10.07.2015 Views

histofthought1

histofthought1

histofthought1

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

126 Economic thought before Adam SmithThus, for Lessius, the price for a lack of money is established on organizedloan markets. But to the extent that a loan market exists, there is no need tojustify each merchant's loan on the basis of his particular opportunity cost ordeprivation of funds. That price, which becomes the just price, is set on theloan market. As Lessius puts it:Moreover, any merchant seems able to demand this price... even though there isno gain of his that stops because of his loan. This is the just price for the privationof money among merchants; for the just price of an article or obligation in anycommunity is that which is put upon it by that community in good faith for thesake of the common good in view of all the circumstances...Therefore, even ifthrough the privation of money for a year there is no gain of mine that stops andno risk of capital, because such a price for just causes has been put upon thisprivation, I may demand it just as the rest do.With carentia pecuniae, therefore, Leonard Lessius delivered the finalblow to smash the usury prohibition, while unfortunately still retaining theprohibition in a formal sense. It is no wonder that Professor Noonan, thegreat scholar of the scholastics on usury, holds Lessius to be 'the theologianwhose views on usury most decidedly mark the arrival of a new era. Morethan any predecessor he would probably have felt completely at ease in themodern financial world. '6The last Salamancan was the Jesuit Cardinal Juan de Lugo (1583-1660).De Lugo takes the Salamancans into the seventeenth century, the century ofthe decline of Spanish power in Europe. After studying law and theology atSalamanca, de Lugo went to Rome to teach at the great Jesuit College. Afterteaching theology in Rome for 22 years, de Lugo was made a cardinal andbecame a member of various influential Church commissions in Rome. Alearned and comprehensive theoretician, de Lugo has been called the greatestmoral theologian since Aquinas. Author of a book on psychology and anotheron physics, de Lugo's masterwork in the area of law and economics was DeJustitia et Jure, published in 1642. This work went through numerous editionsduring the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, its last edition havingappeared as late as 1893.In his theory of value, this culminating work of the Salamancan Schooldisplayed a subtle and advanced subjective utility explanation. The prices ofgoods, de Lugo pointed out, fluctuate 'on account of their utility in respect ofhuman need, and then only on account of estimation; for jewels are much lessuseful than corn in the house, and yet their price is much higher'. Here deLugo, once again, comes very close to the late nineteenth century marginalutility explanation of value, and to solving the value paradox. Corn is higherthan jewellery in use value, but is cheaper in price. The answer to thisparadox is that subjective estimates or valuations differ from objective use-

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!