10.07.2015 Views

histofthought1

histofthought1

histofthought1

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

The Christian Middle Ages 49More specifically, Thomas Chabham, despite his insistence on every pennyof the just price, observed correctly that merchants performed the function oftaking goods from areas of abundance and distributing them to areas of deficiency.Albert the Great repeated this insight later in the thirteenth century.If trading is a useful and even necessary activity, it follows that profits formaintaining such activity are justifiable. Hence the theologians reiterated thetwelfth century doctrine of the merchant being allowed to gain profits for thesupport of himself and his family. To the needs justification, the twelfthcentury theologians added the lawful nature of making profits in order to giveto charity. The Franciscan Alexander of Hales was perhaps the first to call it ajust and pious motive for trading to perform works of charity and mercy. Itwas unworthy, however - echoing the Huguccian doctrine - to gain profitsfor the sake of avarice or endless and insatiable cupidity.If the labourer in the Christian tradition was 'worthy of his hire' (Luke10:7), then profits from the useful activities of the merchant could be justifiedas covering his 'labour', or rather his labour and expenses as the jurists hadalready declared. Aquinas considered the earnings of the merchant a stipendfor labour. For the theologians, 'labour' consisted of several types: transportinggoods; storage and care; and - as had come in with the thirteenth centurycanonists - the assumption of risk. Thus mercantile profits were a payment orreward for the merchant's labour of transportation and storage, and his assumptionof risk. The risk factor was stressed particularly by Alexander ofHales and St Thomas Aquinas. It should be noted, in contrast to many laterhistorians, that the purpose of the jurists' and theologians' discussions oflabour, cost, and risk was not to use these factors in determining the just price(which was simply the current common price) but to justify the profits obtainedby the merchant.Robert of Cour~on was the first thirteenth century theologian to add anatural law angle to the traditional though flimsily grounded theologicaldenunciations of usury. Cour~on simply appropriated the canonist Huguccio'ssophistical moral distinction between a lease and a loan, with the formerbeing licit and the latter illicit because ownership of the money had temporarilybeen shifted to the borrower. More influential was fellow Parisian theologianWilliam ofAuxerre, who added a string of new fallacies to the mountingintensity of the Church's assault upon usury. William ranted that usury wasintrinsically evil and monstrous, without really explaining why; he also didone better on the standard likening of usury to theft by actually comparingusury to murder, to the detriment of the former. Killing, he said can sometimesbe licit, since only certain forms of killing are sinful, but usury is sinfuleverywhere and can never be licit. Since usury, according to William ofAuxerre, is sinful by its very nature, this made it a violation of the natural lawin addition to its other alleged iniquities.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!