10.07.2015 Views

histofthought1

histofthought1

histofthought1

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

From Middle Ages to Renaissance 91gave, would not buy; nor would a seller sell, unless he hoped for profit fromthe price'.But the most comprehensive and systematic assault on the usury prohibitioncame from Gabriel Biel's most distinguished student and his successor inthe theology chair at the University ofTiibingen, Conrad Summenhart (1465­1511), who had also been a student at the University of Paris. The critiquecame in Summenhart's massive Treatise on Contracts (Tractatus deContractibus) (1499).Summenhart's contribution was twofold: first, in enormously widening allthe possible exceptions to the usury prohibition, e.g. the census and lucrumcessans; and second, in launching a blistering direct assault on all the timehonouredarguments against whatever usury contracts remained. On the first,Summenhart developed the argument for insured or guaranteed partnershipsfar more subtly and extensively than before. He also widened the lucrumcessans exception far more than anyone had ever done. Money is fruitful,Summenhart declared boldly, it is the merchant's tool, which he can makefruitful by the use of his labour. Consequently, the merchant should becompensated for loss of the use of his money just as a farmer should berecompensed for the loss of his fields. Unfortunately, however, Summenhart'swidening of lucrum cessans was still limited, as among the earlier scholastics,to loans made out of charity.The boldest loosening of the usury bonds by Summenhart was in his radicaldefence of the widest possible interpretation of census contracts. HereSummenhart justified many of the credit transactions then used in Germany.Coupled with his development of the idea of the changeable value of money,this meant 'the emptying of the usury prohibition of all practical significance' .7Money, declared Summenhart, may licitly be trafficked in for profit. Furthermore,he asserted that a census is not a (sinful) loan because the right to moneyis a good of another kind than the money exchanged. But in that case,Summenhart asks himself, couldn't a usurer say the same thing, and simplystate that the right to money he was demanding in exchange was a good of adifferent kind than the money loaned? Astonishingly, Summenhart replied, thiswas all right, provided that the lender did not intend this to be usury, and washimself really convinced that he was buying the right to money which was adifferent good than the money itself. But if usury was only subjective intentionand not the objective fact of a loan charging interest, then there was noobjective way of identifying or enforcing the prohibition against usury! In thisway alone, Summenhart effectively destroyed the prohibition against usury.But this was not all. For Summenhart explicitly declared that the purchaseby someone of a discounted debt is not a usurious loan because it is only thepurchase of a right to money. The purchase of a debt was licit in the sameway as a census. Furthermore, the 'purchase of a debt' could be that of a

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!