10.07.2015 Views

histofthought1

histofthought1

histofthought1

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

500 Economic thought before Adam SmithCadet Corps at St Petersburg, and educating the future Czar Nicholas I andhis younger brother in Smithian political economy. Helping to bringSmithianism to Russia, von Storch wrote, in German, a nine-volume historicaland statistical work on Russia at the end of the eighteenth century (1797­1803), and later wrote a treatise on economics in French, Cours d'economiepolitique (1815). The book was published in St Petersburg for the educationof the future czar. A moderate Smithian, von Storch sensibly rejected the ideathat some labour was 'unproductive', and dabbled in a form of pre-Keynesianincome analysis in his last work in 1824.17.6 The Smithian conquest of economic thoughtBy the turn of the nineteenth century, the views and doctrines ofAdam Smithhad swept the board of European opinion, though they had scarcely beenembodied in political institutions. Even in France, as will be seen in thesecond volume of this series, the pre-Smithian subjective utility-scarcityapproach to value, as well as the stress on entrepreneurship in the market,continued to be prominent, but only under the cloak of a proclaimed devotionto Adam Smith as the founder of economic theory and free market policy. Inthe hands of James Mill and Ricardo in England, of J.B. Say in France, andthroughout the rest of the Continent, Adam Smith would be treated as theembodiment of the new discipline of 'political economy'.There were advantages but probably greater disadvantages to this Smithiandominance over economic thought after the 1790s. On the one hand, it meantat least a moderate appreciation of and devotion to freedom of trade at homeand abroad. Even more solidly, it meant a keen understanding and a steadfastadherence to the virtues of saving and investment and a refusal to indulge inproto-Keynesian worry about 'hoarding' or underconsumption. Moreover,this adherence to what Schumpeter calls the Turgot-Smith view of savingand investment also meant a determined opposition to wildly inflationaryschemes of expansion of money and credit.On the other hand, there were dire costs to economic thought in thisSmithian takeover. Even on the monetary front, Smith had gone against hiseighteenth century colleagues in adopting crucial aspects of John Law'sinflationary doctrine, in particular praising expansion of bank credit andmoney within a specie standard framework. In this way, Smith paved the wayfor later apologetics on behalf of the Bank of England and its generation ofcredit expansion.More fatefully, Smith totally set back price and value theory, and led it intoa fateful cuI de sac, from which it took a century to recover; in some respects,it has never fully recovered. At the root of Smith's drastic changes in theorywas undoubtedly his Calvinist contempt for luxury consumer spending. Hence,only work on material goods (i.e. material capital goods) was productive.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!