10.07.2015 Views

histofthought1

histofthought1

histofthought1

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

144 Economic thought before Adam Smithproductive as the goods bought with it, he hedges his defence of usurysufficiently so that his views are little different from many others. He doesmaintain that the charge of interest on a loan per se is unjust, but ingeniouslypoints out that a lender charges for the utility of the money rather than for themoney itself. But Molinaeus attacks the 'cruel usuries' permitted by lucrumcessans, and maintains with Calvin that interest may not be charged for loansto the poor. (One wonders that if such a rule were enforced, who in the worldwould ever lend to the poor, and would the poor then be better off by beingdeprived of all credit?)Indeed, it seems that Molinaeus' main contribution was to blacken unjustlythe name of poor Conrad Summenhart, a cruel injustice that would last forfour centuries. In an act obviously motivated by malice toward scholasticism,Molinaeus took the great Summenhart's arguments against the usury ban andtwisted them to make the German theologian a particularly doltish advocateof the prohibition. He took Summenhart's initial arguments for the prohibition,which he had stated in order to knock down, claimed that they wereSummenhart's own, and then plagiarized Summenhart's critique of thesearguments without acknowledgment. As a result of this shabby mendacity, asProfessor Noonan points out, since 'Du Moulin's writings have alone becomefamous, Conrad [Summenhart] has appeared to posterity only as Du Moulincaricatures him', i.e.. 'as a particularly obstinate and strangely stupid defenderof the usury prohibition'.10The honour of putting the final boot to the usury prohibition belongs to theseventeenth century classicist and Dutch Calvinist, Claude Saumaise (latinizedname, Claudius Salmasius) (1588-1653). In several works published inLeyden, beginning with De usuris tiber in 1630 and continuing to 1645,Salmasius finished off this embarrassing remnant of the mountainous errorsof the past. His forte was not so much in coining new theoretical argumentsas in finally willing to be consistent. In short, Salmasius trenchantly pointedout that money-lending was a business like any other, and like other businesseswas entitled to charge a market price. He did make the importanttheoretical point, however, that, as in any other part of the market, if thenumber of usurers multiplies, the price of money or interest will be drivendown by the competition. So that if one doesn't like high interest rates, themore usurers the better!Salmasius also had the courage to point out that there were no validarguments against usury, either by divine or natural law. The Jews onlyprohibited usury against other Jews, and this was a political and tribal actrather than an expression of a moral theory about an economic transaction.As for Jesus, he taught nothing at all about civil polity or economic transactions.This leaves the only ecclesiastical law against usury that of the pope,and why should a Calvinist obey the pope? Salmasius also took some de-

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!