10.07.2015 Views

histofthought1

histofthought1

histofthought1

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

The Christian Middle Ages 45renting of a good or buying cheap in order to sell dear as not being cases ofusury. Huguccio's tortured moral distinction maintained that a commodatum- a rental contract that transferred only the use of a good - was somehowmorally very different from a mutuum - a pure loan where ownership wastransferred for a time. Charging for a lease, a commodatum was all rightbecause the owner retains ownership and charges for the use of his owngood; but somehow it becomes sinful when a lender charges for the use of agood which he no longer (temporarily) owns. Profits on trade, too, could belegitimate and lawful as a reward for risk, but interest on a loan - where therisk is borne by the borrower and not the lender - was always usury.The later decretalists, attempting to combat practices of merchants in disguisingusury in various contracts, pressed on to condemn such contracts as'implicit usury', provided, as we have seen in treatment of sales contracts,that there is no uncertainty on the future price in the minds of buyer andseller. The early thirteenth century canonist Alanus Anglicus declared that ifthere was uncertainty in such a contract, and buyer and seller stood equalchance to gain or lose, usury did not exist. Providing the first real, if small,loophole in the sweeping prohibition against usury, Anglicus explained thatthis form of implicit usury could exist only in the mind and could not besubject to legal enforcement. This uncertainty loophole was widened slightlyin the Decretals of Gregory IX.On the other hand, the canonists persisted in cracking down on evasions ofthe usury ban which the market kept creatively inventing. Contracts providingfor deferred payment on a sale were treated with suspicion, and very highprices in such a contract were taken by the canonists to prove intent tocommit usury beyond a reasonable doubt. The Decretals also went so far asto condemn creditors charging interest for loans to travelling merchants, eventhough the canonists realized that the interest was a direct compensation forrisks. Although canonists after Innocent IV began to talk of risks justifyingprofits, so that a profit on risky investments was considered perfectly justified,any interest on a pure loan (or mutuum) was condemned as usury despitereasonably mitigating circumstances.The usury prohibition was the tragic flaw in the economic views of medievaljurists and theologians. The prohibition was economically irrational,depriving marginal borrowers and high credit risks of any borrowed capitalwhatever. It had no groundwork in natural law and virtually none in Old orNew Testament teachings. And yet it was clung to fiercely throughout theMiddle Ages, so that jurists and theologians had to engage in ingenious andartful twists in reasoning in order to make exceptions from the prohibitionand to accommodate the growing practice of lending money and charginginterest on a loan. And yet the medievalists, especially the later philosophersand theologians, had a fascinating and important point: for what was the

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!