10.07.2015 Views

histofthought1

histofthought1

histofthought1

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

The late Spanish scholastics 103could well be considered, returned to the old, nearly forgotten laissez-faireRoman law tradition of free individual bargaining as providing the just price.For in this situation, Vitoria maintained, the price had to be settled by theexchanging parties themselves. Vitoria, however, then added a curious distinctionbetween luxury and non-luxury goods. Luxuries could be sold for a'fancy price', since the buyer pays the high price voluntarily and out of hisfree will. Why this 'free will' should disappear with non-luxury items Vitoriaunfortunately does not explain.Vitoria's most eminent student and fellow theologian at Salamanca was theDominican Domingo de Soto (1494-1560). Born in Segovia of comfortablebut not wealthy parents, de Soto studied at the University of Alcala nearMadrid and then went to Paris, where he studied under Vitoria, and laterbecame a professor. Returning to Spain, de Soto became professor of metaphysicsat Alcala, and then entered the Dominican Order, joining his mentoras a theology professor at Salamanca in 1532. Though a shy personality, deSoto was repeatedly involved in university administration, and was severaltimes prior of the college of Estaban in the University. De Soto's work inphysics is also considered outstanding.In 1545 the Emperor Charles V honoured de Soto by naming him as hisrepresentative at the great council of Trent, the mighty council of the CatholieCounter-Reformation. Soon de Soto became confessor to the emperor, butgave it up in a few years to return to his professorship at Salamanca. DeSoto's fame rested on his treatise De justitia et jure, published in 1553 andbased on lectures given originally at Salamanca in 1540-41. De Justitia etjure was reprinted no less than 27 times before the end of the century, andwas read and quoted by jurists and moralists until the mid-eighteenth century.Unfortunately, on economies de Soto was a reactionary thinker, and set backsome of the liberal gains of the previous scholastics. Thus, while de Sotoconceded that 'the price of goods is not determined by their nature but by themeasure in which they serve the needs of mankind', this utility analysis wasweakened by vague concessions to the 'labour, trouble, and risk' involved in asale. Worse than that, de Soto was not content to concede the propriety ofgovernment fixing the price of goods and letting it go at that. Instead, hedeclared flatly that a fixed price is always superior to the market price, and thatideally all prices should be fixed by the state. And even lacking such control,prices, for de Soto, should be set 'by the opinion of prudent and fair-mindedmen' (whoever they might be!) who have nothing to do with any transactions.They should not be determined by the free bargaining of the buyers and sellersinvolved. Thus de Soto, more than any other scholastic thinker, called forstatism rather than market determination of price.On foreign exchange, de Soto's influence was confusing, cutting both forand against that market. In its favour, he contributed perhaps the first cogent

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!