Recovery Plan for the Northern Spotted Owl - DRAFT

Recovery Plan for the Northern Spotted Owl - DRAFT Recovery Plan for the Northern Spotted Owl - DRAFT

10.07.2015 Views

Two concepts are useful for understanding the employment effects of owlconservation measures. One is the relationship among the various factors thataffect the decisions of businesses with employment directly related to timberharvest, such as sawmills. The key factors of interest are the supply of timberand labor and the demand for timber. The second is the relationship betweendirect employment in timber cutting and milling and employment in relatedindustries and in the economy as a whole.Figure H. 15 shows the factors that affect a sawmill's management decisions.The mill manager determines the rate of lumber production, the rate of timberpurchases, and the amount of labor and other inputs it needs for that rate ofproduction. These decisions are affected by the price of lumber, the price oftimber, and the prices of labor and other inputs. The demand for workers inthe timber industry results from the decisions of many mills and other businessesinvolved in the harvesting, transportation, and processing of timber.The price of timber provides the connection between the availability of timberas represented by the timber supply curve and the rate of production andlevels of employment in timber businesses. As shown in Figure H.5, the priceof timber is represented by the intersection between the demand curve fortimber and the supply curve.The demand curve for timber shows the rate of timber consumption at eachtimber price. The demand for timber is derived from the demand for lumber. Ifthere are many firms producing lumber, none can affect lumber prices. Eachsawmill must sell its lumber at the market price. At a given lumber price, eachsawmill's profits and production rate depend on the firm's costs. The price oftimber is an important factor in the total costs of producing lumber. Whentimber prices increase, profits and the rate of production decrease.Some firms are efficient enough to be able to absorb an increase in the price oftimber and continue operating, though at lower output. Firms that weremarginally profitable before an increase in timber prices will be forced to close.Thus when the price of timber in a region is higher, the total output of lumberwill be lower.To minimize costs, a firm would normally adjust its mix of inputs whenever aninput price changed significantly. Often, increased use of some inputs canoffset the reduction in use of an input whose price has increased. In sawmilloperations, however, there is little flexibility to alter the amount of timberneeded to make a board foot of lumber, at least in the short run (the periodduring which capital equipment cannot be changed). Therefore, to simplify thediscussion, it is reasonable to assume that for each rate of lumber productionthere is a corresponding rate of timber purchases by the mill. Furthermore, foreach rate of lumber production, there is a profit maximizing employment level.Thus, direct employment in the timber and wood products industries is higherwhen timber prices are lower. If restrictions in the availability of timber forharvest shift the supply curve to the left as in Figure H.5, timber prices will behigher. As a result, lumber output and direct employment will be lower.The level of output in a region's timber industry also affects employmentoutside of that industry. Timber businesses buy goods and services from avariety of firms in other sectors of the economy, from equipment manufacturingto accounting. At lower levels of output, the timber industry uses less ofthese goods and services. Firms in other sectors must reduce their levels ofoutput to avoid producing goods that cannot be sold. Workers are laid off ornew hiring is deferred when such reductions occur. Thus changes in output inthe timber and lumber industries induce changes in employment in othersectors. In addition to the direct employment effects of a change in timberavailability, there are induced employment effects in the related industries.572

Further employment effects, called indirect effects, occur because of thechanges in income levels that are caused by changes in employment. Indirecteffects result from the reduced consumer spending that is caused whenunemployment reduces the income people have to spend. The total employmenteffects of reducing timber availability include direct, induced, and indirecteffects.5. Effects on the Value of Capital Assets.The two forns of asset most strongly affected by the reduction of timberharvest are sawmills and homes. Home asset losses result from the decline inincome of many residents in a community. Losses in the value of housingcause a transfer of wealth that can seriously affect people's lives, but suchlosses do not represent a significant loss to the output of the national economy.Losses in the value of real estate also cause a reduction in the tax base of localgovernments. When mills close because they cannot make a profit at thehigher timber prices that will result from owl conservation, the mill equipmentusually is scrapped. Capital equipment of this sort is valued for the profits itcan yield. Once the profits disappear, the value of the capital becomes negligible.Although the resulting loss in mill asset values reflects a loss in economicoutput in the national economy, that loss is already accounted for bythe reduction in timber consumers' surplus (that is, profits) discussed earlier.Thus, separate estimates of housing and mill asset losses are of interestprimarily because of their effect on the local or regional economy but theyshould not be added to the estimates of the underlying losses in the componentsof income that cause them.C. Estimating Economic Effects of Implementing theRecovery PlanAs noted earlier, the FWS, with assistance from the Forest Service and BLM,conducted an economic analysis of the critical habitat designation for thenorthern spotted owl (USDI 1992). As a part of this analysis it developedmethods to estimate the loss of federal timber harvest from various measuresto protect owl habitat. It developed methods for estimating the employmenteffects of the resulting harvest reductions in each of the affected counties. Italso developed methods to estimate the net effect on the U.S. Treasury and onthe timber revenues shared with the county governments. The analysisprovided a comparison of the effects of the original forest plans, the implementationof the ISC strategy and the effect of Endangered Species Act protectionsof the owl, including the designated critical habitat. To provide comparablepreliminary estimates for the draft recovery plan, the ISC strategy, and thecritical habitat designation, it was decided that the same methods of analysis.with some adjustments appropriate to the recovery plan, would be applied toestimate the economic effects of implementing the recovery plan.The methods used for making preliminary estimates of the effects of implementingthe recovery plan are summarized here.1. Estimating the Loss of Benefitsfrom Federal TimberHarvest.The estimation of the loss in the economic benefits from the federal timberharvest that will be foregone to provide owl habitat (Area A in Figure H. 13) isstraightforward. An estimate of the change in the annual harvest is multiplied573

Two concepts are useful <strong>for</strong> understanding <strong>the</strong> employment effects of owlconservation measures. One is <strong>the</strong> relationship among <strong>the</strong> various factors thataffect <strong>the</strong> decisions of businesses with employment directly related to timberharvest, such as sawmills. The key factors of interest are <strong>the</strong> supply of timberand labor and <strong>the</strong> demand <strong>for</strong> timber. The second is <strong>the</strong> relationship betweendirect employment in timber cutting and milling and employment in relatedindustries and in <strong>the</strong> economy as a whole.Figure H. 15 shows <strong>the</strong> factors that affect a sawmill's management decisions.The mill manager determines <strong>the</strong> rate of lumber production, <strong>the</strong> rate of timberpurchases, and <strong>the</strong> amount of labor and o<strong>the</strong>r inputs it needs <strong>for</strong> that rate ofproduction. These decisions are affected by <strong>the</strong> price of lumber, <strong>the</strong> price oftimber, and <strong>the</strong> prices of labor and o<strong>the</strong>r inputs. The demand <strong>for</strong> workers in<strong>the</strong> timber industry results from <strong>the</strong> decisions of many mills and o<strong>the</strong>r businessesinvolved in <strong>the</strong> harvesting, transportation, and processing of timber.The price of timber provides <strong>the</strong> connection between <strong>the</strong> availability of timberas represented by <strong>the</strong> timber supply curve and <strong>the</strong> rate of production andlevels of employment in timber businesses. As shown in Figure H.5, <strong>the</strong> priceof timber is represented by <strong>the</strong> intersection between <strong>the</strong> demand curve <strong>for</strong>timber and <strong>the</strong> supply curve.The demand curve <strong>for</strong> timber shows <strong>the</strong> rate of timber consumption at eachtimber price. The demand <strong>for</strong> timber is derived from <strong>the</strong> demand <strong>for</strong> lumber. If<strong>the</strong>re are many firms producing lumber, none can affect lumber prices. Eachsawmill must sell its lumber at <strong>the</strong> market price. At a given lumber price, eachsawmill's profits and production rate depend on <strong>the</strong> firm's costs. The price oftimber is an important factor in <strong>the</strong> total costs of producing lumber. Whentimber prices increase, profits and <strong>the</strong> rate of production decrease.Some firms are efficient enough to be able to absorb an increase in <strong>the</strong> price oftimber and continue operating, though at lower output. Firms that weremarginally profitable be<strong>for</strong>e an increase in timber prices will be <strong>for</strong>ced to close.Thus when <strong>the</strong> price of timber in a region is higher, <strong>the</strong> total output of lumberwill be lower.To minimize costs, a firm would normally adjust its mix of inputs whenever aninput price changed significantly. Often, increased use of some inputs canoffset <strong>the</strong> reduction in use of an input whose price has increased. In sawmilloperations, however, <strong>the</strong>re is little flexibility to alter <strong>the</strong> amount of timberneeded to make a board foot of lumber, at least in <strong>the</strong> short run (<strong>the</strong> periodduring which capital equipment cannot be changed). There<strong>for</strong>e, to simplify <strong>the</strong>discussion, it is reasonable to assume that <strong>for</strong> each rate of lumber production<strong>the</strong>re is a corresponding rate of timber purchases by <strong>the</strong> mill. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>for</strong>each rate of lumber production, <strong>the</strong>re is a profit maximizing employment level.Thus, direct employment in <strong>the</strong> timber and wood products industries is higherwhen timber prices are lower. If restrictions in <strong>the</strong> availability of timber <strong>for</strong>harvest shift <strong>the</strong> supply curve to <strong>the</strong> left as in Figure H.5, timber prices will behigher. As a result, lumber output and direct employment will be lower.The level of output in a region's timber industry also affects employmentoutside of that industry. Timber businesses buy goods and services from avariety of firms in o<strong>the</strong>r sectors of <strong>the</strong> economy, from equipment manufacturingto accounting. At lower levels of output, <strong>the</strong> timber industry uses less of<strong>the</strong>se goods and services. Firms in o<strong>the</strong>r sectors must reduce <strong>the</strong>ir levels ofoutput to avoid producing goods that cannot be sold. Workers are laid off ornew hiring is deferred when such reductions occur. Thus changes in output in<strong>the</strong> timber and lumber industries induce changes in employment in o<strong>the</strong>rsectors. In addition to <strong>the</strong> direct employment effects of a change in timberavailability, <strong>the</strong>re are induced employment effects in <strong>the</strong> related industries.572

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!