00.80.60.40.20.00 20 40 60 80 100 120Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex. . . But Not <strong>in</strong> Poor CountriesPrivate credit, % of GDP1.41.21.00.80.60.40.20.00 20 40 60 80 100Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex3025201510500 20 40 60 80 100 120Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dexInterest-rate spread353025201510500 20 40 60 80 100Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dexNote: The correlations shown <strong>in</strong> these figures are statistically significant at the 5 percent level for wealthy countries, statistically <strong>in</strong>significant for poorer countries<strong>in</strong> the case of private credit, and statistically significant at the 10 percent level for poorer countries <strong>in</strong> the case of <strong>in</strong>terest-rate spread.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.<strong>in</strong>solvency provisions efficiently. Furthermore, thecredit market is small, and enterprises typically haveonly one f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitution as the ma<strong>in</strong> lender.The present state of bankruptcy practice around theworld is broadly consistent with that pattern. Severalpoor and lower-middle-<strong>in</strong>come countries—Bosniaand Herzegov<strong>in</strong>a, Egypt, Jordan, Kenya, Nepal,Panama, Syria, Uganda, and Zambia—do not have arehabilitation procedure. Where one exists, as <strong>in</strong>Bulgaria or Mozambique, it is rarely used. Of the1,320 Bulgarian companies that entered bankruptcy<strong>in</strong> 2000–01, only 37 applied for rehabilitation. InMozambique, as already mentioned, only state-ownedcompanies have used the rehabilitation procedure.In still other countries, some attractive features ofrehabilitation—such as the ability to raise newf<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g that enjoys priority over exist<strong>in</strong>g debt—donot exist. Jordan, Lebanon, Moldova, Ukra<strong>in</strong>e, and theRepublic of Yemen do not give priority to new debt(table 6.6). In contrast, Germany and the UnitedK<strong>in</strong>gdom recently enhanced their rehabilitationprocedures. 18


Clos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Table 6.6Countries Where New Debt Does Not Receive HighPriorityAlbania Egypt Malaysia SwedenAustria Guatemala Moldova SyriaAzerbaijan India Nicaragua TurkeyBolivia Iran, Islamic Rep. Nigeria Ukra<strong>in</strong>eBosnia Jamaica Pakistan UzbekistanCh<strong>in</strong>a Jordan S<strong>in</strong>gapore VenezuelaCzech Rep. Lebanon Slovak Rep. Yemen, Rep.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.In rich countries, a specialized court can improve<strong>in</strong>solvency procedures, because specialized judgeshave better tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and more expertise and becauseissues not covered sufficiently <strong>in</strong> the law are decidedswiftly <strong>in</strong> the profession. The existence of specializedcourts is significantly related to <strong>in</strong>solvency proceed<strong>in</strong>gsthat are shorter (by almost a year) and cheaper (by athird). But they may be little used <strong>in</strong> countries withfew bankruptcy cases, and they come at the cost ofspread<strong>in</strong>g scarce resources more th<strong>in</strong>ly. In suchcountries, a specialized section or specialized judgeswith<strong>in</strong> the general court should be the preferredvenue for resolv<strong>in</strong>g f<strong>in</strong>ancial distress.Involv<strong>in</strong>g Stakeholders<strong>in</strong> the Insolvency ProcessReforms of bankruptcy procedures have emphasizedmore powers for stakeholders, with the judgesupervis<strong>in</strong>g and facilitat<strong>in</strong>g the process—not controll<strong>in</strong>git. The appo<strong>in</strong>tment and replacement of the<strong>in</strong>solvency adm<strong>in</strong>istrator is one such area, as withLatvia <strong>in</strong> its 2001 reforms. Best practice suggests thatthe court choose at random from a list of licensedadm<strong>in</strong>istrators. Creditors may request replacement ofthe adm<strong>in</strong>istrator <strong>in</strong> the event of biased or fraudulentbehavior. 19 But <strong>in</strong> many countries, the creditors arenot consulted dur<strong>in</strong>g the adm<strong>in</strong>istrator’s appo<strong>in</strong>tmentand have no possibility of replac<strong>in</strong>g one, as <strong>in</strong>Cameroon, Ecuador, France, Lithuania, Paraguay,Poland, and Taiwan (Ch<strong>in</strong>a). Countries where creditorshave a say <strong>in</strong> appo<strong>in</strong>tment and replacement havebankruptcy procedures that are significantly cheaper(11 percent of estate value versus 15 percent) and moreefficient <strong>in</strong> achiev<strong>in</strong>g the right outcome (65 percent ofcountries do versus 36 percent that do not).Creditors also need to be <strong>in</strong>formed about the workof the bankruptcy adm<strong>in</strong>istrator. The ma<strong>in</strong> mechanismof bankruptcy law is to require the adm<strong>in</strong>istrator tofile reports with creditors, dur<strong>in</strong>g and at the end ofthe case, on transactions <strong>in</strong>volv<strong>in</strong>g the debtor andother decisions made <strong>in</strong> the course of bankruptcy. Inseveral countries, the adm<strong>in</strong>istrator is not required tofile a report, as <strong>in</strong> Bolivia, Colombia, India, Korea,Moldova, Spa<strong>in</strong>, Taiwan (Ch<strong>in</strong>a), Thailand, Uruguay,and Vietnam. In yet other countries, a report is filedonly with the court and is not accessible to creditors.Such a report would <strong>in</strong>form the creditors and providea higher chance of ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g absolute priority.Another set of judicial procedures def<strong>in</strong>es the powersof various stakeholders <strong>in</strong> formulat<strong>in</strong>g and adopt<strong>in</strong>g arehabilitation plan. It is hard to justify laws thatmandate the formulation of a plan by the court, withouteffective participation of creditors or management. Butsuch is the case <strong>in</strong> many countries, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g Ben<strong>in</strong>,Mali, Morocco, and Tunisia. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the adoption ofthe plan, creditors vote <strong>in</strong>dividually or by class <strong>in</strong> mostcountries, with an acceptance threshold of themajority of claims by value. That method ensures thatthe will of major creditors is taken <strong>in</strong>to account. But <strong>in</strong>Azerbaijan, Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso, Cameroon, Costa Rica, Mali,Moldova, and Niger, the court adopts the plan withoutconsider<strong>in</strong>g the views of creditors. Ignor<strong>in</strong>g them iscounter<strong>in</strong>tuitive—because one of the goals ofbankruptcy is to preserve the value of creditors’ claims.Tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy Judges andAdm<strong>in</strong>istratorsJudicial procedure will improve with qualified judges,and tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g judges <strong>in</strong> commercial litigation has becomewidespread. From Thailand to Ecuador to Nepal tothe Dom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic, a judicial career depends ongo<strong>in</strong>g through specialized tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>gaccount<strong>in</strong>g and bus<strong>in</strong>ess courses. Several countrieshave recently established <strong>in</strong>stitutes to tra<strong>in</strong> judges <strong>in</strong>handl<strong>in</strong>g commercial cases (chapter 4).In most middle-<strong>in</strong>come countries where bankruptcyadm<strong>in</strong>istrators are responsible for manag<strong>in</strong>g acompany <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>solvency, the profession is still develop<strong>in</strong>g.81


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>82Progress is needed <strong>in</strong> two areas: ensur<strong>in</strong>g the properqualifications for adm<strong>in</strong>istrators (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the necessaryeducation and bus<strong>in</strong>ess experience prior to receiv<strong>in</strong>ga license), and periodically renew<strong>in</strong>g adm<strong>in</strong>istrators’licenses on the basis of cont<strong>in</strong>ued tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and practicewith <strong>in</strong>solvency cases. Lithuania and the Czech andSlovak Republics do not have education requirementsfor adm<strong>in</strong>istrators. 20 Thus, the lists of licensed adm<strong>in</strong>istratorsthere are long—more than 800 <strong>in</strong> Lithuaniaand more than 1,600 <strong>in</strong> the Czech Republic. Furthermore,many adm<strong>in</strong>istrators do not have legal,account<strong>in</strong>g, or economics education. Nor do themajority of adm<strong>in</strong>istrators have bus<strong>in</strong>ess experience,which is crucial for manag<strong>in</strong>g a company <strong>in</strong> distress.In some countries, professional associations haveprovidedtra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g. But cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g education needs to bemandatory, as it is <strong>in</strong> the account<strong>in</strong>g and legal professions.In Argent<strong>in</strong>a, <strong>in</strong>solvency adm<strong>in</strong>istrators arerequired to receive a certa<strong>in</strong> number of tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g creditswith<strong>in</strong> a four-year period. If they do not, their licensesare revoked. 21 In lower-middle-<strong>in</strong>come countries, wherethe trustee profession is still nascent, regulators canconsider licens<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dividual experts, along with consult<strong>in</strong>g,account<strong>in</strong>g, and law firms, which have an easiertime pull<strong>in</strong>g together the required capacity. But stricterlicens<strong>in</strong>g should not benefit just one profession, such aslawyers and law firms. Such reform, now be<strong>in</strong>g considered<strong>in</strong> Croatia, alleviates some problems but createsmany others—among them, reduc<strong>in</strong>g competition <strong>in</strong>the trustee market and leav<strong>in</strong>g the pool of managementskills and account<strong>in</strong>g competencies deficient.Notes1. Bruno 1561.2. Lev<strong>in</strong>thal 1919.3. Berglof, Rosenthal, and von Thadden 2002.4. Rajak 1997.5. Posner 1992.6. The survey was conducted <strong>in</strong> cooperation withCommittee J (Insolvency and Creditor Rights). <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong><strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> gratefully acknowledges the leadership ofSel<strong>in</strong>da Melnik, Esq., Chairwoman of Committee J atthe time of the survey.7. For a further description, see the data notes section <strong>in</strong>the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Indicators tables.8. Claessens and Klapper (2001) collect data on 35 jurisdictions,primarily <strong>in</strong> the OECD.9. The hypothetical case does not address whetheranonviable company is rescued—because the cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>gexistence of <strong>in</strong>solvent firms is typically a privilege oflarge enterprises that have national importance or alarge number of employees—firms “too big to fail.”10. Stromberg 2000, Thorburn 2000.11. Court costs almost always have the top priority. In somecountries, postpetition claims take priority over securedclaims. A further <strong>in</strong>dicator of priority is the <strong>in</strong>cidence ofshareholders’ gett<strong>in</strong>g paid before secured creditors.Studies of the United States (such as Betker 1995) showthat shareholders often get paid <strong>in</strong> reorganization whencreditors have not been fully paid. Such reversals of theorder of claims may occur <strong>in</strong> Argent<strong>in</strong>a, Belarus, theDom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic, Ecuador, Guatemala, Indonesia,Nigeria, Taiwan (Ch<strong>in</strong>a), and Ukra<strong>in</strong>e.12. Pistor and others (forthcom<strong>in</strong>g) also f<strong>in</strong>d that reformof commercial codes is faster <strong>in</strong> developed countries.13. Wood 1995.14. Modigliani and Perotti 2000.15. Another scenario for the use of private workouts iswhen the rights of debtors and creditors are balancedand the judicial process is efficient and predictable.For example, private workouts are often used <strong>in</strong>New Zealand and Switzerland. In contrast, they areseldom used <strong>in</strong> countries with strong creditors’ rights,such as Hong Kong (Ch<strong>in</strong>a), S<strong>in</strong>gapore, and the UnitedK<strong>in</strong>gdom, or <strong>in</strong> countries with strong debtors’ rights,such as Ireland, F<strong>in</strong>land, and Spa<strong>in</strong>. This scenario doesnot arise <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, where the outcome ofthe bankruptcy process is typically far from predictable.16. La Porta and Lopez-de-Silanes 2001.17. See La Porta and others (1997, 1998) for a view fromthe creditor’s perspective, and Hart (2000) and Stiglitz(2001) for an overall review of bankruptcy provisions.18. Couwenberg 2001.19. The court approves any request for replacement of theadm<strong>in</strong>istrator by creditors <strong>in</strong> all countries exceptGuatemala, Jamaica, and the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom.20. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2001a, <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2001b, <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>2002a, <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2002b.21. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2002c.


7The Practice of RegulationThe pervasiveness of government regulation<strong>in</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity raises questions. Whichcountries regulate the most? Do the activitiesbe<strong>in</strong>g regulated or the characteristics of thecountry <strong>in</strong>fluence the choice of regulation? Is the levelof regulation an outcome of efficient social choice, orhas it persisted because of <strong>in</strong>ertia and a lack ofcapacity for reform? Is regulation generally good, asthe positive correlation between its growth and thegrowth of <strong>in</strong>come over the last century seems to<strong>in</strong>dicate? Or has bus<strong>in</strong>ess regulation been an obstacleto economic and social progress? What are the ma<strong>in</strong>obstacles to regulatory reform? The answers to thosequestions, presented <strong>in</strong> this report, have implicationsfor economic theory and public policy.The analysis reveals three f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs concern<strong>in</strong>g thepractice of regulation:• Regulation varies widely around the world.• Heavier regulation of bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity generallybr<strong>in</strong>gs bad outcomes, while clearly def<strong>in</strong>ed and wellprotectedproperty rights enhance prosperity.• Rich countries regulate bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong> a consistentmanner. Poor countries do not.Regulation Varies Widely around the <strong>World</strong>Belarus, Chad, and Colombia have the most proceduresto start a bus<strong>in</strong>ess: 19. Algeria, Bolivia,Paraguay, and Uganda come next, each with morethan 15 procedures. Burundi has the most proceduresto enforce contracts through the courts: 62. Angola,Ben<strong>in</strong>, Bolivia, Cameroon, El Salvador, Kazakhstan,the Kyrgyz Republic, Mexico, Panama, Paraguay,Sierra Leone, and Venezuela come next, with morethan 40 each. Costa Rica and Guatemala have themost complex contract enforcement processes. Inemployment regulation, Ethiopia has the mostgenerous paid-vacation allowance of any country, at39 work<strong>in</strong>g days a year. Panama has the mostrestrictive regulations on part-time and fixed-termemployment contracts. Bolivia and Nicaragua havethe longest m<strong>in</strong>imum daily rest for workers. Angola,Belarus, and Paraguay place the most restrictions onfir<strong>in</strong>g. The powers of the judge <strong>in</strong> decid<strong>in</strong>g the courseof <strong>in</strong>solvency proceed<strong>in</strong>gs are greatest <strong>in</strong> Ben<strong>in</strong>,Bolivia, Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso, Cameroon, Côte d’Ivoire, andthe Philipp<strong>in</strong>es.In contrast, Australia has the fewest entry procedures:2. Canada, Ireland, New Zealand, andSweden come next. Australia has the fewest proceduresto enforce a contract through the courts, with11. Norway and the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom come next, with12. With respect to labor regulations, S<strong>in</strong>gaporemakes the dismisal of workers the easiest. Denmark,Hong Kong (Ch<strong>in</strong>a), New Zealand, Sweden, and theUnited States are among the countries with the mostflexible labor regulations overall. The powers of thejudge <strong>in</strong> decid<strong>in</strong>g the course of bankruptcy proceed<strong>in</strong>gsare the weakest <strong>in</strong> Australia, F<strong>in</strong>land, NewZealand, the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, and the United States.Rich countries regulate less on all aspects of bus<strong>in</strong>essactivity covered <strong>in</strong> this report (figure 7.1). The averagenumber of procedures to start a new bus<strong>in</strong>ess is 7 <strong>in</strong>high-<strong>in</strong>come countries, 10 <strong>in</strong> upper-middle-<strong>in</strong>comecountries, 12 <strong>in</strong> lower-middle-<strong>in</strong>come countries, and11 <strong>in</strong> low-<strong>in</strong>come countries. The employment regulation<strong>in</strong>dex has an average value of 43 <strong>in</strong> high-<strong>in</strong>come83


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>84Figure 7.1Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries Regulate MoreMoreregulationLessregulation661130Low-<strong>in</strong>come53countries, 53 <strong>in</strong> upper-middle-<strong>in</strong>come countries, 55 <strong>in</strong>lower-middle-<strong>in</strong>come countries, and 53 <strong>in</strong> low-<strong>in</strong>comecountries. The average number of procedures toenforce a contract is 18 <strong>in</strong> high-<strong>in</strong>come countries, 27 <strong>in</strong>middle-<strong>in</strong>come countries, and 30 <strong>in</strong> low-<strong>in</strong>comecountries. The <strong>in</strong>dex of court powers <strong>in</strong> bankruptcy hasan average value of 43 <strong>in</strong> high-<strong>in</strong>come countries, 56 <strong>in</strong>upper-middle-<strong>in</strong>come countries, 63 <strong>in</strong> lower-middle<strong>in</strong>comecountries, and 66 <strong>in</strong> low-<strong>in</strong>come countries,where higher <strong>in</strong>dex scores reflect more regulation.Income is not the only important factor determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gdifferences <strong>in</strong> regulation. The regulatory regimes ofmost develop<strong>in</strong>g countries are not <strong>in</strong>digenous—they are shaped by their colonial heritage. When theDutch, English, French, Germans, Spaniards, andPortuguese colonized much of the world, theybrought with them their laws and <strong>in</strong>stitutions. After<strong>in</strong>dependence, many countries revised their legislation,but <strong>in</strong> only a few cases have they strayed farfrom the orig<strong>in</strong>al.Regulation <strong>in</strong> developed countries varies systematically,shaped by their history over the last millennium.1 England developed a common-law tradition,characterized by <strong>in</strong>dependent judges and juries, thelow importance of regulation, and a preference forHigh-<strong>in</strong>come(benchmark)Note: The <strong>in</strong>dicators for high-<strong>in</strong>come countries are used as benchmarks. The average value of the <strong>in</strong>dicator is shownabove each column.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.6312275556102753Lower-middle<strong>in</strong>comeUpper-middle<strong>in</strong>comeCourt-powers-<strong>in</strong>bankruptcy<strong>in</strong>dexEntry proceduresContract proceduresEmployment-laws <strong>in</strong>dex437 18 43private litigation as a meansof address<strong>in</strong>g social problems.France, follow<strong>in</strong>g the Romans,developed a civil-law tradition,characterized by stateemployedjudges, emphasison legal and proceduralcodes, and a preference forstate regulation over privatelitigation. Germany and theNordic countries developedtheir own civil-law traditions,also based on Roman law.Napoleon exported theFrench legal system, after hisconquests, to Spa<strong>in</strong>, Portugal,and Holland. Through hisand subsequent colonialconquests, the French legalsystem was transplanted toall of Lat<strong>in</strong> America, Quebec, large parts of Europe,North and West Africa, parts of the Caribbean, andparts of Asia. 2 The common-law tradition was transplantedby England to the United States, Canada(except for Quebec), Australia, New Zealand, EastAfrica, large parts of Asia (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g India), andmost of the Caribbean. The German legal systemwas adopted voluntarily <strong>in</strong> Japan, and through Japanit <strong>in</strong>fluenced the legal systems of the Republic ofKorea, Taiwan (Ch<strong>in</strong>a), and Ch<strong>in</strong>a. Austria andSwitzerland were also <strong>in</strong>fluenced by German legalscholarship. Through the Austro-Hungarian Empire,much of today’s central and eastern Europe<strong>in</strong>herited German commercial laws. F<strong>in</strong>ally, theSoviet Union <strong>in</strong>stituted its socialist legal system <strong>in</strong>the 15 republics, and <strong>in</strong>fluenced commercial law <strong>in</strong>Mongolia (figure 7.2).Those channels of transplantation suggest theexistence of systematic variations <strong>in</strong> regulation thatare not a consequence of either domestic politicalchoice or pressures toward regulatory efficiency. Thedata agree. Nordic and common-law countries regulatethe least (figure 7.3). This f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g is especially strik<strong>in</strong>gfor the common-law group, which <strong>in</strong>cludes poorcountries like Ethiopia, Ghana, Nigeria, Sierra Leone,


The Practice of RegulationIBRD 32476Nor waySweden F<strong>in</strong>landNether landsDenmar k Russian LatviaFed. LithuaniaUnitedK<strong>in</strong>gdom Ger many Poland Belar usBelgiumUkr a<strong>in</strong>eSwitz erlandMoldo vaFrance ItalyRomaniaIrelandKazakhstanKyrgyzRep.Georgia UzbekistanAr menia Az erbaijanBulgar iaTu r keySpa<strong>in</strong>Por tugalGreeceSyr ianAr abRep. Islamic Rep .of IranJordanKuwaitLebanonBurk<strong>in</strong>aFasoUkr a<strong>in</strong>eGer manyPolandCz ech RepublicSlo vak Republic*Note: Data for Taiwan, Hong Kong,and Puer to Rico have been broken outfrom the national dataset.TunisiaAustriaHungar ySlo veniaRomaniaCroatiaBosnia andHerzegov<strong>in</strong>a SerbiaandMonteneg roBulgar iaFYRMacedoniaItalyAlbaniaGreece85HaitiDom<strong>in</strong>ican Rep.Puer toRico*R.B. deVenezuelaColombiaPeru BrazilBoliviaParaguayChileArgent<strong>in</strong>aUr ugua yThailandVietnamMala ysiaRussian FederationMongoliaCh<strong>in</strong>aIsraelMoroccoPakistanNepalAlger iaAr ab Rep .of EgyptBangladeshSaudiArabiaIndiaUnited Ar abEmiratesOmanMauritaniaNigerMaliRep. of YemenChadSenegalGu<strong>in</strong>eaSr iLankaEthiopiaS<strong>in</strong>gaporeRep.ofKoreaPhilipp<strong>in</strong>esIndonesiaNiger iaJapanBen<strong>in</strong>Côted’Ivoire GhanaAustraliaSierra LeoneNe wZealandCentr alAfr ican Rep.CameroonTogoUgandaKe nyaCongoRwandaBurundiD.R. ofCongoTanzaniaAngolaMala wiZambiaMadagascarMozambiqueZimbabw eBotswanaSouthAfricaLaoP.D.R.NamibiaCambodiaTaiwan*Hong Kong*PapuaNe wGu<strong>in</strong>eaLesothoFigure 7.2<strong>World</strong> Map of Legal Orig<strong>in</strong>EnglishFrenchGermanNordicSocialistNot <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> sampleCanadaUnited StatesMexicoJamaicaHondur asGuatemalaEl Salvador Nicar aguaPanamaCosta RicaEcuadorThis map was produced by the MapDesign Unit of The <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>.The boundaries, colors, denom<strong>in</strong>ationsand any other <strong>in</strong>formation shown onthis map do not imply, on the part ofThe <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> Group, any judgmenton the legal status of any territory, orany endorsement or acceptance ofsuch boundaries.SEPTEMBER 2003Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>86Figure 7.3Nordic-Orig<strong>in</strong> and Common-Law Countries Regulate LeastRegulationMoreLess4810EntryproceduresNote: The <strong>in</strong>dicators for Nordic-orig<strong>in</strong> countries are used as benchmarks. Average values are shown above columns.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.11 12 NordicEnglishGermanSocialistFrench42 39506158Employmentlaws<strong>in</strong>dexContractproceduresand Zimbabwe. Because Nordic laws and regulationhave not been transplanted to other parts of theworld, it is not known whether they would be aseffective <strong>in</strong> poor countries, where the <strong>in</strong>cl<strong>in</strong>ation toregulate is greater, as <strong>in</strong>, say, F<strong>in</strong>land or Norway.Across all sets of <strong>in</strong>dicators, <strong>in</strong>come and legal orig<strong>in</strong>are the most important variables for expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gdifferent levels of regulatory <strong>in</strong>tervention, togetheraccount<strong>in</strong>g for more than 60 percent of the variation<strong>in</strong> regulation among the 133 <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> countries.However, heritage is not dest<strong>in</strong>y. Tunisia, a lowermiddle-<strong>in</strong>comecountry <strong>in</strong> the French legal tradition, isamong the world’s best at contract enforcement.Uruguay has one of the world’s most flexible regulationson fir<strong>in</strong>g, stand<strong>in</strong>g alone among Lat<strong>in</strong>American countries. And France is among the richestcountries despite heavier regulatory <strong>in</strong>tervention <strong>in</strong>relation to its peers.The effect of other factors is weaker and less systematic.Of particular importance: the politicalsystem. If regulations were put <strong>in</strong> place to remedymarket failures, the level of regulation should behigher <strong>in</strong> countries with political systems characterizedby the convergence of policy choices andsocial preferences—countries with more-representativegovernments. In contrast, less-democratic regimes are17222027 28334257 5869Court-powers-<strong>in</strong>bankruptcy<strong>in</strong>dexmore likely to be captured by<strong>in</strong>cumbent bus<strong>in</strong>esses and tohave regulation aimed atmaximiz<strong>in</strong>g benefits of anelite group. 3Regulation is lighter <strong>in</strong>countries with morerepresentativegovernments,more openness to competition,and greater politicalrights and media freedoms,even controll<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>in</strong>comeper capita and legal orig<strong>in</strong>. 4Regulation is heavy <strong>in</strong>Belarus and Syria, light <strong>in</strong>Canada, Latvia, and Norway.The countries with theheaviest employment regulations<strong>in</strong> Europe—Portugaland Spa<strong>in</strong>—<strong>in</strong>herited them from the dictatorships ofAntónio Salazar and Generalissimo Franco.But might not other <strong>in</strong>stitutional determ<strong>in</strong>ants beat work?• Democracy is more difficult to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>countries with ethnol<strong>in</strong>guistic differences, religiousdivisions, and low levels of human capital. And theassociation between stricter regulation anddemocracy could be driven by Lat<strong>in</strong> America orAfrica, the two cont<strong>in</strong>ents with the most-checkeredhistory of repressive governments.• Geography might <strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>in</strong>stitutional development<strong>in</strong> other ways—for example, it has been arguedthat the environment <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America was relativelysuitable to large-scale production technologies,which <strong>in</strong> turn led to significant <strong>in</strong>equalities and poorquality<strong>in</strong>stitutions. 5• Inhospitable environments for European settlers,as measured by mortality rates, may haveshaped <strong>in</strong>stitutional development. 6 The lack of<strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> public adm<strong>in</strong>istration capacity <strong>in</strong>the Congo under K<strong>in</strong>g Leopold of Belgium is oneexample. 7• F<strong>in</strong>ally, the openness of countries to tradecould encourage <strong>in</strong>stitutional development.


The Practice of RegulationThe Netherlands, an early free-trader, developedcredit registries to help its merchant class extendbus<strong>in</strong>ess to new places.Analysis controll<strong>in</strong>g for all the above factors showsthat heavy regulation on the dimensions measuredhere is strongly and consistently associated with lower<strong>in</strong>comes and with French and socialist legal orig<strong>in</strong>s. Itis sometimes associated with less democracy and withtropical climates. Other factors are not significantlyassociated with the extent of regulation.Heavier Regulation Br<strong>in</strong>gs Bad OutcomesHeavier regulation is generally associated with greater<strong>in</strong>efficiency of public <strong>in</strong>stitutions (see, for example,figures 4.7 and 4.8) and more corruption (see, forexample, figures 2.6 and 4.4)—but not with betterquality of private or public goods. The countries thatregulate the most—the poor countries—have theleast enforcement capacity and the fewest checks andbalances to ensure that regulatory discretion is notused to abuse bus<strong>in</strong>esses and extract bribes.Regulation has a perverse effect on the people itis meant to protect. Faced with a large regulatoryburden and few <strong>in</strong>centives to become formal,entrepreneurs <strong>in</strong> many develop<strong>in</strong>g countries chooseto operate <strong>in</strong> the unofficial economy (see figure 2.5).Bad <strong>in</strong>stitutions—cumbersome entry procedures,rigid employment laws, weakcreditor rights, <strong>in</strong>efficientcourts, and overly complexbankruptcy laws—simplydo not get used. Instead,bus<strong>in</strong>esses use <strong>in</strong>formal <strong>in</strong>stitutions—animprovement buta poor substitute for goodpracticeregulation.In Bolivia, one of the mostheavily regulated economies,an estimated 82 percent ofthe bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity takesplace <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal sector.There, workers enjoy no paidvacations or maternity leave.It is hard for bus<strong>in</strong>esses to get credit or resolve disputesthrough formal <strong>in</strong>stitutions, such as courts. Growth is<strong>in</strong>hibited because transactions take place only with<strong>in</strong> anarrow group of established bus<strong>in</strong>ess relationships.The resources for deliver<strong>in</strong>g basic <strong>in</strong>frastructure arereduced because bus<strong>in</strong>esses do not pay taxes. There isno quality control of products. And entrepreneurskeep their operations small, below an efficient productionsize, for fear of <strong>in</strong>spectors and the police.The results: poor economic outcomes, a reducedtax base, a large group of entrepreneurs andbus<strong>in</strong>esses never enter<strong>in</strong>g the formal sector, and ageneral failure of the state to provide for its citizens. Itis <strong>in</strong> the most heavily regulated countries that<strong>in</strong>vestment and productivity are low, and unemploymentis high (figure 7.4). 8It might be argued that hav<strong>in</strong>g less regulationwould result <strong>in</strong> lower quality products, an <strong>in</strong>ability toresolve disputes, poor protection of worker rights,and, ultimately, social unrest. That democraticcountries regulate less and that regulatory countriesdo not differ from nonregulatory ones <strong>in</strong> social capital(religion, ethnol<strong>in</strong>guistic divisions) suggest otherwise.In the absence of many burdensome regulations,bus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>in</strong> poor countries would rely on privatereputation mechanisms—as they have for centuries. 9Instead of impos<strong>in</strong>g burdensome regulations onbus<strong>in</strong>ess, a government may focus on better def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gthe property rights of its citizens and protect<strong>in</strong>gFigure 7.4Lighter Regulation Is Associated with Higher Productivity and LowerUnemploymentLabor productivity, US$1,000 per worker4030201001 2 3 401 2 3 4Less More Less MoreCountries ranked by procedures to start aCountries ranked by complexity <strong>in</strong> contractbus<strong>in</strong>ess, quartilesenforcement, quartilesSources: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database; <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> 2003.Unemployment, %1296387


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>Figure 7.5Efficient Courts and Creditor Rights Are Associated with Deeper Credit MarketsPrivate credit, % of GDPMorePrivate credit, % of GDPMoreLessCountries ranked by days to enforce a contract, decilesMoreLessCountries ranked by creditor rights, decilesMoreNote: Relationships are significant at the 1 percent level for creditor rights and at the 5 percent level for court efficiency. The correlations shown <strong>in</strong> these figures control for<strong>in</strong>come, GDP growth, <strong>in</strong>flation, credit <strong>in</strong>formation, creditor rights, and number of days to enforce a contract.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.88them aga<strong>in</strong>st <strong>in</strong>jury from other citizens and thestate. Two examples are creditor rights—the legalrights of lenders to recover their <strong>in</strong>vestment if aborrower defaults—and the efficient enforcement ofproperty rights <strong>in</strong> court. Countries that protect suchrights achieve better economic and social outcomes.Assur<strong>in</strong>g lenders of a fair return on their<strong>in</strong>vestments is associated with depth of creditmarkets, even controll<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>in</strong>come, growth,<strong>in</strong>flation, and credit <strong>in</strong>formation (figure 7.5). It alsodemocratizes access to markets, because lenderswill be will<strong>in</strong>g to extend credit beyond large, wellconnectedfirms if they know that their rights torecover loans are secure.The fact that the governments best at def<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gand protect property rights do so by us<strong>in</strong>g littleregulation suggests a trade-off between regulatory<strong>in</strong>tervention and a narrow focus on achiev<strong>in</strong>g thema<strong>in</strong> purpose of government. For example,countries with stronger creditor rights—a subset ofproperty rights—regulate employment relationslightly (figure 7.6). Rather than spend resources oncostly (and often <strong>in</strong>effective) regulation, good governmentschannel their energies <strong>in</strong>to enhanc<strong>in</strong>gprosperity.Figure 7.6Countries with Stronger Property Rights RegulateEmployment LightlyEmployment-regulation <strong>in</strong>dex605040Score 0 Score 1 Score 2 Score 3 Score 4Creditor rightsSource: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.Rich Countries Regulate <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> a ConsistentMannerIn the well-known open<strong>in</strong>g to Anna Karen<strong>in</strong>a,Tolstoypronounced: “All happy families are alike; eachunhappy family is unhappy <strong>in</strong> its own way.” The waygovernments regulate bus<strong>in</strong>ess is similar. Richcountries tend to regulate consistently on all


The Practice of RegulationTable 7.1Correlations of Regulation Indicators for Rich CountriesEntry Employment- Contract Procedural- Creditor-Procedures Regulation Index Procedures Complexity Index Rights IndexEmployment-laws <strong>in</strong>dex 0.50***Contract procedures 0.23* 0.47***Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 0.59*** 0.56*** 0.36***Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex –0.23* –0.29** –0.15 –0.08Court-powers-<strong>in</strong>-bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>dex 0.30** 0.36*** 0.23 0.41*** –0.27*Note: *** The correlation is significant at the 1 percent level. ** The correlation is significant at the 5 percent level. * The correlation is significant at the 10 percent level. The sample<strong>in</strong>cludes 49 countries classified as high-<strong>in</strong>come and upper-middle-<strong>in</strong>come by the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.dimensions of bus<strong>in</strong>ess regulation and propertyrightsprotection. Those that encourage bus<strong>in</strong>essentry by means of fewer and simpler regulations alsopermit more-flexible hir<strong>in</strong>g and fir<strong>in</strong>g, protectcreditors, and have less regulation <strong>in</strong> their courts and<strong>in</strong>solvency systems (table 7.1).Common-law countries (Australia, Canada, HongKong [Ch<strong>in</strong>a], New Zealand, the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, andthe United States) and Nordic countries (Denmark,F<strong>in</strong>land, Norway, and Sweden) offer the best practices<strong>in</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess regulation. Japan, the Republic of Korea,the Netherlands, and S<strong>in</strong>gapore also figure among thebest-practice regulators (table 7.2). Regardless of howthe <strong>in</strong>dices are constructed, those countries regulatethe least and protect property rights the most. Bycomb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g modest levels of regulation with propertyrights that are clearly def<strong>in</strong>ed and well protected, thecountries achieve what many others strive to do: haveregulators act as public servants and not publicmasters.The significant correlations across the <strong>in</strong>dicatorssuggest that all governments have a general regulatorystance toward more or less <strong>in</strong>tervention.Does that fact mean that the <strong>in</strong>dicators capture oneunderly<strong>in</strong>g variable? Apparently not, at least for thetopics covered <strong>in</strong> this report. The <strong>in</strong>dicators havedist<strong>in</strong>ctly different explanatory power over specificeconomic outcomes, as theory predicts. Thecreditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex helps expla<strong>in</strong> the depth ofcredit markets, but the employment-laws <strong>in</strong>dex andentry-regulations measures do not. And though theemployment-laws <strong>in</strong>dex helps expla<strong>in</strong> unemploymentlevels, the creditor-rights and court-powers-<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>solvency<strong>in</strong>dices bear no relation to unemployment.Although rich countries converge, there is muchmore variation among poor countries. Correlationsacross the <strong>in</strong>dicators are much less significant(table 7.3). Some countries have reformed one or twoareas of bus<strong>in</strong>ess regulation while ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g heavycontrol <strong>in</strong> others. Over the last decade, Latvia, SerbiaTable 7.2The Ten Least-Regulated Countries across <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong><strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> IndicatorsRegulatory Regulation and ItsRegulation 1 Outcomes 2 Outcomes 3Australia Canada AustraliaCanada Ireland CanadaDenmark Japan DenmarkHong Kong (Ch<strong>in</strong>a) Netherlands NetherlandsJamaica New Zealand New ZealandNetherlands Norway NorwayNew Zealand Republic of Korea S<strong>in</strong>gaporeS<strong>in</strong>gapore S<strong>in</strong>gapore SwedenSweden Sweden United K<strong>in</strong>gdomUnited K<strong>in</strong>gdom United K<strong>in</strong>gdom United StatesNotes: 1 Entry procedures, contract-enforcement procedures, procedural-complexity<strong>in</strong>dex, employment-regulation <strong>in</strong>dex, court-powers-<strong>in</strong>-bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>dex. 2 <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>-entrydays and cost, contract-enforcement days and cost, bankruptcy days and cost. 3 Entry procedures,contract-enforcement procedures, procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex, employmentregulation<strong>in</strong>dex, court-powers-<strong>in</strong>-bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>dex, bus<strong>in</strong>ess-entry days and cost,contract-enforcement days and cost, bankruptcy days and cost. Comb<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>dicators<strong>in</strong> different ways can change country rank<strong>in</strong>gs. Aggregated <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong>dicatorswill be further analyzed <strong>in</strong> future reports as the coverage of bus<strong>in</strong>ess environment topicsexpands.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.89


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>Table 7.3Correlations of Regulation Indicators for Poor CountriesEntry Employment- Contract Procedural- Creditor-Procedures Regulation Index Procedures Complexity Index Rights IndexEmployment-laws <strong>in</strong>dex 0.48***Contract procedures 0.14 0.32***Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 0.28* 0.27** 0.35***Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex –0.09 –0.21* –0.03 0.03Court-powers-<strong>in</strong>-bankruptcy <strong>in</strong>dex 0.13 0.04 0.13 0.37*** –0.14Note: *** The correlation is significant at the 1 percent level. ** The correlation is significant at the 5 percent level. * The correlation is significant at the 10 percent level. The sample<strong>in</strong>cludes 70 countries classified as lower-middle-<strong>in</strong>come and low-<strong>in</strong>come by the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>.Source: <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> database.90and Montenegro, South Africa, Thailand, Tunisia, andVietnam have achieved great improvements <strong>in</strong> someareas of regulatory efficiency. In 1996, Tunisia reformedits judicial procedures to allow summary execution ofjudgment <strong>in</strong> commercial cases, and today it is one ofthe most efficient countries at resolv<strong>in</strong>g commercialdisputes. South Africa implemented a similar reform <strong>in</strong>1999. Latvia, Serbia and Montenegro, and Vietnamhave all reformed bus<strong>in</strong>ess entry regulations, mak<strong>in</strong>gthem among the most efficient <strong>in</strong> that area. InThailand, the 1999 bankruptcy reforms have achievedgreat success—but whether they will extend to otherareas of bus<strong>in</strong>ess regulation rema<strong>in</strong>s to be seen.Those developments are grounds for optimism,because they suggest that partial reforms have alreadybeen undertaken <strong>in</strong> many develop<strong>in</strong>g countries.Further reforms, <strong>in</strong> other areas of bus<strong>in</strong>ess regulation,are now necessary. With more-limited capacity <strong>in</strong>their public adm<strong>in</strong>istration, develop<strong>in</strong>g countries areless equipped to do comprehensive reforms. However,the practice shows that small steps <strong>in</strong> some reformshave made larger reforms possible elsewhere. Only ahandful of countries—for example, Angola, Bolivia,Guatemala, Mozambique, and Paraguay—have heavyregulation <strong>in</strong> all aspects of bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity. For thosecountries, comprehensive reforms may be necessary.What Do These F<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs Mean for EconomicTheory?Dur<strong>in</strong>g the 20th century, economists have come upwith several ways of th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g about governmentregulation. 10 The three ma<strong>in</strong> theories are the public<strong>in</strong>teresttheory of regulation associated with ArthurPigou, 11 the contract<strong>in</strong>g theory associated withRonald Coase, 12 and the capture theory of GeorgeStigler. 13 The data and analysis <strong>in</strong> this report haveimplications for all three—and provide the empiricalfoundations for new theoretical work.The public-<strong>in</strong>terest theory of regulation holds thatunregulated markets exhibit frequent failures. A governmentthat pursues social efficiency protects thepublic by means of regulation. As applied to bus<strong>in</strong>essentry, this theory says that governments shouldscreen new entrants to make sure that consumers buyhigh-quality products from “desirable” sellers. Inaddition, governments control prices to preventnatural monopolies from overcharg<strong>in</strong>g, impose safetystandards to prevent accidents such as fires or foodpoison<strong>in</strong>gs, regulate labor markets to counteremployers’ power over employees, regulate bankruptcyprocedures to ensure that stakeholders are notcheated, and so on. 14 Joseph Stiglitz takes the theoryfurther by argu<strong>in</strong>g that develop<strong>in</strong>g countries havemore market failures—and thus a greater need forgovernment regulation. 15The theory has been subject to three criticisms.The first critique blames public-<strong>in</strong>terest theory forexaggerat<strong>in</strong>g the extent of market failure and for notrecogniz<strong>in</strong>g the ability of competition to address manyof the alleged problems. For example, competition forlabor ensures that employers provide good work<strong>in</strong>gconditions for employees. If an employer failed to doso, competitors would offer better packages and


The Practice of Regulationattract workers. Similarly, private markets ensureefficient safety levels <strong>in</strong> a variety of products andservices, such as food, houses, and cars. Sellers who failto deliver those levels lose market share to competitorswho sell unspoiled food, build safer houses, or producesafer cars. As discussed <strong>in</strong> chapter 2, the data show thatstricter entry regulation is not associated with betterconsumer protection.Even when competitive forces are not strongenough, private order<strong>in</strong>gs work to address potentialmarket failures. Neighbors resolve disputes amongthemselves, without government <strong>in</strong>tervention,because they need to get along with each other overlong stretches of time. 16 Private credit <strong>in</strong>formationbureaus are established to protect lenders fromextend<strong>in</strong>g credit to bad borrowers. Professional associationsof accountants, exporters, and teachersimpose standards on their members to guaranteequality and penalize cheaters so that, <strong>in</strong> the long run,customers cont<strong>in</strong>ue their patronage. 17The second critique, orig<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the work ofCoase, ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>s that where competition and privateorder<strong>in</strong>gs do not address market failures, impartialcourts can do so. Employers can offer workersemployment contracts that specify what happens <strong>in</strong>the event of an accident. Security issuers can voluntarilydisclose <strong>in</strong>formation to potential <strong>in</strong>vestorsand guarantee its accuracy. And so on. With wellfunction<strong>in</strong>gcourts enforc<strong>in</strong>g property rights andcontracts, the scope for desirable regulation is reduced.The data agree. As shown <strong>in</strong> chapter 4, countries withmore efficient courts tend to regulate lightly.Private order<strong>in</strong>gs do work well <strong>in</strong> some situations,but they also degenerate <strong>in</strong>to anarchy, where<strong>in</strong>the strong—not the just—w<strong>in</strong> the day. Moreover, theempirical evidence suggests that courts around theworld are often <strong>in</strong>efficient. Courts <strong>in</strong> Guatemala takemore than 4 years to resolve a simple dispute, those <strong>in</strong>Brazil take more than 5 to collect collateral, and those<strong>in</strong> India take more than 10 to close down an unviablebus<strong>in</strong>ess.The third critique of regulation questions theassumption that a government is benevolent andcompetent, the essence of Stigler’s theory. 18 First,<strong>in</strong>cumbent bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong>terests typically capture theprocess of regulation. Regulation not only fails tocounter monopoly pric<strong>in</strong>g—it susta<strong>in</strong>s it. Second,even where regulators try to promote social welfare,they lack the capacity to do so, and regulation makesth<strong>in</strong>gs even worse. Empirical evidence providessupport for this conclusion. Bureaucratic entry isassociated with more corruption, and heavy regulationof court procedures leads to less impartialityand longer delays. However, today we also live <strong>in</strong> amuch richer but also more regulated society, and weare generally happy as consumers with many of theregulations that protect us. A more nuanced theory—which recognizes the benefits of public <strong>in</strong>volvement<strong>in</strong> at least some activities—is clearly needed to keeptheory and facts together.To be effective, regulation needs to be enforced. Thenature of the regulation and the activity regulateddeterm<strong>in</strong>es the success <strong>in</strong> enforcement. In thebackground research for this report, conducted withProfessor Andrei Shleifer and his colleagues, that view iscalled “the enforcement theory.” 19 Its premise is a basictradeoff between two social costs: the cost of private<strong>in</strong>jury and the cost of state <strong>in</strong>tervention. Private <strong>in</strong>juryrefers to the ability of private agents to harm others—to steal, cheat, overcharge, or impose external costs.State <strong>in</strong>tervention refers to the ability of governmentofficials to expropriate private agents throughbureaucratic hassle or the confiscation of property. Asone moves from private order<strong>in</strong>gs to private litigationto regulation to public ownership, the powers of thegovernment rise and those of private agents fall. Thesocial losses from private <strong>in</strong>jury decl<strong>in</strong>e as those fromstate <strong>in</strong>tervention <strong>in</strong>crease.The theory implies that the appropriate choice ofgovernment <strong>in</strong>tervention—from market discipl<strong>in</strong>e, toreliance on courts and litigation, to regulation, to stateownership—depends on the type of activity and oncountry circumstances, such as adm<strong>in</strong>istrative capacity.The ma<strong>in</strong> strength of market discipl<strong>in</strong>e as amethod of enforcement is that it is free of publicenforcers. When market discipl<strong>in</strong>e can control private<strong>in</strong>jury, it is the best approach, because it has thelowest social costs of state <strong>in</strong>tervention—particularly<strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, where government capacity<strong>in</strong> the courts and public adm<strong>in</strong>istration is low.91


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>92But market discipl<strong>in</strong>e may not be enough.Employers may under<strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> safety and blameaccidents on an <strong>in</strong>jured worker’s own carelessness. Insuch <strong>in</strong>stances, societies efficiently accept a higherlevel of government <strong>in</strong>tervention by rely<strong>in</strong>g onenforcement through private litigation. Injuredemployees can sue their employers for damages. Ajudge would recognize whether employees had notbeen adequately protected and award damages tocompensate them for their losses. But <strong>in</strong> manycountries, even simple litigation can take years toresolve and may <strong>in</strong>cur substantial costs.Compared with court enforcement, regulation hasadvantages. Unlike judges, public regulators can beexpert and motivated to pursue social objectives <strong>in</strong>specific areas. Indeed, this has been the ma<strong>in</strong>argument for public regulation of securities markets. 20This comb<strong>in</strong>ation of expertise and <strong>in</strong>centives makespublic enforcement more efficient, <strong>in</strong> some circumstances,than private or court enforcement. 21Alas, public regulation has problems. The keyproblem is the risk of an official’s abuse of marketparticipants. Overzealous enforcement is a particularproblem <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, where officialssometimes hassle bus<strong>in</strong>esses for bribes, 22 therebypush<strong>in</strong>g them <strong>in</strong>to the <strong>in</strong>formal economy. Thissituation suggests that regulation is a more attractiveoption <strong>in</strong> richer countries, where the checks on governmentregulators are stronger. Heavy regulatory<strong>in</strong>tervention is generally a bad idea <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries and <strong>in</strong> countries with undemocratic governments,where the risks of abuse are the greatest.In some situations, noth<strong>in</strong>g short of governmentownership can foster a good bus<strong>in</strong>ess environment. Ifmonopolies cannot be restra<strong>in</strong>ed through regulation,if quality cannot be assured except with full statecontrol, if public safety is jeopardized, there is a casefor state ownership. For example, the police functionneeds to be state-controlled if it is to protectbus<strong>in</strong>esses from <strong>in</strong>jury by others. Otherwisebus<strong>in</strong>esses would have an <strong>in</strong>centive to support privatepolice. The more powerful the bus<strong>in</strong>ess, the morelikely it is that its police will dom<strong>in</strong>ate the others.Commercial disputes would then be resolved <strong>in</strong> favorof the powerful. 23More mundanely, <strong>in</strong> countries with underdevelopedand concentrated f<strong>in</strong>ancial markets, publicownership of credit registries may be the only way to<strong>in</strong>crease the shar<strong>in</strong>g of credit <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> the shortterm.Why? Because there would not be enough profitopportunities for a private bus<strong>in</strong>ess to enter beforethe credit market was sufficiently developed. Andbecause banks that already control a large customerbase would not voluntarily divulge <strong>in</strong>formation.Public registries perform an admirable job <strong>in</strong>countries as diverse as Mozambique and Nepal.Enforcement theory predicts that regulation maybest be limited <strong>in</strong> countries with <strong>in</strong>sufficientenforcement capacity and <strong>in</strong> undemocratic countries,because heavy regulation would result <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>feriorsocial outcomes.Pr<strong>in</strong>ciples of Good RegulationIn the regulation of bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity, two pr<strong>in</strong>ciplesapply. First, regulate only when private order<strong>in</strong>g orlitigation are not sufficient to <strong>in</strong>duce good conduct.Second, regulate only if there is capacity to enforce.Countries that perform well have common elements<strong>in</strong> their approach to regulation:• Simplify and deregulate <strong>in</strong> competitive markets.• Focus on enhanc<strong>in</strong>g property rights.• Expand the use of technology.• Reduce court <strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>in</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess matters.• Make reform a cont<strong>in</strong>uous process.Simplify and Deregulate <strong>in</strong> CompetitiveMarketsThere is too much regulation <strong>in</strong> countries, particularly<strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, where other meanswould suffice and where its complexity and volumecannot be enforced. Rather than <strong>in</strong>duc<strong>in</strong>g goodconduct, such regulation puts bus<strong>in</strong>esses at the discretionof government <strong>in</strong>spectors and officials, whosometimes abuse their powers to extract bribes. Sothere is less bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity, and much of it rema<strong>in</strong>s<strong>in</strong>formal.Several areas for deregulation stand out. Wherethere is enough competition <strong>in</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>ess and <strong>in</strong> labor


The Practice of Regulationmarkets, markets would be enhanced if fewer regulationswere imposed on the participants. If newlyestablished firms produce <strong>in</strong>ferior products, they willsoon be driven out of bus<strong>in</strong>ess. And if a bus<strong>in</strong>ess doesnot provide its workers with adequate conditions ofemployment, other companies will attract the workers.In most develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, government lacksthe capacity to enforce complex regulation, as <strong>in</strong>bankruptcy. But out-of-court resolution of <strong>in</strong>solvencycan be sought—say, through private contracts andefficient collateral enforcement. If reform is notpursued, regulation imposes high costs and breedscorruption, thereby encourag<strong>in</strong>g bus<strong>in</strong>esses tooperate <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy. There, workers haveno protections, and entrepreneurs live <strong>in</strong> constantfear of the tax adm<strong>in</strong>istrator and the police. Firms donot grow to their efficient size, thus reduc<strong>in</strong>g thenumber of productive jobs and severely dim<strong>in</strong>ish<strong>in</strong>gthe opportunities for grow<strong>in</strong>g out of poverty.Some regulations—such as those for commercialdispute resolution—are necessary, but need simplificationand fewer formalities to be effective. There isno reason to believe that Ben<strong>in</strong> needs or can enforce44 procedures to resolve disputes <strong>in</strong> the courts ifFrance, whose laws Ben<strong>in</strong> adapted, has only 21. Andthere is no reason for Angola to have one of the mostrigid employment laws if Portugal, whose lawsAngola adapted, has already revised them twice tomake the labor market more flexible. In both Angolaand Ben<strong>in</strong>, greatly simplify<strong>in</strong>g the regulatory processis advisable.Focus on Enhanc<strong>in</strong>g Property RightsMuch of the evidence <strong>in</strong> this report shows that <strong>in</strong>most countries government <strong>in</strong>tervention is excessiveand that it hurts bus<strong>in</strong>ess. There is also evidence thatgovernments do too little to protect property rights.The best-practice countries build efficient courts andsupport laws and <strong>in</strong>stitutions that def<strong>in</strong>e the rights ofcitizens and bus<strong>in</strong>esses to their property. This year<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> has constructed <strong>in</strong>dicators on twoaspects of property rights: court efficiency and the legalrights of creditors. On these dimensions, high regulatory<strong>in</strong>tervention is associated with less protectionof property rights, not more. Ironically, the <strong>in</strong>stitutionsthat def<strong>in</strong>e and enforce property rights <strong>in</strong> manydevelop<strong>in</strong>g countries—the court system, property registries,and law enforcement agencies—are often theleast modern and least funded of all public <strong>in</strong>stitutions.Better protection of property rights benefitseveryone, especially the poor. One example comesfrom Peru, where <strong>in</strong> the last decade the governmenthas issued property titles to 1.2 million urbansquatter households. As a result, there has been a substantial<strong>in</strong>crease, of almost 20 percent, <strong>in</strong> the numberof work hours away from home, and a nearly 30percent reduction <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>cidence of child labor.Secure property rights have enabled parents to leavetheir homes and f<strong>in</strong>d jobs <strong>in</strong>stead of stay<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> toprotect the property. The ma<strong>in</strong> beneficiaries are theirchildren, who can now go to school. 24Expand the Use of TechnologyFor all areas of regulation covered <strong>in</strong> this report, theuse of technology is improv<strong>in</strong>g efficiency, <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>formation, and reduc<strong>in</strong>g opportunities for bureaucraticdiscretion. In the best-practice countries,modern technology m<strong>in</strong>imizes the regulatory burdenon bus<strong>in</strong>ess. With Internet-based bus<strong>in</strong>ess registrationsystems <strong>in</strong> Canada and Australia, application-process<strong>in</strong>gtime is the fastest <strong>in</strong> the world. And becauseentrepreneurs never have to face a bureaucrat, thereare no opportunities to extract bribes. Electronic<strong>in</strong>formation systems <strong>in</strong> the Slovak Republic have dramaticallyimproved court efficiency.In credit markets, technology enables develop<strong>in</strong>gcountries to leapfrog levels of <strong>in</strong>stitutional development,the spread of credit registries to poorer countriesbe<strong>in</strong>g spurred by fall<strong>in</strong>g costs and easier access to newtechnologies. For a few hundred thousand dollars,Albania is establish<strong>in</strong>g a comprehensive electronicregistry with access <strong>in</strong> real time, similar to the systemsof many OECD countries. Technology also helpscreate regional markets, enabl<strong>in</strong>g small countries torealize faster and cheaper access to best-practice <strong>in</strong>stitutions.In southern Africa, the private credit bureau<strong>in</strong> South Africa has recently expanded its services tocover bus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>in</strong> Botswana, Namibia, andSwaziland. Similarly, the private credit registry <strong>in</strong> Fijioperates from a server based <strong>in</strong> New Zealand.93


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>94Such technology has other positive effects. InMalaysia, one benefit of the credit bureau is thecapability to validate records and detect fraud.Lenders are able to identify multiple charges of thesame collateral for different loans.Reduce Court Involvement <strong>in</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>MattersOne of the major simplifications <strong>in</strong> many areas of regulationis to reduce the <strong>in</strong>volvement of courts. Forbus<strong>in</strong>ess entry, tak<strong>in</strong>g registration out of the courts andmak<strong>in</strong>g it an adm<strong>in</strong>istrative process radically reducesregistration time and eases the backlog of commercialcases <strong>in</strong> the judiciary. Permitt<strong>in</strong>g private enforcement ofcollateral, with recourse to the courts only for disputes,substantially reduces enforcement time and encourageslend<strong>in</strong>g.For contract enforcement and bankruptcy proceed<strong>in</strong>gs,reduc<strong>in</strong>g the <strong>in</strong>volvement of courts can openthe way for specialized sections <strong>in</strong> the general jurisdictioncourts or for specialized commercial courts,which can use streaml<strong>in</strong>ed processes <strong>in</strong> notification,evidence collection, and judgments, especially <strong>in</strong>countries with greater adm<strong>in</strong>istrative capacity. Alternatively,the role of courts can be reduced by<strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>g summary procedures for commercialdisputes, thereby limit<strong>in</strong>g the time for judgment. Oneexample comes from Nicaragua, where the summaryprocedure to collect debt takes about four months onaverage. In contrast, the normal civil procedure forresolv<strong>in</strong>g commercial disputes lasts more than five years.Make Reform a Cont<strong>in</strong>uous ProcessCountries that consistently perform well across the<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong>dicators do so because of cont<strong>in</strong>uousreform. Denmark revised its bus<strong>in</strong>ess entry regulations<strong>in</strong> 1996 by remov<strong>in</strong>g several procedures,mak<strong>in</strong>g the process electronic, and elim<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g all fees.Australia has built <strong>in</strong> regulatory reform by <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g“sunset provisions” <strong>in</strong> new regulations, which automaticallyexpire after a certa<strong>in</strong> period if not renewedby parliament. And Sweden <strong>in</strong>troduced a “guillot<strong>in</strong>e”approach for regulatory reform, with hundreds ofobsolete regulations be<strong>in</strong>g canceled after the governmentrequired regulatory agencies to register allessential regulations. 25 On average, laws <strong>in</strong> wealthycountries have been enacted or amended much morerecently than those <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, whichoften date to colonial times. This situation makes theoften-heard compla<strong>in</strong>t of “reform fatigue” <strong>in</strong>develop<strong>in</strong>g countries difficult to fathom.Over the last decade, several countries have <strong>in</strong>troducedregulatory impact assessments, which arecarried out when new regulation is proposed.Requir<strong>in</strong>g government agencies and m<strong>in</strong>istries toengage <strong>in</strong> cost-benefit analyses has proven to be aneffective tool <strong>in</strong> w<strong>in</strong>now<strong>in</strong>g out burdensome, poorlydesigned, and socially costly regulations and <strong>in</strong>improv<strong>in</strong>g those that are necessary. Regulatoryimpact assessments are a standard feature of newbus<strong>in</strong>ess regulation <strong>in</strong> the European Union and havebeen adopted <strong>in</strong> many accession candidates, such asHungary and Poland.Cont<strong>in</strong>uous reforms require political will but notnecessarily large resources. Indeed, if properlyimplemented, deregulation can save the governmentmoney and permit allocations to meet the needs ofpoor people. Other reforms, such as <strong>in</strong>troduc<strong>in</strong>gadm<strong>in</strong>istrative registration of bus<strong>in</strong>esses and creat<strong>in</strong>gcredit registries, can pay for themselves <strong>in</strong> two tothree years, as Serbia and Montenegro and Malaysiashow. In the Netherlands, for example, adm<strong>in</strong>istrativecosts are reduced by an <strong>in</strong>dependent agency, ACTAL.ACTAL, which has only n<strong>in</strong>e staff members, isempowered to advise on all proposed laws and regulations.To date, simplification of adm<strong>in</strong>istrative procedureshas been achieved <strong>in</strong> the areas of corporatetaxation, social security, environmental regulations,and statistical requirements. The estimated sav<strong>in</strong>gsare $600 million <strong>in</strong> streaml<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g of the taxrequirements alone.Other reforms, such as revis<strong>in</strong>g commercial codesand company laws, require big <strong>in</strong>vestments and takeseveral years. In the <strong>in</strong>terim, the public needs to beconsulted, and the costs and benefits of the newlegislation must be evaluated. Once <strong>in</strong> place, however,such reforms have enormous impact on privatebus<strong>in</strong>ess. Vietnam’s new enterprise law is but oneexample.


The Practice of RegulationNotes1. Glaeser and Shleifer 2002.2. Thailand is the only East Asian country never to havebe colonized. In the Middle East, several present-daycountries had British rule after <strong>World</strong> War I.3. Olson 1991; De Long and Shleifer 1993.4. Also see Djankov and others 2002, 2003.5. Engerman and Sokoloff 2002.6. Acemoglu, Johnson, and Rob<strong>in</strong>son 2001.7. Hochschild 1998.8. Ales<strong>in</strong>a and others 2003; Dollar and others 2003.9. Greif 1989; MacMillan and Woodruff 1999a, b.10. This section is based on Djankov and others(forthcom<strong>in</strong>g).11. Pigou 1938.12. Coase 1960.13. Stigler 1971.14. Allais 1947; Meade 1948; Lewis 1949.15. Stiglitz 1989.16. Ellickson 1991.17. Greif 1989; Bernste<strong>in</strong> 1992.18. See also Posner 1974.19. See Djankov and others (forthcom<strong>in</strong>g).20. Landis 1938; Acemoglu and others 2001; Pistor andXu 2002.21. Along these l<strong>in</strong>es, Glaeser and Shleifer (2003)argue that “The Rise of the Regulatory State” <strong>in</strong>the United States dur<strong>in</strong>g the Progressive Era at thebeg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g of the twentieth century was a response tothe grow<strong>in</strong>g problems of subversion of courts byrobber barons.22. Hellman, Jones, and Kaufmann (forthcom<strong>in</strong>g).23. Hart, Shleifer, and Vishny (1997) make the case forstate ownership of prisons.24. Field 2002.25. Jacobs 2002.95


ReferencesChapter 1Batra, Geeta. 2003. “Investment Climate Measurement:Pitfalls and Possibilities.” Discussion Paper. InvestmentClimate Unit, Private Sector Vice-Presidency, <strong>World</strong><strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Batra, Geeta, Daniel Kaufmann, and Andrew Stone. 2003.Investment Climate Around the <strong>World</strong>: Voices of theFirms from the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Environment Survey.Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.: <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>.BERI (<strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Environment Risk Intelligence). 2002.User Guide.Friday Harbor, Wash.Bertrand, Marianne, and Sendhil Mulla<strong>in</strong>athan. 2002. “DoPeople Mean What They Say? Implications forSubjective Survey Data.” American Economic Review91(2): 67–72.Bishop, George, Robert Oldendick, and Alfred Tuchfarber.1986. “Op<strong>in</strong>ions on Fictitious Issues: The Pressure toAnswer Survey Questions.” Public Op<strong>in</strong>ion Quarterly50(3): 240–50.Botero, Juan, Simeon Djankov, Rafael La Porta, FlorencioLopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 2003. “TheRegulation of Labor.” Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 9756. NationalBureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Mass.Cornelius, Peter, Michael Porter, and Klaus Schwab. 2003.The Global Competitiveness Report 2002–2003.London: Oxford University Press.Djankov, Simeon, Oliver Hart, Tatiana Nenova, andAndrei Shleifer. 2003. “The Efficiency of <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy.”Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper. Department of Economics, HarvardUniversity, Cambridge, Mass.Djankov, Simeon, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 2002. “The Regulationof Entry.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(1):1–37.———. 2003. “Courts.” Quarterly Journal of Economics118(2): 342–87.Djankov, Simeon, Caralee McLiesh, and Andrei Shleifer.2003. “Remedies <strong>in</strong> Credit Markets.” Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper.Department of Economics, Harvard University,Cambridge, Mass.Ernst&Young. 2003. Corporate Tax Guide.Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Friedman, Eric, Simon Johnson, Daniel Kaufman, andPablo Zoido-Lobaton. 2000. “Dodg<strong>in</strong>g the Grabb<strong>in</strong>gHand: Determ<strong>in</strong>ants of Unofficial Activity <strong>in</strong> 69Countries.” Journal of Public Economics 76(3): 459–93.Hammergren, L<strong>in</strong>n. 2003. “Uses of Empirical Research <strong>in</strong>Refocus<strong>in</strong>g Judicial Reforms: Lessons from FiveCountries.” Lat<strong>in</strong> America and Caribbean Region,<strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Jentzsch, Nicola. 2003. “The Regulatory Environment for<strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Information Shar<strong>in</strong>g.” Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper.Monitor<strong>in</strong>g, Analysis and Policy Unit, PrivateSector Development Vice Presidency, <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>,Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Massimo Mastruzzi.2003. “Governance Matters III: Governance Indicatorsfor 1996–2002.” Policy Research Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 3106.<strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, AndreiShleifer, and Robert Vishny. 1998. “Law and F<strong>in</strong>ance.”Journal of Political Economy 106(6): 1113–55.Meade, James, and Richard Stone. 1941. An Analysis of theSources of War F<strong>in</strong>ance and an Estimate of theNational Income and Expenditure <strong>in</strong> 1938 and 1940.United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, Treasury, H.M.S.O., London.Petty, Sir William. 1691. Verbum Sapienti. Published withThe Political Anatomy of Ireland. London: Brown andRogers. Repr<strong>in</strong>ted <strong>in</strong> The Economic Writ<strong>in</strong>gs of SirWilliam Petty. C.H. Hull, ed., 2 vols. CambridgeUniversity Press, 1899.Schneider, Friedrich. 2002. “Size and Measurement of theInformal Economy <strong>in</strong> 110 Economies Around the<strong>World</strong>.” Discussion Paper. Monitor<strong>in</strong>g, Analysis and97


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>98Policy Unit, Private Sector Vice-Presidency, <strong>World</strong><strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Schwarz, Norbert, Fritz Strack, and Hans-Peter Mai. 1991.“Assimilation and Contrast Effects <strong>in</strong> Part-WholeQuestion Sequence: A Conversational Logic Analysis.”Public Op<strong>in</strong>ion Quarterly 55(1): 3–23.Schwarz, Norbert, Hans J. Hippler, Brigitte Deutsch, andFritz Strack. 1985. “<strong>Response</strong> Categories: Effects onBehavioral Reports and Comparative Judgments.”Public Op<strong>in</strong>ion Quarterly 49(2): 388–95.The Heritage Foundation. 2002. 2003 Index of EconomicFreedom.Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.<strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>. 2002a. Investment Climate Assessment: India.Private Sector Advisory Services. Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.———. 2002b. The Juicio Executivo Mercantil <strong>in</strong> theFederal District Courts of Mexico. Lat<strong>in</strong> America andthe Caribbean Region, Poverty Reduction andEconomic Management Unit. Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.———. 2002c. The Investment Climate for ForeignCompanies <strong>in</strong> Turkey.Monitor<strong>in</strong>g, Analysis and PolicyUnit, Private Sector Vice-Presidency. Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.———. 2003. Informe F<strong>in</strong>al de la Investigacion Sobre el Usode la Justicia Civil en el Ecuador. Lat<strong>in</strong> America and theCaribbean Region, Poverty Reduction and EconomicManagement Unit, <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Chapter 2Ales<strong>in</strong>a, Alberto, Silvia Ardagna, Guiseppe Nicoletti, andFabio Schiantarelli. 2003. “Regulation andInvestment.” Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 9560. National Bureau ofEconomic Research, Cambridge, Mass.Batra, Geeta, Daniel Kaufmann, and Andrew Stone. 2003.Investment Climate Around the <strong>World</strong>: Voices of theFirms from the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Environment Survey.Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.: <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>.Berle, Adolf, and Gard<strong>in</strong>er Means. 1932. The ModernCorporation and Private Property. New York: Macmillan.Bertrand, Marianne, and Francis Kramarz. 2002. “DoesEntry Regulation H<strong>in</strong>der Job Creation? Evidencefrom the French Retail Industry.” Quarterly Journal ofEconomics 117(4): 1369–1413.Blumberg, David. 1986. “Limited Liability and CorporateGroups.” Journal of Corporation Law 11(4): 573–631.DeLong, J. Bradford, and Andrei Shleifer. 1993. “Pr<strong>in</strong>cesand Merchants: European City Growth Before theIndustrial Revolution.” Journal of Law and Economics36(2): 671–702.De Soto, Hernando. 1989. The Other Path. New York:Harper and Row.Diamond, Aubrey. 1982. “Corporate Personality andLimited Liability.” In Limited Liability and theCorporation,ed. Tony Orhnial. London and Canberra:Croom Helm.Djankov, Simeon, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 2002. “The Regulationof Entry.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(1):1–37.European Commission. 2002. Benchmark<strong>in</strong>g theAdm<strong>in</strong>istration of <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Start-Ups.Center forStrategy and Evaluation Services, EnterpriseDirectorate General, Brussels.FIAS (Foreign Investment Advisory Service). 2003.Adm<strong>in</strong>istrative Barriers <strong>in</strong> Latvia.<strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>,Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Friedman, Eric, Simon Johnson, Daniel Kaufman, andPablo Zoido-Lobaton. 2000. “Dodg<strong>in</strong>g the Grabb<strong>in</strong>gHand: Determ<strong>in</strong>ants of Unofficial Activity <strong>in</strong>69 Countries.” Journal of Public Economics 76(3):459–93.Hoekman, Bernard, Hiao Looi Kee, and MarceloOlarreaga. 2001. “Mark-ups, Entry Regulation andTrade: Does Country Size Matter?” Policy ResearchWork<strong>in</strong>g Paper 2662. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Horvath, Michael, and Michael Woywode. 2003. “TheEntrepreneurial Choice of Limited Liability.”Discussion Paper, University of Mannheim, Germany.Jacobs, Scott. 2002. “Reform<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Registration <strong>in</strong>Serbia.” Jacobs and Associates, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Japanese Association of Small <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>. 1999. Constra<strong>in</strong>tsto <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Entry.Tokyo.Jordan, Cally. 1996. “A Comparative Survey of Companies’Laws <strong>in</strong> Selected Jurisdictions.” McGill University,Law Faculty, Montreal.Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Massimo Mastruzzi.2003. “Governance Matters III: Governance Indicatorsfor 1996–2002.” Policy Research Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 3106.<strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, AndreiShleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 1999. “The Quality ofGovernment.” Journal of Law, Economics, andOrganization 15(1): 222–79.Morisset, Jacques, and Olivier Lumenga Neso. 2002.“Adm<strong>in</strong>istrative Barriers to Foreign Investment <strong>in</strong>Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries.” Policy Research Work<strong>in</strong>gPaper 2848. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.


ReferencesOlson, Mancur. 1991. “Autocracy, Democracy, andProsperity.” In Strategy of Choice,ed.RichardZeckhauser. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press.Pistor, Kathar<strong>in</strong>a, and Daniel Berkowitz. 2003. “OfLegal Transplants, Legal Irritants, and EconomicDevelopment.” In Corporate Governance andCapital Flows <strong>in</strong> a Global Economy,eds. PeterCornelius and Bruce Kogut. London: OxfordUniversity Press.Sader, Frank. 2002. A View on One-Stop Shops.Work<strong>in</strong>gPaper. Foreign Investment Advisory Service,Investment Climate Department, Private SectorVice-Presidency, <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Shannon, Herbert. 1931. “The Com<strong>in</strong>g of GeneralLimited Liability.” Economic History 2(6): 267–91.Smith, Adam. 1776. [1937]. The Wealth of Nations.NewYork: Random House.Trang, Nguyen Phuong Quynh, Bui Tuong Anh, HanManh Tien, Hoang Xuan Thanh, and Nguyen ThiHoai Thu. 2001. “<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Under the NewEnterprise Law: A Survey of Newly RegisteredCompanies.” Private Sector Discussion Paper 12.Mekong Project Development Facility, Mekong,Vietnam.Zhuravskaya, Ekater<strong>in</strong>a. 2003. “Assess<strong>in</strong>g Russia’s <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Climate.” Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper. Department of Economics,Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton University, Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton, NJ.Chapter 3Abowd, John, Francis Kramarz, and David Margolis.1999. “M<strong>in</strong>imum Wages and Employment <strong>in</strong>France and the United States.” Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper6996. National Bureau of Economic Research,Cambridge, Mass.Aidt, Toke, and Zafiris Tzannatos. 2002. Unions andCollective Barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g: Economic Effects <strong>in</strong> a GlobalEnvironment.Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.: <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>.Batra, Geeta, Daniel Kaufmann, and Andrew Stone. 2003.Voices of the Firms: Investment Climate and GovernanceF<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs of the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Environment Survey.<strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Becker, Gary. 1971. The Economics of Discrim<strong>in</strong>ation.Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Besley, Timothy, and Rob<strong>in</strong> Burgess. 2003. “Can LaborRegulation H<strong>in</strong>der Economic Performance? Evidencefrom India.” Discussion Paper. Department ofEconomics, London School of Economics, London.Betcherman, Gordon. 2002. “An Overview of Labor Markets<strong>World</strong>-Wide: Key Trends and Major Policy Issues.”Discussion Paper 205. Social Protection DiscussionSeries. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Betcherman, Gordon, Amy Lu<strong>in</strong>stra, and Makoto Ogawa.2001. “Labor Market Regulation: InternationalExperience <strong>in</strong> Promot<strong>in</strong>g Employment and SocialProtection.” Discussion Paper 128. Social ProtectionDiscussion Series, <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Blanchard, Olivier. 2002. “Design<strong>in</strong>g Labor MarketInstitutions.” MIT, Department of Economics,Cambridge, Mass.Blanchard, Olivier, and August<strong>in</strong> Landier. 2000. “ThePerverse Effects of Partial Labor Market Reform:Fixed Duration Contracts <strong>in</strong> France.” MIT,Department of Economics, Cambridge, Mass.Blanchard, Olivier, and Pedro Portugal. 2001. “WhatHides Beh<strong>in</strong>d an Unemployment Rate: Compar<strong>in</strong>gPortuguese and U.S. Labor Markets.” AmericanEconomic Review 91 (1): 187–207.Booth, Alison. 1995. The Economics of the Trade Union.Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Botero, Juan, Simeon Djankov, Rafael La Porta, FlorencioLopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 2003. “TheRegulation of Labor.” Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 9756. NationalBureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Mass.Dolado, Juan, Florent<strong>in</strong>o Felgueroso, and Juan Jimeno.1997. “The Effects of M<strong>in</strong>imum Barga<strong>in</strong>ed Wages onEarn<strong>in</strong>gs: Evidence from Spa<strong>in</strong>.” European EconomicReview 41 (3–5): 713–21.Fallon, Peter, and Robert Lucas. 1991. “The Impact ofChanges <strong>in</strong> Job Security Regulations <strong>in</strong> India andZimbabwe.” <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> Economic Review 5 (3):395–413.Fields, Gary, and Henry Wan. 1989. “Wage-Sett<strong>in</strong>gInstitutions and Economic Growth.” <strong>World</strong>Development 17 (4): 1471–83.Fishback, Price. 1998. “Operations of ‘Unfettered’ LaborMarkets: Exit and Voice <strong>in</strong> American Labor Marketsat the Turn of the Century.” Journal of EconomicLiterature 36 (2): 722–65.Gill, Indermit, Claudio Montenegro, and DorteDomeland, editors. 2002. Craft<strong>in</strong>g Labor Policy:Techniques and Lessons from Lat<strong>in</strong> America.Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.: <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>.Heckman, James, and Carmen Pages. 2000. “The Cost ofJob Security Regulation: Evidence from Lat<strong>in</strong>American Labor Markets.” Economia 6 (2): 109–54.99


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>100Holmes, Thomas. 1998. “The Effect of State Policies onthe Location of Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g: Evidence from StateBorders.” Journal of Political Economy 106 (4): 667–705.Hopenhayn, Hugo. 2001. “Labor Market Policies andEmployment Duration: The Effects of Labor MarketReform <strong>in</strong> Argent<strong>in</strong>a.” Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 407. Inter-American Development <strong>Bank</strong>, Research Department,Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.International Labor Organization. 1998. ILO Declarationon Fundamental Pr<strong>in</strong>ciples and Rights at Work.Geneva, Switzerland.———. 2000. Your Voice at Work.Geneva, Switzerland.———. 2001. Stopp<strong>in</strong>g Forced Labor.Geneva, Switzerland.———. 2002. A Future Without Child Labor.Geneva,Switzerland.———. 2003. Time for Equality at Work.Geneva,Switzerland.Kugler, Adriana. 2000. “The Incidence of Job SecurityRegulations on Labor Market Flexibility andCompliance <strong>in</strong> Colombia: Evidence from the 1990Reform.” Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 393. Inter-AmericanDevelopment <strong>Bank</strong>, Research Department,Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Lazear, Edward. 1990. “Job Security Provisions andEmployment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 105 (3):699–727.Maloney, William, and Juan Nunez. 2000. “M<strong>in</strong>imum Wages<strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America.” <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Montenegro, Claudio, and Carmen Pages. 2003. “WhoBenefits from Labor Market Regulations: Chile1960–1988.” Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 9850. National Bureau ofEconomic Research, Cambridge, Mass.Mulligan, Casey, and Xavier Sala-i-Mart<strong>in</strong>. 2000.“Measur<strong>in</strong>g Aggregate Human Capital.” Journal ofEconomic Growth 5 (2): 215–52.Nicoletti, Giuseppe, and Stefano Scarpetta. 2003.“Regulation, Productivity and Growth: The OECDEvidence.” Policy Research Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 2944.<strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Nicoletti, Giuseppe, Andrea Bassan<strong>in</strong>i, Ekkehard Ernst,Sebastien Jean, Paulo Santiago, and Paul Swa<strong>in</strong>. 2001.“Product and Labor Market Interactions <strong>in</strong> OECDCountries.” Economics Department Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper312. Organisation of Economic Co-operation andDevelopment, Paris.OECD (Organisation of Economic Co-operation andDevelopment). 1998. The OECD EmploymentOutlook.Paris.Saavedra, Jaime, and Maximo Torrero. 2000. “LaborMarket Reforms and Their Impact on Formal LaborDemand and Job Market Turnover: The Case ofPeru.” Research Network Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 394.Inter-American Development <strong>Bank</strong>, ResearchDepartment, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Scarpetta, Stefano. 1996. “Assess<strong>in</strong>g the Role of LaborMarket Policies and Institutional Sett<strong>in</strong>gs onUnemployment: A Cross-Country Study.” OECDEconomic Studies 26 (1): 43–98.Scarpetta, Stefano, and Thierry Verdier. 2002.“Productivity and Convergence <strong>in</strong> a Panel of OECDIndustries: Do Regulations and Institutions Matter?”Economics Department Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 28/2002.Organisation of Economic Co-operation andDevelopment, Paris.Schneider, Friedrich. 2002. “Size and Measurement of theInformal Economy <strong>in</strong> 110 Economies around the<strong>World</strong>.” Discussion Paper. Monitor<strong>in</strong>g, Analysis andPolicy Unit, Private Sector Vice-Presidency, <strong>World</strong><strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Tur<strong>in</strong>, Stepan. 1934. From Peter the Great to Len<strong>in</strong>.London: K<strong>in</strong>g and Sons.Valenze, David. 1985. The First Industrial Woman.London: Oxford University Press.Van Audenrode, Marc. 1994. “Short-Time Compensation,Job Security, and Employment Contracts: Evidencefrom Selected OECD Countries.” Journal of PoliticalEconomy 102 (1): 76–102.<strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>. 2002a. The Russian Labor Market: Mov<strong>in</strong>gfrom Crisis to Recovery.Europe and Central Asia Region,Human Development Sector Unit, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.———. 2002b. Brazil Jobs Report.Brazil CountryManagement Unit, Lat<strong>in</strong> America and the CaribbeanRegion, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.———. 2003a. Republic of Tunisia: Employment Strategy.Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.———. 2003b. <strong>World</strong> Development Indicators.Wash<strong>in</strong>gton D.C.Chapter 4Bannerjee, Abhijit, and Esther Duflo. 2000. “ReputationEffects and the Limits of Contract<strong>in</strong>g: A Study of theIndian Software Industry.” Quarterly Journal ofEconomics 115 (3): 989–1017.Batra, Geeta, Daniel Kaufmann, and Andrew Stone.2003. Voices of the Firms: Investment Climate and


ReferencesGovernance F<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs of the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Environment Survey.<strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Bigsten, Arne, Paul Collier, Stefan Dercon, MarcelFafchamps, Bernard Gauthier, Jan Willem Gunn<strong>in</strong>g,Abena Oduro, Remco Oostendorp, Cathy Patillo,Mans Soderbom, Francis Teal, and Albert Zeufack.2000. “Contract Flexibility and Dispute Resolution <strong>in</strong>African Manufactur<strong>in</strong>g.” Journal of DevelopmentStudies 36 (4): 1–17.Botero, Juan, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes,Andrei Shleifer, and Alexander Volokh. 2003. “JudicialReform.” <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> Research Observer 18 (1): 61–88.Clay, Karen. 1997. “Trade without Law: Private OrderInstitutions <strong>in</strong> Mexican California.” Journal of Law,Economics, and Organization 13 (1): 202–31.Dakolias, Maria. 1999. “Court Performance around the<strong>World</strong>: A Comparative Perspective.” Technical Paper430. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Dawson, John. 1960. A History of Lay Judges.Cambridge,Mass: Harvard University Press.Djankov, Simeon, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 2003. “Courts.” QuarterlyJournal of Economics 18 (2): 453–517.Doll<strong>in</strong>ger, Philippe. 1970. The German Hansa. Stanford:Stanford University Press.F<strong>in</strong>negan, David. 2001. “Observations on Tanzania’sCommercial Court: A Case Study.” Paper presented atthe <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> Conference on Empowerment,Security, and Opportunity through Law and Justice,July 8–12, St. Petersburg, Russia.Goethe, Johann Wolfgang von. 1969. The Autobiography ofJohann Wolfgang von Goethe.Trn.John Oxenford.New York: Horizon Press.Greif, Avner. 1993. “Contract Enforceability andEconomic Institutions <strong>in</strong> Early Trade: The MaghribiTraders’ Coalition.” American Economic Review 83 (3):525–548.Hammergren, L<strong>in</strong>n. 2000. “Diagnos<strong>in</strong>g JudicialPerformance: Toward a Tool to Help Guide JudicialReform Programs.” Lat<strong>in</strong> America and the CaribbeanRegion, <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.———. 2003. “Uses of Empirical Research <strong>in</strong> Refocus<strong>in</strong>gJudicial Reforms: Lessons from Five Countries.” Lat<strong>in</strong>America and the Caribbean Region, <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>,Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.McMillan, John, and Christopher Woodruff. 1999. “DisputePrevention without Courts <strong>in</strong> Vietnam.” Journal ofLaw, Economics, and Organization 15 (3): 637–58.———. 2000. “Private Order under Dysfunctional PublicOrder.” Michigan Law Review 98(8): 101–38.Milgrom, Paul, Douglass North, and Barry We<strong>in</strong>gast.1990. “The Role of Institutions <strong>in</strong> the Revival ofTrade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, andChampagne Fairs.” Economics and Politics 2(1): 1–23.Muldrew, Craig. 1993. “Credit and the Courts: DebtLitigation <strong>in</strong> a Seventeenth-Century Urban Community.”Economic History Review XLVI (1): 23–38.Murrell, Peter. 2003. “Firms Fac<strong>in</strong>g New Institutions:Transactional Governance <strong>in</strong> Romania.” Journal ofComparative Economics 31(4): 768–791.PriceWaterhouseCoopers. 2001. Report on Debt RecoveryTribunals <strong>in</strong> India.Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.S<strong>in</strong>are, Hanwa. 2000. “An Advocate’s Overview of theCommercial Court Performance.” The High Court,Dar es Saalam, Tanzania.Woodruff, Christopher. 1998. “Contract Enforcement andTrade Liberalization <strong>in</strong> Mexico’s Footwear Industry.”<strong>World</strong> Development 26 (5): 979–91.<strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>. 2001a. “Adm<strong>in</strong>istration of Justice and theLegal Profession <strong>in</strong> Slovakia.” Europe and CentralAsia Region, Poverty Reduction and EconomicManagement Unit, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.———. 2001b. Argent<strong>in</strong>a: Legal and Judicial SectorAssessment.Legal Vice Presidency, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.———. 2002a. The <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> Legal Review: Law andJustice for Development.Legal Vice Presidency,Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.———. 2002b. Initiatives <strong>in</strong> Legal and Judicial Reform.Legal Vice Presidency, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Zweigert, Konrad. 1983. The International Encyclopedia ofComparative Law: Specific Contracts.J.C.B. Mohr.Tub<strong>in</strong>gen, Germany.Chapter 5Barron, John, and Michael Staten. 2003. “The Value ofComprehensive Credit Reports: Lessons from the U.S.Experience.” In Credit Report<strong>in</strong>g Systems and theInternational Economy, ed. Margaret Miller. Boston:MIT Press.Besley, Timothy. 1995. “Nonmarket Institutions for Creditand Risk Shar<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Low-Income Countries.” Journalof Economic Perspectives 9 (3): 115–27.Bolton, Patrick, and David Scharfste<strong>in</strong>. 1996. “OptimalDebt Structure and the Number of Creditors.” Journalof Political Economy 101 (1): 1–25.101


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>102Campbell, Tim, and William Kracaw. 1980. “InformationProduction, Market Signall<strong>in</strong>g and the Theory ofF<strong>in</strong>ancial Intermediation.” Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance 25 (4):853–82.Demirguc-Kunt, Asli, and Vojislav Maksimovic. 1998.“Law, F<strong>in</strong>ance, and Firm Growth.” Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance53(6): 2107–37.Diamond, Douglas. 1984. “F<strong>in</strong>ancial Intermediation andDelegated Monitor<strong>in</strong>g.” Review of Economic Studies51(3): 393–414.Djankov, Simeon, Caralee McLiesh, and Andrei Shleifer.2003. “Remedies <strong>in</strong> Credit Markets.” Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper,Department of Economics, Harvard University,Cambridge, Mass.Fuentes, Rodrigo, and Carlos Maquieira. 2001. “WhyBorrowers Repay: Understand<strong>in</strong>g High Performance<strong>in</strong> Chile’s F<strong>in</strong>ancial Market.” In Defus<strong>in</strong>g Default:Incentives and Institutions,ed.Marco Pagano.Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.: Inter-American Development <strong>Bank</strong>.Gal<strong>in</strong>do, Arturo, and Margaret Miller. 2001. “Can CreditRegistries Reduce Credit Constra<strong>in</strong>ts? EmpiricalEvidence on the Role of Credit Registries <strong>in</strong> FirmInvestment Decisions.” Paper prepared for the annualmeet<strong>in</strong>gs of the Inter-American Development <strong>Bank</strong>,Santiago, Chile, March.Garro, Alejandro. 1998. “Difficulties <strong>in</strong> Obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g SecuredLend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America: Why Law Reform ReallyMatters.” In Norton, Joseph and Mads Andenas, eds.,Emerg<strong>in</strong>g F<strong>in</strong>ancial Markets and Secured Transactions.London: Klewer Law International.Greif, Avner, Paul Milgrom, and Barry We<strong>in</strong>gast. 1994.“Coord<strong>in</strong>ation, Commitment and Enforcement: TheMerchant Guild as a Nexus of Contracts.” Journal ofPolitical Economy 102 (5): 745–76.Hadlow, John. 2003. How a Credit Bureau Enhances the CreditApproval and Risk Management Process.Paper presentedat The Central Asian Credit Bureau Conference, heldJanuary 29-31 <strong>in</strong> Almaty, Kazakhstan.Hill, Claire. 2002. “Is Secured Debt Efficient?” Texas LawReview 80 (3): 1117–1173.Hoffman, Philip T., Gilles Poste-V<strong>in</strong>ay, and Jean-LaurentRosenthal. 1998. “What Do Notaries Do? Overcom<strong>in</strong>gAsymetric Information <strong>in</strong> F<strong>in</strong>ancial Markets: TheCase of Paris, 1751.” Journal of Institutional andTheoretical Economics 154 (3): 499–530.Jappelli, Tullio, and Marco Pagano. 1993. “InformationShar<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Credit Markets.” The Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance 43(5): 1693–718.———. 2000. “Information Shar<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> Credit Markets:The European Experience.” Center for Studies <strong>in</strong>Economics and F<strong>in</strong>ance Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper No. 35, TheUniversity of Salerno, Italy.———. 2002. “Information Shar<strong>in</strong>g, Lend<strong>in</strong>g and Defaults:Cross-Country Evidence.” Journal of <strong>Bank</strong><strong>in</strong>g andF<strong>in</strong>ance 26 (10): 2017–45.Jentzsch, Nicola. 2003a. “The Regulatory Environment for<strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Information Shar<strong>in</strong>g.” Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper.Monitor<strong>in</strong>g, Analysis and Policy Unit, Private SectorDevelopment Vice Presidency, <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>,Wash<strong>in</strong>gton D.C.Jentzsch, Nicola. 2003b. “The Regulation of F<strong>in</strong>ancialPrivacy: A Comparative Study of the United Statesand Europe.” Research Report 5, European CreditResearch Institute, Brussels.Ke<strong>in</strong>an, Yoram. 2001. “The Evolution of SecuredTransactions.” <strong>World</strong> Development Report 2002,Background Paper. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.K<strong>in</strong>g, Robert, and Ross Lev<strong>in</strong>e. 1993. “F<strong>in</strong>ance andGrowth: Schumpeter Might be Right.” QuarterlyJournal of Economics 108(3): 717–37.La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, AndreiShleifer, and Robert Vishny. 1998. “Law and F<strong>in</strong>ance.”Journal of Political Economy 106 (6): 1113–55.Lev<strong>in</strong>e, Ross. 1997. “F<strong>in</strong>ancial Development andEconomic Growth: Views and Agenda.” Journal ofEconomic Literature 35 (2): 688–726.———. 1998. “The Legal Environment, <strong>Bank</strong>s, and Long-Run Economic Growth.” Journal of Money, Credit, and<strong>Bank</strong><strong>in</strong>g 30 (3): 596–613.Love, Inessa, and Nataliya Mylenko. 2003. “CreditReport<strong>in</strong>g and F<strong>in</strong>anc<strong>in</strong>g Constra<strong>in</strong>ts.” Work<strong>in</strong>gPaper. <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Mann, Ronald. 1997. “Expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the Pattern of SecuredCredit.” Harvard Law Review 110 (2): 625–668.Miller, Margaret. 2003. “Credit Report<strong>in</strong>g Systems Aroundthe Globe: The State of the Art <strong>in</strong> Public and PrivateCredit Registries.” In Credit Report<strong>in</strong>g Systems and theInternational Economy, ed. Margaret Miller. Boston:MIT Press.Olegario, Rowena. 2003. “Credit-Report<strong>in</strong>g Agencies: AHistorical Perspective.” In Credit Report<strong>in</strong>g Systemsand the International Economy, ed. Margaret Miller.Boston: MIT Press.Rajan, Raghuram, and Luigi Z<strong>in</strong>gales. 1998. “F<strong>in</strong>ancialDependence and Growth.” American Economic Review88 (3): 559–86.


ReferencesStiglitz, Joseph, and Andrew Weiss. 1988. “<strong>Bank</strong>s as SocialAccountants and Screen<strong>in</strong>g Devices for the Allocationof Credit.” Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 2710. National Bureau ofEconomic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.Chapter 6Berglof, Erik, Howard Rosenthal, and Ernst-Ludwig vonThadden. 2002. “The Formation of Legal Institutionsfor <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy: A Comparative Study of theLegislative History.” Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton University,Department of Politics, Pr<strong>in</strong>ceton, N.J.Betker, Brian. 1995. “Power and Deviations from AbsolutePriority <strong>in</strong> Chapter 11 <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcies.” Journal of<strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> 68 (2): 161–183.Bruno, Matteo. 1561. Tractatus Matthaei Bruni Arim<strong>in</strong>enide Cessione Bonoru, Apud Haeredes AloysijValuassoris & Ioannem Dom<strong>in</strong>icum Michaelem. Vol.115. Venice.Claessens, Stijn, and Leora Klapper. 2001. “<strong>Bank</strong>ruptcyAround the <strong>World</strong>: Explanations for Its Relative Use.”University of Amsterdam, Department of F<strong>in</strong>ance,The Netherlands.Couwenberg, Oscar. 2001. “Survival Rates <strong>in</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcySystems: Overlook<strong>in</strong>g the Evidence.” Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper.University of Gron<strong>in</strong>gen, Department of Economics,The Netherlands.Hart,Oliver. 2000. “Different Approaches to <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy.”Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 7921. National Bureau of EconomicResearch, Cambridge, Mass.La Porta, Rafael, and Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes. 2001.“Creditor Protection and <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy Law Reform.”In Resolution of F<strong>in</strong>ancial Distress, eds. StijnClaessens, Simeon Djankov, and Ashoka Mody.Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.: <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>.La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, AndreiShleifer, and Robert Vishny. 1997. “LegalDeterm<strong>in</strong>ants of External F<strong>in</strong>ance.” Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance52 (3): 1131–50.———. 1998. “Law and F<strong>in</strong>ance.” Journal of PoliticalEconomy 106 (6): 1113–55.Lev<strong>in</strong>thal, Louis. 1919. “The Early History of English<strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy.” University of Pennsylvania Law Review1: 17–81.Modigliani, Franco, and Enrico Perotti. 2000. “SecurityMarkets versus <strong>Bank</strong> F<strong>in</strong>ance: Legal Enforcement andInvestor Protection.” International Review of F<strong>in</strong>ance1(2): 81–96.Pistor, Kathar<strong>in</strong>a, Yoram Ke<strong>in</strong>an, Jan Kle<strong>in</strong>heisterkamp,and Mark D. West. Forthcom<strong>in</strong>g. “Innovation <strong>in</strong>Corporate Law.” Journal of Comparative Economics.Posner, Richard. 1992. Economic Analysis of Law. Boston:Little Brown.Rajak, Harry. 1997. “Rescue versus Liquidation <strong>in</strong> Centraland Eastern Europe.” Texas International Law Journal33 (4): 157–72.Stiglitz, Joseph. 2001. “<strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy Laws: Basic EconomicPr<strong>in</strong>ciples.” In Resolution of F<strong>in</strong>ancial Distress, eds.Stijn Claessens, Simeon Djankov, and Ashoka Mody.Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.: <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>.Stromberg, Per. 2000. “Conflicts of Interest and MarketIlliquidity <strong>in</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy Auctions: Theory and Tests.”Journal of F<strong>in</strong>ance 55 (4): 2641–92.Thorburn, Kar<strong>in</strong>. 2000. “<strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy Auctions: Costs ofDebt Recovery and Firm Survival.” Journal ofF<strong>in</strong>ancial Economics 58 (3): 337–68.Wood, Philip. 1995. “Pr<strong>in</strong>ciples of International Insolvency.”International Insolvency Review 4: 94–138.<strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>. 2001a. “The Insolvency and Creditor RightsSystem <strong>in</strong> the Czech Republic.” Report on Observanceof Standards and Codes. Legal Vice Presidency,Private Sector Development Law, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.———. 2001b. “Pr<strong>in</strong>ciples and Guidel<strong>in</strong>es for EffectiveInsolvency and Creditor Rights Systems.” Legal VicePresidency, Private Sector Development Law,Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.———. 2002a. “The Insolvency and Creditor RightsSystem <strong>in</strong> the Slovak Republic.” Report onObservance of Standards and Codes. Legal VicePresidency, Private Sector Development Law,Wash<strong>in</strong>gton. D.C.———. 2002b. “The Insolvency and Creditor RightsSystem <strong>in</strong> Lithuania.” Report on Observance ofStandards and Codes. Legal Vice Presidency, PrivateSector Development Law, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.———. 2002c. “The Insolvency and Creditor RightsSystem <strong>in</strong> Argent<strong>in</strong>a.” Report on Observance ofStandards and Codes. Legal Vice Presidency, PrivateSector Development Law, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Chapter 7Acemoglu, Daron, James Rob<strong>in</strong>son, and Simon Johnson.2001. “The Colonial Orig<strong>in</strong>s of ComparativeDevelopment: An Empirical Investigation.” AmericanEconomic Review 91 (5): 1369–1401.103


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>104Ales<strong>in</strong>a, Alberto, Silvia Ardagna, Guiseppe Nicoletti, andFabio Schiantarelli. 2003. “Regulation andInvestment.” Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper 9560. National Bureau ofEconomic Research, Cambridge, Mass.Allais, Maurice. 1947. “Le Probleme de la PlanificationEconomique dans une Economie Collectiviste.” KyklosII: 48–71.Bernste<strong>in</strong>, Lisa. 1992. “Opt<strong>in</strong>g Out of the Legal System:Extralegal Contractual Relations <strong>in</strong> the DiamondIndustry.” Journal of Legal Studies 21(1): 115–57.Coase, Ronald. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost.”Journal of Law and Economics 3(1): 1–44.DeLong, J. Bradford, and Andrei Shleifer. 1993. “Pr<strong>in</strong>cesand Merchants: European City Growth Before theIndustrial Revolution.” Journal of Law and Economics36(2): 671–702.Djankov, Simeon, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 2002. “The Regulation ofEntry.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (1): 1–37.———. 2003. “Courts.” Quarterly Journal of Economics118 (2): 452–517.———. Forthcom<strong>in</strong>g. “The New ComparativeEconomics.” Journal of Comparative Economics.Dollar, David, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, and TayeMengistae. 2003. “Investment Climate and FirmPerformance <strong>in</strong> Develop<strong>in</strong>g Countries.” Work<strong>in</strong>gPaper, Development Research Department, <strong>World</strong><strong>Bank</strong>, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton D.C.Ellickson, Robert. 1991. Order Without Law.Cambridge,Mass: Harvard University Press.Engerman, Stanley, and Kenneth Sokoloff. 2002. “FactorEndowments, Inequality, and Paths of Developmentamong New <strong>World</strong> Economies.” Journal of the Lat<strong>in</strong>American and Caribbean Economic Association 3 (1):41–88.Field, Erica. 2003. “Entitled to Work: Urban PropertyRights and Labor Supply <strong>in</strong> Peru.” Work<strong>in</strong>g paper.Department of Economics, Harvard University,Cambridge, Mass.Glaeser, Edward, and Andrei Shleifer. 2002. “Legal Orig<strong>in</strong>s.”Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4): 1193–229.———. 2003. “The Rise of the Regulatory State.” Journalof Economic Literature 41 (2): 401–425.Greif, Avner. 1989. “Reputation and Coalitions <strong>in</strong>Medieval Trade: Evidence on the Maghribi Traders.”Journal of Economic History 49(4): 857–882.Hart,Oliver, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny. 1997.“The Proper Scope of Government.” Quarterly Journalof Economics 112 (4): 1127–1161.Hellman, Joel, Gera<strong>in</strong>t Jones, and Daniel Kaufmann.Forthcom<strong>in</strong>g. “Seize the State, Seize the Day: StateCapture and Influence <strong>in</strong> Transition Economies.”Journal of Comparative Economics.Hochschild, Adam. 1998. K<strong>in</strong>g Leopold’s Ghost: A Story ofGreed, Terror and Heroism <strong>in</strong> the Congo.Boston, Mass:Houghton Miffl<strong>in</strong>.Jacobs, Scott. 2002. “Reform<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Registration <strong>in</strong>Serbia.” Jacobs and Associates, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.Landis, James. 1938. The Adm<strong>in</strong>istrative Process.NewHaven, Conn: Yale University Press.Lewis, Arthur. 1949. The Pr<strong>in</strong>ciples of Economic Plann<strong>in</strong>g.London: George Allen and Unw<strong>in</strong> Ltd.McMillan, John, and Christopher Woodruff. 1999a.“Dispute Prevention without Courts <strong>in</strong> Vietnam.”Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 15 (3):637–58.———. 1999b. “Interfirm Relationships and InformalCredit <strong>in</strong> Vietnam.” Quarterly Journal of Economics114 (4): 1285–1320.Meade, James. 1948. Plann<strong>in</strong>g and the Price Mechanism:the Liberal Socialist Solution.London:George Allenand Unw<strong>in</strong> Ltd.Olson, Mancur. 1991. “Autocracy, Democracy, andProsperity.” In Strategy of Choice, ed. RichardZeckhauser. Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press.Pigou, Alfred. 1938. The Economics of Welfare. 4th edition.London: Macmillan.Pistor, Kathar<strong>in</strong>a, and Chenggang Xu. 2002. “LawEnforcement under Incomplete Law: Theory andEvidence from F<strong>in</strong>ancial Market Regulation.”Columbia School of Law, New York.Posner, Richard. 1972. “A Theory of Negligence.” Journalof Legal Studies 1 (1): 29–96.———. 1974. “Theories of Economic Regulation.” BellJournal of Economics 5 (2): 335–58.Stigler, George. 1971. “The Theory of EconomicRegulation.” Bell Journal of Economics 2: 3–21.Stiglitz, Joseph. 1989. “Markets, Market Failures, andDevelopment.” American Economic Review 79 (2):197–203.<strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>. 2003. <strong>World</strong> Development Indicators.Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, D.C.


Data NotesThe <strong>in</strong>dicators presented and analyzed <strong>in</strong><strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> focus on government regulationand its effect on bus<strong>in</strong>esses. Basedon assessment of laws and regulations, withverification and <strong>in</strong>put from local governmentofficials, lawyers, bus<strong>in</strong>ess consultants, and other professionalsadm<strong>in</strong>ister<strong>in</strong>g or advis<strong>in</strong>g on legal and regulatoryrequirements, this methodology offers severaladvantages. It is based on factual <strong>in</strong>formation andallows multiple <strong>in</strong>teractions with the respondent,ensur<strong>in</strong>g accuracy by clarify<strong>in</strong>g possible mis<strong>in</strong>terpretationsof the survey questions. It is <strong>in</strong>expensive, sodata can be collected <strong>in</strong> a large sample of countries.And because the same standard assumptions areapplied <strong>in</strong> the data collection, which is transparentand easily replicable, comparisons and benchmarksare valid across countries.The <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> methodology has three limitationsthat should be considered when <strong>in</strong>terpret<strong>in</strong>gthe data. First, <strong>in</strong> many cases the collected data referto bus<strong>in</strong>esses <strong>in</strong> the country’s most populous cityand may not be representative of regulatorypractices <strong>in</strong> other parts of the country. Second, thedata often focus on a specific bus<strong>in</strong>ess form—limited liability company—and may not be representativeof the regulation on other bus<strong>in</strong>esses, forexample sole proprietorships. F<strong>in</strong>ally, some<strong>in</strong>dicators—e.g. on time—<strong>in</strong>volve an element ofjudgment by the expert respondents. The time<strong>in</strong>dicators reported <strong>in</strong> <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> representmedian perceived values of several respondentsunder the assumptions of the case study.Updated <strong>in</strong>dicators, as well as any revisions of orcorrections to the pr<strong>in</strong>ted data, are available on the<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> website: http://rru.worldbank.org/do<strong>in</strong>gbus<strong>in</strong>ess/.Economy CharacteristicsRegion and Income group<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> reports the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> regional and<strong>in</strong>come group<strong>in</strong>gs, available at http://www.worldbank.org/data/countryclass/countryclass.htmlGross National Income (GNI) per Capita<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> reports <strong>in</strong>come per capita as at end2002, calculated us<strong>in</strong>g the Atlas method (current US$),as published <strong>in</strong> the <strong>World</strong> Development Indicators.Population<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> reports population statistics aspublished <strong>in</strong> the <strong>World</strong> Development Indicators2002.Legal orig<strong>in</strong>Legal orig<strong>in</strong> identifies the orig<strong>in</strong> of the Company Lawor Commercial Code <strong>in</strong> each country. It is compiledby the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> team us<strong>in</strong>g several sources,<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g La Porta et al. (1999) and the CIA Factbook(2002). There are five possible orig<strong>in</strong>s: English,French, German, Nordic, and Socialist. The Englishorig<strong>in</strong> comprises jurisdictions <strong>in</strong> the common lawtradition. French legal orig<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>cludes the majority ofcountries <strong>in</strong> the civil law tradition. Laws have been105


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>106transplanted through voluntary adoption or colonization.Jurisdictions <strong>in</strong> the Socialist law tradition<strong>in</strong>clude only the countries which did not have welldevelopedcommercial laws prior to the found<strong>in</strong>g ofthe Soviet Union and the Socialist Bloc after <strong>World</strong>War II. The countries of Central and Eastern Europeand the Baltics thus belong to the German or Frenchlegal tradition.Informal economyMeasures the output <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>formal economy as ashare of gross national <strong>in</strong>come. Source: Schneider(2002).Start<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong><strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> compiles a comprehensive list of entryregulations by record<strong>in</strong>g the procedures that areofficially required for an entrepreneur to obta<strong>in</strong> allnecessary permits, and to notify and file with allrequisite authorities, <strong>in</strong> order to legally operate abus<strong>in</strong>ess. The current mark of the data refers toJanuary 2003.The survey divides the process of start<strong>in</strong>g up abus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong>to dist<strong>in</strong>ct procedures, and then calculatesthe costs and time necessary for the accomplishmentof each procedure under normal circumstances. Theassumption is that the required <strong>in</strong>formation is readilyavailable and that all government and nongovernmententities <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> the process function efficientlyand without corruption.There are a number of procedures necessary to legallyoperate <strong>in</strong>dustrial or commercial bus<strong>in</strong>esses. These<strong>in</strong>clude (1) obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the necessary permits andlicenses, and (2) complet<strong>in</strong>g all of the required<strong>in</strong>scriptions, verifications, and notifications to enablethe company to start operation. A “procedure” isdef<strong>in</strong>ed as any <strong>in</strong>teraction of the company founder withexternal parties (government agencies, lawyers, auditors,notaries, etc). Interactions between company foundersor company officers and employees are not consideredas separate procedures. For example, an <strong>in</strong>augurationmeet<strong>in</strong>g where shareholders elect the directors andsecretary of the company is not considered a procedure,as there are no outside parties <strong>in</strong>volved.All procedures that are required for establish<strong>in</strong>g abus<strong>in</strong>ess are recorded, even if they may be avoided <strong>in</strong>exceptional cases or for exceptional types of bus<strong>in</strong>ess.In general, there are four types of procedures: (1) proceduresthat are always required; (2) procedures thatare generally required but that can be avoided <strong>in</strong>exceptional cases or for exceptional types of bus<strong>in</strong>esses;(3) mandatory procedures that are not generallyrequired (<strong>in</strong>dustry-specific and procedures specific tolarge bus<strong>in</strong>esses); and (4) voluntary procedures. Thedata cover only procedures <strong>in</strong> the first two categories.Assumptions about the <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>To make the bus<strong>in</strong>ess comparable across countries,several assumptions are employed:• The bus<strong>in</strong>ess is a limited liability company. If thereis more than one type of limited liability company<strong>in</strong> the country, the most popular limited liabilityform among domestic firms is chosen. Informationon the most popular form is obta<strong>in</strong>ed from<strong>in</strong>corporation lawyers or the statistical office.• It operates <strong>in</strong> the country’s most populous city.• The bus<strong>in</strong>ess is 100 percent domestically owned,and has five owners, none of whom is a legal entity.• The bus<strong>in</strong>ess has a start-up capital of 10 times<strong>in</strong>come per capita <strong>in</strong> 2002. The company’s start-upcapital cannot <strong>in</strong>clude contributions <strong>in</strong> k<strong>in</strong>d, i.e., itis composed of 100 percent cash.• It performs general <strong>in</strong>dustrial or commercialactivities, such as the production or sale of productsor services to the public. It does not perform activitiesof foreign trade and does not handle productssubject to a special tax regime, for example, liquor ortobacco. The company is not us<strong>in</strong>g heavily pollut<strong>in</strong>gproduction processes.• The bus<strong>in</strong>ess leases the commercial plant andoffices and is not a proprietor of real estate.• It does not qualify for <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong>centives or anyspecial benefits.• The bus<strong>in</strong>ess has up to 50 employees one monthafter the commencement of operations. Allemployees are nationals.• It has a turnover up to 10 times its start-up capital.• The company deed is 10 pages long.


Data NotesAssumptions about ProceduresTo make the procedures comparable across countries,several assumptions are employed:• On facilitators: It is assumed that the founderscomplete all procedures themselves, withoutmiddlemen, facilitators, accountants, lawyers, etc.,unless the use of such third party is mandated bylaw. In all countries, it is possible to hire aconsultant or middleman to perform most or all ofthe entry procedures, but this tends to be expensive.• On voluntary procedures: Procedures that are notrequired by law for gett<strong>in</strong>g the bus<strong>in</strong>ess started areignored. For example, the procedure of obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gexclusive rights over the company name is notcounted <strong>in</strong> a country where bus<strong>in</strong>esses can use a“number” as identification.• On nonmandatory lawful shortcuts: Lawfulshortcuts are counted as “required” procedures.These are procedures fulfill<strong>in</strong>g the follow<strong>in</strong>g fourrequirements: (1) they are not mandatory by law;(2) they are not illegal; (3) they are available for thegeneral public (i.e. they are not specificallydesigned for special people); and (4) avoid<strong>in</strong>g themcauses substantial delays.• On <strong>in</strong>dustry-specific requirements: Only proceduresthat are required of all bus<strong>in</strong>esses are covered. Thestudy does not track procedures that only bus<strong>in</strong>esses<strong>in</strong> specific <strong>in</strong>dustries undergo. For example,procedures to comply with environmental regulationsare <strong>in</strong>cluded only when they apply to all bus<strong>in</strong>esses.• On utilities: Procedures that the bus<strong>in</strong>essundergoes <strong>in</strong> order to hook up for electricity, water,gas, and waste-disposal services are not <strong>in</strong>cluded,unless these constitute required <strong>in</strong>spections for thebus<strong>in</strong>ess to legally start operations.Cost MeasureThe text of the Company Law, the Commercial Code,or specific regulations are used as a source for the costsassociated with start<strong>in</strong>g up a bus<strong>in</strong>ess. If there are conflict<strong>in</strong>gsources and the laws are not clear, the mostauthoritative source is used. If the sources have thesame rank, the source <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g the most costlyprocedure is used, s<strong>in</strong>ce an entrepreneur neversecond-guesses a government official. In the absenceof express legal fee schedules, a governmental officer’sestimate is taken as an official source. If several sourceshave different estimates, the median reported value isused. In the absence of government officers’ estimates,estimates of <strong>in</strong>corporation lawyers are used <strong>in</strong>stead. Ifthese differ, the median reported value is computed. Inall cases, the cost estimate excludes bribes.Time MeasureTime is recorded <strong>in</strong> calendar days. For the sake of uniformity,for all countries it is assumed that them<strong>in</strong>imum time required to fulfill a proceduralrequirement is one day. Therefore, the shortestprocedure lasts one calendar day. The time variablecaptures the average duration that <strong>in</strong>corporationlawyers estimate is necessary to complete a procedure.If a procedure can be accelerated at additional cost,the fastest procedure, <strong>in</strong>dependent of cost, is chosen.It is assumed that the entrepreneur does not wastetime and commits to the completion of eachrema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g procedure from the previous day, unlessthe law stipulates the contrary. When estimat<strong>in</strong>g thetime needed for comply<strong>in</strong>g with entry regulations,the time that the entrepreneur spends <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formationgather<strong>in</strong>g is ignored. The entrepreneur is aware of allentry regulations and their sequence from the verybeg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g. Information is collected on the sequence<strong>in</strong> which the procedures are to be completed, as wellas any procedures that lend themselves to be<strong>in</strong>gcarried out simultaneously.M<strong>in</strong>imum Capital RequirementThe m<strong>in</strong>imum capital requirement reflects theamount that the entrepreneur needs to deposit <strong>in</strong> abank account <strong>in</strong> order to obta<strong>in</strong> a bus<strong>in</strong>ess registrationnumber. This amount is typically specified <strong>in</strong> theCommercial Code or the Company Law.This methodology is orig<strong>in</strong>ally developed <strong>in</strong> Djankov,Simeon, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes,and Andrei Shleifer, “The Regulation of Entry,” QuarterlyJournal of Economics, 117, 1–37, Feb. 2002 andadopted with m<strong>in</strong>or changes here.107


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>108Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersThe data on hir<strong>in</strong>g and fir<strong>in</strong>g workers are based onan assessment of employment laws and regulationsas well as specific constitutional provisionsgovern<strong>in</strong>g this area. The employment laws of mostcountries are available onl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the NATLEXdatabase, published by the International LabourOrganization. Constitutions are available onl<strong>in</strong>e onthe U.S. Law Library of Congress website. The ma<strong>in</strong>secondary sources <strong>in</strong>clude the International Encyclopaediafor Labour Law and Industrial Relations,and Social Security Programs Throughout the <strong>World</strong>.Data were confirmed with more than one source.In most cases both the actual laws and a secondarysource were used to ensure accuracy. All conflict<strong>in</strong>ganswers were checked with two additional sources,<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g a local legal treatise on labor and socialsecurity laws. Legal advice from lead<strong>in</strong>g local lawfirms was solicited to confirm accuracy <strong>in</strong> all cases.The current mark of the data refers to January2003.Follow<strong>in</strong>g the OECD Job Study and the InternationalEncyclopaedia for Labour Law and IndustrialRelations, the areas subject to statutory regulation <strong>in</strong>all countries were identified. Those <strong>in</strong>clude hir<strong>in</strong>g ofworkers, conditions of employment, and fir<strong>in</strong>g ofworkers.Assumptions about the WorkerTo make the worker comparable across countries,several assumptions are employed.• The worker is a nonexecutive full-time maleemployee who has worked <strong>in</strong> the same companyfor 20 years.• His salary plus benefits equal the country’s averagewage dur<strong>in</strong>g the entire period of his employment.• The worker has a nonwork<strong>in</strong>g wife and twochildren. The family has always resided <strong>in</strong> thecountry’s most populous city.• The worker is a lawful citizen who belongs to thesame race and religion as the majority of thecountry’s population.• He is not a member of the labor union (unlessmembership is mandatory).Assumptions about the <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>To make the bus<strong>in</strong>ess comparable across countries,several assumptions are employed.• The bus<strong>in</strong>ess is a limited liability corporation.• It operates <strong>in</strong> the country’s most populous city.• The bus<strong>in</strong>ess is 100 percent domestically owned.• It operates <strong>in</strong> the manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sector.• The bus<strong>in</strong>ess has 201 employees.• It abides by every law and regulation, but does notgrant workers more benefits than what is legallymandated.Construction of IndicesFour <strong>in</strong>dices are constructed: a flexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>dex, the conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex, aflexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex and an overall employmentregulation<strong>in</strong>dex. Each <strong>in</strong>dex may take values between0 and 100, with higher values <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g more rigidregulation.The flexibility of hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex covers the availability ofpart-time and fixed-term contracts. Conditions ofemployment cover work<strong>in</strong>g time requirements,<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g mandatory m<strong>in</strong>imum daily rest, maximumnumber of hours <strong>in</strong> a normal workweek, premium forovertime work, restrictions on weekly holiday,mandatory payment for nonwork<strong>in</strong>g days, (which<strong>in</strong>cludes days of annual leave with pay and paid time offfor holidays), and m<strong>in</strong>imum wage legislation. The constitutionalpr<strong>in</strong>ciples deal<strong>in</strong>g with the m<strong>in</strong>imum conditionsof employment are also coded. Flexibility offir<strong>in</strong>g covers workers’ legal protections aga<strong>in</strong>st dismissal,<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g grounds for dismissal, procedures fordismissal (<strong>in</strong>dividual and collective), notice period, andseverance payment. The constitutional pr<strong>in</strong>ciplesdeal<strong>in</strong>g with protection aga<strong>in</strong>st dismissal are also coded.The <strong>in</strong>dex of employment regulation is a simpleaverage of the flexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex, the conditionsof-employment<strong>in</strong>dex, and the flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>dex.This methodology is developed <strong>in</strong> Botero, Juan, SimeonDjankov, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes,and Andrei Shleifer, “The Regulation of Labor,” Work<strong>in</strong>gPaper 9756, National Bureau of Economic Research,June 2003, and adopted with m<strong>in</strong>or changes here.


Data NotesEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractThe data on enforc<strong>in</strong>g a contract are derived fromquestionnaires answered by attorneys at private lawfirms. The current mark of the data refers to January2003. The questionnaire covers the step-by-stepevolution of a debt recovery case before local courts <strong>in</strong>the country’s most populous city. The respondentfirms were provided with significant detail, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>gthe amount of the claim, the location and ma<strong>in</strong> characteristicsof the litigants, the presence of city regulations,the nature of the remedy requested by thepla<strong>in</strong>tiff, the merit of the pla<strong>in</strong>tiff’s and the defendant’sclaims, and the social implications of the judicialoutcomes. These standardized details enabled therespondent law firms to describe the proceduresexplicitly and <strong>in</strong> full detail.Assumptions about the case• The debt value equals 50 percent of the country’s<strong>in</strong>come per capita.• The pla<strong>in</strong>tiff has fully complied with the contract(the pla<strong>in</strong>tiff is 100 percent right).• The case presents a lawful transaction betweenbus<strong>in</strong>esses resid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the country’s most populouscity.• The bank refuses payment for lack of funds <strong>in</strong> theborrower’s account.• The pla<strong>in</strong>tiff files a lawsuit to collect the debt.• The debtor attempts to delay service of process butit is f<strong>in</strong>ally accomplished.• The debtor opposes the compla<strong>in</strong>t (default judgmentis not an option).• The judge decides every motion for the pla<strong>in</strong>tiff.• The pla<strong>in</strong>tiff attempts to <strong>in</strong>troduce documentaryevidence and to call one witness. The debtor attemptsto call one witness. Neither party presents objections.• The judgment is <strong>in</strong> favor of the pla<strong>in</strong>tiff.• No appeals or post-judgment motions are filed byeither party to the case.• The debt is successfully collected.The study develops three ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dicators of theefficiency of the judicial system on the enforcementof commercial contracts. The first <strong>in</strong>dicator is thenumber of procedures mandated by law or courtregulation that demand <strong>in</strong>teraction between theparties or between them and the judge or courtofficer.The second <strong>in</strong>dicator of efficiency is an estimate—<strong>in</strong> calendar days—of the duration of the dispute resolutionprocess. Time is measured as the number ofdays from the moment the pla<strong>in</strong>tiff files the lawsuit <strong>in</strong>court, until the moment of actual payment. Thismeasure <strong>in</strong>cludes both the days where actions takeplace and wait<strong>in</strong>g periods between actions. Therespondents make separate estimates of the averageduration until the completion of service of process,the issuance of judgment (duration of trial), and themoment of payment or repossession (duration ofenforcement).The third <strong>in</strong>dicator is cost, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g court costsand attorney fees, as well as payments to other professionalslike accountants and bailiffs.The study also develops an <strong>in</strong>dex of the proceduralcomplexity of contract enforcement. This <strong>in</strong>dexmeasures substantive and procedural statutory <strong>in</strong>tervention<strong>in</strong> civil cases <strong>in</strong> the courts, and is formed byaverag<strong>in</strong>g the follow<strong>in</strong>g sub<strong>in</strong>dices:1. Use of professionals: This sub<strong>in</strong>dex measureswhether the resolution of the case provided wouldrely mostly <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>tervention of professional judgesand attorneys, as opposed to the <strong>in</strong>tervention ofother types of adjudicators and lay people.2. Nature of actions: This sub<strong>in</strong>dex measures thewritten or oral nature of the actions <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong>the procedure, from the fil<strong>in</strong>g of the compla<strong>in</strong>t toenforcement.3. Legal justification: This sub<strong>in</strong>dex measures thelevel of legal justification required <strong>in</strong> the process ofdispute resolution.4. Statutory regulation of evidence: This sub<strong>in</strong>dexmeasures the level of statutory control or<strong>in</strong>tervention of the adm<strong>in</strong>istration, admissibility,evaluation, and record<strong>in</strong>g of evidence.5. Control of superior review: This sub<strong>in</strong>dexmeasures the level of control or <strong>in</strong>tervention of theappellate court’s review of the first <strong>in</strong>stancejudgment.109


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>1106. Other statutory <strong>in</strong>terventions: This sub<strong>in</strong>dexmeasures the formalities required to engage someone<strong>in</strong>to the procedure or to hold him/her accountablefor the judgment.The procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex varies from 0 to100, with higher values <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g more proceduralcomplexity <strong>in</strong> enforc<strong>in</strong>g a contract.The methodology is developed <strong>in</strong> Djankov, Simeon,Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and AndreiShleifer, “Courts,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118,453–517, May 2003.Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditTwo sets of measures on gett<strong>in</strong>g credit are constructed:<strong>in</strong>dicators on credit <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g and an<strong>in</strong>dicator of the legal protection of creditor rights.The data on credit <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutionswere built start<strong>in</strong>g with a survey of bank<strong>in</strong>gsupervisors, designed to:• confirm the presence/absence of public creditregistries and private credit <strong>in</strong>formation bureaus,• collect descriptive data on credit market outcomes(bank<strong>in</strong>g concentration rates, loan default rates),and• collect <strong>in</strong>formation on related rules <strong>in</strong> creditmarkets (<strong>in</strong>terest rate controls, collateral, laws oncredit <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g).For countries that confirmed the presence of a publiccredit registry, a detailed survey on the registry’sstructure, laws, and associated rules followed. Similarsurveys were sent to major private credit bureaus.These surveys were designed as a jo<strong>in</strong>t cooperativeeffort with the “Credit Report<strong>in</strong>g Systems Project” <strong>in</strong>the <strong>World</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> Group, adapt<strong>in</strong>g previous surveysconducted by this project. Input was also receivedfrom Professor Marco Pagano of the University ofSalerno. Variables assessed <strong>in</strong>clude:• coverage of the market• scope of <strong>in</strong>formation collected• scope of <strong>in</strong>formation distributed• accessibility of the data available• quality of <strong>in</strong>formation available• legal framework for <strong>in</strong>formation shar<strong>in</strong>g andquality of data.Public Credit Registry CoverageA public credit registry is def<strong>in</strong>ed as a databasemanaged by the public sector, usually by the Central<strong>Bank</strong> or Super<strong>in</strong>tendent of <strong>Bank</strong>s, that collects<strong>in</strong>formation on the stand<strong>in</strong>g of borrowers (personsand/or bus<strong>in</strong>esses) <strong>in</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>ancial system and makesit available to f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions.The coverage <strong>in</strong>dicator reports the number of <strong>in</strong>dividualsand/or firms listed <strong>in</strong> the public credit registryas of January 2003 with current <strong>in</strong>formation onrepayment history, unpaid debts, or credit outstand<strong>in</strong>g.The number is scaled to country’s population(per 1,000 capita). A coverage value of zero <strong>in</strong>dicatesthat no public registry operates.Extensiveness-of-Public-Credit-Registries IndexScores can range from 0 to 100, where higher values<strong>in</strong>dicate that the rules of the public credit registry arebetter designed to support credit transactions. Theoverall <strong>in</strong>dex of the extensiveness of public credit registriesis a simple average of the collection, distribution,access, and quality <strong>in</strong>dices, described below.• Collection <strong>in</strong>dexAssigns a positive score if the registry: lists both firmsand <strong>in</strong>dividuals; shares <strong>in</strong>formation with other registries;collects <strong>in</strong>formation that is submitted voluntarily;has laws/regulations that require lenders toconsult the registry when mak<strong>in</strong>g loans; requires thatparticipat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions report data at least weekly;ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>s historical records of more than seven years;ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>s records of defaults even after they havebeen repaid; collects data from nonbank f<strong>in</strong>ancial<strong>in</strong>stitutions; reports all loans, regardless of theamount; and if there is a m<strong>in</strong>imum loan size for<strong>in</strong>clusion, the m<strong>in</strong>imum loan size is lower than thesample median.Higher values <strong>in</strong>dicate broader rules on collection of<strong>in</strong>formation.


Data Notes• Distribution <strong>in</strong>dexAssigns a positive score if the registry: allows distributionof historical data (more than currentmonth); distributes disaggregated loan <strong>in</strong>formation;distributes both positive and negative data on <strong>in</strong>dividuals;distributes both positive and negative data onfirms; distributes an extensive number of types of<strong>in</strong>formation on <strong>in</strong>dividuals; distributes an extensivenumber of types of <strong>in</strong>formation on firms.Higher values <strong>in</strong>dicate broader rules on distributionof <strong>in</strong>formation.• Access <strong>in</strong>dexAssigns a positive score if: the registry allows accessfor other parties beyond bank<strong>in</strong>g supervisors,<strong>in</strong>formation submitters, and consumers; the registrydoes not require f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions to submit data<strong>in</strong> order to access the registry; borrower’s authorizationis not required for access; <strong>in</strong>formation can beaccessed not only on certa<strong>in</strong> types of borrower;<strong>in</strong>formation can be accessed with<strong>in</strong> a day; access iselectronic; time to distribute data is regulated.Higher values <strong>in</strong>dicate broader rules on access to<strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> the registry.• Quality <strong>in</strong>dexAssigns a positive score if: legal penalties for report<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>accurate data are imposed; by law consumers may<strong>in</strong>spect data; there is a legal requirement to respond toborrower compla<strong>in</strong>ts; rout<strong>in</strong>e checks with other data,borrower compla<strong>in</strong>ts, statistical checks and softwareprograms are used as quality checks; by law data needsto be submitted with<strong>in</strong> two weeks of report<strong>in</strong>g period;more than 95 percent of f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions submitdata on time; time to correct reported errors is lessthan two weeks; data is available for distributionwith<strong>in</strong> one week of submission; registry has been <strong>in</strong>existence for an extended period of time.Higher values <strong>in</strong>dicate more extensive rules on thequality of <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>in</strong> the registry.Private Credit Bureau CoverageA private credit bureau is def<strong>in</strong>ed as a private firm ora non-profit organization that ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>s a databaseon the stand<strong>in</strong>g of borrowers (persons or bus<strong>in</strong>esses)<strong>in</strong> the f<strong>in</strong>ancial system, and its primary role is tofacilitate exchange of credit <strong>in</strong>formation amongstbanks and f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions.Credit <strong>in</strong>vestigative bureaus and credit report<strong>in</strong>gfirms that do not directly facilitate exchange of<strong>in</strong>formation between f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions exist <strong>in</strong>many countries, but are not considered here.The coverage <strong>in</strong>dicator reports the number of<strong>in</strong>dividuals and/or firms listed <strong>in</strong> the private creditbureau as of January 2003 with current <strong>in</strong>formationon repayment history, unpaid debts, or credit outstand<strong>in</strong>g.The number is scaled to country’s population(per 1,000 capita). A coverage value of 0<strong>in</strong>dicates that no private credit bureau operates.Creditor-Rights Index<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> reports an <strong>in</strong>dicator of creditor rights<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>solvency, based on the methodology of La Portaand others (1998). The <strong>in</strong>dicator measures four powersof secured lenders <strong>in</strong> liquidation and reorganization:• Restrictions on enter<strong>in</strong>g reorganization: whetherthere are restrictions, such as creditor consent, whena debtor files for reorganization—as opposed tocases where debtors can seek unilateral protectionfrom creditors’ claims by fil<strong>in</strong>g for reorganization.• No automatic stay: whether secured creditors areable to seize their collateral after the decision forreorganization is approved, <strong>in</strong> other words whetherthere is no “automatic stay” or “asset freeze” imposedby the court.• Secured creditors are paid first: whether securedcreditors are paid first out of the proceeds fromliquidat<strong>in</strong>g a bankrupt firm, as opposed to otherparties such as government (e.g., for taxes) or workers.• Management does not stay <strong>in</strong> reorganization:Whether an adm<strong>in</strong>istrator is responsible formanagement of the bus<strong>in</strong>ess dur<strong>in</strong>g the resolutionof reorganization, <strong>in</strong>stead of hav<strong>in</strong>g the managementof the bankrupt debtor cont<strong>in</strong>ue to run thebus<strong>in</strong>ess.A value of one is assigned for each variable when acountry’s laws and regulations provide these powersfor secured creditors. The aggregate creditor rights111


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>112<strong>in</strong>dex sums the total score across all four variables. Am<strong>in</strong>imum score of zero represents weak creditorrights and the maximum score of four representsstrong creditor rights.This methodology is developed <strong>in</strong> Djankov, Simeon,Caralee McLiesh, and Andrei Shleifer, “Remedies <strong>in</strong> CreditMarkets,” work<strong>in</strong>g paper, Department of Economics,Harvard University, July 2003; and La Porta, Rafael,Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and RobertVishny, “Law and F<strong>in</strong>ance,” Journal of PoliticalEconomy, 106, 1113–55, 1998.Clos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Members of the International Bar Association’sCommittee on Insolvency were asked to fill out aquestionnaire relat<strong>in</strong>g to a hypothetical corporatebankruptcy. A first draft of the survey was preparedwith scholars from Harvard University, and withadvice from practic<strong>in</strong>g attorneys <strong>in</strong> Argent<strong>in</strong>a,Bulgaria, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Nigeria,the United K<strong>in</strong>gdom, and the United States. Thissurvey was then piloted <strong>in</strong> the Czech Republic, Italy,Latvia, the Russian Federation, Spa<strong>in</strong>, and Uzbekistan.<strong>Response</strong>s from these countries were used to revisethe <strong>in</strong>itial questionnaire. Next, participat<strong>in</strong>g lawfirms or bankruptcy judges from around the worldwere sent a f<strong>in</strong>al questionnaire to fill out. Answerswere provided by a senior partner at each firm, <strong>in</strong>cooperation with one or two junior associates. In allcases, respondents were contacted for additional<strong>in</strong>formation follow<strong>in</strong>g focus group presentations atthe International Bar Association’s Committee onInsolvency meet<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> Dubl<strong>in</strong>, Ireland, Durban,South Africa, and Rome, Italy. This helped theaccurate <strong>in</strong>terpretation of answers, to completemiss<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation, and to clarify possible <strong>in</strong>consistencies.After this second round, a file was completedfor each country and sent back to the respondents forf<strong>in</strong>al clearance.Participants were asked to base their responses onthe follow<strong>in</strong>g scenario:Assumptions about the <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>• The bus<strong>in</strong>ess is a limited liability corporation.• It operates <strong>in</strong> the country’s most populous city.• The bus<strong>in</strong>ess is 100 percent domestically owned, ofwhich 51 percent is owned by its founder, who isalso the chairman of the supervisory board. Asidefrom the founder, there is no other shareholderwho has above 1 percent of shares.• Its only asset is downtown real estate.• The bus<strong>in</strong>ess runs a hotel <strong>in</strong> the real estate it owns.• There is a professional general manager.• The bus<strong>in</strong>ess has average annual revenue of 1,000times <strong>in</strong>come per capita over the last three years.• The bus<strong>in</strong>ess has 201 employees, and 50 suppliers,each of whom is owed money for the last delivery.• Five years ago the bus<strong>in</strong>ess borrowed from adomestic bank, and bought real estate (the hotelbuild<strong>in</strong>g), us<strong>in</strong>g it as a security for the bank loan.• The loan has 10 years to full repayment.• The bus<strong>in</strong>ess has observed the payment scheduleand all other conditions of the loan up to now.• The current value of the mortgage pr<strong>in</strong>cipal isexactly equal to the market value of the hotel.• The entire case <strong>in</strong>volves domestic entities (i.e.,there are no cross-border issues).Assumptions about ProceduresIn January 2003, the hypothetical bus<strong>in</strong>ess is experienc<strong>in</strong>gliquidity problems. The company’s loss <strong>in</strong>2002 brought its net worth to a negative figure. Thecash flow available <strong>in</strong> 2003 will cover all operat<strong>in</strong>gexpenses: supplier payments, salaries, hotel upkeepcosts, and outstand<strong>in</strong>g taxes. However, there will be nocash left to pay the bank either <strong>in</strong>terest or pr<strong>in</strong>cipal <strong>in</strong>full, due on January 2, 2003. Therefore, the bus<strong>in</strong>esswill default on its loan. Management believes thatlosses will be <strong>in</strong>curred <strong>in</strong> 2003 and <strong>2004</strong> as well.In countries where float<strong>in</strong>g charges are possible, itis assumed that the bank holds a float<strong>in</strong>g chargeaga<strong>in</strong>st the hotel. If the law does not permit a float<strong>in</strong>gcharge, but contracts nevertheless commonly usesome other provision to that effect, such as allow<strong>in</strong>gthe lender rights to the future stream of profits orother proceeds of the collateral, the assumption isthat this provision is specified <strong>in</strong> the lend<strong>in</strong>g contract.


Data NotesIf the bank were to have the new projections, itmight try to salvage as much of its loan as possible,for example by seiz<strong>in</strong>g and sell<strong>in</strong>g the security (thehotel build<strong>in</strong>g) or by fil<strong>in</strong>g for formal liquidation.The bank prefers to act fast.The only argument management can make <strong>in</strong> favorof keep<strong>in</strong>g the company <strong>in</strong> operation is that the valueof the firm is higher as a go<strong>in</strong>g concern than if it isliquidated. In contrast, the market price of the bank’ssecurity is decreas<strong>in</strong>g every day. Further, it seemsunlikely that, without a strong boom <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dustry,the bus<strong>in</strong>ess will be able to catch up with backpayments.Assumptions about InformationAvailability• Management has the entire <strong>in</strong>formation.• The bank will observe the payment default by thecompany on January 2, 2003, when its <strong>in</strong>terestand pr<strong>in</strong>cipal payments are due. However, thebank does not know the new projections for thefuture. The latter <strong>in</strong>formation will only beavailable <strong>in</strong> the 2002 Annual Report published onMarch 31, 2003.• The shareholders will have access to the AnnualReport on March 31, 2003, will be present at thegeneral shareholders meet<strong>in</strong>g, and know any public<strong>in</strong>formation.• Suppliers do not have access to the new projections,and are therefore not aware of the hotel’s f<strong>in</strong>ancialproblems. Unless any developments are publiclyannounced, or unless suppliers are contacted ascreditors as part of a legal proceed<strong>in</strong>g, they will notforesee problems before October 1, 2003, when theirpayment and the new <strong>in</strong>ventory delivery is due.Suppliers can consult the Annual Report on March31, 2003.• The tax agency and any other <strong>in</strong>stitutions thatsupervise firms do not have access to the newprojections, but will have the f<strong>in</strong>ancial statementsfor 2002 once the company publishes its AnnualReport on March 31, 2003.• Employees will have access to the Annual Reporton March 31, 2003.The claims as of January 1, 2003, and a set of f<strong>in</strong>ancialstatements for 2001–2002, as well as 2003–2005 projections,are attached as an appendix to the case sentto the respondents.Assumptions about Legal OptionsThe bus<strong>in</strong>ess has too many creditors to renegotiateout of court. Its options are:• A procedure aimed at rehabilitation or any procedurethat will reorganize the bus<strong>in</strong>ess to permit furtheroperation,• A procedure aimed at liquidation,• A procedure aimed at sell<strong>in</strong>g the hotel, either as ago<strong>in</strong>g concern or piecemeal, either enforced throughcourt (or a government authority like a debtcollection agency) or out of court (receivership).Cost MeasureThe answers of practic<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>solvency lawyers are usedas a source for the costs associated with resolv<strong>in</strong>g<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong> the courts. If several respondents reportdifferent estimates, the median reported value is used.Cost is def<strong>in</strong>ed as the cost of the entire bankruptcyprocess, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g court costs, <strong>in</strong>solvency practitioners’costs, the cost of <strong>in</strong>dependent assessors,lawyers, accountants, etc. In all cases, the cost estimateexcludes bribes. The cost figures are averages of theestimates <strong>in</strong> a multiple-choice question, where therespondents choose among the follow<strong>in</strong>g options: 0–2percent, 3–5 percent, 6–10 percent, 11–25 percent,26–50 percent, and more than 50 percent of the<strong>in</strong>solvency estate value.Time MeasureTime is recorded <strong>in</strong> calendar years. The time measurecaptures the average duration that <strong>in</strong>solvency lawyersestimate is necessary to complete a procedure. If aprocedure can be accelerated at additional cost, thefastest procedure, <strong>in</strong>dependent of cost, is chosen. Thelegal team of the party fil<strong>in</strong>g for <strong>in</strong>solvency is aware ofall procedures and their sequence from the verybeg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g. The study collects <strong>in</strong>formation on thesequence <strong>in</strong> which the <strong>in</strong>solvency procedures are to becompleted, as well as any procedures that can be113


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>114carried out simultaneously. The time measure <strong>in</strong>cludesall delays due to legal derailment tactics that parties tothe <strong>in</strong>solvency may use. In particular, it <strong>in</strong>cludes delaysdue to extension of response periods or to appeals, ifthese are allowed under the law. As such, the measurerepresents the actual time of the <strong>in</strong>solvency proceed<strong>in</strong>gs,not the time that the law may mandate.Absolute Priority PreservedThe measure documents the order <strong>in</strong> which claimsare paid <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>solvency process, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g paymentof post-petition claims. The measure is scaled so thathigher values imply stricter observance of priority. A100 on Absolute Priority Preserved means thatsecured creditors are paid before labor claims, taxclaims and shareholders. A 67 means that securedcreditors get paid second, and 33 means they get paidthird. A zero on Absolute Priority Preserved meansthat secured creditors get paid after all labor claimsand tax claims are satisfied, and after shareholdershave received payments as well.Efficient Outcome AchievedThe measure documents the success of the <strong>in</strong>solvencyregime <strong>in</strong> reach<strong>in</strong>g the economically efficient outcome.A one on Efficient Outcome Achieved means that the<strong>in</strong>solvency process results <strong>in</strong> either foreclosure orliquidation with a go<strong>in</strong>g-concern sale or <strong>in</strong> a successfulrehabilitation ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the bus<strong>in</strong>ess buthir<strong>in</strong>g new management. A zero <strong>in</strong>dicates that theefficient outcome is not achieved.Goals-of-Insolvency IndexThe measure documents the success <strong>in</strong> reach<strong>in</strong>g thethree goals of <strong>in</strong>solvency, as stated <strong>in</strong> Hart (1999). Itis calculated as the simple average of the cost of<strong>in</strong>solvency (rescaled from 0 to 100, where higherscores <strong>in</strong>dicate less cost), time of <strong>in</strong>solvency(rescaled from 0 to 100, where higher scores <strong>in</strong>dicateless time), the observance of absolute priority ofclaims, and the efficient outcome achieved. The totalGoals-of-Insolvency Index ranges from 0 to 100: ascore 100 on the <strong>in</strong>dex means perfect efficiency(F<strong>in</strong>land, Norway, and S<strong>in</strong>gapore have 99), a 0means that the <strong>in</strong>solvency system does not functionat all.Court-Powers IndexThe measure documents the degree to which thecourt drives <strong>in</strong>solvency proceed<strong>in</strong>gs. It is an averageof three <strong>in</strong>dicators: whether the court appo<strong>in</strong>ts andreplaces the <strong>in</strong>solvency adm<strong>in</strong>istrator with norestrictions imposed by law, whether the reports ofthe adm<strong>in</strong>istrator are accessible only to the court andnot creditors, and whether the court decides on theadoption of the rehabilitation plan. The <strong>in</strong>dex isscaled from 0 to 100, where higher values <strong>in</strong>dicatemore court <strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>solvency process.This methodology is developed <strong>in</strong> Djankov, Simeon,Oliver Hart, Tatiana Nenova, and Andrei Shleifer,“Efficiency <strong>in</strong> <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy,” work<strong>in</strong>g paper, Departmentof Economics, Harvard University, July 2003.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> IndicatorsECONOMY CHARACTERISTICSCountry Region Income group Legal orig<strong>in</strong>Albania Europe & Central Asia Lower-middle FrenchAlgeria Middle East & North Africa Lower-middle FrenchAngola Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchArgent<strong>in</strong>a Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Upper-middle FrenchArmenia Europe & Central Asia Low SocialistAustralia OECD: High Income High EnglishAustria OECD: High Income High GermanAzerbaijan Europe & Central Asia Low SocialistBangladesh South Asia Low EnglishBelarus Europe & Central Asia Lower-middle SocialistBelgium OECD: High Income High FrenchBen<strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchBolivia Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Lower-middle FrenchBosnia and Herzegov<strong>in</strong>a Europe & Central Asia Lower-middle GermanBotswana Sub-Saharan Africa Upper-middle EnglishBrazil Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Lower-middle FrenchBulgaria Europe & Central Asia Lower-middle GermanBurk<strong>in</strong>a Faso Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchBurundi Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchCambodia East Asia & Pacific Low FrenchCameroon Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchCanada OECD: High Income High EnglishCentral African Republic Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchChad Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchChile Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Upper-middle FrenchCh<strong>in</strong>a East Asia & Pacific Lower-middle GermanColombia Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Lower-middle FrenchCongo, Dem. Rep. of Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchCongo, Rep. of Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchCosta Rica Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Upper-middle FrenchCôte d’Ivoire Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchCroatia Europe & Central Asia Upper-middle GermanCzech Republic Europe & Central Asia Upper-middle GermanDenmark OECD: High Income High NordicDom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Lower-middle FrenchEcuador Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Lower-middle French115


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>Country Region Income group Legal orig<strong>in</strong>116Egypt, Arab Rep. of Middle East & North Africa Lower-middle FrenchEl Salvador Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Lower-middle FrenchEthiopia Sub-Saharan Africa Low EnglishF<strong>in</strong>land OECD: High Income High NordicFrance OECD: High Income High FrenchGeorgia Europe & Central Asia Low SocialistGermany OECD: High Income High GermanGhana Sub-Saharan Africa Low EnglishGreece OECD: High Income High FrenchGuatemala Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Lower-middle FrenchGu<strong>in</strong>ea Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchHaiti Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Low FrenchHonduras Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Lower-middle FrenchHong Kong, Ch<strong>in</strong>a East Asia & Pacific High EnglishHungary Europe & Central Asia Upper-middle GermanIndia South Asia Low EnglishIndonesia East Asia & Pacific Low FrenchIran, Islamic Rep. of Middle East & North Africa Lower-middle EnglishIreland OECD: High Income High EnglishIsrael Middle East & North Africa High EnglishItaly OECD: High Income High FrenchJamaica Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Lower-middle EnglishJapan OECD: High Income High GermanJordan Middle East & North Africa Lower-middle FrenchKazakhstan Europe & Central Asia Lower-middle SocialistKenya Sub-Saharan Africa Low EnglishKorea, Rep. of OECD: High Income High GermanKuwait Middle East & North Africa High FrenchKyrgyz Republic Europe & Central Asia Low SocialistLao PDR East Asia & Pacific Low FrenchLatvia Europe & Central Asia Upper-middle GermanLebanon Middle East & North Africa Upper-middle FrenchLesotho Sub-Saharan Africa Low EnglishLithuania Europe & Central Asia Upper-middle FrenchMacedonia, FYR Europe & Central Asia Lower-middle GermanMadagascar Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchMalawi Sub-Saharan Africa Low EnglishMalaysia East Asia & Pacific Upper-middle EnglishMali Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchMauritania Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchMexico Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Upper-middle FrenchMoldova Europe & Central Asia Low SocialistMongolia East Asia & Pacific Low SocialistMorocco Middle East & North Africa Lower-middle FrenchMozambique Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchNamibia Sub-Saharan Africa Lower-middle EnglishNepal South Asia Low EnglishNetherlands OECD: High Income High FrenchNew Zealand OECD: High Income High EnglishNicaragua Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Low French


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> IndicatorsCountry Region Income group Legal orig<strong>in</strong>Niger Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchNigeria Sub-Saharan Africa Low EnglishNorway OECD: High Income High NordicOman Middle East & North Africa Upper-middle FrenchPakistan South Asia Low EnglishPanama Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Upper-middle FrenchPapua New Gu<strong>in</strong>ea East Asia & Pacific Low EnglishParaguay Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Lower-middle FrenchPeru Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Lower-middle FrenchPhilipp<strong>in</strong>es East Asia & Pacific Lower-middle FrenchPoland Europe & Central Asia Upper-middle GermanPortugal OECD: High Income High FrenchPuerto Rico Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean High FrenchRomania Europe & Central Asia Lower-middle FrenchRussian Federation Europe & Central Asia Lower-middle SocialistRwanda Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchSaudi Arabia Middle East & North Africa Upper-middle EnglishSenegal Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchSerbia and Montenegro Europe & Central Asia Lower-middle GermanSierra Leone Sub-Saharan Africa Low EnglishS<strong>in</strong>gapore East Asia & Pacific High EnglishSlovak Republic Europe & Central Asia Upper-middle GermanSlovenia Europe & Central Asia High GermanSouth Africa Sub-Saharan Africa Lower-middle EnglishSpa<strong>in</strong> OECD: High Income High FrenchSri Lanka South Asia Lower-middle EnglishSweden OECD: High Income High NordicSwitzerland OECD: High Income High GermanSyrian Arab Republic Middle East & North Africa Lower-middle FrenchTaiwan, Ch<strong>in</strong>a East Asia & Pacific High GermanTanzania Sub-Saharan Africa Low EnglishThailand East Asia & Pacific Lower-middle EnglishTogo Sub-Saharan Africa Low FrenchTunisia Middle East & North Africa Lower-middle FrenchTurkey Europe & Central Asia Lower-middle FrenchUganda Sub-Saharan Africa Low EnglishUkra<strong>in</strong>e Europe & Central Asia Lower-middle SocialistUnited Arab Emirates Middle East & North Africa High EnglishUnited K<strong>in</strong>gdom OECD: High Income High EnglishUnited States OECD: High Income High EnglishUruguay Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Upper-middle FrenchUzbekistan Europe & Central Asia Low SocialistVenezuela, RB Lat<strong>in</strong> America & Caribbean Upper-middle FrenchVietnam East Asia & Pacific Low FrenchYemen, Rep. of Middle East & North Africa Low EnglishZambia Sub-Saharan Africa Low EnglishZimbabwe Sub-Saharan Africa Low English117


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>Start<strong>in</strong>g-a-<strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Indicators—measure the procedures, time, cost, and m<strong>in</strong>imum capital requirementsto register a bus<strong>in</strong>ess formallyCostM<strong>in</strong>. capitalNumber of Time Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come (% of <strong>in</strong>comeCountry procedures (days) (US$) per capita) per capita)118Albania 11 47 897 65.0 51.7Algeria 18 29 548 31.9 73.0Angola 14 146 5531 838.0 174.0Argent<strong>in</strong>a 15 68 324 8.0 0.0Armenia 10 25 68 8.7 11.0Australia 2 2 402 2.0 0.0Austria 9 29 1534 6.6 140.8Azerbaijan 14 106 119 16.8 0.0Bangladesh 7 30 272 75.5 0.0Belarus 19 118 369 27.1 110.7Belgium 7 56 2633 11.3 75.1Ben<strong>in</strong> 9 63 719 189.2 377.6Bolivia 18 67 1499 166.6 0.0Bosnia and Herzegov<strong>in</strong>a 12 59 657 51.8 379.1Botswana 10 97 1076 36.1 0.0Brazil 15 152 331 11.6 0.0Bulgaria 10 30 148 8.3 134.4Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso 15 136 716 325.2 652.2Burundi .. .. .. .. ..Cambodia 11 94 1551 553.8 1825.8Cameroon 12 37 1068 190.7 243.6Canada 2 3 127 0.6 0.0Central African Republic .. .. .. .. ..Chad 19 73 870 395.3 652.2Chile 10 28 493 11.6 0.0Ch<strong>in</strong>a 12 46 135 14.3 3855.9Colombia 19 60 498 27.2 0.0Congo, Dem. Rep. of 13 215 785 871.9 320.7Congo, Rep. of 8 67 1897 271.0 205.0Costa Rica 11 80 879 21.4 0.0Côte d’Ivoire 10 77 873 143.1 235.2Croatia 13 50 843 18.2 50.7Czech Republic 10 88 648 11.7 110.0Denmark 4 4 0 0.0 52.3Dom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic 12 78 1115 48.1 23.2Ecuador 14 90 914 63.0 27.6Egypt, Arab Rep. of 13 43 900 61.2 788.6El Salvador 12 115 2690 129.3 549.5Ethiopia 8 44 422 421.6 1756.1F<strong>in</strong>land 4 33 739 3.1 32.0France 10 53 663 3.0 32.1Georgia 9 30 171 26.3 140.1Germany 9 45 1341 5.9 103.8Ghana 10 84 302 111.7 1.2Greece 16 45 8115 69.6 145.3Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> IndicatorsCostM<strong>in</strong>. capitalNumber of Time Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come (% of <strong>in</strong>comeCountry procedures (days) (US$) per capita) per capita)Guatemala 13 39 1167 66.7 36.5Gu<strong>in</strong>ea 13 71 941 229.9 396.6Haiti 12 203 875 198.9 209.8Honduras 14 80 670 72.8 165.4Hong Kong, Ch<strong>in</strong>a 5 11 581 2.3 0.0Hungary 5 65 3396 64.3 220.3India 10 88 239 49.8 430.4Indonesia 11 168 103 14.5 302.5Iran, Islamic Rep. of 9 48 113 6.6 7.4Ireland 3 12 2473 10.4 0.0Israel 5 34 784 4.7 0.0Italy 9 23 4565 24.1 49.6Jamaica 7 31 458 16.2 0.0Japan 11 31 3518 10.5 71.3Jordan 14 98 876 49.8 2404.2Kazakhstan 10 25 153 10.1 35.2Kenya 11 61 194 54.0 0.0Korea, Rep. of 12 33 1776 17.9 402.5Kuwait 13 34 329 1.8 910.6Kyrgyz Republic 9 26 39 13.4 74.8Lao PDR 9 198 60 19.5 150.7Latvia 7 11 513 14.7 93.0Lebanon 6 46 5185 129.9 83.1Lesotho 9 92 317 67.4 20.2Lithuania 9 26 231 6.3 74.4Macedonia, FYR 13 48 223 13.1 138.4Madagascar 15 67 151 62.8 30.5Malawi 11 45 201 125.4 0.0Malaysia 8 31 961 27.1 0.0Mali 13 61 557 232.2 597.8Mauritania 11 73 452 110.2 896.7Mexico 7 51 1110 18.8 87.6Moldova 11 42 121 26.2 86.3Mongolia 8 31 53 12.0 2046.9Morocco 11 36 227 19.1 762.5Mozambique 15 153 209 99.6 30.2Namibia 10 85 332 18.7 0.0Nepal 8 25 439 191.0 0.0Netherlands 7 11 3276 13.7 70.7New Zealand 3 3 28 0.2 0.0Nicaragua 12 71 1335 337.8 0.0Niger 11 27 759 446.6 844.0Nigeria 10 44 268 92.3 28.6Norway 4 24 1460 3.9 33.1Oman 9 34 385 5.3 720.9Pakistan 10 22 192 46.8 0.0Panama 7 19 1057 26.3 0.0Papua New Gu<strong>in</strong>ea 7 69 140 26.4 0.0119Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>CostM<strong>in</strong>. capitalNumber of Time Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come (% of <strong>in</strong>comeCountry procedures (days) (US$) per capita) per capita)120Paraguay 18 73 1883 160.9 0.0Peru 9 100 510 24.9 0.0Philipp<strong>in</strong>es 11 59 249 24.4 9.5Poland 12 31 925 20.3 21.4Portugal 11 95 1360 12.5 43.4Puerto Rico 6 6 300 2.8 0.0Romania 6 27 217 11.7 3.3Russian Federation 12 29 200 9.3 29.8Rwanda 9 43 534 232.3 457.3Saudi Arabia 14 95 10814 130.5 1610.5Senegal 9 58 581 123.6 296.1Serbia and Montenegro 10 44 186 13.3 5.5Sierra Leone 9 26 1817 1297.6 0.0S<strong>in</strong>gapore 7 8 249 1.2 0.0Slovak Republic 10 98 401 10.2 111.8Slovenia 10 61 1518 15.5 89.1South Africa 9 38 227 8.7 0.0Spa<strong>in</strong> 11 115 2366 16.4 19.6Sri Lanka 8 58 154 18.3 0.0Sweden 3 16 190 0.8 41.4Switzerland 6 20 3228 8.5 33.8Syrian Arab Republic 10 42 189 16.7 5627.2Taiwan, Ch<strong>in</strong>a 8 48 807 6.1 217.4Tanzania 13 35 557 199.0 0.0Thailand 9 42 144 7.3 0.0Togo 14 63 760 281.4 531.4Tunisia 10 46 327 16.4 351.7Turkey 13 38 927 37.1 13.2Uganda 17 36 338 135.1 0.0Ukra<strong>in</strong>e 14 40 210 27.3 450.8United Arab Emirates 10 29 4944 24.5 404.0United K<strong>in</strong>gdom 6 18 264 1.0 0.0United States 5 4 210 0.6 0.0Uruguay 10 27 2043 46.7 699.0Uzbekistan 9 33 72 16.0 64.3Venezuela, RB 14 119 788 19.3 0.0Vietnam 11 63 129 29.9 0.0Yemen, Rep. of 13 96 1294 264.1 1716.9Zambia 6 40 80 24.1 137.8Zimbabwe 10 122 1322 285.3 0.0Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> IndicatorsHir<strong>in</strong>g-and-Fir<strong>in</strong>g Indicators—measure the degree of rigidity <strong>in</strong> employment lawsFlexibility-of- Conditions-of- Flexibility-of- Employment-Country hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex employment <strong>in</strong>dex fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex laws <strong>in</strong>dexAlbania 33 76 15 41Algeria 58 60 19 46Angola 71 89 74 78Argent<strong>in</strong>a 71 81 46 66Armenia 51 84 37 57Australia 33 61 13 36Austria 33 41 14 30Azerbaijan 71 90 27 63Bangladesh 33 85 32 50Belarus 71 89 71 77Belgium 33 90 22 48Ben<strong>in</strong> 48 86 20 52Bolivia 58 95 45 66Bosnia and Herzegov<strong>in</strong>a 53 63 31 49Botswana 33 55 17 35Brazil 78 89 68 78Bulgaria 43 90 26 53Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso 53 79 27 53Burundi 58 76 51 62Cambodia 33 81 49 54Cameroon 48 43 39 44Canada 33 52 16 34Central African Republic 53 84 50 62Chad 78 93 27 66Chile 56 65 29 50Ch<strong>in</strong>a 17 67 57 47Colombia 33 85 60 59Congo, Dem. Rep. of 73 63 43 60Congo, Rep. of 53 78 49 60Costa Rica 58 83 46 63Côte d’Ivoire 53 61 45 53Croatia 76 89 31 65Czech Republic 17 63 27 36Denmark 33 25 17 25Dom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic 33 79 35 49Ecuador 37 63 65 55Egypt, Arab Rep. of 33 83 61 59El Salvador 81 75 52 69Ethiopia 58 67 29 51F<strong>in</strong>land 71 43 52 55France 63 61 26 50Georgia 51 66 49 55Germany 63 46 45 51Ghana 33 56 17 35Greece 78 81 43 67Guatemala 58 85 51 65Gu<strong>in</strong>ea 78 44 57 60121


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>Flexibility-of- Conditions-of- Flexibility-of- Employment-Country hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex employment <strong>in</strong>dex fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex laws <strong>in</strong>dex122Haiti 58 85 35 60Honduras 33 87 47 56Hong Kong, Ch<strong>in</strong>a 58 22 1 27Hungary 46 92 23 54India 33 75 45 51Indonesia 76 53 43 57Iran, Islamic Rep. of 33 77 47 52Ireland 48 68 30 49Israel 33 64 16 38Italy 76 62 40 59Jamaica 33 52 18 34Japan 39 64 9 37Jordan 33 82 64 60Kazakhstan 33 89 42 55Kenya 33 53 16 34Korea, Rep. of 33 88 32 51Kuwait 33 40 50 41Kyrgyz Republic 71 90 33 64Lao PDR 33 87 44 54Latvia 58 87 42 62Lebanon 53 50 35 46Lesotho 58 51 25 45Lithuania 71 90 31 64Macedonia, FYR 65 53 32 50Madagascar 48 86 49 61Malawi 33 68 54 52Malaysia 33 26 15 25Mali 53 86 23 54Mauritania 62 47 66 59Mexico 81 81 70 77Moldova 71 75 54 67Mongolia 33 90 25 50Morocco 56 63 33 51Mozambique 73 85 64 74Namibia 17 57 54 43Nepal 33 54 47 45Netherlands 51 79 33 54New Zealand 33 43 20 32Nicaragua 33 90 58 61Niger 53 89 34 59Nigeria 17 76 36 43Norway 58 39 25 41Oman 58 78 25 54Pakistan 65 75 33 58Panama 81 87 68 79Papua New Gu<strong>in</strong>ea 17 57 4 26Paraguay 58 90 71 73Peru 71 81 69 73Philipp<strong>in</strong>es 58 73 50 60


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> IndicatorsFlexibility-of- Conditions-of- Flexibility-of- Employment-Country hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex employment <strong>in</strong>dex fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex laws <strong>in</strong>dexPoland 33 92 39 55Portugal 76 88 73 79Puerto Rico 33 67 24 41Romania 48 85 29 54Russian Federation 33 77 71 61Rwanda 53 94 32 60Saudi Arabia 33 58 16 36Senegal 48 83 30 54Serbia and Montenegro 51 88 29 56Sierra Leone 56 84 62 67S<strong>in</strong>gapore 33 26 1 20Slovak Republic 34 89 60 61Slovenia 53 84 41 59South Africa 42 36 30 36Spa<strong>in</strong> 76 88 45 70Sri Lanka 33 52 40 42Sweden 56 39 31 42Switzerland 33 53 23 36Syrian Arab Republic 33 79 22 45Taiwan, Ch<strong>in</strong>a 81 59 32 57Tanzania 57 77 49 61Thailand 78 73 30 61Togo 53 80 36 57Tunisia 73 53 44 57Turkey 58 91 17 55Uganda 33 44 50 42Ukra<strong>in</strong>e 58 93 69 73United Arab Emirates 33 66 37 45United K<strong>in</strong>gdom 33 42 9 28United States 33 29 5 22Uruguay 58 56 3 39Uzbekistan 46 69 50 55Venezuela, RB 78 88 60 75Vietnam 43 77 48 56Yemen, Rep. of 33 66 28 43Zambia 33 64 40 46Zimbabwe 33 22 26 27123


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>Enforc<strong>in</strong>g-a-Contract Indicators—cover the procedures, time, cost, and degree of complexity <strong>in</strong> the proceduresto resolve a payment disputeNumber of Time Cost Cost Procedural-Country procedures (days) (US$) (% <strong>in</strong>come per capita) complexity <strong>in</strong>dex124Albania 37 220 794 72.6 76Algeria 20 387 .. .. 72Angola 46 865 83 15.7 65Argent<strong>in</strong>a 32 300 621 8.5 80Armenia 22 65 80 15.3 46Australia 11 320 1623 8.0 29Austria 20 434 240 1.0 54Azerbaijan 25 115 20 3.3 53Bangladesh 15 270 1019 48.2 51Belarus 19 135 564 43.6 56Belgium 22 365 2205 9.1 53Ben<strong>in</strong> 44 248 114 31.0 53Bolivia 44 464 52 5.3 78Bosnia and Herzegov<strong>in</strong>a 31 630 260 21.3 63Botswana 22 56 .. .. 52Brazil 16 380 83 2.4 48Bulgaria 26 410 95 6.4 69Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso 24 376 375 172.8 71Burundi 62 367 29 27.6 58Cambodia 20 210 752 268.5 78Cameroon 46 548 367 62.9 63Canada 17 425 6065 28.0 29Central African Republic .. .. .. .. ..Chad 50 604 121 58.4 72Chile 21 200 663 14.7 73Ch<strong>in</strong>a 20 180 268 32.0 52Colombia 37 527 119 5.9 56Congo, Dem. Rep. of 55 414 800 92.3 54Congo, Rep. of 44 500 330 51.0 67Costa Rica 21 370 857 22.6 86Côte d’Ivoire 18 150 572 83.3 57Croatia 20 330 305 6.6 50Czech Republic 16 270 967 18.5 65Denmark 14 83 1210 3.8 40Dom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic 19 495 9250 440.5 69Ecuador 33 333 132 10.5 72Egypt, Arab Rep. of 19 202 450 30.7 50El Salvador 42 240 149 7.3 81Ethiopia 24 895 35 34.6 52F<strong>in</strong>land 19 240 3886 15.8 48France 21 210 896 3.8 79Georgia 17 180 408 63.1 48Germany 22 154 1483 6.0 61Ghana 21 90 80 23.8 33Greece 15 315 980 8.2 64Guatemala 19 1460 338 20.0 90Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> IndicatorsNumber of Time Cost Cost Procedural-Country procedures (days) (US$) (% <strong>in</strong>come per capita) complexity <strong>in</strong>dexGu<strong>in</strong>ea 41 150 171 40.0 77Haiti 41 76 87 18.4 69Honduras 32 225 57 6.7 72Hong Kong, Ch<strong>in</strong>a 17 180 1737 6.9 50Hungary 17 365 256 5.4 57India 22 365 444 95.0 50Indonesia 29 225 1754 269.0 67Iran, Islamic Rep. of 23 150 96 5.8 67Ireland 16 183 1604 7.2 42Israel 19 315 5635 34.1 51Italy 16 645 780 3.9 64Jamaica 14 202 1138 42.1 38Japan 16 60 2223 6.4 39Jordan 32 147 5 0.3 49Kazakhstan 41 120 103 7.9 65Kenya 25 255 173 49.5 44Korea, Rep. of 23 75 402 4.5 50Kuwait 17 195 788 4.4 76Kyrgyz Republic 44 365 730 254.7 48Lao PDR .. .. .. .. ..Latvia 19 189 218 7.5 56Lebanon 27 721 2160 54.3 67Lesotho .. .. .. .. ..Lithuania 17 74 580 13.0 58Macedonia, FYR 27 509 750 43.0 67Madagascar 29 166 304 120.2 63Malawi 16 108 920 520.6 48Malaysia 22 270 671 19.4 41Mali 27 150 16 7.0 71Mauritania .. .. .. .. ..Mexico 47 325 504 10.0 62Moldova 36 210 56 14.2 48Mongolia 26 224 7 1.8 71Morocco 17 192 108 9.1 69Mozambique 18 540 20 9.1 71Namibia .. .. .. .. ..Nepal 24 350 106 44.2 63Netherlands 21 39 120 0.5 46New Zealand 19 50 1526 11.6 31Nicaragua 17 125 70 17.7 79Niger 29 365 103 57.1 63Nigeria 23 730 18 6.6 52Norway 12 87 3606 10.4 48Oman 54 250 346 4.8 51Pakistan 30 365 200 45.8 53Panama 44 197 642 20.0 82Papua New Gu<strong>in</strong>ea 22 270 244 41.1 45Paraguay 46 188 461 34.0 67125Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>Number of Time Cost Cost Procedural-Country procedures (days) (US$) (% <strong>in</strong>come per capita) complexity <strong>in</strong>dex126Peru 35 441 613 29.7 82Philipp<strong>in</strong>es 28 164 1086 103.7 75Poland 18 1000 466 11.2 65Portugal 22 420 534 4.9 54Puerto Rico 55 365 2250 20.9 52Romania 28 225 217 13.1 60Russian Federation 16 160 350 20.2 48Rwanda .. .. .. .. ..Saudi Arabia 19 195 .. .. 50Senegal 30 335 238 48.6 75Serbia and Montenegro 40 1028 200 20.0 61Sierra Leone 48 114 11 8.3 29S<strong>in</strong>gapore 23 50 3521 14.4 49Slovak Republic 26 420 494 13.3 40Slovenia 22 1003 360 3.6 65South Africa 26 207 510 16.7 56Spa<strong>in</strong> 20 147 1600 10.7 83Sri Lanka 17 440 64 7.6 59Sweden 21 190 4590 7.6 44Switzerland 14 224 1490 3.9 44Syrian Arab Republic 36 596 300 31.3 69Taiwan, Ch<strong>in</strong>a 15 210 68 0.5 37Tanzania 14 127 10 3.8 62Thailand 19 210 589 29.6 53Togo 43 503 59 21.4 63Tunisia 14 7 86 4.1 60Turkey 18 105 154 5.4 38Uganda 16 99 30 10.0 40Ukra<strong>in</strong>e 20 224 80 11.0 51United Arab Emirates 27 559 2148 10.6 56United K<strong>in</strong>gdom 12 101 120 0.5 36United States 17 365 120 0.4 46Uruguay 38 360 822 13.7 55Uzbekistan 34 258 13 2.1 57Venezuela, RB 41 360 2000 46.9 81Vietnam 28 120 33 8.5 46Yemen, Rep. of 27 240 2 0.5 60Zambia 16 188 50 15.8 32Zimbabwe 13 197 183 39.5 50Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> IndicatorsGett<strong>in</strong>g-Credit Indicators—measure <strong>in</strong>stitutions for credit <strong>in</strong>formation and legal protection of creditorsExtensiveness-ofPublic registry coverage public-credit- Private bureau coverage Creditor-Country (borrowers/1,000 cap.) registries <strong>in</strong>dex (borrowers/1,000 cap.) rights <strong>in</strong>dexAlbania 0 0 0 3Algeria 0 0 0 1Angola 10 60 0 3Argent<strong>in</strong>a 149 61 475 1Armenia 0 0 0 2Australia 0 0 722 3Austria 9 66 308 3Azerbaijan 0 0 0 3Bangladesh 1 51 0 2Belarus .. 42 0 2Belgium 68 63 42 2Ben<strong>in</strong> 1 22 0 1Bolivia 55 58 134 2Bosnia and Herzegov<strong>in</strong>a 0 0 67 3Botswana 0 0 382 3Brazil 44 50 439 1Bulgaria 5 47 0 3Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso 1 22 0 1Burundi 1 49 0 1Cambodia 0 0 0 2Cameroon


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>Extensiveness-ofPublic registry coverage public-credit- Private bureau coverage Creditor-Country (borrowers/1,000 cap.) registries <strong>in</strong>dex (borrowers/1,000 cap.) rights <strong>in</strong>dex128Guatemala 0 0 35 1Gu<strong>in</strong>ea .. .. 0 1Haiti 1 59 0 2Honduras 45 42 0 2Hong Kong, Ch<strong>in</strong>a 0 0 200 4Hungary 0 0 15 2India 0 0 0 3Indonesia 3 61 0 2Iran, Islamic Rep. of .. 45 0 2Ireland 0 0 730 1Israel 0 0 47 3Italy 55 61 416 1Jamaica 0 0 0 2Japan 0 0 777 2Jordan 19 47 0 1Kazakhstan 0 0 0 2Kenya 0 0 309 4Korea, Rep. of 0 0 530 3Kuwait 0 0 147 2Kyrgyz Republic 0 0 0 3Lao PDR .. .. 0 0Latvia 0 0 0 3Lebanon 0 0 0 4Lesotho 0 0 0 2Lithuania 7 63 0 2Macedonia, FYR 2 42 0 3Madagascar 2 46 0 2Malawi 0 0 0 2Malaysia 105 59 461 2Mali 1 22 0 1Mauritania .. .. 0 3Mexico 0 0 382 0Moldova 0 0 0 2Mongolia 15 68 0 1Morocco .. 33 0 1Mozambique 1 52 0 2Namibia 0 0 .. ..Nepal 0 0 0 2Netherlands 0 0 530 3New Zealand 0 0 818 4Nicaragua 50 45 0 4Niger 1 22 0 1Nigeria


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> IndicatorsExtensiveness-ofPublic registry coverage public-credit- Private bureau coverage Creditor-Country (borrowers/1,000 cap.) registries <strong>in</strong>dex (borrowers/1,000 cap.) rights <strong>in</strong>dexPapua New Gu<strong>in</strong>ea 0 0 0 2Paraguay .. .. .. 2Peru 92 54 185 0Philipp<strong>in</strong>es 0 0 22 1Poland 0 0 543 2Portugal 496 61 24 1Puerto Rico 0 0 .. 1Romania 1 59 0 0Russian Federation 0 0 0 2Rwanda


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>Clos<strong>in</strong>g-a-<strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Indicators—measure the procedures, time, and cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency proceed<strong>in</strong>gsas well as court powers <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>solvency proceed<strong>in</strong>gsAbsolute Efficient Goals-of- Court-Time Cost priority outcome <strong>in</strong>solvency powersCountry (years) (% of estate) preserved achieved <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>in</strong>dex130Albania no practice no practice 67 1 42 67Algeria 3.5 4 33 0 45 33Angola no practice no practice 33 0 8 67Argent<strong>in</strong>a 2.8 18 67 0 43 67Armenia 1.9 4 100 0 65 33Australia 1.0 18 100 1 80 0Austria 1.3 18 67 1 71 33Azerbaijan 2.7 8 67 0 49 100Bangladesh no practice no practice 100 0 25 67Belarus 2.2 4 0 0 40 67Belgium 0.9 4 100 1 93 67Ben<strong>in</strong> 3.2 18 33 0 33 100Bolivia 2.0 18 100 0 53 100Bosnia and Herzegov<strong>in</strong>a 1.9 8 67 0 51 67Botswana 2.2 18 100 1 77 33Brazil 10.0 8 33 0 24 67Bulgaria 3.8 18 100 0 48 67Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso 4.0 8 0 0 29 100Burundi no practice no practice 33 0 8 67Cambodia no practice no practice 100 0 25 67Cameroon 2.0 18 67 0 44 100Canada 0.8 4 100 1 93 33Central African Republic .. .. .. .. .. ..Chad 10.0 38 33 0 11 100Chile 5.8 18 0 0 19 67Ch<strong>in</strong>a 2.6 18 100 0 51 67Colombia 3.0 1 33 1 77 33Congo, Dem. Rep. of no practice no practice 33 0 8 33Congo, Rep. of 3.0 18 67 0 42 100Costa Rica 2.5 18 67 0 43 100Côte d’Ivoire 2.2 18 67 0 44 100Croatia 3.1 18 100 0 50 67Czech Republic 9.2 38 67 0 22 0Denmark 4.2 8 100 1 79 33Dom<strong>in</strong>ican Republic 3.5 4 0 0 37 67Ecuador 3.5 18 0 0 24 67Egypt, Arab Rep. of 4.3 18 67 0 39 67El Salvador no practice no practice 67 1 42 67Ethiopia 2.2 8 67 1 75 33F<strong>in</strong>land 0.9 1 100 1 99 0France 2.4 18 67 0 43 100Georgia 3.2 1 100 0 69 33Germany 1.2 8 100 0 61 33Ghana no practice no practice 67 0 17 33Greece 2.2 8 33 0 42 33Notes: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> IndicatorsAbsolute Efficient Goals-of- Court-Time Cost priority outcome <strong>in</strong>solvency powersCountry (years) (% of estate) preserved achieved <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>in</strong>dexGuatemala 4.0 18 67 0 40 67Gu<strong>in</strong>ea no practice no practice 33 0 8 100Haiti no practice no practice 67 1 42 67Honduras no practice no practice 67 0 17 67Hong Kong, Ch<strong>in</strong>a 1.0 18 33 1 63 67Hungary 2.0 38 67 0 38 33India 11.3 8 33 0 21 33Indonesia 6.0 18 67 0 35 100Iran, Islamic Rep. of 1.8 8 100 1 84 67Ireland 0.4 8 100 1 88 33Israel 4.0 38 100 1 67 67Italy 1.3 18 67 0 46 33Jamaica 1.1 18 33 1 63 67Japan 0.6 4 100 1 93 33Jordan 4.3 8 33 0 37 33Kazakhstan 3.3 18 67 1 66 67Kenya 4.6 18 100 0 47 33Korea, Rep. of 1.5 4 100 1 91 67Kuwait 4.2 1 67 1 83 67Kyrgyz Republic 4.0 4 100 0 61 33Lao PDR no practice no practice 0 0 14 67Latvia 1.2 4 100 1 92 67Lebanon 4.0 18 33 0 31 67Lesotho .. .. .. .. .. ..Lithuania 1.2 18 100 0 54 67Macedonia, FYR 3.6 38 67 0 34 67Madagascar no practice no practice 100 0 25 67Malawi 2.8 8 33 0 40 67Malaysia 2.2 18 100 0 52 33Mali 3.5 18 33 0 32 100Mauritania 8.0 8 33 0 28 67Mexico 2.0 18 33 1 61 67Moldova 2.8 8 67 0 49 67Mongolia 4.0 8 100 0 54 67Morocco 1.9 18 33 0 36 100Mozambique no practice no practice 100 0 25 67Namibia .. .. .. .. .. ..Nepal 5.0 8 33 0 35 33Netherlands 2.6 1 100 1 95 33New Zealand 2.0 4 100 1 90 0Nicaragua 2.3 8 100 0 58 67Niger 5.0 18 67 0 37 100Nigeria 1.6 18 67 0 45 67Norway 0.9 1 100 1 99 67Oman 7.0 4 0 0 29 67Pakistan 2.8 4 100 0 63 33Panama 6.5 38 100 0 36 33131Notes: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>Absolute Efficient Goals-of- Court-Time Cost priority outcome <strong>in</strong>solvency powersCountry (years) (% of estate) preserved achieved <strong>in</strong>dex <strong>in</strong>dex132Papua New Gu<strong>in</strong>ea .. .. .. .. .. ..Paraguay 3.9 8 67 0 46 67Peru 2.1 8 33 1 67 33Philipp<strong>in</strong>es 5.7 38 100 0 38 100Poland 1.5 18 67 1 70 67Portugal 2.6 8 33 1 66 33Puerto Rico 3.8 8 67 1 71 33Romania 3.2 8 33 0 39 33Russian Federation 1.5 4 67 0 58 67Rwanda no practice no practice 33 0 8 33Saudi Arabia 3.0 18 100 0 50 33Senegal 3.0 8 67 1 73 100Serbia and Montenegro 7.3 38 33 1 42 67Sierra Leone 2.5 38 0 0 20 33S<strong>in</strong>gapore 0.7 1 100 1 99 33Slovak Republic 4.8 18 100 1 71 67Slovenia 3.7 18 67 0 41 67South Africa 2.0 18 100 0 53 67Spa<strong>in</strong> 1.5 8 33 1 68 33Sri Lanka 2.3 18 33 0 35 67Sweden 2.0 8 100 1 84 33Switzerland 4.6 4 100 0 59 67Syrian Arab Republic 4.1 8 33 0 37 67Taiwan, Ch<strong>in</strong>a 0.8 4 0 1 68 100Tanzania 3.0 8 33 1 65 67Thailand 2.6 38 67 1 62 33Togo no practice no practice 33 0 8 100Tunisia 2.5 8 67 0 50 67Turkey 1.8 8 67 0 51 67Uganda 2.0 38 33 1 55 67Ukra<strong>in</strong>e 3.0 18 67 0 42 33United Arab Emirates 5.0 38 33 0 23 33United K<strong>in</strong>gdom 1.0 8 100 1 86 0United States 3.0 4 100 1 88 33Uruguay 4.0 8 100 0 54 67Uzbekistan 3.3 4 33 0 46 67Venezuela, RB 4.0 38 100 1 67 67Vietnam no practice no practice 33 1 33 67Yemen, Rep. of 2.4 4 33 0 47 33Zambia 3.7 8 100 0 55 33Zimbabwe 2.3 18 100 0 52 67Notes: .. means no data available.


Country TablesALBANIAEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,380 Number of procedures 11Population 3,164,400 Time (days) 47Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 33.40 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 65.0Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 51.7Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 37Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 76 Time (days) 220Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 15 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 72.6Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 41 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 76Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) No practicePublic registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) No practicePublic-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 42Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67ALGERIAMiddle East and North Africa133Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,720 Number of procedures 18Population 30,835,000 Time (days) 29Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 34.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 31.9Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 73.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Number of procedures 20Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 60 Time (days) 387Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 19 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) ..Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 46 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 72Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.5Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 45Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>ANGOLASub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 660 Number of procedures 14Population 13,512,450 Time (days) 146Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 838.0Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 174.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 71 Number of procedures 46Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 89 Time (days) 865Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 74 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 15.7Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 78 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 65Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) No practicePublic registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 10 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) No practicePublic-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 60 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 8Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67ARGENTINALat<strong>in</strong> America and Caribbean134Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 4,060 Number of procedures 15Population 37,488,000 Time (days) 68Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 25.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 8.0Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 71 Number of procedures 32Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 81 Time (days) 300Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 46 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 8.5Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 66 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 80Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.8Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 149 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 61 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 475 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 43Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67ARMENIAEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 790 Number of procedures 10Population 3,088,000 Time (days) 25Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 46.3 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 8.7Legal orig<strong>in</strong> Socialist M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 11.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 51 Number of procedures 22Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 84 Time (days) 65Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 37 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 15.3Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 57 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 46Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.9Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 65Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesAUSTRALIAOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 19,740 Number of procedures 2Population 19,386,820 Time (days) 2Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 15.3 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 2.0Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 11Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 61 Time (days) 320Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 13 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 8.0Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 36 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 29Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 722 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 80Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 0AUSTRIAOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 23,390 Number of procedures 9Population 8,132,000 Time (days) 29Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 10.2 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 6.6Legal orig<strong>in</strong> German M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 140.8Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 20Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 41 Time (days) 434Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 14 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 1.0Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 30 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 54Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.3Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 9 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 66 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 308 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 71Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33135AZERBAIJANEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 710 Number of procedures 14Population 8,116,110 Time (days) 106Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 60.6 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 16.8Legal orig<strong>in</strong> Socialist M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 71 Number of procedures 25Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 90 Time (days) 115Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 27 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 3.3Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 63 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 53Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.6Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 49Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 100Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>BANGLADESHSouth AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 360 Number of procedures 7Population 133,345,160 Time (days) 30Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 35.6 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 75.5Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 15Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 85 Time (days) 270Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 32 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 48.2Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 51Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) No practicePublic registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 1 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) No practicePublic-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 51 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 25Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67BELARUSEurope and Central Asia136Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,360 Number of procedures 19Population 9,970,260 Time (days) 118Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 48.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 27.1Legal orig<strong>in</strong> Socialist M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 110.7Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 71 Number of procedures 19Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 89 Time (days) 135Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 71 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 43.6Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 77 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 56Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.1Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) .. Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 42 Absolute priority preserved 0Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 40Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67BELGIUMOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 23,250 Number of procedures 7Population 10,286,000 Time (days) 56Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 23.2 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 11.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 75.1Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 22Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 90 Time (days) 365Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 22 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 9.1Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 48 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 53Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 0.8Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 68 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 63 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 42 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 93Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesBENINSub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 380 Number of procedures 9Population 6,436,660 Time (days) 63Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 45.2 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 189.2Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 377.6Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 48 Number of procedures 44Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 86 Time (days) 248Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 20 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 31.0Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 52 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 53Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.2Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 1 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 22 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 33Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 100BOLIVIALat<strong>in</strong> America and CaribbeanEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 900 Number of procedures 18Population 8,515,220 Time (days) 67Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 67.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 166.6Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Number of procedures 44Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 95 Time (days) 464Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 45 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 5.3Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 66 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 78137Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 55 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 134 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 53Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 100BOSNIA AND HERZEGOVINAEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,270 Number of procedures 12Population 4,060,000 Time (days) 59Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 34.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 51.8Legal orig<strong>in</strong> German M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 379.1Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Number of procedures 31Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 63 Time (days) 630Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 31 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 21.3Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 49 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 63Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.86Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 67 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 51Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>BOTSWANASub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 2,980 Number of procedures 10Population 1,695,000 Time (days) 97Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 33.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 36.1Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 22Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 55 Time (days) 56Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 17 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) ..Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 35 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 52Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.2Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 382 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 77Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33BRAZILLat<strong>in</strong> America and Caribbean138Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 2,850 Number of procedures 15Population 172,386,000 Time (days) 152Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 39.8 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 11.6Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 78 Number of procedures 16Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 89 Time (days) 380Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 68 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 2.4Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 78 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 48Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 10.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 44 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 50 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 439 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 24Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67BULGARIAEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,790 Number of procedures 10Population 7,913,000 Time (days) 30Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 36.9 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 8.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> German M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 134.4Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 43 Number of procedures 26Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 90 Time (days) 410Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 26 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 6.4Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 69Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.8Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 5 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 47 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 48Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesBURKINA FASOSub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 220 Number of procedures 15Population 11,552,570 Time (days) 136Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 38.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 325.2Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 652.2Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Number of procedures 24Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 79 Time (days) 376Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 27 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 172.8Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 71Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 4.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 1 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 22 Absolute priority preserved 0Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 29Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 100BURUNDISub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 100 Number of procedures ..Population 6,938,010 Time (days) ..Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) ..Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) ..Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Number of procedures 62Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 76 Time (days) 367Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 51 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 27.6Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 62 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 58139Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) No practicePublic registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 1 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) No practicePublic-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 49 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 8Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67CAMBODIAEast Asia and PacificEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 280 Number of procedures 11Population 12,265,220 Time (days) 94Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 553.8Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 1825.8Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 20Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 81 Time (days) 210Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 49 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 268.5Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 54 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 78Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) No practicePublic registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) No practicePublic-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 25Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>CAMEROONSub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 560 Number of procedures 12Population 15,197,470 Time (days) 37Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 32.8 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 190.7Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 243.6Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 48 Number of procedures 46Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 43 Time (days) 548Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 39 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 62.9Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 44 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 63Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita)


Country TablesCHADSub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 220 Number of procedures 19Population 7,916,010 Time (days) 73Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 395.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 652.2Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 78 Number of procedures 50Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 93 Time (days) 604Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 27 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 58.4Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 66 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 72Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 10.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita)


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>COLOMBIALat<strong>in</strong> America and CaribbeanEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,830 Number of procedures 19Population 43,035,168 Time (days) 60Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 39.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 27.2Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 37Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 85 Time (days) 527Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 60 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 5.9Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 59 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 56Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 1Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 187 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 77Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33CONGO, DEM. REP. ofSub-Saharan Africa142Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 90 Number of procedures 13Population 52,354,100 Time (days) 215Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 871.9Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 320.7Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 73 Number of procedures 55Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 63 Time (days) 414Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 43 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 92.3Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 60 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 54Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) No practicePublic registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) No practicePublic-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 8Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33CONGO, REP. ofSub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 700 Number of procedures 8Population 3,103,350 Time (days) 67Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 271.0Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 205.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Number of procedures 44Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 78 Time (days) 500Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 49 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 51.0Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 60 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 67Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita)


Country TablesCOSTA RICALat<strong>in</strong> America and CaribbeanEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 4,100 Number of procedures 11Population 3,873,000 Time (days) 80Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 26.2 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 21.4Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Number of procedures 21Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 83 Time (days) 370Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 46 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 22.6Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 63 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 86Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.5Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 7 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 44 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 55 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 43Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 100CÔTE D’IVOIRESub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 610 Number of procedures 10Population 16,410,080 Time (days) 77Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 39.9 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 143.1Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 235.2Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Number of procedures 18Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 61 Time (days) 150Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 45 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 83.3Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 57143Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.2Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 1 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 22 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 44Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 100CROATIAEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 4,640 Number of procedures 13Population 4,380,780 Time (days) 50Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 33.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 18.2Legal orig<strong>in</strong> German M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 50.7Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 76 Number of procedures 20Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 89 Time (days) 330Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 31 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 6.6Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 65 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 50Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.1Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 50Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>CZECH REPUBLICEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 5,560 Number of procedures 10Population 10,224,000 Time (days) 88Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 19.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 11.7Legal orig<strong>in</strong> German M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 110.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 17 Number of procedures 16Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 63 Time (days) 270Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 27 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 18.5Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 36 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 65Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 9.2Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 10 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 38Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 60 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 136 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 22Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 0DENMARKOECD: High Income144Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 30,290 Number of procedures 4Population 5,359,000 Time (days) 4Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 18.2 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Legal orig<strong>in</strong> Nordic M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 52.3Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 14Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 25 Time (days) 83Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 17 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 3.8Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 25 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 40Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 4.2Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 58 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 79Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33DOMINICAN REPUBLICLat<strong>in</strong> America and CaribbeanEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 2,320 Number of procedures 12Population 8,505,200 Time (days) 78Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 32.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 48.1Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 23.2Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 19Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 79 Time (days) 495Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 35 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 440.5Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 49 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 69Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.5Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) .. Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 42 Absolute priority preserved 0Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 423 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 37Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesECUADORLat<strong>in</strong> America and CaribbeanEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,450 Number of procedures 14Population 12,879,000 Time (days) 90Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 34.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 63.0Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 27.6Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 37 Number of procedures 33Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 63 Time (days) 333Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 65 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 10.5Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 55 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 72Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.5Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 82 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 55 Absolute priority preserved 0Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 24Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67EGYPT, ARAB REP. ofMiddle East and North AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,470 Number of procedures 13Population 65,176,940 Time (days) 43Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 35.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 61.2Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 788.6Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 19Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 83 Time (days) 202Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 61 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 30.7Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 59 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 50Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 4.3Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) .. Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 48 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 39Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67145EL SALVADORLat<strong>in</strong> America and CaribbeanEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 2,080 Number of procedures 12Population 6,400,000 Time (days) 115Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 129.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 549.5Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 81 Number of procedures 42Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 75 Time (days) 240Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 52 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 7.3Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 69 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 81Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) No practicePublic registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 130 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) No practicePublic-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 50 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 128 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 42Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>ETHIOPIASub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 100 Number of procedures 8Population 65,816,048 Time (days) 44Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 40.3 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 421.6Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 1756.1Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Number of procedures 24Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 67 Time (days) 895Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 29 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 34.6Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 51 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 52Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.2Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 75Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33FINLANDOECD: High Income146Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 23,510 Number of procedures 4Population 5,188,000 Time (days) 33Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 18.3 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 3.1Legal orig<strong>in</strong> Nordic M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 32.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 71 Number of procedures 19Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 43 Time (days) 240Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 52 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 15.8Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 55 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 48Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 0.9Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 1Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 96 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 99Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 0FRANCEOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 22,010 Number of procedures 10Population 59,190,600 Time (days) 53Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 15.3 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 3.0Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 32.1Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 63 Number of procedures 21Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 61 Time (days) 210Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 26 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 3.8Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 50 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 79Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.4Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 12 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 43Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 100Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesGEORGIAEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 650 Number of procedures 9Population 5,224,000 Time (days) 30Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 67.3 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 26.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> Socialist M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 140.1Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 51 Number of procedures 17Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 66 Time (days) 180Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 49 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 63.1Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 55 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 48Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.2Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 1Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 69Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33GERMANYOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 22,670 Number of procedures 9Population 82,333,000 Time (days) 45Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 16.3 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 5.9Legal orig<strong>in</strong> German M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 103.8Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 63 Number of procedures 22Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 46 Time (days) 154Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 45 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 6.0Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 51 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 61Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.2Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 5 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 44 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 693 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 61Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33147GHANASub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 270 Number of procedures 10Population 19,707,740 Time (days) 84Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 38.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 111.7Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 1.2Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 21Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 56 Time (days) 90Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 17 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 23.8Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 35 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 33Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) No practicePublic registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) No practicePublic-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita)


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>GREECEOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 11,660 Number of procedures 16Population 10,590,870 Time (days) 45Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 28.6 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 69.6Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 145.3Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 78 Number of procedures 15Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 81 Time (days) 315Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 43 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 8.2Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 67 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 64Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.2Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 86 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 42Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33GUATEMALALat<strong>in</strong> America and Carribean148Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,750 Number of procedures 13Population 11,683,000 Time (days) 39Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 51.5 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 66.7Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 36.5Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Number of procedures 19Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 85 Time (days) 1460Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 51 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 20.0Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 65 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 90Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 4.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 35 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 40Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67GUINEASub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 150 Number of procedures 13Population 1,225,620 Time (days) 71Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 229.4Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 396.6Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 78 Number of procedures 41Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 44 Time (days) 150Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 57 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 40.0Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 60 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 77Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) No practicePublic registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) .. Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) No practicePublic-registry <strong>in</strong>dex .. Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 8Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 100Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesHAITILat<strong>in</strong> America and CaribbeanEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 440 Number of procedures 12Population 8,132,000 Time (days) 203Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 198.9Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 209.8Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Number of procedures 41Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 85 Time (days) 76Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 35 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 18.4Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 60 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 69Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) No practicePublic registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 1 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) No practicePublic-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 59 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 42Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67HONDURASLat<strong>in</strong> America and CaribbeanEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 920 Number of procedures 14Population 6,584,730 Time (days) 80Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 49.6 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 72.8Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 165.4Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 32Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 87 Time (days) 225Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 47 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 6.7Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 56 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 72Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) No practicePublic registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 45 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) No practicePublic-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 42 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 17Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67149HONG KONG, CHINAEast Asia and PacificEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 24,750 Number of procedures 5Population 6,725,000 Time (days) 11Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 16.6 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 2.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Number of procedures 17Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 22 Time (days) 180Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 6.9Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 27 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 50Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 200 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 63Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 4 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>HUNGARYEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 5,280 Number of procedures 5Population 10,187,000 Time (days) 65Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 25.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 64.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> German M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 220.3Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 46 Number of procedures 17Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 92 Time (days) 365Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 23 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 5.4Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 54 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 57Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 38Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 15 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 38Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33INDIASouth Asia150Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 480 Number of procedures 10Population 1,032,354,600 Time (days) 88Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 23.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 49.8Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 430.4Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 22Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 75 Time (days) 365Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 45 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 95.0Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 51 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 50Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 11.3Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Develop<strong>in</strong>g Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 21Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33INDONESIAEast Asia and PacificEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 710 Number of procedures 11Population 208,981,000 Time (days) 168Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 19.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 14.5Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 302.5Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 76 Number of procedures 29Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Time (days) 225Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 43 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 269.0Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 57 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 67Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 6.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 3 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 61 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 35Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 100Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesIRAN, ISLAMIC REP. ofMiddle East and North AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,710 Number of procedures 9Population 64,528,160 Time (days) 48Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 18.9 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 6.6Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 7.4Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 23Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 77 Time (days) 150Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 47 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 5.8Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 52 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 67Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.8Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) .. Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 45 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 84Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67IRELANDOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 23,870 Number of procedures 3Population 3,839,000 Time (days) 12Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 15.8 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 10.4Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 48 Number of procedures 16Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 68 Time (days) 183Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 30 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 7.2Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 49 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 42Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 0.4Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 730 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 88Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33151ISRAELMiddle East and North AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 16,710 Number of procedures 5Population 6,362,950 Time (days) 34Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 21.9 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 4.7Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 19Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 64 Time (days) 315Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 16 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 34.1Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 38 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 51Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 4.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 38Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 47 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 67Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>ITALYOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 18,960 Number of procedures 9Population 57,948,000 Time (days) 23Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 27 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 24.1Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 49.6Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 76 Number of procedures 16Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 62 Time (days) 645Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 40 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 3.9Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 59 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 64Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.3Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 55 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 61 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 416 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 46Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33JAMAICALat<strong>in</strong> America and Caribbean152Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 2,820 Number of procedures 7Population 2,590,000 Time (days) 31Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 36.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 16.2Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 14Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 52 Time (days) 202Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 18 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 42.1Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 34 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 38Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.1Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 63Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67JAPANOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 33,550 Number of procedures 11Population 127,034,880 Time (days) 31Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 11.3 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 10.5Legal orig<strong>in</strong> German M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 71.3Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 39 Number of procedures 16Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 64 Time (days) 60Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 9 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 6.4Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 37 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 39Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 0.6Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 777 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 93Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesJORDANMiddle East and North AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,760 Number of procedures 14Population 5,030,800 Time (days) 98Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 19.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 49.8Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 2404.2Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 32Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 82 Time (days) 147Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 64 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.3Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 60 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 49Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 4.3Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 19 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 47 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 37Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33KAZAKHSTANEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,510 Number of procedures 10Population 14,895,310 Time (days) 25Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 43.2 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 10.1Legal orig<strong>in</strong> Socialist M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 35.2Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 41Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 89 Time (days) 120Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 42 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 7.9Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 55 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 65Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.3Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 66Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67153KENYASub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 360 Number of procedures 11Population 30,735,760 Time (days) 61Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 34.3 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 54.0Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 25Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Time (days) 255Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 16 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 49.5Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 34 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 44Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 4.6Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 309 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 47Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 4 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>KOREA, REP. ofOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 9,930 Number of procedures 12Population 47,343,000 Time (days) 33Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 27.5 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 17.9Legal orig<strong>in</strong> German M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 402.5Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 23Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 88 Time (days) 75Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 32 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 4.5Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 51 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 50Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.47Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 530 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 91Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67KUWAITMiddle East and North Africa154Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) .. Number of procedures 13Population 2,044,270 Time (days) 34Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 1.8Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 910.6Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 17Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 40 Time (days) 195Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 50 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 4.4Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 41 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 76Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 4.2Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 1Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 147 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 83Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67KYRGYZ REPUBLICEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 290 Number of procedures 9Population 4,955,000 Time (days) 26Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 39.8 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 13.4Legal orig<strong>in</strong> Socialist M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 74.8Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 71 Number of procedures 44Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 90 Time (days) 365Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 254.7Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 64 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 48Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 4.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 61Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesLAO PDREast Asia and PacificEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 310 Number of procedures 9Population 5,403,170 Time (days) 198Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 19.5Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 150.7Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures ..Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 87 Time (days) ..Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 44 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) ..Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 54 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex ..Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) No practicePublic registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) .. Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) No practicePublic-registry <strong>in</strong>dex .. Absolute priority preserved 0Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 14Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67LATVIAEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 3,480 Number of procedures 7Population 2,359,000 Time (days) 11Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 39.9 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 14.7Legal orig<strong>in</strong> German M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 93.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Number of procedures 19Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 87 Time (days) 189Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 42 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 7.5Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 62 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 56Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.2Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 92Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67155LEBANONMiddle East and North AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 3,990 Number of procedures 6Population 4,384,680 Time (days) 46Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 34.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 129.9Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 83.1Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Number of procedures 27Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 50 Time (days) 721Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 35 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 54.3Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 46 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 67Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 4.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 31Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 4 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>LESOTHOSub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 470 Number of procedures 9Population 2,061,730 Time (days) 92Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 67.4Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 20.2Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Number of procedures ..Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 51 Time (days) ..Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 25 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) ..Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 45 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex ..Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) ..Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) ..Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved ..Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved ..Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex ..Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex ..LITHUANIAEurope and Central Asia156Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 3,660 Number of procedures 9Population 3,482,000 Time (days) 26Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 30.3 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 6.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 74.4Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 71 Number of procedures 17Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 90 Time (days) 74Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 31 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 13.0Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 64 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 58Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.2Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 7 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 63 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 54Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67MACEDONIA, FYREurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,700 Number of procedures 13Population 2,035,000 Time (days) 48Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 13.1Legal orig<strong>in</strong> German M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 138.4Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 65 Number of procedures 27Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Time (days) 509Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 32 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 43.0Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 50 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 67Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.6Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 2 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 38Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 42 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 34Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesMADAGASCARSub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 240 Number of procedures 15Population 15,975,750 Time (days) 67Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 39.6 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 62.8Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 30.5Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 48 Number of procedures 29Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 86 Time (days) 166Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 49 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 120.2Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 61 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 63Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) No practicePublic registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 2 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) No practicePublic-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 46 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 25Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67MALAWISub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 160 Number of procedures 11Population 10,526,300 Time (days) 45Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 40.3 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 125.4Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 16Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 68 Time (days) 108Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 54 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 520.6Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 52 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 48Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.8Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 40Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67157MALAYSIAEast Asia and PacificEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 3,540 Number of procedures 8Population 23,802,360 Time (days) 31Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 31.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 27.1Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 22Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 26 Time (days) 270Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 15 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 19.4Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 25 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 41Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.2Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 105 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 59 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 461 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 52Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>MALISub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 240 Number of procedures 13Population 11,094,340 Time (days) 61Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 41 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 232.2Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 597.8Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Number of procedures 27Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 86 Time (days) 150Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 23 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 7.0Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 54 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 71Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.5Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 1 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 22 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 32Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 100MAURITANIASub-Saharan Africa158Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 410 Number of procedures 11Population 2,749,150 Time (days) 73Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 110.2Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 896.7Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 62 Number of procedures ..Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 47 Time (days) ..Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 66 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) ..Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 59 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex ..Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? .. Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 8.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) .. Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex .. Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 28Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67MEXICOLat<strong>in</strong> America and CaribbeanEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 5,910 Number of procedures 7Population 99,419,688 Time (days) 51Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 30.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 18.8Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 87.6Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 81 Number of procedures 47Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 81 Time (days) 325Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 70 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 10.0Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 77 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 62Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 382 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 61Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesMOLDOVAEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 460 Number of procedures 11Population 4,270,000 Time (days) 42Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 45.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 26.2Legal orig<strong>in</strong> Socialist M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 86.3Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 71 Number of procedures 36Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 75 Time (days) 210Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 54 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 14.2Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 67 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 48Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.8Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 49Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67MONGOLIAEast Asia and PacificEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 440 Number of procedures 8Population 2,421,360 Time (days) 31Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 18.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 12.0Legal orig<strong>in</strong> Socialist M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 2046.9Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 26Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 90 Time (days) 224Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 25 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 1.8Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 50 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 71Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 4.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 15 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 68 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 54Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67159MOROCCOMiddle East and North AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,190 Number of procedures 11Population 29,170,000 Time (days) 36Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 36.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 19.1Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 762.5Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 56 Number of procedures 17Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 63 Time (days) 192Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 9.1Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 51 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 69Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.9Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) .. Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 36Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 100Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>MOZAMBIQUESub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 210 Number of procedures 15Population 18,071,160 Time (days) 153Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 40.3 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 99.6Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 30.2Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 73 Number of procedures 18Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 85 Time (days) 540Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 64 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 9.1Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 74 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 71Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) No practicePublic registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 1 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) No practicePublic-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 52 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 25Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67NAMIBIASub-Saharan Africa160Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,780 Number of procedures 10Population 1,792,060 Time (days) 85Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 18.7Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 17 Number of procedures ..Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 57 Time (days) ..Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 54 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) ..Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 43 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex ..Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) ..Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) ..Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved ..Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? .. Efficient outcome achieved ..Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) .. Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex ..Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex .. Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex ..NEPALSouth AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 230 Number of procedures 8Population 23,584,710 Time (days) 25Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 38.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 191.0Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 24Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 54 Time (days) 350Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 47 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 44.2Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 45 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 63Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 5.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 35Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesNETHERLANDSOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 23,960 Number of procedures 7Population 16,039,000 Time (days) 11Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 13 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 13.7Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 70.7Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 51 Number of procedures 21Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 79 Time (days) 39Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.5Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 54 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 46Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.6Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 1Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 530 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 95Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33NEW ZEALANDOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 13,710 Number of procedures 3Population 3,849,000 Time (days) 3Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 12.7 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.2Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 19Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 43 Time (days) 50Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 20 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 11.6Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 32 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 31Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 818 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 90Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 4 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 0161NICARAGUALat<strong>in</strong> America and CaribbeanEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 395 Number of procedures 12Population 5,205,000 Time (days) 71Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 45.2 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 337.8Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 17Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 90 Time (days) 125Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 17.7Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 61 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 79Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.3Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 50 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 45 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 58Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 4 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>NIGERSub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 170 Number of procedures 11Population 11,184,130 Time (days) 27Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 41.9 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 446.6Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 844.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Number of procedures 29Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 89 Time (days) 365Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 34 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 57.1Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 59 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 63Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 5.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 1 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 22 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 37Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 100NIGERIASub-Saharan Africa162Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 290 Number of procedures 10Population 129,874,976 Time (days) 44Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 57.9 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 92.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 28.6Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 17 Number of procedures 23Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 76 Time (days) 730Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 36 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 6.6Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 43 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 52Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.6Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita)


Country TablesOMANMiddle East and North AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) .. Number of procedures 9Population 2,478,000 Time (days) 34Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 5.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 720.9Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Number of procedures 54Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 78 Time (days) 250Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 25 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 4.8Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 54 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 51Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 7.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 0Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 29Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67PAKISTANSouth AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 410 Number of procedures 10Population 141,450,144 Time (days) 22Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 36.8 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 46.8Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 65 Number of procedures 30Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 75 Time (days) 365Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 45.8Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 53Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.8Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 1 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 42 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita)


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>PAPUA NEW GUINEAEast Asia and PacificEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 530 Number of procedures 7Population 5,252,530 Time (days) 69Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 26.4Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 17 Number of procedures 22Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 57 Time (days) 270Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 41.1Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 26 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 45Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) ..Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) ..Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved ..Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved ..Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex ..Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex ..PARAGUAYLat<strong>in</strong> America and Caribbean164Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,170 Number of procedures 18Population 5,390,000 Time (days) 73Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 160.9Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Number of procedures 46Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 90 Time (days) 188Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 71 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 34.0Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 73 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 67Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? .. Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.9Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) .. Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex .. Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? .. Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) .. Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 46Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67PERULat<strong>in</strong> America and CaribbeanEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 2,050 Number of procedures 9Population 26,347,000 Time (days) 100Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 59.9 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 24.9Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 71 Number of procedures 35Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 81 Time (days) 441Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 69 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 29.7Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 73 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 82Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.1Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 92 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 54 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 185 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 67Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesPHILIPPINESEast Asia and PacificEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,020 Number of procedures 11Population 78,317,032 Time (days) 59Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 43.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 24.4Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 9.5Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Number of procedures 28Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 73 Time (days) 164Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 50 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 103.7Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 60 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 75Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 5.7Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 38Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 22 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 38Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 100POLANDEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 4,570 Number of procedures 12Population 38,641,000 Time (days) 31Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 27.6 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 20.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> German M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 21.4Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 18Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 92 Time (days) 1000Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 39 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 11.2Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 55 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 65Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.5Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 543 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 70Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67165PORTUGALOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 10,840 Number of procedures 11Population 10,024,000 Time (days) 95Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 22.6 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 12.5Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 43.4Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 76 Number of procedures 22Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 88 Time (days) 420Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 73 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 4.9Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 79 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 54Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.6Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 496 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 61 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 24 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 66Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>PUERTO RICOLat<strong>in</strong> America and CaribbeanEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) .. Number of procedures 6Population 3,840,000 Time (days) 6Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 2.8Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 55Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 67 Time (days) 365Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 24 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 20.9Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 41 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 52Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.8Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? .. Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) .. Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 71Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33ROMANIAEurope and Central Asia166Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,850 Number of procedures 6Population 22,408,000 Time (days) 27Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 34.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 11.7Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 3.3Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 48 Number of procedures 28Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 85 Time (days) 225Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 29 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 13.1Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 54 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 60Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.2Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 1 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 59 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 39Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33RUSSIAN FEDERATIONEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 2,140 Number of procedures 12Population 144,752,000 Time (days) 29Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 46.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 9.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> Socialist M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 29.8Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 16Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 77 Time (days) 160Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 71 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 20.2Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 61 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 48Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.53Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 58Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesRWANDASub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 230 Number of procedures 9Population 7,933,000 Time (days) 43Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 232.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 457.3Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Number of procedures ..Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 94 Time (days) ..Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 32 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) ..Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 60 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex ..Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) No practicePublic registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita)


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>SERBIA AND MONTENEGROEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,400 Number of procedures 10Population 10,651,000 Time (days) 44Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 29.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 13.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> German M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 5.5Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 51 Number of procedures 40Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 88 Time (days) 1028Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 29 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 20.0Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 56 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 61Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 7.3Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita)


Country TablesSLOVAK REPUBLICEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 3,950 Number of procedures 10Population 5,404,000 Time (days) 98Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 18.9 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 10.2Legal orig<strong>in</strong> German M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 111.8Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 34 Number of procedures 26Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 89 Time (days) 420Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 60 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 13.3Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 61 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 40Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 4.8Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 2 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 48 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 71Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67SLOVENIAEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 9,810 Number of procedures 10Population 1,992,000 Time (days) 61Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 27.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 15.5Legal orig<strong>in</strong> German M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 89.1Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Number of procedures 22Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 84 Time (days) 1003Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 41 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 3.6Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 59 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 65Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.7Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 14 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 60 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 41Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67169SOUTH AFRICASub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 2,600 Number of procedures 9Population 43,240,000 Time (days) 38Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 28.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 8.7Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 42 Number of procedures 26Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 36 Time (days) 207Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 30 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 16.7Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 36 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 56Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 469 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 53Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>SPAINOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 14,430 Number of procedures 11Population 41,117,000 Time (days) 115Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 22.6 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 16.4Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 19.6Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 76 Number of procedures 20Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 88 Time (days) 147Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 45 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 10.7Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 70 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 83Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.53Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 305 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 64 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 0Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 0SRI LANKASouth Asia170Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 840 Number of procedures 8Population 18,732,000 Time (days) 58Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 44.6 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 18.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 17Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 52 Time (days) 440Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 40 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 7.6Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 42 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 59Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.3Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 9 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 35Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67SWEDENOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 24,820 Number of procedures 3Population 8,894,000 Time (days) 16Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 19.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.8Legal orig<strong>in</strong> Nordic M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 41.4Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 56 Number of procedures 21Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 39 Time (days) 190Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 31 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 7.6Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 42 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 44Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 489 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 84Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesSWITZERLANDOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 37,930 Number of procedures 6Population 7,231,000 Time (days) 20Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 8.8 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 8.5Legal orig<strong>in</strong> German M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 33.8Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 14Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Time (days) 224Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 23 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 3.9Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 36 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 44Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 4.6Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 178 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 59Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67SYRIAN ARAB REPUBLICMiddle East and North AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,130 Number of procedures 10Population 16,593,210 Time (days) 42Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 19.3 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 16.7Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 5627.2Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 36Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 79 Time (days) 596Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 22 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 31.3Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 45 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 69Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 4.1Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 37Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67171TAIWAN, CHINAEast Asia and PacificEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 13,300 Number of procedures 8Population 22,342,000 Time (days) 48Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 19.6 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 6.1Legal orig<strong>in</strong> German M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 217.4Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 81 Number of procedures 15Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 59 Time (days) 210Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 32 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.5Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 57 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 37Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 0.8Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 27 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 70 Absolute priority preserved 0Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) .. Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 68Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 100Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>TANZANIASub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 280 Number of procedures 13Population 34,449,620 Time (days) 35Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 58.3 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 199.0Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 57 Number of procedures 14Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 77 Time (days) 127Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 49 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 3.8Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 61 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 62Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 65Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67THAILANDEast Asia and Pacific172Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 1,980 Number of procedures 9Population 61,183,900 Time (days) 42Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 52.6 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 7.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 78 Number of procedures 19Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 73 Time (days) 210Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 30 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 29.6Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 61 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 53Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.6Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 38Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 98 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 62Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33TOGOSub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 270 Number of procedures 14Population 4,653,400 Time (days) 63Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) .. Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 281.4Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 531.4Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Number of procedures 43Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 80 Time (days) 503Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 36 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 21.4Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 57 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 63Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) No practicePublic registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 1 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) No practicePublic-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 22 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 8Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 100Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesTUNISIAMiddle East and North AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 2,000 Number of procedures 10Population 9,673,600 Time (days) 46Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 38.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 16.4Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 351.7Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 73 Number of procedures 14Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 53 Time (days) 7Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 44 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 4.1Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 57 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 60Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.5Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 4 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 48 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 50Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67TURKEYEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 2,500 Number of procedures 13Population 68,529,000 Time (days) 38Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 32.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 37.1Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 13.2Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Number of procedures 18Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 91 Time (days) 105Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 17 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 5.4Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 55 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 38Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.8Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 7 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 44 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 204 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 51Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67173UGANDASub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 250 Number of procedures 17Population 22,788,000 Time (days) 36Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 43.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 135.1Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 16Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 44 Time (days) 99Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 50 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 10.0Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 42 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 40Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 38Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 55Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>UKRAINEEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 770 Number of procedures 14Population 49,093,000 Time (days) 40Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 52.2 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 27.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> Socialist M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 450.8Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Number of procedures 20Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 93 Time (days) 224Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 69 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 11.0Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 73 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 51Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.97Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 67Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 42Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33UNITED ARAB EMIRATESMiddle East and North Africa174Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 20,218 Number of procedures 10Population 2,976,290 Time (days) 29Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 26.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 24.5Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 404.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 27Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 66 Time (days) 559Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 37 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 10.6Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 45 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 56Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 5Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 12 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 38Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 44 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 23Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33UNITED KINGDOMOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 25,250 Number of procedures 6Population 58,800,000 Time (days) 18Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 12.6 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 1.0Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 12Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 42 Time (days) 101Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 9 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.5Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 28 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 36Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 1.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 652 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 86Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 4 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 0Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesUNITED STATESOECD: High IncomeEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 35,060 Number of procedures 5Population 285,318,016 Time (days) 4Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 8.8 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.6Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 17Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 29 Time (days) 365Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 5 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.4Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 22 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 46Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 810 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 88Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33URUGUAYLat<strong>in</strong> America and CaribbeanEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 4,370 Number of procedures 10Population 3,361,000 Time (days) 27Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 51.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 46.7Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 699.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 58 Number of procedures 38Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 56 Time (days) 360Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 13.7Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 39 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 55Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 4.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 49 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 57 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? Yes Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 479 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 54Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 3 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67175UZBEKISTANEurope and Central AsiaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 450 Number of procedures 9Population 25,068,000 Time (days) 33Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 34.1 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 16.0Legal orig<strong>in</strong> Socialist M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 64.3Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 46 Number of procedures 34Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 69 Time (days) 258Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 50 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 2.1Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 55 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 57Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.25Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 46Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67Note: .. means no data available.


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>VENEZUELA, RBLat<strong>in</strong> America and CaribbeanEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 4,090 Number of procedures 14Population 24,632,000 Time (days) 119Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 33.6 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 19.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 78 Number of procedures 41Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 88 Time (days) 360Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 60 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 46.9Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 75 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 81Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 4.0Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 97 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 38Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 46 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 67Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 2 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67VIETNAMEast Asia and Pacific176Economy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 430 Number of procedures 11Population 79,526,048 Time (days) 63Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 15.6 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 29.9Legal orig<strong>in</strong> French M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 43 Number of procedures 28Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 77 Time (days) 120Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 48 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 8.5Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 56 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 46Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) No practicePublic registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 2 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) No practicePublic-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 67 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 1Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 33Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67YEMEN, REP. ofMiddle East and North AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 490 Number of procedures 13Population 18,045,750 Time (days) 96Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 27.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 264.1Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 1716.9Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 27Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 66 Time (days) 240Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 28 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.5Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 43 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 60Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? Yes Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.4Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 7 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 4Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 38 Absolute priority preserved 33Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 47Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33Note: .. means no data available.


Country TablesZAMBIASub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 330 Number of procedures 6Population 10,282,500 Time (days) 40Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 48.9 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 24.1Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 137.8Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 16Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 64 Time (days) 188Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 40 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 15.8Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 46 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 32Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 3.7Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 8Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 55Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 1 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 33ZIMBABWESub-Saharan AfricaEconomy CharacteristicsStart<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>GNI per capita (US$) 463 Number of procedures 10Population 12,820,650 Time (days) 122Informal economy (% of <strong>in</strong>come) 59.4 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 285.3Legal orig<strong>in</strong> English M<strong>in</strong>imum capital (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 0.0Hir<strong>in</strong>g and Fir<strong>in</strong>g WorkersEnforc<strong>in</strong>g a ContractFlexibility-of-hir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 33 Number of procedures 13Conditions-of-employment <strong>in</strong>dex 22 Time (days) 197Flexibility-of-fir<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dex 26 Cost (% of <strong>in</strong>come per capita) 39.5Employment-law <strong>in</strong>dex 27 Procedural-complexity <strong>in</strong>dex 50Gett<strong>in</strong>g CreditClos<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Public credit registry operates? No Time to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (years) 2.3Public registry coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Cost to go through <strong>in</strong>solvency (% estate) 18Public-registry <strong>in</strong>dex 0 Absolute priority preserved 100Private credit-<strong>in</strong>formation bureau operates? No Efficient outcome achieved 0Private bureau coverage (borrowers/1,000 capita) 0 Goals-of-<strong>in</strong>solvency <strong>in</strong>dex 52Creditor-rights <strong>in</strong>dex 4 Court-powers <strong>in</strong>dex 67177Note: .. means no data available.


List of ContributorsWe would like to thank the follow<strong>in</strong>g organizations and <strong>in</strong>dividualswho have generously contributed to the data collection ofthe <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> project. Contact details of local partners areavailable on the <strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> website at http://rru.worldbank.org/do<strong>in</strong>gbus<strong>in</strong>ess/.Global ContributorsBaker & McKenzieDun and Bradstreet InternationalInternational Bar AssociationLex Mundi Association of law firmsTransUnion InternationalAlbaniaArtur Asllani Studio Legale TonucciYair Baranes USAIDGenc Boga Boga & AssociatesVilsa Dado Kalo & AssociatesShpati Hoxha Boga & AssociatesSonila Ibrahimi Boga & AssociatesPerparim Kalo Kalo & AssociatesMiranda Ramaj <strong>Bank</strong> of AlbaniaAlgeriaBranka Achari-Djokic <strong>Bank</strong> of AlgeriaMamoun Aidoud Aidoud Law FirmAm<strong>in</strong>e Hadad Ghellal & MekerbaMustapha Hamdane Cab<strong>in</strong>et d Avocats Mustapha HamdaneSamir Hamouda Cab<strong>in</strong>et d Avocats Samir HamoudaYam<strong>in</strong>a Kebir Yem<strong>in</strong>a Kebir Law OfficesSaid Maherzi <strong>Bank</strong> of AlgeriaAngolaFátima Freitas Fátima Freitas Law FirmLeão Peres National <strong>Bank</strong> of AngolaArgent<strong>in</strong>aJuan Arocena Allende & Brea Law FirmVanesa Balda Manoff & Feilbogen Law FirmOscar Del Rio Central <strong>Bank</strong> of Argent<strong>in</strong>aBernardo Horacio Fernandez Central <strong>Bank</strong> of Argent<strong>in</strong>aAlejandro Fiuza Marval O’Farrell & MairalNicolas Garcia P<strong>in</strong>to Baker & McKenzieMart<strong>in</strong> Lanfranco Marval O’Farrell & MairalRoberto Laterza Organización VerazPatricia Lopez Aufranc Marval O’Farrell & MairalMaria Lujan Bianchi Brons & Salas Law FirmEugenio Maurette Abeledo Gottheil AbogadosSean McCormick Llerena & Asociados AbogadosOlga Mu<strong>in</strong>o Centro de Estudios BonaerensesMiguel Murray Estudio Juridico BordaAlfredo O’Farrell Marval O’Farrell & MairalJuan Manuel Alvarez Prado Alvarez Prado & AsociadosJorge Raul Postiglione Brons & Salas Law FirmLiliana Segade Quattr<strong>in</strong>i Laprida & AsociadosAlfredo Vicens Organización VerazOctavio Miguel Zenarruza Alvarez Prado & AsociadosArmeniaKaren Hambardzoumyan Central <strong>Bank</strong> of ArmeniaAlan Kuchukyan KPMG ArmeniaSuren Melikyan KPMG ArmeniaTom Samuelian Arlex InternationalArtur Tunyan Tunyan & AssociatesAustraliaBrett Cook Allens Arthur Rob<strong>in</strong>sonDavid Cross Allens Arthur Rob<strong>in</strong>sonChristopher Davie Clayton UtzPaul James Clayton UtzSonya Karo ASICTimothy L’Estrange Allens Arthur Rob<strong>in</strong>sonJudy Lau Australian Prudential Regulation AuthorityJohn Lobban Blake Dawson WaldronHelen MacKay Allens Arthur Rob<strong>in</strong>sonTim O’Doherty Baker & McKenzieMichael O’Donnell Thomson PlayfordMichael Qu<strong>in</strong>tan Allens Arthur Rob<strong>in</strong>sonAndrew Smith Mallesons Stephen JaquesRe<strong>in</strong>hard Toegl Dr. Re<strong>in</strong>hard Toegl Law OfficesJane Wilson Baycorp AdvantageAustriaJohannes Barbist B<strong>in</strong>der Grösswang RechtsanwälteWalter Bornett Austrian Institute for SME Research179


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>180Tibor Fabian B<strong>in</strong>der Grösswang RechtsanwälteJulian Feicht<strong>in</strong>ger Cerha Hempel & SpiegelfeldBernhard Gumpoldsberger Sax<strong>in</strong>ger Chalupsky Weber & PartnersHarald Heschl Kreditschutzverband von 1870Sylvia Hof<strong>in</strong>ger Vienna City GovernmentAlexander Klauser Brauneis, Klauser & PrändlRobert Kovacs Coface IntercreditChristian Lettmayr Austrian Institute for SME ResearchIrene Mandl Austrian Institute for SME ResearchLeopold Mayer Dun and Bradstreet Information ServicesWolfgang Messeritsch National <strong>Bank</strong> of AustriaNorbert Scherbaum Scherbaum/Seebacher RechtsanwälteBenedikt Spiegelfeld Cerha Hempel & SpiegelfeldDagmar Straka National <strong>Bank</strong> of AustriaRe<strong>in</strong>hard Töegl Re<strong>in</strong>hard Töegl Law OfficesAzerbaijanOfelia Abdulaeva SalansNazli Ahmadova Baku Law CentreElgar Alekperov Baku Law CentreAykhan Asadov Baker & McKenzieRufat Aslanov National <strong>Bank</strong> of AzerbaijanAlum Bati Salans Hertzfeld & Heilbronn Law FirmChrist<strong>in</strong>e Ferguson Baker BottsFarhad Hajizade Salans Hertzfeld & Heilbronn Law FirmDaniel Matthews Baker & McKenzieKanan Safarov Led<strong>in</strong>gham ChalmersSafkhan Shahmammadli Baker BottsMichael Walsh Led<strong>in</strong>gham ChalmersBangladeshJasim Udd<strong>in</strong> Ahmad <strong>Bank</strong> of BangladeshHalim Bepari Supreme Court of BangladeshShir<strong>in</strong> Chaudhury The Law AssociatesA.B.M. Badrud Doulah Doulah & Doulah Advocates Attorneys& NotariesShamsud Doulah Doulah & Doulah AdvocatesAneek Haque Huq & CompanyRaquibul Haque Miah Advocates & Attorneys Law FirmMirza Quamrul Hasan Advisers’ Legal AllianceKhondker Shamsudd<strong>in</strong> Mahmood Advisers’ Legal AllianceAmir-Ul Islam The Law AssociatesBelarusVladimir Biruk Belarusian Community of Specialists <strong>in</strong> CrisisManagementSvetlana Dashuk Vlasova & PartnersAlexandr Dovgenko Incorporation LawyerYuri Krasnov National <strong>Bank</strong> of the Republic of BelarusIgor Likhogrud National <strong>Bank</strong> of the Republic of BelarusVassili Salei Borovtsov & SaleiVitaliy Sevrukevich DICSA International Group of LawyersVassili Volosh<strong>in</strong>ets Incorporation LawyerBelgiumPamela Cordova LoyensLudo Cornelis Eubelius AttorneysDirk De Backer Allen & OveryMarc Dechevre Union Professionnelle du CréditLuc Demeyere Allen & OveryPieter De Koster Allen & OveryJoan Dubaere Peeters Advocaten-AvocatsAla<strong>in</strong> Francois Eubelius AttorneysIgnace Maes Baker & McKenzieAndre Moreau National <strong>Bank</strong> of BelgiumDidier Muraille National <strong>Bank</strong> of BelgiumLeo Peeters Peeters Advocaten-AvocatsHans Seeldrayers Eubelius AttorneysRudy Trogh National <strong>Bank</strong> of BelgiumJan Van Celst Allen & OveryBen<strong>in</strong>Rafikou Alabi Cab<strong>in</strong>et Rafikou AlabiVilevo Biova Devo Centrale des Risques de l’Union MonetaireOuest Africa<strong>in</strong>eEvelyne Mandessi Bell Mandessi Bell Law FirmJacques Migan Jacques Migan Law FirmEdgar-Yves Monnou Cab<strong>in</strong>et Edgar-Yves MonnouFrancois Nare Centrale des Risques de l’Union Monetaire OuestAfrica<strong>in</strong>eBoliviaCarol<strong>in</strong>a Aguirre Urioste Bufete AguirreFernando Aguirre Bufete AguirreCarlos Ferreira C.R. & F. Rojas AbogadosPrimitivo Gutiérrez Guevara & GutierrezEnrique Hurtado Super<strong>in</strong>tendency of <strong>Bank</strong>s and F<strong>in</strong>ancial EntitiesRicardo Indacochea San Martín Indacochea & AsociadosManfredo Kempff C.R. & F. Rojas AbogadosFernando Rojas C.R. & F. Rojas AbogadosPablo Rojas C.R & F. Rojas AbogadosSergio Salazar-Machicado Salazar, Salazar & AsociadosBosnia and Herzegov<strong>in</strong>aYair Baranes USAIDAdnan Hrenovica LRC Credit BureauNikola Jankovic Lansky & Partner AttorneysKerim Karabdic Advokati Salih & Kerim KarabdicVesna Mrkovic Lansky & Partner AttorneysIbrahim Polimac Agency for <strong>Bank</strong><strong>in</strong>g of Federationof Bosnia and Herzegov<strong>in</strong>aBotswanaNeill Armstrong Armstrongs AttorneysJohn Carr-Hartley Armstrongs AttorneysTopiwa Chilume Armstrongs Attorneys Notaries & ConveyancersEdward Fashole Luke II Luke & AssociatesV<strong>in</strong>cent Galeromeloe Information Trust CorporationKwadwo Osei-Ofei Armstrongs AttorneysMoses Pelaelo <strong>Bank</strong> of BotswanaVirgil Vergeer Coll<strong>in</strong>s Newman & CoBrazilAdriana Baroni Santi Ulhôa Canto Rezende e Guerra-AdvogadosThomas Benes Felsberg Felsberg e Associados


List of ContributorsHeloisa Bonciani Nader di Cunto Duarte Garcia CaselliGuimarães e Terra AdvogadosAltamiro Boscoli Demarest e Almeida AdvogadosUlhôa Canto Ulhôa Canto Rezende e Guerra-AdvogadosGustavo Castro Viseu Castro Cunha e Oricchio AdvogadosPaulo Sérgio Cavalheiro Central <strong>Bank</strong> of BrazilPedro Vitor Araujo da Costa Escritorio de Advocacia GouvêaVieiraSilvia Poggi de Carvalho Duarte Garcia Caselli Guimarães e TerraAdvogadosAloysio Meirelles de Miranda Ulhôa Canto Rezende e Guerra-AdvogadosSilvio de Salvo Venosa Demarest e Almeida AdvogadosDuarte Garcia Duarte Garcia Caselli Guimarães e TerraAdvogadosReg<strong>in</strong>a Gasulla Bouza Goulart Penteado, Iervol<strong>in</strong>oe Lefosse – AdvogadosRenato Giovanni Filho Ulhôa Canto Rezende e Guerra-AdvogadosCaio Julius Bol<strong>in</strong>a Lazzareschi AdvogadosMaria Fernanda Lopes Ferraz Tella Felsberg and AssociadosJosé Augusto Mart<strong>in</strong>s Baker & McKenzieAndré Megale Goulart Penteado, Iervol<strong>in</strong>o e Lefosse – AdvogadosFabiano Milani Goulart Penteado, Iervol<strong>in</strong>o e Lefosse – AdvogadosAndrea Oricchio Kirsh Viseu Castro Cunha e Oricchio AdvogadosValéria Salomão Central <strong>Bank</strong> of BrazilBulgariaSvetl<strong>in</strong> Adrianov Legal InterConsult - Penkov Markov andPartners Law OfficeBorislav Boyanov Borislav Boyanov & CoGeorge Dimitrov O.R.A.C. Dimitrov Petrov & CoVasil Iliev ConsultGeorgi Kitanov Totev PartnersS. Kyutchukov Dj<strong>in</strong>gov Goug<strong>in</strong>ski Kyutchukov & VelichkovYordan Manahilov Bulgarian National <strong>Bank</strong>Stoyan Manolov Bulgarian National <strong>Bank</strong>Vladimir Penkov Legal InterConsult - Penkov Markov andPartners Law OfficeKamelia Popova Coface Intercredit BulgariaIr<strong>in</strong>a Tsvetkova Landwell BulgariaBurk<strong>in</strong>a FasoBernard<strong>in</strong> Dabire Dabire Sorgho & ToeVilevo Biova Devo Centrale des Risques de l’Union MonetaireOuest Africa<strong>in</strong>eFrank Didier Toe Dabire Sorgho & ToeBarthélémy Kere Cab<strong>in</strong>et d’Avocats Barthélémy KereEvelyne Mandessi Bell Mandessi Bell Law FirmFrancois Nare Centrale des Risques de l’Union Monetaire OuestAfrica<strong>in</strong>eMarie-Anto<strong>in</strong>ette Sorgho-Sery Dabire Sorgho & ToeOumarou Ouedraogo Ohada LegisDieudonné Bonkoungou Ohada LegisBurundiTharcisse Ntakiyica Cab<strong>in</strong>et Tharcisse NtakiyicaYves Ntivumbura Central <strong>Bank</strong> of BurundiCambodiaPhyroath Heng IMC Consult<strong>in</strong>gTim Smyth IMC Consult<strong>in</strong>gCameroonD. Etah Akoh Etah-Nan & C. Société d’AvocatsBarristers & SolicitorsDavid Boyo Henri Job & PartnersEmmanuel Ekobo Cab<strong>in</strong>et EkoboIsabelle Fomukong Cab<strong>in</strong>et FomukongTahir Souleyman Haggar La Commission Bancaire de l’AfriqueCentralePaul J<strong>in</strong>g Henri Job & PartnersGaston Kenfack M<strong>in</strong>istry of JusticeKumfa Jude Kwenyui Juris Consul Law FirmDaniel Mwambo Ndeley Juris Consul Law FirmEvelyne Mandessi Bell Mandessi Bell Law FirmMwambo Litombe Ndeley Juris Consul Law FirmRafael Tung Nsue La Commission Bancaire de l’Afrique CentraleHenri Pierre Job Henri Job & PartnersCanadaArthur Adams Southern Ontario Credit BureauEldon Bennett Aird & BerlisDavid Bish GoodmansJay Carfagn<strong>in</strong>i GoodmansThomas Cumm<strong>in</strong>g Gowl<strong>in</strong>g Lafleur HendersonYo<strong>in</strong>e Goldste<strong>in</strong> Goldste<strong>in</strong> Flanz & FishmanLeonid Gorelik Baker & McKenzieKaren Grant TransUnionCharles Johnston Super<strong>in</strong>tendency of F<strong>in</strong>ancial InstitutionsCharles Magerman Baker & McKenziePatrick McCarthy Borden Ladner GervaisTim Paleczny Government of OntarioDebbie Ranger Canada Customs and Revenue AgencyJeff Rosekat Baker & McKenziePaul Schabas Blake Cassels & GraydonLeneo Sdao Baker & McKenzieJason Vonderhaar TransUnionJonathan Wigley Baker & McKenzieChristopher William Besant Cassels BrockCentral African RepublicTahir Souleyman Haggar La Commission Bancairede l’Afrique CentraleRafael Tung Nsue La Commission Bancaire de l’Afrique CentraleNicolas Tiangaye Nicolas Tiangaye Law FirmChadThomas D<strong>in</strong>gamgoto Cab<strong>in</strong>et D<strong>in</strong>gamgoto et AssociesTahir Souleyman Haggar Centrale Recapitulative des RisquesRafael Tung Nsue La Commission Bancaire de l’Afrique CentraleChileCristian Araya Alca<strong>in</strong>o Rodriguez & Sahli Law FirmManuel Blanco Blanco & Cia AbogadosJimena Bronfman Guerrero Olivos Novoa y Errázuriz181


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>182Jaime Cordova Super<strong>in</strong>tendencia de Bancos yInstitutciones F<strong>in</strong>ancieras ChileRodrigo Cuchacovich Baker & McKenzieMartín del Río Vial y Palma AbogadosRicardo Escobar Carey y Cia Law FirmCristian Eyzaguirre Claro & CiaRoberto Guerrero Guerrero Olivos Novoa y ErrázurizLuis Gutierrez Puga & OrtizSilvio Figari Napoli Databus<strong>in</strong>essAndrés Jana L<strong>in</strong>etzky Alvarez H<strong>in</strong>zpeter Jana & ValleCesar Jimenez Ortiz Super<strong>in</strong>tendencia de Bancos y InstitucionesF<strong>in</strong>ancieras ChileLeón Larra<strong>in</strong> Baker & McKenzieClaudio Ortiz Tello Bolet<strong>in</strong> ComercialFelipe Ossa Claro & CiaJuan Eduardo Palma Vial y Palma AbogadosDaniela Peña Fergadiott Barros Court Correa y Cia. AbogadosSebastián Yunge Guerrero Olivos Novoa y ErrázurizCh<strong>in</strong>aBrian Barron Baker & McKenzieCharles Booth University of Hong KongBarry Cheng Baker & McKenzieBob Kwauk Blake Cassels & GraydonJoseph Lam DeaconsWang Li De Heng Law OfficesYang L<strong>in</strong>g Huaxia International <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Credit Consult<strong>in</strong>gJerry Liu Huaxia International <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Credit Consult<strong>in</strong>gL<strong>in</strong>fei Liu Jun He Law OfficesChen M<strong>in</strong> Blake Cassels & GraydonLi Wang DeHeng Law OfficeXiaochuan Yang PricewaterhouseCoopers New York OfficeJ<strong>in</strong> Zhong Jun He Law OfficesZhang Zihong People’s <strong>Bank</strong> of Ch<strong>in</strong>aColombiaDario Cárdenas Navas Cárdenas & CárdenasJorge Lara Baker & McKenzieJosé Antonio Lloreda José Lloreda Camacho & CoJuan Manuel Villaveces Hollmann DataCréditoLuis E. Nieto Arrieta Mantilla & AsociadosJuanita Olaya Garcia National Department of Plann<strong>in</strong>gRicardo León Otero Super<strong>in</strong>tendencia Bancaria de ColombiaDaniel Posse Posse Herrera & RuizZuli Rodríguez Legal Department División de Personas JurídicasBernardo Salazar Brigard & UrrutiaPaula Samper Salazar Gomez P<strong>in</strong>zon L<strong>in</strong>ares Samper Suarez VillamilCarlos Urrutia-Holgu<strong>in</strong> Brigard & UrrutiaJuan Manuel Villaveces Hollmann ComputecCongo, Dem. Rep. ofLouman Mpoy Cab<strong>in</strong>et Louman MpoyCongo, Rep. ofTahir Souleyman Haggar Centrale Recapitulative des RisquesJean Petro Cab<strong>in</strong>et d’Avocats Jean PetroRafael Tung Nsue La Commission Bancaire de l’Afrique CentraleCosta RicaBernardo Alfaro Araya Super<strong>in</strong>tendencia General de EntidadesBancarias de Costa RicaKathya Araya Facio & CañasFreddy Fachler Pacheco CotoAlfredo Fournier Beeche Fournier AsociadosManuel Gonzalez Sanz Facio & CañasTomás Guardia Facio & CañasFernando Mora Rojas Mora Bolanos y AsociadosRodrigo Oreamuno Facio & CañasMario Qu<strong>in</strong>tana Asesores Juridicos Asociados Don<strong>in</strong>elli& Qu<strong>in</strong>tanaLuis Monge Sancho TeletecCôte d’IvoireJean-Charles Dagu<strong>in</strong> Fidafrica Member of PricewaterhouseCoopersVilevo Biova Devo Centrale des Risques de l’Union MonetaireOuest Africa<strong>in</strong>eKarim Fadika Fadika-Delafosse-Kacoutie-AnthonyColette Kacoutie Fadika-Delafosse-Kacoutie-AnthonyEvelyne Mandessi Bell Mandessi Bell Law FirmGhisla<strong>in</strong>e Moise-Bazie SCPA Konate Moise-Bazie & KoyoFrancois Nare Centrale des Risques de l’Union Monetaire OuestAfrica<strong>in</strong>eGeorges N’Goan N’Goan Asman & AssociesDom<strong>in</strong>ique Taty Fidafrica Member of PricewaterhouseCoopersCroatiaMladen Duliba Croatian National <strong>Bank</strong>Marijan Hanzekovic Hanzekovic & RadakovicZdenko Haramija Koprer & HaramijaIr<strong>in</strong>a Jelcic Hanzekovic & RadakovicSanja Juric Juric Law OfficesDavor Juros Coface Intercredit CroatiaVanja Kalogera Croatian Investment Promotion AgencyJer<strong>in</strong>a Malesevic Koprer & HaramijaAna Mataga Croatian National <strong>Bank</strong>T<strong>in</strong> Matić Matić Law OfficeZeljko Pazur M<strong>in</strong>istry of F<strong>in</strong>anceVlado Sevsek Vlado Sevsek & Zeljka BrlecicLidija Stopfer Vukmir Law OfficeJane Tait PricewaterhouseCoopersHrvoje Vukic Vukic Jeluŝic Sul<strong>in</strong>a Stankovic Jurcan & JabukaEugen Zadravec Eugen Zadravec Law FirmCzech RepublicVladimir Ambruz Ambruz & Dark advokati v.o.s.Libor Basl Baker & McKenzieJiri Bobek Squire Sanders & DempseyJiri Cerny Peterka Leuchterova & PartnersTomas Denmark Czech <strong>Bank</strong><strong>in</strong>g Credit BureauAndrea Korpasova Baker & McKenziePetr Kucera Aspekt KilcullenJan Molik Judr Jan Molik AdvokatJarmila Musilova Czech National <strong>Bank</strong>Ivo Nesrovnal Gleiss Lutz AdvokatiPetr Ríha Procházka Randl Kubr


List of ContributorsRoman Studnicny Coface Intercredit CzechiaRu˜zena Trojánková L<strong>in</strong>klaters & AllianceKater<strong>in</strong>a Trojanova Czech <strong>Bank</strong><strong>in</strong>g Credit BureauLudek Vrána L<strong>in</strong>klaters & AllianceDenmarkJens Arnesen EvershedsSusanne Baekvig Danish Commerce and Companies AgencyClaus Bennetsen AccuraOle Borch Bech-Bruun DragstedN.V. Fall<strong>in</strong>g Olsen Poul Schmith KammeradvokatenUlrik Frirs Danish Commerce and Companies AgencySteen Halm<strong>in</strong>d Bech-Bruun DragstedJørn Skovslund Hansen RKI Kredit InformationMikkel Hesselgren Gorrissen Federspiel Kierkegaard Law FirmJørgen Jepsen Kromann ReumertJørgen Kjærgaard Madsen Kromann ReumertPoul Meisler Danish Commerce and Companies AgencyPia Møller Danish F<strong>in</strong>ancial AuthorityThomas Nielsen Hjejle Gersted & MogensenKurt Skovlund Kromann ReumertDom<strong>in</strong>ican RepublicJesus Almanzar Rojas De Marchena Kaluche & AsociadosFlavia Baez de George Pellerano & HerreraLuis Heredia Bonetti Russ<strong>in</strong> Vecchi & Heredia BonettiAna Isabel Caceres Troncoso & CaceresFrankl<strong>in</strong> Guilamo De Marchena Kaluche & AsociadosHipolito Herrera V. Pellerano & HerreraPorfirio Lopez Data-CreditoXavier Marra Dhimes & MarraRoberto Payano Super<strong>in</strong>tendencia de Bancos de la RepublicaDomenicanaLuis Pellerano Pellerano & HerreraMarcel<strong>in</strong>o San Miguel CICLAJuan Suero Aaron Suero & Peders<strong>in</strong>iManuel Tapia Dr. Ramon Tapia Esp<strong>in</strong>al & AsociadosEcuadorXavier Amador P<strong>in</strong>o Estudio Juridico AmadorMiguel Macías Carmigniani Macias Hurtado & MaciasJose Rumazo Arcos Perez Bustamante & Ponce AbogadosFrancisco Boloña Morales Boloña AbogadosLucía Cordero-Ledergerber Falconi Puig AbogadosAntonio Donoso Naranjo Super<strong>in</strong>tendencia de Bancos e Seguros,Republica del EcuadorLuis Eduardo Garcia Asesoria Legal LégalasJacob Hidrowoh Perez Bustamante & Ponce AbogadosSebastián Pérez-Arteta Asesoria Legal LégalasFalconi Puig Falconi Puig AbogadosHernan Santacruz Perez Bustamante & Ponce AbogadosSantiago Terán Muñoz Estudio Jurídico Moeller & CiaGuillermo Torres InfaesEgypt, Arab Rep. ofAmal Afifi Dawood Denton Wilde SapteMohamed Ajsa Central <strong>Bank</strong> of EgyptRania Bata Sarwat A. Shahid Law FirmAshraf Elibrachy Ibrachy & DermarkarDiaa El-D<strong>in</strong> Abd Rabou Central <strong>Bank</strong> of EgyptSarwat Abd El-Shahid Sarwat A. Shahid Law Firm Gotshal& MangesAhmed Farid Mohamed El-Sherb<strong>in</strong>y Ahmed El-Sherb<strong>in</strong>yLaw FirmSamiha Fawzy The Egyptian Center for Economic StudiesKarim Adel Kamel Adel Kamel Law OfficeMohamed Kamel Kamel Law FirmKater<strong>in</strong>a Miltiadou MecosAttef Mohmed Alfeky Soliman & Partners AdvocatesMahmoud Shedid Shalakany Law OfficeRagy Soliman Ibrachy & DermarkarMohamad Talaat Baker & McKenzieMona Zulficar Shalakany Law OfficeEl SalvadorFrancisco Armando Arias Rivera F.A. Arias & MuñozRoberta Gallardo F.A. Arias & MuñozMarcela Mancia F.A. Arias & MuñozAstrud Melendez Asociacion Protectora de Creditos de elSalvadorHilda Morena Segovia Super<strong>in</strong>tendencia del Sistema F<strong>in</strong>anciero,El SalvadorCel<strong>in</strong>a Padilla F.A. Arias & MuñozJose Roberto Romero P<strong>in</strong>eda & AsociadosRoxana Romero Romero P<strong>in</strong>eda & AsociadosEthiopiaTeshome Gabre-Mariam Bokan Teshome Gabre-MariamDebebe Legesse Debebe Legesse Law FirmLakew Lemma National <strong>Bank</strong> of EthiopiaTameru Wondm Agegnehu Tameru Wondm AgegnehuLaw OfficesF<strong>in</strong>landAhti Auikol<strong>in</strong>en M<strong>in</strong>istry of LaborTimo Esko Esko Timo & Uoti SamiBerndt Heikel Hannes SnellmanPekka Jaat<strong>in</strong>en Castren & SnellmanBernt Juthstrom Roschier-Holmberg & WaseliusKaija Kilappa F<strong>in</strong>ancial Supervision AuthorityGisela Knuts Roschier-Holmberg & WaseliusPatrik L<strong>in</strong>dfors Hannes Snellman Attorneys at LawTomas L<strong>in</strong>dholm Roschier-Holmberg & WaseliusSamu Palkonen Roschier-Holmberg & WaseliusMikko Parjanne Suomen Asiakastieto Oy F<strong>in</strong>skaBekka Rasane Employment and Economic DevelopmentCenterMikko Re<strong>in</strong>ika<strong>in</strong>en PricewaterhouseCoopersSakari E Sorri Bützow NordiaSarah Tähkälä Hannes SnellmanSami Tuom<strong>in</strong>en PricewaterhouseCoopersEeva Vahtera M<strong>in</strong>istry of LaborHelena Viita Roschier-Holmberg & WaseliusGunnar Westerlund Roschier-Holmberg & Waselius183


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>184FranceAnto<strong>in</strong>e Azam-Darley Azam-Darley & AssociesLaurent Barbara Baker & McKenzieNicolas Barberis Ashurst Morris CrispLouis Bernard Buchman Caubet Chouchana MeyerStéphanie Chatelon Deloitte & Touche Juridique et FiscalJohn Crothers Gide Loyrette NouelBertrand Debosque Bignon Lebray Delsol & AssociesOlivier Jaudo<strong>in</strong> Banque de FranceAnto<strong>in</strong>e Maffei De Pardieu Brocas Maffei & LeygoniePhilippe Prevost Banque de FranceAlexia Simon Azam-Darley & AssociesLaurent Valadoux Banque de FrancePhilippe Xavier-Bender Gide Loyrette NouelGeorgiaIrakli Adeishvili Okraliashvili & PartnersGiorgi Begiashvili Begiashvili & Co.Lado Chanturia Supreme Court of GeorgiaMurtaz Kikoria National <strong>Bank</strong> of GeorgiaVictor Kipiani Mgaloblishvili Kipiani DzidziguriDimitri Kitoshvili Okraliashvili & PartnersRa<strong>in</strong>er Magold Baker & McKenzieArchil Melikadze Center for Enterprises Restructur<strong>in</strong>g andManagement AnalysisAvto Namicheishvili Begiashvili & Co.Vakhtang Shepardnadze Mgaloblishvili Kipiani DzidziguriGermanyWulf Bach SchufaJennifer Bierly-Seipp Gassner Stockmann & KollegenHans-Joachim Dohr Federal F<strong>in</strong>ancial Supervisory AuthorityUte Foshag Hogan & Hartson RaueKlaus Günther Oppenhoff & Rädler-L<strong>in</strong>klaters & AllianceManfred He<strong>in</strong>rich Deutsche BundesbankPeter Hoegen Allen & OveryChristof Kautzsch Haarmann HemmelrathJoerg Rossen CreditreformIngrid Seitz Deutsche BundesbankHolger Thomas SJ Berw<strong>in</strong> Knopf Tulloch Ste<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gerFrank Vogel SJ Berw<strong>in</strong> Knopf Tulloch Ste<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>gerGhanaReg<strong>in</strong>ald Bannerman Bruce-Lyle Bannerman & ThompsonStella Bentsi-Enchill Lexconsult & CoWilliam Fugar Fugar & Co Legal Practitioners and Notaries PublicDavid Hesse Hesse & Larsey Law FirmKenneth Laryea Laryea Laryea & Co PCD.A.K Mensah Central DatabankSam Okudzeto Sam Okudzeto & AssociatesLawrence Otto Fugar and CompanyJacob Saah PricewaterhouseCoopersV.J. Dela Selormey <strong>Bank</strong> of GhanaGreeceThemis Antoniou <strong>Bank</strong> of GreeceGeorgios Baz<strong>in</strong>as Anagnostopoulos Baz<strong>in</strong>as Fifis Counsellor &Attorneys at LawIoanna Bokorou Kyriakides-Georgopoulos Law FirmAngeliki Delicostopoulou A & A DelicostopoulouStefanoyannis Economou Law Offices Economou and AssociatesJohn Kyriakides Kyriakides-Geogropoulos Law FirmKonstant<strong>in</strong>os Mellios Sarantitis & PartnersEffie Mitsopoulou Kyriakides-Geogropoulos Law FirmDimitris Paraskevas Elias Sp. ParaskevasKleanthis Roussos Roussos Law FirmVictoria Zachopoulou TiresiasGuatemalaJuan Luis Aguilar Salguero Aguilar & ZarceñoAlfonso Carrillo Carrillo & AsociadosRodimiro Castaneda Super<strong>in</strong>tendencia de Bancos GuatemalaAnabella Chaclan Arenales & Sk<strong>in</strong>ner-KléeGuillermo Contreras Bancared ORBEJuan Diaz Lopez Super<strong>in</strong>tendencia de Bancos GuatemalaGabriela Maria Franco TransUnionRodolfo Fuentes Protectora de Credito ComercialEduardo Mayora Dawe Mayora & MayoraAlfredo Rodríguez-Mahuad Rodríguez Archila Castellanos Solares& AguilarLuis Turk Mejia Super<strong>in</strong>tendencia de Bancos GuatemalaGu<strong>in</strong>eaBoubacar Barry Boubacar Barry Law FirmHaitiYves Joseph <strong>Bank</strong> of the Republic of HaitiLouis Gary Lissade Cab<strong>in</strong>et LissadeSalim Succar Cab<strong>in</strong>et LissadeHondurasTania Casco Bufete Casco & AsociadosJorge Omar Casco Bufete Casco & AsociadosEstela Chavez TransUnionLeón Gómez B & B AbogadosLaureano Gutierrez Bufete Gutierrez FallaF. Dario Lobo Bufete Gutierrez FallaArmida Maria Lopez de Arguello ACZLAW Bufete Internacionalde AbogadosUlises Mejía B & B AbogadosAna Crist<strong>in</strong>a de Pereira Comisión Nacional de Bancos y Seguros,HondurasJose Ramon Paz J.R. Paz & AsociadosJose Rafael Rivera Ferrari J.R. Paz & AsociadosRene Lopez Rodezno Lopez Rodezno & AsociadosRoberto Zacarias Jr. Zacarias Aguilar & AsociadosVioleta Zuniga de Godoy Comision Nacional de Bancos y Seguros,HondurasHong Kong, Ch<strong>in</strong>aAndrew Baggio Baker & McKenzieBrian Barron Baker & McKenzieCharles Booth University of Hong KongTeresa Ma L<strong>in</strong>klaters


List of ContributorsRupert Nicholl Johnson Stokes & MasterRichard Tollan Johnson Stokes & MasterJim Hy Wong Hong Kong Monetary AuthorityAlex Yuen TransUnionShirley Yuen TransUnionHungaryCsendes Agnes Dessewffy Bellák & Partners Law OfficeBarbara Bognar Hungarian F<strong>in</strong>ancial Supervisory AuthorityTunde Ezsias Coface Intercredit HungaryGábor Felsen Köves Clifford Chance PünderGabor Horvàth Oppenheim ès Tàrsai Freshfields BruckhausDer<strong>in</strong>gerAndrea Jardi Nemeth Haarmann HemmelrathIstvan Nagy Creditreform Inter<strong>in</strong>foPéter Nógrádi Nógrádí Law OfficeKlara Oppenheim Oppenheim ès Tàrsai Freshfields BruckhausDer<strong>in</strong>gerÁdám Pethó´ Interbank Informatics ServicesKonrád Siegler Baker & McKenzieBenedek Sipöcz Dewey Ballant<strong>in</strong>eGábor Spitz Haarmann Hemmelrath & PartnerÁgnes Szent-Ivány Sándor Szegedi Szent-IványErica Voros Hungarian F<strong>in</strong>ancial Supervisory AuthorityIndiaR. Amurty Commerce & Co AgencyFreyan Desai Kachwaha & PartnersRajkumar Dubey S<strong>in</strong>ghania & CoR.J. Gagrat Gagrat & Co-Advocates & SolicitorsVishal Gandhi Nishith Desai AssociatesTrupti Garach Brand Farrar Buxbaum LLPRavi Kulkarni Little & CoN. Marwah Commerce & Co AgencyStephen Mathias Kochhar & Co BangaloreShri Vijay Mathur M<strong>in</strong>istry of F<strong>in</strong>ance Department of RevenueCentral Board of Direct TaxesDara Mehta Little & CoGanpat Raj Mehta India Law InfoS. K. Mitra Indian Investment CenterAjit Mittal Reserve <strong>Bank</strong> of IndiaRavi Nath Raj<strong>in</strong>der Nara<strong>in</strong> & CoG. S. Ram M<strong>in</strong>istry of LaborK.K. Ramani Laws4IndiaAbhishek Saket S<strong>in</strong>ghania & CoD.C. S<strong>in</strong>ghania S<strong>in</strong>ghania & CoSuhas Sr<strong>in</strong>ivasiah Kochhar & Co BangaloreK. Suresh StartupbazaarIndonesiaEman Achmad Lubis Santosa & MaulanaAbrahem Adr<strong>in</strong>aaz PricewaterhouseCoopersAndu Ambuml Investment Coord<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g BoardH.M.U. Fachri Asaari Warens & AchyarTheodoor Bakker Ali Budiardjo NugrohoReksodiputro Counsellors at LawSteven Bloom KPMGDanmawan Dgayusmam Investment Coord<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g BoardErwandi Hendarta Baker & McKenzieAli Imron Murim Central <strong>Bank</strong> of IndonesiaDarrell Johnson SSEK Indonesian Legal ConsultantsTimbul Thomas Lubis Lubis Ganie SurowidjojoBill Macdonald PricewaterhouseCoopersFerry Madian Nugroho ReksodiputroYoga Mulya Baker & McKenzieLuhut Pangaribuan Luhut M.P. Pangaribuan & PartnersBasuui Sidharta KPMGErnst Tehuteru Ali Budiardjo Nugroho Reksodiputro Counsellorsat LawIran, Islamic Rep. ofAlexander Aghayan Alexander Aghayan & AssociatesBehrooz Akhlaghi Dr. Behrooz Akhlaghi & AssociatesReza Askari Foreign Legal Affairs GroupB.F. Zar<strong>in</strong>-Ghalam <strong>Bank</strong><strong>in</strong>g Information DepartmentKater<strong>in</strong>a Miltiadou MecosParviz Savrai Dr. Parviz Savrai and AssociatesM. Shahabi Tavakoli & Shahabi Attorneys and Counselors at LawB.F. Zar<strong>in</strong>-Ghalam Central <strong>Bank</strong> of the Islamic Republic of IranIrelandAndrew Bates Dillon EustaceDeclan Black Mason Hayes & CurranTanya Colbert Mason Hayes & CurranAnthony Coll<strong>in</strong>s Eugene F. Coll<strong>in</strong>s SolicitorsKathryn Copeland Central <strong>Bank</strong> of IrelandJohn Doyle Dillon EustaceMelissa Jenn<strong>in</strong>gs Arthur CoxWilliam Johnston Arthur CoxN. McDonald Companies Registration OfficeMichael Meghen Arthur CoxDavid O’Donohoe Arthur CoxBarry O’Neill Eugene F. Coll<strong>in</strong>s SolicitorsDermot Rowe Dubl<strong>in</strong> CorporationMaurice Phelan Mason Hayes & CurranSeamus Tighearnaigh Irish Credit BureauDeirdre Ward Company Formations InternationalIsraelEli Arbel <strong>Bank</strong> of IsraelPaul Baris Yigal Arnon & Co.Gil Birger Embassy of Israel <strong>in</strong> Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DCSab<strong>in</strong>a Blank Small <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Authority of IsraelAmihud Doron A. Doron & Co.David Drutman Amihud Doron & Co., Law OfficesAlex Hertman S. Horowitz & Co.Zvi Howard Nixon Elchanan Landau Law OfficesP<strong>in</strong>chas Katz <strong>Bank</strong> of IsraelGideon Koren Ben Zvi KorenMichelle Liberman S. Horowitz & Co.Jakob Melcer E.S. Shimron I. Molho Persky & Co.Vazana Mordechai M<strong>in</strong>istry of F<strong>in</strong>anceVIVID Management SystemsStel P<strong>in</strong>hasov Embassy of Israel <strong>in</strong> Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DC185


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>186Eliot Sacks Herzog Fox & NeemanYaacov Salomon Lipschutz & Co.Asaf Samuel Lipschutz & Co.Ron Storch Global Credit ServicesDror Vigdor Yigal Arnon & Co.ItalyMaria Pia Ascenzo <strong>Bank</strong> of ItalyGiuseppe Alemani Mallet-Prevost Colt & MosleGian Bruno Bruni Bruni Gramell<strong>in</strong>i e AssociatiLisa Curran Allen & OveryFederico Dettori Gianni Origoni Grippo & PartnersGiuseppe Godano <strong>Bank</strong> of ItalyEnrico Lodi CRIFGiuseppe Lombardi Pedersoli Lombardi e AssociatiStefano Macchi di Cellere Studio Legale Macchi di Cellere eGangemiAlberto Maria Fornari Baker & McKenzie Giuseppe AlemaniCurtis Mallet-Prevost Colt & MosleFabrizio Mariotti Studio Legale BeltramoIda Marotta The Brosio Casati e AssociatiFrancesco Pensato Franzosi Dal NegroAndrea Rescigno White & Case – Varrenti e AssociatiNerio Saguatti Consorzio per la Tutela del CreditoPensato Setti Studio Legale Macchi di Cellere e GangemiVittorio Tadei Chiomenti Studio LegaleFabio Tortora Experian Credit BureauJamaicaRosslyn Combie Sykes Nunes Scholefield Deleon & Co.Dave Garcia Myers Fletcher & GordonGayon Hos<strong>in</strong> <strong>Bank</strong> of JamaicaAnthony Jenk<strong>in</strong>son Nunes Scholefield DeLeon & Co.Derek Jones Myers Fletcher & GordonRattray Misheca Seymour Myers Fletcher & GordonAlfred Rattray Myers Fletcher & GordonO. J. Rattray Patterson & RattrayJapanSh<strong>in</strong>ichiro Abe Credit Information Center CorpNaoki Eguchi Baker & McKenzieTamotsu Hatasawa Hatasawa & Wakai Law FirmOsamu Kawakami Japan Information Center CorpNobuaki Matsuoka Yamaguchi InternationalToshio Miyatake Law Firm Adachi Henderson Miyatake & FujitaSatoshi Ogishi Nishimura & PartnersYuji Onuki Asahi Law OfficesJeremy Pitts Baker & McKenzieSetsuko Sato CCBTomoe Sato Credit Information Center CorpGaku Suzuki Asahi Koma Law OfficesSh<strong>in</strong>jiro Takagi Industrial Revitalization Corporation of JapanTadeshi Yokoyama F<strong>in</strong>ancial Services AgencyJordanSami Al-Louzi Ali Sharif Zu’Bi & Sharif Ali Zu’BiNelly Batchoun Central <strong>Bank</strong> of JordanFrancis Bawab PricewaterhouseCoopersMicheal Dabit Micheal Dabit & Associates Attorneys at LawSalahel D<strong>in</strong>e Al-Bashir International <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Legal AssociatesYousef Khalilieh Rajai Dajani & Associates Law OfficeMichel Mazto M<strong>in</strong>istry of F<strong>in</strong>anceKater<strong>in</strong>a Miltiadou MecosShadi Zghoul DaJani & AssociatesAli Sharif Zu’bi Ali Sharif Zu’Bi & Sharif Ali Zu’BiKazakhstanAhmetzhan Abdulaev Grata Law FirmMadiar Balken Graduate Law Academy AdiletJohn W. Barnum McGuireWoods, KazakhstanYuri Bass<strong>in</strong> AequitasYuri A. Bolotov Michael Wilson & PartnersOlga Chentsova SalansMariya Gekko Baker & McKenzieEric Imashev McGuireWoods, KazakhstanKuliash Muratovna Iliasova Scientific Research Institute forPrivate Law, Humanities and Law UniversitySnezhana V. Popova McGuireWoods, KazakhstanJazykbaeva Raushan AequitasRichard Remias McGuireWoods, KazakhstanMarla Valdez Denton Wilde Sapte Law FirmValerie Zhakenov Zhakenov and Partners, <strong>in</strong> affiliation withWhite SavelievaRima Zhakupova SalansKenyaK.S. Anjarwalla Kapila Anjarwalla & Khanna AdvocatesBill Deverell Kaplan & StrattonW.S. Deverell Kaplan & StrattonOliver Fowler Kaplan & StrattonFiona Fox PricewaterhouseCoopersSheetal Kapila Kapila Anjarwalla & KhannaHamish Keith Daly & Figgis AdvocatesJohn Murugu Central <strong>Bank</strong> of KenyaWanjiru Nduati Kaplan & StrattonConrad Nyakuri PricewaterhouseCoopersFred Ochieng Kaplan & StrattonRichard Omwela Hamilton Harrison & Mathews Law FirmSonal Sejpal Kapila Anjarwalla & Khanna AdvocatesKorea, Rep. ofDuck-Soon Chang First Law Offices of KoreaEui Jong Chung Kim & LeeJu Myung Hwang Hwang Mok Park & J<strong>in</strong>James (Ik-Soo) Jeon Sojong PartnersDaniel Y. Kim Sojong PartnersGahng Hee Lee M<strong>in</strong>istry of LaborK. C. Lee Korea Trade-Investment Promotion AgencyDong Ch<strong>in</strong> Lim Chung & Suh Attorneys at LawSharon Noh Korea Information ServicesPaul Stephan Penczner Lee International IP & Law GroupKyung-Han Sohn Aram International Law OfficesSung-il Yang M<strong>in</strong>istry of Health and Welfare.


List of ContributorsKuwaitWalid Abd Elrahim Ahmed Abdullah Kh. Al-Ayoub & AssociatesAbdullah Kh. Al-Ayoub Abdullah Kh. Al-Ayoub & AssociatesMishare M. Al-Ghazali Mishare M. Al-Ghazali & PartnersRuba El- Habel Abdullah Kh. Al-Ayoub & AssociatesJasm<strong>in</strong> Koh<strong>in</strong>a Abdullah Kh. Al-Ayoub & AssociatesKyrgyz RepublicJulia Bulatova Law Firm PartnerGulnara Kalikova Chadbourne & ParkeNatalia Sidorovna Galiampova Third Arbitrage CourtNurlanbek Tynaev National <strong>Bank</strong> of the Kyrgyz RepublicEmil Oskonbale Sphynx ConsultMirgul Smanalieva Law Firm PartnerLarisa Tashtemirovna Zhanibekova Larisa TashtemirovnaZhanibekova Law FirmLao PDREdwards Nicholas DFDLIsabelle Rob<strong>in</strong>eau DFDLLouis-Mart<strong>in</strong> Desautels DFDLLatviaIr<strong>in</strong>a Ivanova F<strong>in</strong>ancial and Capital Markets CommissionDace Jenava A. Jenava BirojsFilip Klav<strong>in</strong>s Klav<strong>in</strong>s Slaid<strong>in</strong>s & LozeValters Kronbergs Kronbergs Law OfficeMonika Kuprijanova Council of Sworn Notaries of LatviaJuris Puce Creditreform LatvijaAnita Tamberga-Salmane Klav<strong>in</strong>s Slaid<strong>in</strong>s & LozeUgis Treilons Klav<strong>in</strong>s Slaid<strong>in</strong>s & LozeZiedonis Udris CB&M Law FirmAsnata Venckava IGK-SystemRomualds Vonsovics Lej<strong>in</strong>s Torgans & Vonsovics Ziedonis UdrisSkudra & UdrisLebanonAnto<strong>in</strong>e Abboud Law Office of A. Abboud & AssociatesWalid Alamudd<strong>in</strong> <strong>Bank</strong><strong>in</strong>g Control Commission of LebanonRamy Aoun Badri and Salim El Meouchi Law FirmRaymond Azar Raymond Azar Law OfficesRanda Bahsoun PricewaterhouseCoopersRaymonde Eid Badri and Salim El Meouchi Law FirmSadim El Meouchi Badri and Salim El Meouchi Law FirmRamzi George PricewaterhouseCoopersNabil Mallat Hyam Mallat Law OfficesYara Maroun The Law Offices of Tyan & ZgheibKater<strong>in</strong>a Miltiadou MecosFadi Moghaizel Moghaizel Law OfficesChandra Muki PricewaterhouseCoopersWalid Nasser Walid Nasser & AssociatesNada Abu Samra Badri and Salim El Meouchi Law FirmNady Tyan The Law Offices of Tyan & ZgheibLesothoStefan Carl Buys Du Preez Liebetrau & Co.Arshad Farouk Du Preez Liebetrau & Co.Margarete Higgs Du Preez Liebetrau & Co.LithuaniaRenata Berzanskiene Sora<strong>in</strong>en Law OfficesTomas Davidonis Sora<strong>in</strong>en Law OfficesDalia Foigt Regija Law FirmKornelija Francuzeviciute <strong>Bank</strong> of LithuaniaRolandas Galvenas Lideika Petrauskas Valiunas ir PartneriaiMarius Jakulis Jason AAA Law FirmM<strong>in</strong>daugas Kiškis Lideika Petrauskas Valiunas ir PartneriaiJurate Kugyte Lideika Petrauskas Valiunas ir PartneriaiMarius Navickas Foresta <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Law GroupRamunas Petravicius Lideika Petrauskas Valiunas ir PartneriaiKazimieras Ramonas <strong>Bank</strong> of LithuaniaLaimonas Skibarka Lideika Petrauskas Valiunas ir PartneriaiMarius Urbelis Sora<strong>in</strong>en Law OfficesVictor Vaitkevicius Kredol<strong>in</strong>eRolandas Valiunas Lideika Petrauskas Valiunas ir PartneriaiMacedonia, FYRZlatko Antevski Lawyers AntevskiDragana Vukobrat National <strong>Bank</strong> of the Republic of MacedoniaMadagascarRaphaël Jakoba MCI Law FirmHanta Radilofe Cab<strong>in</strong>et Félicien RadilofeTheodore Ramangalahy Commission de Supervision Bancaire etF<strong>in</strong>anciereHenri Bernard Razakariasa Banque Centrale de MadagascarMalawiRobert Atherstone Stumbles Sacranie Gow & Co.Rosel<strong>in</strong>e Gramani Savjani & Co.S. E. Jussab Sacranie Gow & Co.Shabir Latif Sacranie Gow & Co.W. R. Milonde Reserve <strong>Bank</strong> of MalawiBen Ndau Savjani & Associates Law FirmD.A. Ravel Wilson & MorganLoganath Sabapathy Logan Sabapathy & Co.MalaysiaSbdul Rahim Ali Registrar of CompaniesFrancis Chan Basis CorporationH. Y. Chong Azman Davidson & Co.Wong Chong Wah Skr<strong>in</strong>eJ. Wilfred Durai Azlan Za<strong>in</strong>, Za<strong>in</strong> & Co.Ch<strong>in</strong> Sok Ee <strong>Bank</strong> Negara MalaysiaWan Hashim Malaysian Industrial Development AuthorityMohammad Haszri Abu Hassan Azmi & AssociatesAr Karunakaran The Malaysian Industrial DevelopmentAuthorityChristopher Lee Baker & McKenzieAzmi Mohd Ali Azmi & AssociatesRajendra Navaratnam Azman Davidson & Co.Loganath Sabapathy Registrar of CompaniesFrancis Tan Azman Davidson & Co.Chung Tze Keog CTOS Sdn BhdJ. Wilfred Durai Za<strong>in</strong> & Co.Azlan Za<strong>in</strong> Za<strong>in</strong> & Co.187


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>188MaliVilevo Biova Devo Centrale des Risques de l’Union MonetaireOuest Africa<strong>in</strong>eSeydou Ibrahim Maiga Cab<strong>in</strong>et d’Avocats Seydou Ibrahim MaigaFrancois Nare Centrale des Risques de l’Union Monetaire OuestAfrica<strong>in</strong>eMauritaniaA. S. Bouhoubeyni Cab<strong>in</strong>et BouhoubeyniOuld Bouhoubeyni Ahmed Salem Ould Bouhoubeyni AhmedSalem Law FirmMexicoGerardo Carreto-Chávez Barrera Siqueiros y Torres LandaAttorneys at LawMaría Casas Baker & McKenzieCarlos Grimm Baker & McKenzieEduardo Heftye López Velarde Heftye y SoriaBill Kryzda Goodrich Riquelme Y AsociadosJorge Leon-Orantes Goodrich Riquelme Y AsociadosEduardo Llamosa ProfancresaEnrique Nort Comision Nacional Bancaria y de ValoresPablo Perezalonso Ritch Heather y MuellerJose Luis Quiroz Mateos W<strong>in</strong>stead y RiveraRafael Ramirez Arroyo Martínez Algaba Estrella De Haro yGalvan-DuqueJuan Manuel R<strong>in</strong>cón Franck Galicia y RoblesArturo Saavedra Rodríguez Rodríguez Vega Rubio Y AsociadosMart<strong>in</strong>ez Arrieta Rodríguez Vega Rubio Y AsociadosCarlos Sanchez-Mejorada Sanchez-Mejorada y PasquelJuan Francisco Torres-Landa R. Barrera Siqueiros y Torres LandaSC Attorneys at LawMoldovaDavid Brodsky Brodsky Uskov Looper Reed & PartnersProcop Buruiana Buruiana & PartnersStela Cibotari National <strong>Bank</strong> of MoldovaVictoria Ciofu National <strong>Bank</strong> of MoldovaIurie Lungu Lev<strong>in</strong>tsa & AssociatesVictor Lev<strong>in</strong>tsa Lev<strong>in</strong>tsa & AssociatesIr<strong>in</strong>a Moghiliova Brodsky Uskov Looper Reed & PartnersAlexander Turcan Turcan & TurcanMongoliaBayarmaa Badarch Lynch & MahoneyBatzaya Bodikhuu Anderson & Anderson MongoliaDavid Buxbaum Anderson & Anderson MongoliaL. Chimgee <strong>Bank</strong> of MongoliaMaurice Lynch Lynch & MahoneyDaniel Mahoney Lynch & MahoneyUlziideleg Taivan Credit Information BureauMoroccoMyriam Bennani Hajji & Associés Association d’AvocatsRichard Cant<strong>in</strong> Cab<strong>in</strong>et Naciri & AssociésFrédéric Elbar C.M.S. Bureau Francis Lefebvre MarocAm<strong>in</strong> Hajji Am<strong>in</strong> Hajji Law OfficesAzzed<strong>in</strong>e Kettani Kettani Law FirmNadia Kettani Kettani Law FirmAhmed Lahrache <strong>Bank</strong> Al-MaghribHicham Naciri Cab<strong>in</strong>et Naciri & AssociésMehdi Salmouni-Zerhouni Hajji & Associés Association d’AvocatsMozambiqueAlexandra Carvalho Vasconcelos Porto & AsociadosCarlos de Sousa e Brito Carlos de Sousa e Brito & AssociadosAntonio de Vasconcelos Porto Vasconcelos Porto & AsociadosAquiles Dimene Vasconcelos Porto & AsociadosRita Furtado H.Gamito, Cuito, Goncalves Pereira, Castelo Branco& AssociadoJoao Mart<strong>in</strong>s PricewaterhouseCoopersCarol Christie Smit American Embassy <strong>in</strong> MaputoBonifácia Mario Suege <strong>Bank</strong> of MozambiqueEric Whitaker American Embassy <strong>in</strong> MaputoNamibiaHanno Bossau Lorentz & BoneNatasha Cochrane P.F. Koep & Co.Peter P.F. Koep & Co Frank Koep P.F. Koep & Co.Richard Mueller P.F. Koep & Co.Phillip Mwangala <strong>Bank</strong> of NamibiaDeon Obbes Lorentz & BoneMarius van Breda Information Trust CorporationNepalIndra Lohani Dhruba Bar S<strong>in</strong>gh Thapa & AssociatesSurendra Man Pradhan Nepal Rastra <strong>Bank</strong>Kusum Shrestha Kusum Law FirmSudheer Shrethha Kusum Law FirmSajjan Thapa Dhruba Bar S<strong>in</strong>gh Thapa & AssociatesBharat Rej Upreti Pioneer Law AssociatesNetherlandsRob Abendroth Allen & OveryCasper Banz Houthoff BurumaMichiel Gorsira Simmons & SimmonsGlenn Haulussy Haulussy AdvokatenM. de Kogel De Netherlandshe <strong>Bank</strong>R. Koster Chamber of Commerce AmsterdamJoop Lobste<strong>in</strong> Sticht<strong>in</strong>g Bureau Krediet RegistratieL. Moll Chamber of CommercePiet Schroeder Baker & McKenzieJaap-Jan Trommel NautaDutilh AttorneysPeter Wakkie De Brauw Blackstone WestbroekMarcel Willems Kennedy Van der LaanNew ZealandTim Buckley Chapman TrippNiels Campbell Bell GullyMargaret Griff<strong>in</strong> Reserve <strong>Bank</strong> of New ZealandPaul Heath High Court of New ZealandJan<strong>in</strong>e Jackson Baycorp AdvantageKirri Lynn Companies’ OfficeLaurence Mayne Russell McVeagh


List of ContributorsLee-Ann McArthur NZ Companies OfficeRichard Peach Baycorp AdvantageNicola Penman-Chambers Simpson GriersonCharlotte Rose Simpson GriersonDouglas Seymour Alderslade Chapman TrippPeter Sheer<strong>in</strong> Baycorp AdvantageArthur Young Chapman TrippNicaraguaRoberto Arguello F.A. Arias & Muñoz Law FirmCarlos Bonilla Super<strong>in</strong>tendencia de Bancos y de OtrasInstituciones F<strong>in</strong>ancierasJose Evenor Taboada Taboada & AsociadosMaría José Guerrero F.A. Arias & Muñoz Law FirmPedro Muñoz F.A. Arias & Muñoz Law FirmAna Rizo F.A. Arias & Muñoz Law FirmOscar Silva Delaney & AssociatesNigerVilevo Biova Devo Centrale des Risques de l’Union MonetaireOuest Africa<strong>in</strong>eSamna Daouda Ohada LegisAïssatou Djibo Maitre Djibo AissatouBernar-Oliver Kouaovi Cab<strong>in</strong>et KouaoviFrancois Narem Centrale des Risques de l’Union MonetaireOuest Africa<strong>in</strong>eNigeriaLara Ademola Lara Ademola & Co.John Adetiba PricewaterhouseCoopersDaniel Agbor Udo Udoma & Belo-OsagieOluseyi Abiodun Ak<strong>in</strong>wunmi Ak<strong>in</strong>wunmi & BusariSamuel Etuk Etuk & UruaAnse Ezetha Chief Law Agu Ezetah & Co.Mohammed Ibrahim Embassy of Nigeria <strong>in</strong> Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DCO. I. Imala Central <strong>Bank</strong> of NigeriaEvelyne Mandessi Bell Mandessi Bell Law FirmNdubisi Chuks Nwasike Chuks Nwasike SolicitorChike Obianwu Udo Udoma & Belo-OsagieUzoma Ogbonna Chief Law Agu Ezetah & Co.Joy Okeaya-Inneh Chief Rotimi Williams’ ChambersNorwayEdgar Barsgoe M<strong>in</strong>istry of Labor and Government Adm<strong>in</strong>istrationMorten Beck Advokatfirmaet PricewaterhouseCoopersFrode Berntsen Advokatfirmaet PricewaterhouseCoopersPaul Buche Tax Law DepartmentLars Carlsson Credit<strong>in</strong>formF<strong>in</strong>n Erik Engzelius Thommessen Greve LundSte<strong>in</strong> Fagerhaug Thommessen Greve LundClaus Fl<strong>in</strong>der Simonsen Føyen AdvokatfirmaHans Haugstad Thommessen Greve LundAase Aa. Lundgaard Deloitte Touche TohmatsuGlenn McKenzie Brønnøysund Register CentreGuri Midttun Norwegian Trade CouncilChristian Mueller Thommessen Greve LundF<strong>in</strong>n Rime Rime & Co. AdvokatfirmaVegard Sivertsen Deloitte & Touche, NorwayLisbeth Strand The <strong>Bank</strong><strong>in</strong>g, Insurance and SecuritiesCommission of NorwayAnne Thorsheim Oslo <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong>Elste Torsvik M<strong>in</strong>istry of Labor and Government Adm<strong>in</strong>istrationSverre Tyrhaug Thommessen Greve LundPreben Willoch Advokatfirmaet PricewaterhouseCoopersOmanMansoor Jamal Malik Al Alawi Mansoor Jamal & Co.PakistanMasood Khan Afridi Afridi & Angell & KhanM. Bilal Aftab News-VIS Credit Information ServicesShamim Ahmed Securities and Exchange CommissionSalman Aslam Butt Cornelius Lane & MuftiMohammad Azam Chaudhry Azam Chaudhry Law AssociatesSyed Ahmad Hassan Shah Afridi & Angell & KhanIshrat Husa<strong>in</strong> State <strong>Bank</strong> of PakistanKairas Kabraji Kabraji & Talibudd<strong>in</strong>Muhammad Khalid Javed Board of Investment, PakistanMuhammad Akram Khan Board of Investment, PakistanSikandar Hassan Khan Cornelius Lane & MuftiRashad Miyan Board of Investment, PakistanBabar Mufti International Credit InformationAmna Piracha International Credit InformationTalat Rasheed Board of Investment, PakistanMuhammad Saleem Credit Information BureauHaider Shamsi Haider Shamsi and Co.PanamaLeonor Alvarado Alvarado Ledezma & De SanctisEbrahim Asvat Patton Moreno & AsvatEric Britton Infante Garrido & Garrido AbogadosDelia Cardenas Super<strong>in</strong>tendencia de Bancos de PanamaJulio Cesar Contreras III Arosemena Noriega & ContrerasJorge Garrido M. Infante Garrido & GarridoFrancisco Pérez Ferreira Patton Moreno & AsvatLizbeth Ramsey Asociación Panameña de CréditoAnalita Romero KPMGJuan Tejada Mora Icaza Gonzalez-Ruiz & AlemanPapua New Gu<strong>in</strong>eaKirsten Kobus Allens Arthur Rob<strong>in</strong>sonV<strong>in</strong>cent Bull Allens Arthur Rob<strong>in</strong>sonRio Fiocco Posman Kua Aisi LawyersRichard Flynn Blake Dawson WaldronParaguayHugo Berkemeyer Berkemeyer Attorneys and CounselorsLuis Breuer Berkemeyer Attorneys and CounselorsEsteban Burt Peroni Sosa Tellechea Burt & NarvajaPeruMarco Antonio Alarcón Piana Estudio Luis Echecopar GarciaLuis Felipe Arizmendi Echecopar Super<strong>in</strong>tendencia de Bancos ySeguros del Peru189


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>190Guilhermo Alceu Auler Muniz Forsyth Ramirez Perez-Taiman &Luna VictoriaLuís Fuentes Barrios Fuentes UrquiagaManuel Olaechea Du BoisAlonso Rey Bustamante Payet Rey Cauvi AbogadosRicardo Silva Muniz Law FirmManuel Villa-García Estudio OlaecheaG<strong>in</strong>o Zolezzi CerticomPhilipp<strong>in</strong>esMarissa Aca<strong>in</strong> PhilBizInfoTheresa Ballelos Baker & McKenzieManuel Batallones BAP Credit BureauAngelica Cayas Board of InvestmentKenneth Chua Castillo Laman Tan Pantaleon & San JoseEmerico De Guzman Angara Abello Concepcion Regala & CruzBenjam<strong>in</strong> Dela Cruz Board of InvestmentsMila Digan Board of InvestmentsNestor Espenilla Central <strong>Bank</strong> of the Philipp<strong>in</strong>esGilberto Gallos Abello Concepción Regala & CruzAndres Gatmaitan Sycip Salazar Hernandez & GatmaitanTadeo Hilado Abello Concepcion Regala & CruzNatividad Kwan Baker & McKenzieRomeo Mendoza Romulo Mabanta Buenaventura Sayoc &de Los AngelesYolanda Mendoza-Eleazar Castillo Laman Tan Pantaleon &San Jose.Efren Lee No Investment Management DepartmentNicanor Padilla Siguion Reyna, Montecillo & Ongsiako LawOfficesPolo Pantaleón Castillo Laman Tan Pantaleon & San JoseEmmanuel Paras Cecile M.E. CaroTeodoro Regala Angara Abello Concepcion Regala & CruzRicardo Romulo Romulo Mabanta Buenaventura Sayoc &de Los AngelesRoger Sapanta Board of InvestmentsTess Sianghio-Baac Abello Concepcion Regala & CruzCirilo T Tolosa Sycip Salazar Hernandez & GatmaitanPolandTomasz Brudkowski Kochanski Brudkowski & PartnersRenata Cichocka Haarmann HemmelrathSlawomir Domzal Biuro Informacji KredytowejMaciej Duszczyk Biuro Informacji KredytowejPawe l Ignatjew Baker & McKenzieIwona Janeczek Commercial Debtor Register/KSV InformationServicesTomasz Kanski Soltysiñski Kawecki & SzlezakKatarzyna Kompowska Coface Intercredit PolandPetr Kucera Aspekt KilcullenWojciech Kwasniak National <strong>Bank</strong> of PolandBartlomiej Raczkowski Soltysiñski Kawecki & SzlezakJean Rossi Gide Loyrette Nouel PolskaTomasz Stawecki Baker & McKenziePrzemyslaw Pietrzak Nörr Stiefenhofer LutzRobert Siuchmo Biuro Informacji KredytowejAnna Talar Jeschke Haarmann HemmelrathTomasz Turek Nikiel & ZacharzewskiTomasz Wardynski Wardynski & PartnersRobert W<strong>in</strong>dmill Haarmann HemmelrathSteven Wood TGC Polska Law FirmPortugalFernando Res<strong>in</strong>a Da Silva Vieira de Almeida & AssociadosJoão Cadete de Matos Banco de PortugalCrist<strong>in</strong>a De<strong>in</strong> Jalles AdvogadosRosemary de Rougemont Neville de Rougemont & AssociadosCarlos de Sousa e Brito Carlos de Sousa e Brito & AsociadosPaulo Lowndes Marques Abreu & Marques V<strong>in</strong>has e AssociadosFernando Marta Cred<strong>in</strong>formacoesInês Batalha Mendes Abreu Cardigos & AsociadosMiguel de Avillez Pereira Abreu Cardigos & AsociadosVicky Rodriguez Neville de Rougemont & Asociados Sociedade deAdvogadosAna Isabel Vieira Banco de PortugalPuerto RicoVicente Antonetti Goldman Antonetti & CordovaMarcelo Lopez Goldman Antonetti & CordovaRomaniaPhilip Ankel Moore Vartires & Associates SCPATiberiu Csaki Altheimer & Gray MooreTeodor Gigea Coface Intercredit RomaniaVeronica Gruzsnicki Babiuc Sulica & AssociatesAndrea Ionescu Altheimer & Gray MooreCor<strong>in</strong>a Gabriela Ionescu Nestor Nestor Diculescu K<strong>in</strong>gstonPetersenNicoleta Kalman Nicoleta Kalman Law OfficeDaniel Lungu Racoti Predoiu & PartnersElena Mirea Delos Credit<strong>in</strong>foIon I. Nestor Nestor Nestor Diculescu K<strong>in</strong>gston PetersenTheodor Nicolescu Theodor Nicolescu Law OfficeDavid Stabb S<strong>in</strong>clair Roche & TemperleyAr<strong>in</strong> Octav Stanescu National Association of Practitioners <strong>in</strong>Reorganization and W<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g UpParaschiva Suica-Neagu Nestor Nestor Diculescu K<strong>in</strong>gstonPetersenValeria Tomesou Credit reform RomaniaCatal<strong>in</strong> Tripon Babiuc Sulica & AssociatesFlorent<strong>in</strong> Tuca Musat & AsociatiiPetre Tul<strong>in</strong> National <strong>Bank</strong> of RomaniaPerry Zizzi Moore Vartires & Associates SCPARussian FederationIr<strong>in</strong>a Astrakhan PricewaterhouseCoopersPeter Barenboim Moscow Interbank Currency ExchangeChristian Becker Haarmann Hemmelrath & PartnerMaria Blagowol<strong>in</strong>a Haarmann Hemmelrath & PartnerVladimir Dragunov Baker & McKenzieIgor Gorchakov Baker & McKenzieJohn Hammond CMS Cameron McKennaDavid Lasfargue Gide Loyrette NouelSergei Lazarev Russ<strong>in</strong> & Vecchi


List of ContributorsLudmila Malykh<strong>in</strong>a CMS Cameron McKennaAlexey Simanovskiy <strong>Bank</strong> of RussiaVladislav Talantsev Russ<strong>in</strong> & VecchiRwandaJean Haguma Haguma & AssociesAngelique Kantengwa National <strong>Bank</strong> of RwandaSaudi ArabiaFahd Al-Mufarrij Saudi Arabian Monetary AgencyMujahid Al-Sawwaf Law Offices of Dr. Mujahid M. Al-SawwafMohammed Jaber Nader Nader LawHassan Mahassni Law Offices of Hassan MahassniFrancois Majdy Kasseem Al-Fallaj Law FirmKater<strong>in</strong>a Miltiadou MecosAkram Mohamed Nader Nader LawSameh Toban Toban Law FirmEbaish Zebar Law Firm of Salah Al-HejailanySenegalVilevo Biova Devo Centrale des Risques de l’Union MonetaireOuest Africa<strong>in</strong>eAboubacar Fall Fall Associates Law OfficesCheikh Fall Cheikh Fall Law OfficesMame Adama Gueye SCP Mame Adama Gueye & AssociesMamadou Mbaye SCP Mame Adama Gueye & AssociésIbrahima Mbodj Etude Maitre Ibrahima MbodjFrancois Nare Centrale des Risques de l’Union MonetaireOuest Africa<strong>in</strong>eFrançois Sarr François Sarr & AssociesMamadou Seck SCP Sow SeckSerbia and MontenegroMiroslav Basic Studio Legale SuttiYorgos Chairetis IKRP Rokas & PartnersIlija Drazic Drazic Lazarevic & BeatovicKerim Karabdic Advokati Salih & Kerim KarabdicDubravka Kosic Kosic & SuttiNikola Kosic Agency Sportnet DiNMirko Lovric National <strong>Bank</strong> of Serbia and MontenegroNeli Markovic Credit Information SystemMilos Zivkovic Zivkovic & Samardzic Law OfficeSierra LeoneEmmanuel Roberts Roberts & PartnersS<strong>in</strong>gaporeLeslie Chew SC Khattar Wong & PartnersTan Peng Ch<strong>in</strong> Tan Peng Ch<strong>in</strong>Cheah Swee Gim Kelv<strong>in</strong> Chia PartnershipDeborah Eval<strong>in</strong>e Barker Khattar Wong & PartnersNg Wai K<strong>in</strong>g Venture LawTham Yew Kong Monetary Authority of S<strong>in</strong>gaporeAngela Lim Baker & McKenzieDaphne Teo Monetary Authority of S<strong>in</strong>gaporeL<strong>in</strong>coln Teo Credit Bureau S<strong>in</strong>gaporeLee Kuan Wei Venture LawJennifer Yeo Yeo-Leong & PehSamuel Yuen David Lim & PartnersSlovak RepublicMart<strong>in</strong> Bednár HMG & PartnersKatar<strong>in</strong>a Cechova Advokátska kanceláriaMilan Horvath National <strong>Bank</strong> of SlovakiaTomáš Kamenec Dedák & PartnersRenátus Kollár Allen & OveryPetr Kucera Aspekt Kilcullen sVladimir Malik Coface Intercredit SlovakiaČechová Rakovský Advokátska kanceláriaZuzana Valerova PricewaterhouseCoopersSloveniaCrtomir Borec Deloitte & ToucheStane Berlec Trade and Investment Promotion OfficeSimon Bracun Colja Rojs & PartnerjiPetra Drobne Small <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Development CenterJoze Golobic Small <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> Development CenterVilma Hanzel <strong>Bank</strong> of SloveniaSreco Jadek Odvetniska Fisarna Jadek & PensaAndrej Jarkovič Selih Selih Janezic & JarkovicDenis Kostrevc Deloitte & ToucheGerald Lambert Deloitte & ToucheKlemen Sesok Deloitte & ToucheIrena Skocir Coface Intercredit SlovenijaBarbara Smolnikar SKB <strong>Bank</strong>a DDSouth AfricaMarianne Brown Institute for Public F<strong>in</strong>ance and Audit<strong>in</strong>gPeter Eugene Whelan Bowman Gilfillan F<strong>in</strong>dlay & TaitMike Forsyth Austen Smith AttorneysDavid Garegae Greater Pretoria Metropolitan CouncilTim Gordon-Grant Bowman GilfillanDesere Jordaan LT Attorneys Notaries & ConveyancersRenee Kruger Webber Wentzel BowensFrancis Manickum Department of Trade and IndustryAndrew Muir Austen Smith AttorneysJohan Neser Cliffe DekkerLaurence Pereira Vorster PereiraJoe Pietersen South Africa Reserve <strong>Bank</strong>Hugo Stark South Africa Reserve <strong>Bank</strong>Jacques Van Wyk Cliffe DekkerGreg Ward TransUnion ITCDavid Watk<strong>in</strong>s Bowman GilfillanPhillip Webster LeBoeuf Lamb Greene & MacRaeRalph Zulman Supreme Court of Appeal of South AfricaSpa<strong>in</strong>Agustí Bou Maqueda Jausas, Nadal & VidalAriadna Cambronero Uría & MenéndezSoledad Cruces de Abia <strong>Bank</strong> of Spa<strong>in</strong>Sergio del Bosque Uría & MenéndezAnselmo Diaz Fernández <strong>Bank</strong> of Spa<strong>in</strong>Alejandro Ferreres Uría & MenéndezAna Just Iuris Valls Abogados191


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>192Alfonso Pedrajas MulleratArturo Ra<strong>in</strong>er Pan Echecopar Abogados Law FirmEduardo Rodriguez Rovira Uria & MenendezMaria Gracia Rubio Baker & McKenzieRafael Sebastián Uría & MenéndezMiguel Torres The Bufete Mullerat Law FirmCarlos Valls Iuris Valls AbogadosCarlos Viladás Jené Uría & MenéndezSri LankaAsanka Abeysekera Tichurelvam AssociatesN. P. H. Amarasena Credit Information Bureau of Sri LankaSavantha De Saram D. L. & F. De SaramSharmela De Silva Tichurelvam AssociatesDesmond Fernando Fernando & Co.T.G. Gooneratne Julius & Creasy Solicitors Attorneys at LawAnanda Lecamwasam PricewaterhouseCoopersRamani Muttetuwegama Tichurelvam AssociatesKandiah Neelakandan Kandiah Neelakandan Law FirmAruni Rajakariar National Development <strong>Bank</strong>P. Samarasiri Central <strong>Bank</strong> of Sri LankaR. Senathi Rajah Julius & Creasy Solicitors Attorneys at LawNiranjan S<strong>in</strong>nethamby Tiruchelvam AssociatesNeelan Tiruchelvam Tiruchelvam AssociatesJohn Wilson Jr. John Wilson PartnersSwedenMats Berter Magnusson Wahl<strong>in</strong> Qvist Stanbrook AdvokatbyraTommy Bisander UC ABVibekke Eliasson F<strong>in</strong>ans<strong>in</strong>spektionenJörgen Estv<strong>in</strong>g Magnusson Wahl<strong>in</strong> Qvist Stanbrook AdvokatbyråElisabet Fura-Sandstrom Advokatfirman V<strong>in</strong>ge & KBLeif Gustafsson Baker & McKenzieEric Halvarsson Hammarskiöld & Co.Peder Hammarskiöld Hammarskiöld & Co.Paula Hammarstrom Andersson Magnusson Wahl<strong>in</strong> QvistStanbrook AdvokatbyraStefan Holmberg Gärde WesslauJohn Henwood Rob<strong>in</strong>son BertramMargret Inger F<strong>in</strong>ans<strong>in</strong>spektionenMattias Larsson Advokatfirman Cederquist KBKnox Nxumalo Rob<strong>in</strong>son BertramLars Nylund Advokatfirman FylgiaCecilia Rembert Invest <strong>in</strong> Sweden AgencyMart<strong>in</strong> Wall<strong>in</strong> L<strong>in</strong>klaters LagerlöfSwitzerlandPeter R. Altenburger Altenburger & PartnersKarl Arnold Pestalozzi Lachenal PatryVischer Frédéric Bétrisey Baker & McKenzieChristian Etter Swiss Embassy <strong>in</strong> Wash<strong>in</strong>gton, DCRolf Gertsch Swiss Federal <strong>Bank</strong><strong>in</strong>g CommissionErw<strong>in</strong> Griesshammer VischerHans R. H<strong>in</strong>termeister ZEK SwitzerlandIur. Yvonne H<strong>in</strong>termeister Handelsregisteramt des Kantons ZurichAndrea Mol<strong>in</strong>o Spiess Brunoni Pedrazz<strong>in</strong>i Mol<strong>in</strong>oGuy-Philippe Rubeli Pestalozzi Lachenal PatryKurt Sp<strong>in</strong>nler Swiss Federal <strong>Bank</strong><strong>in</strong>g CommissionSyrian Arab RepublicKanaan Al-Ahmar Al-Ahmar & PartnersHani Bitar Syrian Arab Consultants Law OfficeRiad Daoudi Syrian Arab Consultants Law OfficeAntoun Joubran Syrian Arab Consultants Law OfficeMuhammed Jumma <strong>Bank</strong> of SyriaFadi Kardous Kardous Law OfficeKater<strong>in</strong>a Miltiadou MecosMoussa Mittry Louka & MitryGabriel Oussi Syrian Arab Consultants Law OfficeTaiwan, Ch<strong>in</strong>aJack J. T. Huang Jones DaySer<strong>in</strong>a Chung Jones DayJulie Chu Jones DayAngela Wu Yangm<strong>in</strong>g PartnersMark Ohlson Yangm<strong>in</strong>g PartnersEdgar Chen Tsar & Tsai Law FirmJohn Chen Formosa Transnational Attorneys at LawHelen Chou Russ<strong>in</strong> & Vecchi LLCPatrick Pai-Chiang Chu Lee and LiJoyce Fan Lee and LiJames Hwang Tsar & Tsai Law FirmEdward Lai Central <strong>Bank</strong> of Ch<strong>in</strong>aBee Leay Teo Baker & McKenzieJust<strong>in</strong> Liang Baker & McKenzieJeffrey L<strong>in</strong> Jo<strong>in</strong>t Credit Information CenterJennifer L<strong>in</strong> Tsar & Tsai Law FirmJen Kong Loh Alliance International Law OfficesThomas McGowan Russ<strong>in</strong> & Vecchi LLCShiau Pan Yang Lee and LiTanzaniaNaimi Dyer Mkono & Co. Law FirmAdemba Gomba Gomba & Co. AdvocatesA. K. Kameja Kameja & Nguluma AdvocatesWilbert Kap<strong>in</strong>ga Mkono & Co. Law FirmPaul<strong>in</strong>e Kasonda Mkono & Co. Law FirmIshengoma Masha Mujulizi & Magai AdvocatesL.H. Mkila <strong>Bank</strong> of TanzaniaNimrod Mkono Mkono & Co. Law FirmCharles Rwechungura Maajar Rwechungura & KamejaMaajar Rwechungura Kameja & Nguluma AdvocatesConstant<strong>in</strong>e Rweyemamu Mutalemwa Masha Mujulizi & MagaiAdvocatesHenry Sato Massaba Kameja & Nguluma AdvocatesLeopold Thomas Kagula Kalunga & CompanyThailandRujira Bunnag Marut Bunnag International Law OfficeVira Kammee International Legal Counsellors ThailandKhun Kanok Thailand-US <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> CouncilKomkrit Kietduriyakul Baker & McKenzieDej-Udom Krairit Dej-Udom & AssociatesK. Kunjara Thai Credit BureauDavid Lyman Tilleke & Gibb<strong>in</strong>s InternationalSteven Miller Johnson Stokes & Master


List of ContributorsCynthia Pornavalai Tilleke & Gibb<strong>in</strong>s InternationalNuttida Samalapa Baker & McKenzieAnongporn Thanachaiary Tilleke & Gibb<strong>in</strong>s InternationalBoonchai Thaveekittikul Boonchai Arthur AndersenHarold Vickery Jr. Vickery & WorachaiPimvimol Vipamaneerut Tilleke & Gibb<strong>in</strong>s InternationalPrapakorn Wannakano <strong>Bank</strong> of ThailandTogoJean-Marie Adenka Cab<strong>in</strong>et AdenkaVilevo Biova Devo Centrale des Risques de l’Union MonetaireOuest Africa<strong>in</strong>eFrancois Nare Centrale des Risques de l’Union Monetaire OuestAfrica<strong>in</strong>eTunisiaBadredd<strong>in</strong>e Barkia Central <strong>Bank</strong> of TunisiaBouaziz Belaiba Yasm<strong>in</strong>a SorencoAdly Bellagha Adly Bellagha & AssociatesLam<strong>in</strong>e Bellagha Adly Bellagha and AssociatesCel<strong>in</strong>e Dupont Ferchiou & Associates Meziou KnaniSalahedd<strong>in</strong>e Caid Essebsi The Salahedd<strong>in</strong>e Caid Essebsi& AssociatesFaiza Feki Central <strong>Bank</strong> of TunisiaNouredd<strong>in</strong>e Ferchiou Ferchiou & Associates Meziou KnaniElyès Ben Mansour Gide Loyrette Nouel TunisieFaouzi Mili Mili and AssociatesIlhem Ouanes Tekaya Ferchiou & AssociesKamel Ben Salah Gide Loyrette Nouel TunisieTurkeyBurcu Acarturk Pek<strong>in</strong> & Pek<strong>in</strong>I. Hakki Arslan Central <strong>Bank</strong> of the Republic of TurkeyErol Bircanoglu Jr. Bircanoglu Law FirmIbrahim Canakci <strong>Bank</strong><strong>in</strong>g Regulation and Supervision AgencyMesut Cakmak Cakmak Ortak Avukat BurosuZeynep Cakmak Cakmak Ortak Avukat BurosuFadlullah Cerrahoglu Mehmet Can EkzenKazim Derman KKB Kredi Kayit BurosuSemiha Gorgulu Yamaner & YamanerAli Gozutok Pek<strong>in</strong> & Pek<strong>in</strong>Selen Gures Law Offices of M. Fadlullah CerrahogluFahri Okumus Central <strong>Bank</strong> of the Republic of TurkeySebnem Onder Cakmak Ortak Avukat BurosuEser Ozer Anorbis Uluslararasi Bilgi MerkeziAhmed Pek<strong>in</strong> Pek<strong>in</strong> & Pek<strong>in</strong>Y. Selim Sariibrahimoglu DTB Dis Ticaret Bilgi MerkeziYesim Sezg<strong>in</strong>gil DTB Dis Ticaret Bilgi MerkeziPaul Sheridan Denton Wilde Sapte & GunerSelcuk Tayfun Ok Chamber of CommerceAysegül Yalç<strong>in</strong>mani Law Offices of M. Fadlullah CerrahogluMehtap Yildirim-Ozturk Cakmak Ortak Avukat BurosuUgandaJust<strong>in</strong>e Bagyenda <strong>Bank</strong> of UgandaMoses Jurua Adriko Adriko & Karugaba AdvocatesOscar Kambona Kampala Associated AdvocatesMasembe Kanyerezi Mugerwa & MasembeSim Katende Katende Sempebwa & Co. AdvocatesDavid Mpanga Mugerwa & Masembe AdvocatesGabriel Mpubani Gabriel Mpubani Law OfficesRose Namarome Odere & Nalyanya Law FirmCharles Odere Odere & Nalyanya Law FirmJust<strong>in</strong> Semuyaba Semuyaba Iga & Co. AdvocatesAlan Shonubi Shonubi Musoke & Co.Ukra<strong>in</strong>eValeria Kazadarova Baker & McKenzieJames T. Hitch Baker & McKenzieOlyana Rudyakova Baker & McKenzieOleg Alyosh<strong>in</strong> Vasil Kisil & PartnersNatalia Artemova Grischenko & PartnersDaniel Bilak Jurvneshservice Attorneys & CounselsSerhiy Chorny Baker & McKenzieOlexandr Fedoriv Credit Rat<strong>in</strong>g Agency SlavRat<strong>in</strong>gAnna Glob<strong>in</strong>a Altheimer & GrayYaroslav Gregirchak Magister & PartnersJames Hitch III Baker & McKenzieRuslan Israpilov Grischenko & PartnersAleksandr Kireyev National <strong>Bank</strong> of Ukra<strong>in</strong>eSergei Konnov Konnov Law OfficesSvetlana Kustova Konnov Law OfficesOlexander Mart<strong>in</strong>enko Scott and Mart<strong>in</strong>enko Law FirmAndrii Palianytsia LCPSMarkian Silecky Silecky Law FirmMykola Stetsenko Scott and Mart<strong>in</strong>enko Law FirmSergei Voitovich Grischenko & PartnersAlexander Yefimov Alexander Yefomiv Law OfficesOleg Z<strong>in</strong>kevych Kravets & LevenetsUnited Arab EmiratesMurad Abida Hadef Al Dhahiri & AssociatesBashir Ahmed Afridi & AngellSaeed Abdulla Al Hamiz Central <strong>Bank</strong> of the United Arab EmiratesHabib Al Mulla Habib Al Mulla & Co.Hassen Ferris Afridi & AngellNabil Issa Afridi & AngellKater<strong>in</strong>a Miltiadou MecosStephen Rodd Bryan CaveJonathan Silver Clyde & Co.United K<strong>in</strong>gdomKenneth Baird Freshfields Bruckhaus Der<strong>in</strong>gerRichard Boulton F<strong>in</strong>ancial Services AuthorityGreg Boyd Baker & McKenzieRichard Clark Slaughter & MayJohn Hadlow ExperianAndrew Haywood Attorney at LawMichael Prior Shawn Coulson International LawyersMilton Psyllides Eversheds Law FirmKathy Smith Slaughter & MayMichael Ste<strong>in</strong>er Denton Wilde SaptePhilip Wood Allen & OveryJohn Young Eversheds Low Firm193


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>194United StatesDavid Adk<strong>in</strong>s Federal Reserve BoardRichard Broude Law Offices of Richard F. BroudePeter Chaffetz Clifford ChanceLarry Haas Baker & McKenzieCharles Kerr Morrison & FoersterErik L<strong>in</strong>dauer Sullivan & CromwellStephen Raslavich United States <strong>Bank</strong>ruptcy CourtRichard Spillenkothen Federal Reserve BoardUruguayMaria Elena Abo Muxi & AsociadosConrado Hughes Delgado Hughes & HughesNoelia Eiras Hughes & HughesDaniel Ferrere Ferrere LamaisonDiego Galante Galante & Mart<strong>in</strong>sManuel González Rocco Banco Central del UruguayRosario Garat Super<strong>in</strong>tendencia de Instituciones deIntermediación F<strong>in</strong>ancieraMarcela Hughes Hughes & HughesMercedes Jimenez de Arrechaga Guyer & RegulesEstudio Jurídico Muxí & AsociadosElbio Kuster Bado Kuster Zerb<strong>in</strong>o & RachettiJose Lorieto Clear<strong>in</strong>g de <strong>in</strong>formesMatilde Milicevic Clear<strong>in</strong>g de InformesAlejandro Miller Artola Guyer & RegulesRicardo Olivera Olivera & DelpiazzoVeronica Raffo Ferrere LamaisonBruno Sant<strong>in</strong> Estudio Jurídico Muxí & AsociadosAlvaro Tarabal Guyer & RegulesUzbekistanSanjarbek Abdukhalilov Denton Wilde SapteSanjar Abduhalilov Denton Wilde SapteDaniel Ferrere Ferrere LamaisonR. Gulyamov Central <strong>Bank</strong> of the Republic of UzbekistanThomas Johnson Denton Wilde SapteTatiana Lopaeva Tashkent City Economic CourtVeronica Raffo Ferrere LamaisonVakhid Saparov Baker & McKenzieSofiya Shaikhrazieva Denton Wilde SapteUmarov Abdurakhim Vakhidovich Uzbek Association of <strong>Bank</strong>sMarla Valdez Denton Wilde SapteVenezuela, RBCarol<strong>in</strong>a Armada ITP Consult<strong>in</strong>gGertrudiz Bonilla Romero-Muci & AsociadosCarlos Dom<strong>in</strong>guez Hoet Pelaez Castillo & DuqueRossanna D’Onza Baker & McKenzieGustavo Muci Romero-Muci & AsociadosIrv<strong>in</strong>g Ochoa Super<strong>in</strong>tendencia de Bancos y Otras InstitucionesF<strong>in</strong>ancierasFernando Pelaez-Pier Hoet Pelaez Castillo & DuqueCarlos Plaza Baker & McKenzieVictor Sanchez Leal Bentata AbogadosPatricia Wallis ITP Consult<strong>in</strong>gVietnamFred Burke Baker & McKenzieUan Pham Cong State <strong>Bank</strong> of VietnamFlorent Fassier Gide Loyrette NouelNguyen Viet Ha Russ<strong>in</strong> & VecchiNgo Thanh Hang PricewaterhouseCoopersJohn Hick<strong>in</strong> Johnson Stokes & MasterRichard Irw<strong>in</strong> PricewaterhouseCoopersNguyen Hoang Kim Oanh Baker & McKenzieIan Lewis Johnson Stokes & MasterHan Mahn Tien Concetti Consult<strong>in</strong>gJohn Malcolm Hick<strong>in</strong> Johnson Stokes & MasterPham Nghiem Xuan Bac Vision & Associates Investment& Management ConsultantsTran Thi Thanh Ha Baker & McKenzieGiles Thomas Cooper Baker & McKenzieYemen, Rep. ofSheikh Khalid Abdullah Law Offices of Sheikh Tariq AbdullahAdel Adham Adham & AssociatesAnwar Adham Adham & AssociatesJamal Adimi Jamal Adimi Law OfficesAbdalla Al-Meqbeli Abdalla Al-Meqbeli & AssociatesAbdula Al-Olofi Central <strong>Bank</strong> of YemenKater<strong>in</strong>a Miltiadou MecosHonorable Mohamed Jaffer Kassim M<strong>in</strong>istry of JusticeZambiaMoses Chatulika <strong>Bank</strong> of ZambiaMwelwa Chibesakunda Corpus Globe AdvocatesElias Chipimo Corpus Globe AdvocatesAbdul Dudhia Musa Dudhia & Co.Pixie L<strong>in</strong>da Mwila Kasonde-Yangailo PricewaterhouseCoopersN.K. Mubonda Dhkemp & Co. Law FirmMorris Mulomba <strong>Bank</strong> of ZambiaKanti Patel Christopher Russell Cook & Co.Solly Patel Christopher Russell Cook & Co.ZimbabweRoger Chadwick Scanlen & HoldernessInnocent Chagonda Atherstone & CookL<strong>in</strong>dsay Cook Atherstone & CookC.L. Dhliwayo Reserve <strong>Bank</strong> of ZimbabweStephen Gwasira Reserve <strong>Bank</strong> of ZimbabweBrenda Wood Kahari B.W. Kahari Law OfficesPeter Lloyd Gill Godlonton & GerransP<strong>in</strong>iel Mkushi Sawyer & MkushiSternford Moyo Scanlen & HoldernessN.K. Mubonda D.H. Kemp and CompanyKanti Patel Christopher Russell Cook & Co.Alwyn Pichanick W<strong>in</strong>tertons Law FirmYuezhen Wei PricewaterhouseCoopers


<strong>Do<strong>in</strong>g</strong> <strong>Bus<strong>in</strong>ess</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>2004</strong>:Understand<strong>in</strong>g Regulation isthe first <strong>in</strong> a series of annualreports <strong>in</strong>vestigat<strong>in</strong>g the scopeand manner of regulations thatenhance bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity andthose that constra<strong>in</strong> it. Newquantitative <strong>in</strong>dicators onbus<strong>in</strong>ess regulations and theirenforcement can be comparedacross more than 130 countries,and over time. The <strong>in</strong>dicatorsare used to analyze economicoutcomes and identify whatreforms have worked, where,and why.For more <strong>in</strong>formation, visit ourwebsite at:http://rru.worldbank.org/do<strong>in</strong>gbus<strong>in</strong>essISBN 0-8213-5341-1

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!